Varieties of Democratic Diffusion: Colonial Networks

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Varieties of Democratic Diffusion: Colonial Networks"

Transcription

1 INSTITUTE Varieties of Democratic Diffusion: Colonial Networks Michael Coppedge, Lucía Tiscornia and Staffan I. Lindberg March 2015 Working Paper SERIES 2015:2 THE VARIETIES OF DEMOCRACY INSTITUTE

2 Varieties of Democracy (V-Dem) is a new approach to the conceptualization and measurement of democracy. It is co-hosted by the University of Gothenburg and University of Notre Dame. With a V-Dem Institute at University of Gothenburg that comprises almost ten staff members, and a project team across the world with four Principal Investigators, fifteen Project Managers, 30+ Regional Managers, 170 Country Coordinators, Research Assistants, and 2,500 Country Experts, the V-Dem project is one of the largest-ever social science research-oriented data collection programs. Please address comments and/or queries for information to: V-Dem Institute Department of Political Science University of Gothenburg Sprängkullsgatan 19, PO Box 711 SE Gothenburg Sweden contact@v-dem.net V-Dem Working Papers are available in electronic format at Copyright 2015 by authors. All rights reserved.

3 Varieties of Democratic Diffusion: Colonial Networks Michael Coppedge University of Notre Dame Lucía Tiscornia University of Notre Dame Staffan I. Lindberg University of Gothenburg Paper prepared for delivery at the meeting of the International Studies Association, New Orleans, February 18-21, 2015 This research project was supported by Riksbankens Jubileumsfond, Grant M :1, PI: Staffan I. Lindberg, V-Dem Institute, University of Gothenburg, Sweden; by Swedish Research Council, PI: Staffan I. Lindberg, V-Dem Institute, University of Gothenburg, Sweden & Jan Teorell, Department of Political Science, Lund University, Sweden; and by Knut & Alice Wallenberg Foundation to Wallenberg Academy Fellow Staffan I. Lindberg, V-Dem Institute, University of Gothenburg, Sweden; the foreign ministries of Sweden, Canada, and Denmark; the research councils of Sweden, Norway, and Denmark; the National Science Foundation; the Universities of Gothenburg and Notre Dame and the Catholic University of Chile; International IDEA; and the Quality of Government Institute at the University of Gothenburg. 1

4 Abstract No man is an island; some countries are, but even so, no country can be regarded as completely self-determined and unaffected by the world beyond its borders (Coppedge 2012, 301). This is a widely accepted proposition backed by many empirical studies. Yet stating that countries are in some way affected by external forces only hints at the innumerable possible pathways of influence, which have only begun to be explored. This paper builds on Brinks and Coppedge (2006), which reported that geographic neighbors tend to converge toward a shared level of democracy. Here we look at a completely distinct set of networks: that linking colonies and occupied states to their colonizers or occupiers. We find that convergence in levels of liberal democracy is also the dominant tendency in colonial networks when diffusion relationships are properly specified. 2

5 Why Convergence? Almost all diffusion hypotheses that have been tested have been confirmed. There is, for example, evidence of strong policy diffusion, leading to waves of welfare-state expansion, trade opening, privatization, taxation, and other policies (Brooks 2012, Collier and Messick 1975, Madrid 2003, Meseguer 2005, Simmons and Elkins 2004). Although they are large, complex, and static phenomena, even political regimes, or degrees of democracy and non-democracy, have been shown to be associated with trends outside their borders. It is probably premature to treat these as causal relationships, as the mechanisms of diffusion are diffuse and hard to pin down when interstate interactions take place at elite, institutional, and mass levels. However, we can observe different patterns of diffusion that we expect to be generated by different hard-to-observe mechanisms, and this can help us rule out some mechanisms in favor of others. For example, the spread of liberal democracy among geographic neighbors calls for closer attention to ideas and resources that flow most heavily within regions and between neighbors: norms, information, population, and commodities. Many studies have tried to measure these channels this by including regional dummy variables or the mean democracy level in a region among their explanatory variables (Bollen 1983, Hadenius 1992, Lipset et al. 1993; Mainwaring and Pérez Liñán 2013, Przeworski and Limongi 1997), but such measures are too blunt to distinguish external influences from shared domestic influences such as language, religion, or level of economic development. Brinks and Coppedge (2006) focused more precisely on immediate neighbors. They also leveraged information about the gaps in democracy levels among neighbors: the more different neighbors levels of democracy were, the more strongly each would be pressured to be like the other. If they were at the same level, there would be no pressure at all. They therefore were able to conclude that diffusion mechanisms of some kind produce convergence in democracy scores. Pevehouse (2002) focused more narrowly on membership in regional organizations, and found that the higher the proportion of democratic members of the organization, the more likely other members were to become and remain democracies. Several analyses have found some evidence that countries that are linked by trade, investment, or flows of information or population tend to have or move toward similar levels of democracy (Rudra 2005, Simmons and Elkins 2004). Levitsky and Way (2006) argue that competitive authoritarian regimes are more likely to democratize if they have strong trade, finance, 3

6 transportation, and information linkages to the West (and if the West chooses to exercise its influence). Others have noted that democracies tend to form political and military alliances with other democracies and that such alliances may reinforce and stabilize members political regimes (Layne 1994). Almost all of the hypotheses that have been tested predict convergence toward democracy: the more countries trade (with the West), the closer they are (to the West), and the more they share information (with the West), the more likely they are to be democratic. The only diffusion hypotheses that have found evidence for something like divergence concern colonial rule. This factor is usually operationalized simply as a series of dummy variables for having been colony of the United Kingdom, Spain, France, or other powers, and this is used to predict how democratic a country is, whether it is democratic, or how likely it is to become democratic or to break down (Barro 1999, Bollen and Jackman 1985, Burkhart 1997, Gassebner et al. 2009, Lipset et al. 1993, Muller 1995). Sometimes the length of colonial rule or the years elapsed since independence are factored in. One of the best studies, Bernhard et al. (2004) found that, among former colonies, democracy is more likely to survive in former Spanish and British colonies, especially those that spent more time under British rule. This and several other studies have reported worse prospects for democracy in former Belgian, Dutch, Portuguese, and sometimes French, colonies. There are grounds, therefore, to expect that experience in at least some colonial networks may hinder rather than help democratization. In this paper we focus intensively on colonial networks. As in Brinks and Coppedge (2006), we are interested in the tendency of countries to converge toward similar levels of liberal democracy. There is little reason to expect colonial networks to possess the same tendency toward convergence found in neighbor networks. As Figure 1 shows, these networks map completely different relationships. 1 One might expect colonial networks, however, to foster either convergence or divergence. Both tendencies can be understood as the result of four possible forces: pull up, pull down, push down, and push up. Convergence happens when colonizers pull colonies up toward their level and/or colonies pull colonizers down toward their level. Divergence happens when colonizers push colonies down to even lower levels and/or colonies push colonizers up to higher levels of liberal democracy. If there are both pull and push forces at work, then their relative strength determines whether the overall tendency is convergence or divergence. 1 We thank Flora Xiao Tang for working on these network graphs in NodeXL. 4

7 Figure 1: Comparison of Neighbor Networks and Colonial Networks Immediate Geographic Neighbors Former Colonial Networks Convergence can happen in colonial networks by creating shared norms due to common history, shared language and religion, and migration between the colonizer and colony. These 5

8 personal ties could also encourage trade and investment. In essence, a shared colonial history creates channels between the colonizer and its colonies and former colonies that facilitate the exchange of information, ideas, technology, education, and norms. This increases the probability that actors in one country (whether influential elites or ordinary citizens whose opinions matter when they are widely shared) will want to emulate political practices they have seen or heard about in the other country. This pull up perspective emphasizes benefits that the colonizer may have bestowed on its colonies: a western religion, education, a common language, technology, infrastructure, and other trappings of civilization. This can, but does not necessarily, include benefits brought by Protestant missionary activity, which tended to be concentrated within certain empires. If so, we would expect a more positive impact in the networks of predominantly Protestant colonizers (Britain, the United States, the Netherlands) and less among Catholics (Spain, France, Portugal). (Germany sent both Protestant and Catholic missionaries) (Woodberry 2012). A less inspiring possibility is that pull down convergence could happen when a colonizer is dragged down by its own colonies, resulting in suppression of protests against the cost of maintaining an empire, tensions surrounding immigration from the colonies, or rationalizations of brutal repression carried out abroad. This scenario calls to mind DeGaulle s interruption of the French Fourth Republic, precipitated by the costly war in Algeria. But there are equally good, if not better, reasons to expect colonial rule to promote divergence rather than convergence. After all, the relationship between colonizer and colonies is asymmetric. In this push down and push up view, colonial rule is exploitative: the colonizer benefits at the expense of the colony. The dependency perspective argues that these patterns often persist even after independence (Cardoso and Faletto 1969). The colonizer, or former colonizer, extracts economic resources minerals, labor, agricultural commodities from the colony, leaving the colony poorer and itself more prosperous. If the modernization thesis is correct, this asymmetry accelerates democratization in the colonizer, pushing it up, and decelerates it in the colony, pushing it down and causing the two to diverge. A different push-down mechanism is based on the belief that socioeconomic equality promotes democratization and inequality inclines states toward non-democratic regimes (Acemoglu and Robinson 2006, Boix 2003). For example (depending on the type of colonization in a given case), colonial rule has often intensified inequality in colonized societies by concentrating land and power in the hands of settlers/planters/encomenderos while reducing the original inhabitants to small tenant 6

9 farming or peonage. During the early twentieth century, higher per capita GDP in colonizing countries was associated with reductions in inequality there (Piketty 2014). If those who see equality as a factor favoring democratization are correct, these different disparities in the distribution of wealth and income (high in the periphery, low in the center) would lead to divergent democratization: faster in the colonizer and slower in the colonies. 2 It is also possible for divergence to result from push up forces. Colonies may provide a positive example for their colonizers. Some examples could include ties between Britain and its former settler colonies (such as the United States, Australia, Canada, and New Zealand); or between some democratic Latin American countries and the Franco dictatorship in Spain; or between Brazil and the Salazar dictatorship in Portugal in the 1950s. The flow of ideas, information, and norms may also promote divergence. Citizens of the colonizers, repelled by what they have heard about conditions in the colonies, may become determined not to allow those practices to happen at home and not to take their rights and liberties for granted. They may take more pride in being civilized (including being democratic) than they would have without colonies. Reality, however, is complex. Although there are reasonable arguments for either convergence or divergence, there are probably forces pushing and pulling in both directions. Whether divergence or convergence dominates depends on whether the pull forces are stronger than the push forces in a given case. Where possible, we estimate pressures in both directions separately. Furthermore, it is important to realize that divergence does not require the colonizer to become more democratic and the colony to become less democratic. Divergence is equally consistent with all the countries in a network becoming more democratic or all becoming less democratic. The same holds true for convergence: it is a question of the rate of change. For convergence to happen, the colonies must democratize faster (on average) than the colonizer. This is difficult because the colonizers are moving targets. The colonial powers were not perfect democracies throughout our study period ( ). Germany and Italy had fascist interludes; Spain and Portugal were usually authoritarian before the 1970s; the Netherlands, Belgium, and France were temporarily occupied by Nazi Germany; and the United Kingdom and the United States gradually improved their scores on our Liberal Democracy Index during the 20 th century. In every case, the differences between their lowest and highest scores over 113 years are dramatic. If both colonizer and colonies evolved in the 2 However, for arguments that a certain degree of inequality is necessary for democratization, see Midlarsky (1992) and Ansell and Samuels (2014). 7

10 direction of greater liberal democracy but the colonizer did so more rapidly, we would observe divergence. And in fact, without controlling for other factors, this is what we observe: from 1900 to 2012, there is net movement in the direction of liberal democracy for practically every group of countries, on average, but the colonizers moved farther and faster, producing divergence. Our approach is unlike any other in several respects beyond the gap-driven mutual adjustment model that leads to inferences about convergence and divergence. First, we use new data on liberal democracy from the Varieties of Democracy project. V-Dem data does not just provide extensive geographic and historical coverage; it is the only dataset that measures liberal democracy (and other types of democracy) for colonies before independence, which is crucial for this analysis. Second, the Liberal Democracy Index we use is constructed from variables measured on a true interval scale, unlike most democracy measures, which are ordinal. Interval-level measurement is especially important for calculating democracy gaps between countries an advantage that ordinal Freedom House data did not afford to Brinks and Coppedge (2006). Third, we operationalize diffusion paths in increasingly fine-grained ways. We start by looking for convergence or divergence within all colonial and occupation networks, past and present. Then we distinguish between colonies and occupations. Then we simultaneously test thirty possible diffusion hypotheses concerning colonies. These hypotheses are necessary implications of assumptions that three distinctions matter for diffusion in colonial networks. First, as argued above, the direction of the relationship matters. This enables us to distinguish pull-up, pull-down, push-up, and push-down forces. Second, we distinguish between current and former colonial networks. (In this paper current means that the unit was a colony in the year of a given observation in the dataset. It does not mean that the unit is a colony today.) Our expectation is that whatever forces are at work act more powerfully during the years when the colonizer is actively governing the colony than in the years following independence. Third, we expect that relationships may be different across the nine colonial networks Belgian, British, Dutch, French, German, Italian, Portuguese, Spanish, and U.S. 3 Each colonizer governed in a different way, and each colonizer underwent a distinct process of democratization at home during its colonial rule period, so we prefer not to assume that the relationship between colonial rule and democratization was the same in all colonial empires. With 2 directions X 2 periods X 9 empires, there are potentially 36 hypotheses, but historical patterns and missing data reduce the number we can test to 30. For example, there are no current Spanish colonies after 1900, and the V-Dem dataset (v3) lacks data on the former Spanish colony Equatorial Guinea. 3 We plan to add current and former Japanese colonial networks eventually. 8

11 Our final model reports what we regard as the best estimates: tendencies in both directions, for current vs. former colonies, within each colonizer s network. The more specifically we model these diffusion relationships, the stronger and clearer they become. The final analysis supports the conclusion that convergence dominates. More specifically, the gaps between colonizers and colonies pull the colonies toward greater liberal democracy more strongly than those gaps push the colonizers away. Varieties of Democracy We use version 3 of the V-Dem dataset from January The sample is observational but is very large, encompassing countries from 1900 to 2012, or whenever they existed during this period, for a maximum of 14,120 country-year observations. 5 Most of the data come from online surveys of 2,156 country experts, the majority of whom were nationals of or residents in the countries they coded. The online questions were typically coded by five experts. The expert ratings were aggregated to country-date ratings by a Bayesian latent-variable measurement model designed by Daniel Pemstein and executed by Eitan Tzelgov, Yi-Ting Wang and others. An earlier version of this model is described in Pemstein et al. (2015). Some variables the relatively objective ones were coded by research assistants and thoroughly validated, and the dataset also contains some variables that were recoded from outside sources such as the Comparative Constitutions Project (Elkins et al. 2012). Some untransformed variables from other projects have been merged into the dataset, although few of those are used in this paper. The dependent variable, Liberal Democracy Index, is an index constructed from 60 fine-grained variables that measure freedom of expression, alternative sources of information, freedom of association, suffrage, clean elections, free and fair elections, elected government, civil liberties, 4 Varieties of Democracy is an international research collaboration with institutional homes at the Varieties of Democracy Institute at the University of Gothenburg and the Kellogg Institute for International Studies at the University of Notre Dame. The Principal Investigators are Michael Coppedge, John Gerring, Staffan I. Lindberg, and Jan Teorell. A complete list of the dozens of Project Managers, Research Fellows, Project Coordinators, Regional Managers, and Country Coordinators who have made essential contributions to the project is available on the main project website, V-Dem data are available only to project members and their collaborators until December 31, On that date, version 3 and other versions will be available to the public at the V-Dem archive, By that date, version 3 will have been superseded by a cleaner and more complete version that will be downloadable from the main project website. 5 Most of the omitted countries are microstates in the Pacific, Persian Gulf, and the Caribbean. Eventually we expect to have data for them as well. 9

12 judicial constraints on the executive, and legislative constraints on the executive. 6 The V-Dem dataset contains indices of other varieties of democracy electoral, participatory, deliberative, and egalitarian but we chose liberal democracy as a first step in order to maximize comparability with other research on diffusion, most of which uses Polity and Freedom House indices, which conform most closely to a concept of liberal democracy. Our index correlates at 0.87 to 0.90 with Polity and the Freedom House indices, which assures us that we are not measuring an entirely different concept. 7 Nevertheless, we believe that V-Dem data are more valid in the sense that they take many more attributes of liberal democracy into account. We also believe that the data are more reliable because they are based on multiple ratings by thousands of raters who know their countries well, and because coder disagreements have been reconciled by a state-of-the-art custom-designed IRT model. 8 Operationalizing Diffusion Hypotheses We test diffusion hypotheses by calculating the expected change, for each country-year, in liberal democracy given the hypotheses associated with each colonial network, and then specifying these expected changes as predictors in regression models. We calculated expected changes in three or four steps: 1) calculating network weights; 2) calculating liberal democracy gaps; and 3) multiplying the two to get the magnitudes of the liberal democracy gaps in each network. For oneto-one relationships, such as the impact of a colonizer on each of its colonies, this is the end of the calculation. For the many-to-one relationships such as the impact of colonies on a single colonizer and all the bidirectional relationships, there is a fourth step: calculating the mean liberal democracy gap between the colonizer and all of the colonies in that network. 6 V-Dem data also make it possible to disaggregate liberal democracy into several components and many specific variables, which may help identify more precisely which aspects of liberal democracy diffuse. The components of this index were first transformed to 0-1 interval with a cumulative density function. Thus, high values are high with respect to all country-years from 1900 to Given the size of the sample, this is an excellent estimate of the full range of possible variation. However, the CDF tends to compress values near the top and bottom of the scale, compared to the point estimates from the measurement model. 7 The V-Dem team is still working toward consensus on the best aggregation formulas for its most general indices. In the meantime, several different versions are in use internally, although they are all very highly correlated. The Liberal Democracy Index used in this paper is.5electoral Democracy Index +.3Liberal Component Index +.2Electoral Democracy IndexLiberal Component Index. 8 The measurement model also provides confidence intervals for most V-Dem variables. Eventually it will be possible to incorporate those measures of uncertainty into the kinds of regression estimates reported here, but we have not attempted this yet. 10

13 Network weights These weights seek to capture two types of relationships, broadly conceived: occupations and colonies. A distinctive feature of occupations is their temporary nature. Even though they may last for an extended period of time, the intent is for them to be short. This distinguishes from colonies. For our purposes, the category of colony includes other relationships such as protectorates or trusteeships. We used information in the V-Dem Country Coding Units document (available at to define colonies and occupations. We coded these networks for the period from 1900 to For that purpose, we built several matrices of 23,165 rows (the 205 countries coded by V-Dem times 113 years) by 205 columns (all countries coded by V-Dem). A value of 1 in a given cell represents the existence of a relationship for the two corresponding countries in a given year, and 0 represents the absence of such relationship. 9 A missing value denotes that the country on the row did not exist in a given year. The connections represented by the networks can be bidirectional, centerperiphery, or peripherycenter. For example, the Democratic Republic of the Congo was a Belgian colony between 1900 and In the bidirectional example, this relationship is coded as 1 for the period with Belgium in the rows and DRC in the corresponding column and with DRC in the rows and Belgium in the corresponding column. This allows the DRC to be among the countries in Belgium s network and Belgium to be among the countries in the DRC s network. Country YearBelgium DRC Belgium Belgium Belgium Belgium DRC DRC DRC DRC In the case of directed variables, a value of 1 denotes who the colonizer or the occupier is. Following the example above, coding the network of colonies for the Belgian empire would look like this: We constructed bidirectional variables for the following relationships: Country YearBelgium DRC Belgium Belgium Belgium Belgium DRC DRC DRC DRC The full set of relationships (both colonies and 9 We refer to these variables as weights because in trade, migration, religious, and other networks, they will take on fractional values. Colonial and neighbor networks are special cases in which a country either is or is not a member of the network. 11

14 occupations, pooled) Colonies only Occupations only The global set of all countries Center-periphery relations (i.e. any country that ever had a colony would be part of the center: for example, South Africa, as it had a colony in Namibia from 1915 to 1989) Periphery-center (i.e. Namibia would be part of South Africa s periphery, and South Africa would be part of the UK s periphery) Empires (Spain, Portugal, The Netherlands, the UK, the USA, Belgium, Italy, Germany and France). The networks were calculated separately for current (for example, the DRC in 1960 is coded as a current colony of Belgium) and former relationships (the DRC from 1961 on is a former colony of Belgium). As with the bidirectional variables, we constructed directed variables for the full set of relationships (colonies and occupations), for colonies only and for occupations only, for center-periphery relations and by empire. We also distinguished between current and former colonial networks. Liberal democracy gaps The liberal democracy gap is simply the difference in liberal democracy scores for each pair of countries in each year between 1900 and They are calculated as the source country s score minus the target country s score. 10 Thus, assuming the colonizer is usually more of a liberal democracy than its colonies, the gap tends to be positive for center-periphery networks and negative for periphery-center networks. Network gaps The final step in the construction of the network variables is to multiply the network weight by the corresponding liberal democracy gap between each pair of countries, yielding a pairwise network gap. Again, these are the final values for the center-periphery variables. For the periphery-center and bidirectional variables, all gaps in the target country s network are averaged. This procedure yields a 10 Our calculation spreadsheets actually subtract source scores from target scores, but the diffusion variables are multiplied by -1 before being used in analyses. 12

15 total of 78 network gap variables to test hypotheses about the diffusion of liberal democracy in colonial and occupation networks. In a few instances, however, information on the democracy index for one or both countries in the dyads is missing. In these cases there is missing data on the network variable. 11 We also use two control variables. Presidential election (v2xel_elecpres) is a dummy for a presidential election taking place in a given year. The natural log of per capita gross domestic product (lnmigdppc), is an interpolation and imputation of data from Maddison (2001) using GDP per capita PPP in constant 2005 international dollars from World Bank (2013). Estimation and Findings Our models make a strenuous effort to approach causal inference by ensuring that coefficient estimates are based on comparisons of cases that are as similar as possible. First, these are fixedeffects estimates, meaning that all variables are transformed into deviations from country means. Each country is therefore compared only to itself; given the thousands of attributes that make each country unique, no other country could be equally similar. Although fixed-effects estimation has been a familiar tool in econometrics for decades, it accomplishes much of what is promised by the differences-in-differences tests that are now popular in causal inference circles (Katz 2014). Second, we use a lagged dependent variable on the right-hand side. Given that the lagged value opaquely explains 97.7 percent of the current value, this specification is almost exactly equivalent to differencing the dependent variable. Indeed, the coefficients for the diffusion variables of interest are nearly identical in a differenced model. Some warn that putting a lagged dependent variable on the right-hand side can wash out the effects of other predictors (Achen 2000); Beck and Katz (2011) argue that this is not necessarily so, and it is not our experience here. 12 The coefficients for the diffusion variables should be interpreted as the difference between, on the one hand, belonging to a given network and having a gap of a given magnitude, and on the other 11 This issue mainly affects the Japanese and Belgian current empires and the Portuguese former empire, but will be remedied in the near future. 12 Unlike Brinks and Coppedge (2006), we do not use a first-stage probit model to correct for selection bias that could be due to factors that inhibit countries from changing. We have estimated such a model (adapted to our continuous dependent variable), and it yields some interesting conclusions about the conditions under which countries change their level of liberal democracy more than an insignificant amount. However, this correction does not significantly or substantively alter estimates in the main model, probably because the lagged dependent variable controls for stasis very well. 13

16 hand, not belonging to any of the networks specified in the model. The reference group for these coefficients is therefore the set of country-years that have never been colonizers and are not, in an observed year, either a current or former colony (or an occupied territory, for the occupation models). Causal inference requires comparing the countries treated by various kinds of colonization to a control group that is as similar as possible to the treatment group in every way except for the treatment. This makes it possible to estimate the average treatment effect. The countries that spent at least a century in this reference group, which serves as our control group, are Afghanistan, Albania, Bulgaria, China, Denmark, Finland, Greece, Iceland, Iran, South Korea, Liberia, Norway, Panama, Russia, Romania, Sweden, Switzerland, Taiwan, and Zimbabwe. 13 It also includes many other country-years for pre-colonial cases. This group is on average more democratic than the whole sample (mean Liberal Democracy Index =.295 for the whole sample vs..344 for the reference cases), but only slightly so; a little wealthier (mean per capita GDP of $5,436 vs. $4,302); and it is about as likely to change scores. The most notable difference is that the reference group has much less experience with colonial rule, either as colonizer or colony. It is not a perfect control group, but it is close. Because the composition of the reference group is crucial for causal inference, it is important to specify the diffusion variables in a comprehensive and balanced way. That is, all of the country-years affected by colonization, either as colonizers or as colonies, current or former, must be represented by a diffusion variable in the model. If they are not, the omitted country-years fall back into the reference group and therefore modify the nature of the average treatment effect. For example, if one were to test for just the effect of being, or having been, a British colony, then the average treatment effect would be the difference between British colonies, on the one hand, and the core reference group and colonies in other empires and Britain itself and other colonizers. The correct specification is to include variables that cover all the empires and the colonizers as well. Similarly, estimating relationships only for former colonies and colonizers relegates current colonies and colonizers to the reference group, changing the effect to the difference between former colonies and colonizers, on the one hand, and the non-colonial reference group and current colonies and colonizers a very different relationship. No previous study has ever specified colonial models this fully, because only the new V-Dem dataset measures liberal democracy for colonies before independence. Fully specifying the colonial diffusion model is essential for drawing conclusions about the effect of 13 Pending data cleaning will remove Panama, South Korea, Zimbabwe, and perhaps Taiwan from the reference group. 14

17 colonial networks versus the non-colonial reference group and the differential effect of each type of colonial network versus all the others, as they are all compared to the same non-colonial reference group. Figure 2 Trends in Colonial Networks (fixed effects) Belgian Network British Network Dutch Network French Network German Network Portuguese Network Spanish Network US Network black=colonizer, red=current colonies, blue=former colonies 15

18 A quick look at the nearly raw data suggests that convergence is unlikely. Figure 2 plots the liberal democracy scores of each colonizer (black) and its line of fit (gray); a scatterplot of liberal democracy scores for all of that colonizer s current (for that year) colonies (pink) and their line of fit (red); and a scatterplot of the liberal democracy scores for all of the colonizer s former colonies (light blue) and their line of fit (darker blue). These are fixed effects trends: the scores are each country s deviations from its own mean, which is in accordance with the regression estimates presented below and also eliminates bias from countries entering and leaving the sample. Because the series are mean-centered, they always cross in the center. Convergence therefore corresponds to colonies having a steeper slope than the colonizers, and divergence to colonizers having a steeper slope than their colonies. Without controls, divergence is the norm. All of the trends are positive; however, with one exception, the slope is more positive for the colonizers than for any of their current or former colonies. The one exception is for Belgium s one current colony (in this dataset), the Belgian Congo (later Zaire, then the Democratic Republic of Congo). This is merely an influential outlier that gets a steep positive slope for one country in one year. We cannot base any general conclusions on it. Therefore, all of the reliable trends we observe here support divergence. Convergence can happen only if these slopes change when we control for other determinants of democracy. For example, a rate of democratization may be partly a function of the level of economic development. The trends may be more positive for some colonies relative to other low- and middleincome countries than the colonizers trends are relative to other high-income countries. Table 1 presents three baseline models without any diffusion variables. Model 1 takes advantage of the largest possible sample. Model 3 controls for ln(per capita GDP) but in the process sacrifices twelve countries and more than four thousand country-year observations due to list deletion. We plan, eventually, to get estimates using multiple imputation to avoid the reduction in the sample and any sample bias that it may bring, but these baseline models suggest that there is no cause for concern. Even the smaller sample contains nearly 10,000 observations, and the estimates are virtually identical for both samples. For reassurance, Model 2 shows estimates for Model 1 using the Model 3 sample; again, they are virtually identical. Therefore, from this point forward, we control for ln(per capita GDP). 16

19 Table 1: Baseline models Independent variables Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 intercept Liberal democracy t Change in liberal democracy t Presidential election year ln(per capita GDP) N N countries R 2 within R 2 between R 2 overall Fixed-effects estimates with robust standard errors clustered by country. Occupations Occupations have no discernable relationship with trends in liberal democracy. 14 As Table 2 shows, whether we examine a bidirectional global network of occupations and occupiers, distinguish between current and former occupations, distinguish between center-periphery and periphery-center networks, or make all possible distinctions, none of these occupation variables approaches significance. However, when occupations and colonies are pooled (Model 7), both former and current networks are significant and positive. Clearly it is the colonial networks that matter in this model, not the occupations. The rest of our analysis therefore narrows attention to colonies. 14 There are 84 country-years of occupation recorded in this sample: Afghanistan ( ), Albania ( ), Austria (1955), Belgium ( ), Burundi ( ), Cambodia ( ), Dominican Republic ( ), Germany ( ), Honduras ( & 1924), Iraq ( ), South Korea ( ), and Palestine/West Bank ( & 1967). The coding of Germany is an error that will be corrected, but the regression results are the same if Germany is omitted from the sample. 17

20 Table 2: Occupation models Independent variables Model 4 Model 5 Model 6 Model 7 intercept Liberal democracy t Change in liberal democracy t Presidential election year ln(per capita GDP) Occupations, global t Former occupations, bidirectional t Current occupations, bidirectional t Current occupations, C-->P t Current occupations, P-->C t Former occupations, C-->P t Former occupations, P-->C t Current occupations & colonies t Former occupations & colonies t N N countries R 2 within R 2 between R 2 overall Fixed-effects estimates with robust standard errors clustered by country. 18

21 Colonial Networks The interpretation of Model 7 is confirmed by Model 8 in Table 3, which reports estimates for current and former colonial networks without occupations. When we estimate bidirectional relationships for all empires as in Model 8, the significant and positive coefficients for both current and former colonial networks suggest convergence. That is, all the countries in a colonial network tend to become more similar in their levels of liberal democracy. A literal interpretation of these estimates is that the less democratic countries pull the more democratic countries down and the more democratic countries pull the less democratic countries up. However, this way of defining the networks actually overlaps with neighbor networks, as it predicts that neighboring colonies and former colonies will affect one another. It is not just the bilateral links between France and the states of French West Africa, for example, that matter here; it is also the multiple linkages among the states of French West Africa, both during colonial rule and as former French colonies after independence. This conflation of colonial and neighbor networks makes it difficult to attribute influence to the colonial networks alone. Things get more interesting when we get separate estimates by empire. The results in Table 3, Model 9 still conflate colonial and neighbor networks, and they also conflate current and former colonies; but they break out the relationship for each colonizer. Now we see the convergence from Model 8 is present only in the Spanish and US networks; the negative coefficient for the German network signifies marked divergence. The weighted average effect across all empires (including some contamination from neighbor networks) can be positive, but that average masks a great deal of variation across empires. 19

22 Table 3: Simple colonial network models Independent variables Model 8 Model 9 intercept Liberal democracy t Change in liberal democracy t Presidential election year ln(per capita GDP) Current colonies, global & bidirectional t Former colonies, global & bidirectional t Belgian network, bidirectional t British network, bidirectional t Dutch network, bidirectional t French network, bidirectional t German network, bidirectional t Italian network, bidirectional t Spanish network, bidirectional t US network, bidirectional t N N countries R 2 within R 2 between R 2 overall Fixed-effects estimates with robust standard errors clustered by country. 20

23 Breaking these relationships up by colonizer requires us to leaven our interpretations with caution, because many of these colonial networks contain few countries, partly due to gaps in the V- Dem dataset. The Belgian network includes only the Belgian Congo, Burundi, and Rwanda. The Dutch network includes only Indonesia and Suriname. The German network includes only Burundi, Namibia, and Rwanda. The Italian network is only Eritrea, Libya, and Somalia. The US network contains only Cuba and the Philippines. Portugal has data only for current colonies Angola, Cape Verde, Guinea-Bissau, Mozambique, and São Tomé & Príncipe. 15 Such sparse networks are vulnerable to local idiosyncrasies, so it is risky to draw general conclusions from them. For example, the strong negative coefficient for the German network is almost certainly spurious. The defeat of the German Empire in World War I led to both the country s first democratic regime during the Weimar Republic and the loss of its colonies in Africa; the gap between Wilhelmine Germany and South West Africa in 1917 did not cause the birth of Weimar two years later. Our conclusions therefore give more weight to the large empires of the United Kingdom (35 countries), France (27 countries), and Spain (18 countries). There is little point in discussing estimates from models that conflate the other distinctions that we expect to matter. As we have seen, ignoring the direction of the relationships obscures the distinction between effects on colonies and effects on colonizers and unintentionally introduces confounding with neighbor networks. Ignoring the distinction between current and former colonial networks would blind us to any differences in the magnitudes or directions of the relationships, as though independence could not possibly matter. Neither are we willing to assume that all empires have the same effects. We therefore proceed to the most disaggregated set of hypotheses. If some of these distinctions turn out not to matter, the estimates will tell us. Because the number of diffusion variables gets large in these more complex models, while the control variables show no meaningful variation from model to model, Figure 3 reports regression estimates in the form of coefficient plots rather than as a table. Figure 3 summarizes the findings of a single model on the thirty diffusion hypotheses generated by every combination of colonizer, direction of influence, and current or former colony. At this level of specificity, 19 of the 30 coefficients are statistically significant despite the powerful control variables that account for almost all the variance in liberal democracy. Painting with a broad brush, one pattern is that the centerperiphery coefficients tend to be positive, although more of them are significant among current colonies than among former colonies. This does not, however, justify a solid, across-the- 15 Brazil will be added soon, along with the other five countries as former colonies. 21

24 board conclusion that colonizers tend to pull their colonies, especially current colonies, toward liberal democracy. Among the three major empires, these coefficients are indistinguishable from zero for the British and French networks. Only the Spanish network has a credibly positive centerperiphery coefficient. Figure 3 Center-->Periphery, F Belgium Britain Netherlands France Germany Italy Spain United States Coefficients of Diffusion Variables CP and PC, Current and Former Periphery-->Center, F Belgium Britain Netherlands France Germany Italy Portugal Spain United States Center-->Periphery, C Belgium Britain Netherlands France Italy United States Periphery-->Center, C Belgium Britain Netherlands France Germany Italy United States Still painting with a broad brush, the periphery-center coefficients tend to be negative for former colonies, but mixed for current colonies. Once again, before we rush to the conclusion that former colonies tend to push their former colonizers toward greater liberal democracy, we must note that these coefficients are not significant for Britain or France with respect to former colonies; and they are very small and negative for current-colony Britain but positive for current-colony France. (Spain has no current-colony variable because all of its colonies in this sample gained independence before 1900.) In models not reported here, we tested the even more precise hypothesis that British colonies of settlement, occupation, and forced settlement are affected differently by colonial diffusion (Owolabi 2012). Surprisingly, they all behave about the same. 22

25 Simulations of predicted relationships This eyeballing of coefficients supports only very rough conclusions that make it hard to judge whether, and under what conditions, the model predicts convergence or divergence. For better interpretation, simulating the predictions of the model is very helpful. That is the best way to judge the implications of the relative size and significance of these coefficients, and especially to see how these very dynamic relationships play out iteratively over a long period of time. We simulate the model with one small graph per colonial network; these are gathered together in Figure 4. The blue elements in each graph correspond to current colonial networks and the red elements correspond to former colonial networks. Within each group, the darker shade is for the colonizer and the lighter shade is for the colonies. The simulation for each colonizer and group of colonies begins at the first year of that network (in our dataset) and ends at its last year (although we stop at the nice round year 2000, as the trends are no different after that). The initial values are the average level of liberal democracy for that country or group in the initial year. Values for subsequent years are based on the estimates in Figure 3: the previous liberal democracy score plus the gap between colonizer and colonies (source minus target) times the coefficient for that network, lagged two years. The shaded areas behind each line are calculated the same way except that they use the lower and upper bounds of the coefficient estimates. Thus they show the range of possible values as this mutual adjustment between colonizer and colonies reproduces itself iteratively year after year. These lines and range areas are not, therefore, the trends that colonizers and colonies historically followed. Rather, they are simulations of what the trends in liberal democracy would have been if the diffusion variables were all that mattered, given the initial values. These small graphs are ideal for making sense of the model s estimates because we can see at a glance whether each network tends to diverge or converge. With the sole exception of German networks, the clear tendency is to converge. As time passes, the current colonies and colonizers (blue lines) draw closer to each other and the former colonies and colonizers (red lines) also draw closer to each other. 16 It also appears that the rate of convergence is faster in the current colonial networks than in the former colonial networks. Not all of these relationships are significant, however. Asterisks mark those that have less than a 5 percent 16 It does not matter that some pairs of curves ascend and some descend. In this simulation, if the starting value for the colonial group is higher than that for the colonizer (light line over dark line), the joint trend is downward; otherwise (dark over light) it ascends. 23

Varieties of Democratic Diffusion: Colonial and Neighbor Networks

Varieties of Democratic Diffusion: Colonial and Neighbor Networks INSTITUTE Varieties of Democratic Diffusion: Colonial and Neighbor Networks Michael Coppedge, Benjamin Denison, Lucía Tiscornia, Staffan I. Lindberg June 2016 Working Paper SERIES 2016:2(2) REVISED THE

More information

BUILDING RESILIENT REGIONS FOR STRONGER ECONOMIES OECD

BUILDING RESILIENT REGIONS FOR STRONGER ECONOMIES OECD o: o BUILDING RESILIENT REGIONS FOR STRONGER ECONOMIES OECD Table of Contents Acronyms and Abbreviations 11 List of TL2 Regions 13 Preface 16 Executive Summary 17 Parti Key Regional Trends and Policies

More information

Educated Preferences: Explaining Attitudes Toward Immigration In Europe. Jens Hainmueller and Michael J. Hiscox. Last revised: December 2005

Educated Preferences: Explaining Attitudes Toward Immigration In Europe. Jens Hainmueller and Michael J. Hiscox. Last revised: December 2005 Educated Preferences: Explaining Attitudes Toward Immigration In Jens Hainmueller and Michael J. Hiscox Last revised: December 2005 Supplement III: Detailed Results for Different Cutoff points of the Dependent

More information

Table A.2 reports the complete set of estimates of equation (1). We distinguish between personal

Table A.2 reports the complete set of estimates of equation (1). We distinguish between personal Akay, Bargain and Zimmermann Online Appendix 40 A. Online Appendix A.1. Descriptive Statistics Figure A.1 about here Table A.1 about here A.2. Detailed SWB Estimates Table A.2 reports the complete set

More information

2018 Social Progress Index

2018 Social Progress Index 2018 Social Progress Index The Social Progress Index Framework asks universally important questions 2 2018 Social Progress Index Framework 3 Our best index yet The Social Progress Index is an aggregate

More information

LABOUR-MARKET INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS IN OECD-COUNTRIES: WHAT EXPLANATIONS FIT THE DATA?

LABOUR-MARKET INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS IN OECD-COUNTRIES: WHAT EXPLANATIONS FIT THE DATA? LABOUR-MARKET INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS IN OECD-COUNTRIES: WHAT EXPLANATIONS FIT THE DATA? By Andreas Bergh (PhD) Associate Professor in Economics at Lund University and the Research Institute of Industrial

More information

IMF research links declining labour share to weakened worker bargaining power. ACTU Economic Briefing Note, August 2018

IMF research links declining labour share to weakened worker bargaining power. ACTU Economic Briefing Note, August 2018 IMF research links declining labour share to weakened worker bargaining power ACTU Economic Briefing Note, August 2018 Authorised by S. McManus, ACTU, 365 Queen St, Melbourne 3000. ACTU D No. 172/2018

More information

A Global Perspective on Socioeconomic Differences in Learning Outcomes

A Global Perspective on Socioeconomic Differences in Learning Outcomes 2009/ED/EFA/MRT/PI/19 Background paper prepared for the Education for All Global Monitoring Report 2009 Overcoming Inequality: why governance matters A Global Perspective on Socioeconomic Differences in

More information

Benefit levels and US immigrants welfare receipts

Benefit levels and US immigrants welfare receipts 1 Benefit levels and US immigrants welfare receipts 1970 1990 by Joakim Ruist Department of Economics University of Gothenburg Box 640 40530 Gothenburg, Sweden joakim.ruist@economics.gu.se telephone: +46

More information

A Partial Solution. To the Fundamental Problem of Causal Inference

A Partial Solution. To the Fundamental Problem of Causal Inference A Partial Solution To the Fundamental Problem of Causal Inference Some of our most important questions are causal questions. 1,000 5,000 10,000 50,000 100,000 10 5 0 5 10 Level of Democracy ( 10 = Least

More information

INSTITUTE. Does Democracy or Good Governance Enhance Health? New Empirical Evidence Yi-ting Wang Valeriya Mechkova Frida Andersson

INSTITUTE. Does Democracy or Good Governance Enhance Health? New Empirical Evidence Yi-ting Wang Valeriya Mechkova Frida Andersson INSTITUTE Does Democracy or Good Governance Enhance Health? New Empirical Evidence 1900-2012 Yi-ting Wang Valeriya Mechkova Frida Andersson September 2015 Working Paper SERIES 2015:11 THE VARIETIES OF

More information

Regional Scores. African countries Press Freedom Ratings 2001

Regional Scores. African countries Press Freedom Ratings 2001 Regional Scores African countries Press Freedom 2001 Algeria Angola Benin Botswana Burkina Faso Burundi Cape Verde Cameroon Central African Republic Chad Comoros Congo (Brazzaville) Congo (Kinshasa) Cote

More information

Income and Population Growth

Income and Population Growth Supplementary Appendix to the paper Income and by Markus Brueckner and Hannes Schwandt November 2013 downloadable from: https://sites.google.com/site/markusbrucknerresearch/research-papers Table of Contents

More information

APPENDIX 1: MEASURES OF CAPITALISM AND POLITICAL FREEDOM

APPENDIX 1: MEASURES OF CAPITALISM AND POLITICAL FREEDOM 1 APPENDIX 1: MEASURES OF CAPITALISM AND POLITICAL FREEDOM All indicators shown below were transformed into series with a zero mean and a standard deviation of one before they were combined. The summary

More information

Comparing the Data Sets

Comparing the Data Sets Comparing the Data Sets Online Appendix to Accompany "Rival Strategies of Validation: Tools for Evaluating Measures of Democracy" Jason Seawright and David Collier Comparative Political Studies 47, No.

More information

Comparing the Wealth of Nations. Emily Lin

Comparing the Wealth of Nations. Emily Lin Comparing the Wealth of Nations Emily Lin What is HDI? What is GDP? What are some of the ways to rank countries economically? Developed vs Developing vs Least Developed GDP GDP per Capita Each method has

More information

Networks and Innovation: Accounting for Structural and Institutional Sources of Recombination in Brokerage Triads

Networks and Innovation: Accounting for Structural and Institutional Sources of Recombination in Brokerage Triads 1 Online Appendix for Networks and Innovation: Accounting for Structural and Institutional Sources of Recombination in Brokerage Triads Sarath Balachandran Exequiel Hernandez This appendix presents a descriptive

More information

Improving the accuracy of outbound tourism statistics with mobile positioning data

Improving the accuracy of outbound tourism statistics with mobile positioning data 1 (11) Improving the accuracy of outbound tourism statistics with mobile positioning data Survey response rates are declining at an alarming rate globally. Statisticians have traditionally used imputing

More information

Exploring the Impact of Democratic Capital on Prosperity

Exploring the Impact of Democratic Capital on Prosperity Exploring the Impact of Democratic Capital on Prosperity Lisa L. Verdon * SUMMARY Capital accumulation has long been considered one of the driving forces behind economic growth. The idea that democratic

More information

3Z 3 STATISTICS IN FOCUS eurostat Population and social conditions 1995 D 3

3Z 3 STATISTICS IN FOCUS eurostat Population and social conditions 1995 D 3 3Z 3 STATISTICS IN FOCUS Population and social conditions 1995 D 3 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION IN THE EU MEMBER STATES - 1992 It would seem almost to go without saying that international migration concerns

More information

Angus Deaton, Princeton University 4 th OECD World Forum, Delhi, October 16 th, 2012 MATERIAL CONDITIONS PROGRESS AND PUZZLES IN MEASUREMENT

Angus Deaton, Princeton University 4 th OECD World Forum, Delhi, October 16 th, 2012 MATERIAL CONDITIONS PROGRESS AND PUZZLES IN MEASUREMENT Angus Deaton, Princeton University 4 th OECD World Forum, Delhi, October 16 th, 2012 MATERIAL CONDITIONS PROGRESS AND PUZZLES IN MEASUREMENT This talk Measurement in three areas Material well-being: purchasing

More information

Appendix to Sectoral Economies

Appendix to Sectoral Economies Appendix to Sectoral Economies Rafaela Dancygier and Michael Donnelly June 18, 2012 1. Details About the Sectoral Data used in this Article Table A1: Availability of NACE classifications by country of

More information

World Refugee Survey, 2001

World Refugee Survey, 2001 World Refugee Survey, 2001 Refugees in Africa: 3,346,000 "Host" Country Home Country of Refugees Number ALGERIA Western Sahara, Palestinians 85,000 ANGOLA Congo-Kinshasa 12,000 BENIN Togo, Other 4,000

More information

KOF Index of Globalization 2017: Netherlands Are the Most Globalized Country

KOF Index of Globalization 2017: Netherlands Are the Most Globalized Country Press Release Zurich, April 17, 9. a.m. KOF Index of Globalization 17: Netherlands Are the Most Globalized Country The current KOF Index of Globalization reflects the extent of economic, social and political

More information

EDUCATION INTELLIGENCE EDUCATION INTELLIGENCE. Presentation Title DD/MM/YY. Students in Motion. Janet Ilieva, PhD Jazreel Goh

EDUCATION INTELLIGENCE EDUCATION INTELLIGENCE. Presentation Title DD/MM/YY. Students in Motion. Janet Ilieva, PhD Jazreel Goh Presentation Title DD/MM/YY Students in Motion Janet Ilieva, PhD Jazreel Goh Forecasting International Student Mobility Global slowdown in the world economy is expected to affect global demand for overseas

More information

Trends in international higher education

Trends in international higher education Trends in international higher education 1 Schedule Student decision-making Drivers of international higher education mobility Demographics Economics Domestic tertiary enrolments International postgraduate

More information

Immigrant-native wage gaps in time series: Complementarities or composition effects?

Immigrant-native wage gaps in time series: Complementarities or composition effects? Immigrant-native wage gaps in time series: Complementarities or composition effects? Joakim Ruist Department of Economics University of Gothenburg Box 640 405 30 Gothenburg, Sweden joakim.ruist@economics.gu.se

More information

LIST OF CHINESE EMBASSIES OVERSEAS Extracted from Ministry of Foreign Affairs of the People s Republic of China *

LIST OF CHINESE EMBASSIES OVERSEAS Extracted from Ministry of Foreign Affairs of the People s Republic of China * ANNEX 1 LIST OF CHINESE EMBASSIES OVERSEAS Extracted from Ministry of Foreign Affairs of the People s Republic of China * ASIA Chinese Embassy in Afghanistan Chinese Embassy in Bangladesh Chinese Embassy

More information

FOREIGN TRADE AND FDI AS MAIN FACTORS OF GROWTH IN THE EU 1

FOREIGN TRADE AND FDI AS MAIN FACTORS OF GROWTH IN THE EU 1 1. FOREIGN TRADE AND FDI AS MAIN FACTORS OF GROWTH IN THE EU 1 Lucian-Liviu ALBU 2 Abstract In the last decade, a number of empirical studies tried to highlight a strong correlation among foreign trade,

More information

The Transmission of Economic Status and Inequality: U.S. Mexico in Comparative Perspective

The Transmission of Economic Status and Inequality: U.S. Mexico in Comparative Perspective The Students We Share: New Research from Mexico and the United States Mexico City January, 2010 The Transmission of Economic Status and Inequality: U.S. Mexico in Comparative Perspective René M. Zenteno

More information

Online Appendix for. Home Away From Home? Foreign Demand and London House Prices

Online Appendix for. Home Away From Home? Foreign Demand and London House Prices Online Appendix for Home Away From Home? Foreign Demand and London House Prices List of Tables A.1 Summary statistics across wards..................... 14 A.2 Robustness of the results.........................

More information

UNHCR, United Nations High Commissioner for Refugees

UNHCR, United Nations High Commissioner for Refugees States Parties to the 1951 Convention relating to the Status of Refugees and the 1967 Protocol Date of entry into force: 22 April 1954 (Convention) 4 October 1967 (Protocol) As of 1 February 2004 Total

More information

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr Abstract. The Asian experience of poverty reduction has varied widely. Over recent decades the economies of East and Southeast Asia

More information

The Political Economy of Public Policy

The Political Economy of Public Policy The Political Economy of Public Policy Valentino Larcinese Electoral Rules & Policy Outcomes Electoral Rules Matter! Imagine a situation with two parties A & B and 99 voters. A has 55 supporters and B

More information

ECON 450 Development Economics

ECON 450 Development Economics ECON 450 Development Economics Long-Run Causes of Comparative Economic Development Institutions University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign Summer 2017 Outline 1 Introduction 2 3 The Korean Case The Korean

More information

Widening of Inequality in Japan: Its Implications

Widening of Inequality in Japan: Its Implications Widening of Inequality in Japan: Its Implications Jun Saito, Senior Research Fellow Japan Center for Economic Research December 11, 2017 Is inequality widening in Japan? Since the publication of Thomas

More information

Global Prevalence of Adult Overweight & Obesity by Region

Global Prevalence of Adult Overweight & Obesity by Region Country Year of Data Collection Global Prevalence of Adult Overweight & Obesity by Region National /Regional Survey Size Age Category % BMI 25-29.9 %BMI 30+ % BMI 25- %BMI 30+ 29.9 European Region Albania

More information

How the US Acquires Clients. Contexts of Acquisition

How the US Acquires Clients. Contexts of Acquisition How the US Acquires Clients Contexts of Acquisition Some Basics of Client Acquisition Client acquisition requires the consent of both the US and the new client though consent of the client can be coercive

More information

Migration and Integration

Migration and Integration Migration and Integration Integration in Education Education for Integration Istanbul - 13 October 2017 Francesca Borgonovi Senior Analyst - Migration and Gender Directorate for Education and Skills, OECD

More information

GDP per capita was lowest in the Czech Republic and the Republic of Korea. For more details, see page 3.

GDP per capita was lowest in the Czech Republic and the Republic of Korea. For more details, see page 3. International Comparisons of GDP per Capita and per Hour, 1960 9 Division of International Labor Comparisons October 21, 2010 Table of Contents Introduction.2 Charts...3 Tables...9 Technical Notes.. 18

More information

WORLDWIDE DISTRIBUTION OF PRIVATE FINANCIAL ASSETS

WORLDWIDE DISTRIBUTION OF PRIVATE FINANCIAL ASSETS WORLDWIDE DISTRIBUTION OF PRIVATE FINANCIAL ASSETS Munich, November 2018 Copyright Allianz 11/19/2018 1 MORE DYNAMIC POST FINANCIAL CRISIS Changes in the global wealth middle classes in millions 1,250

More information

The Global State of Corruption Control. Who Succeeds, Who Fails and What Can Be Done About It

The Global State of Corruption Control. Who Succeeds, Who Fails and What Can Be Done About It European Research Centre for Anti-Corruption and State-Building at the Hertie School of Governance The Global State of Corruption Control. Who Succeeds, Who Fails and What Can Be Done About It www.againstcorruption.eu

More information

Proposed Indicative Scale of Contributions for 2016 and 2017

Proposed Indicative Scale of Contributions for 2016 and 2017 October 2015 E Item 16 of the Provisional Agenda SIXTH SESSION OF THE GOVERNING BODY Rome, Italy, 5 9 October 2015 Proposed Indicative Scale of Contributions for 2016 and 2017 Note by the Secretary 1.

More information

DETERMINANTS OF THE LONG TERM ECONOMIC GROWTH OF NATIONS IN THE ERA OF THE CRYSTALLIZATION OF THE MODERN WORLD SYSTEM

DETERMINANTS OF THE LONG TERM ECONOMIC GROWTH OF NATIONS IN THE ERA OF THE CRYSTALLIZATION OF THE MODERN WORLD SYSTEM DETERMINANTS OF THE LONG TERM ECONOMIC GROWTH OF NATIONS IN THE ERA OF THE CRYSTALLIZATION OF THE MODERN WORLD SYSTEM A Senior Scholars Thesis by NIHAD MANSIMZADA Submitted to Honors and Undergraduate

More information

Commission on Growth and Development Cognitive Skills and Economic Development

Commission on Growth and Development Cognitive Skills and Economic Development Commission on Growth and Development Cognitive Skills and Economic Development Eric A. Hanushek Stanford University in conjunction with Ludger Wößmann University of Munich and Ifo Institute Overview 1.

More information

The National Police Immigration Service (NPIS) forcibly returned 412 persons in December 2017, and 166 of these were convicted offenders.

The National Police Immigration Service (NPIS) forcibly returned 412 persons in December 2017, and 166 of these were convicted offenders. Monthly statistics December 2017: Forced returns from Norway The National Police Immigration Service (NPIS) forcibly returned 412 persons in December 2017, and 166 of these were convicted offenders. The

More information

Inclusive global growth: a framework to think about the post-2015 agenda

Inclusive global growth: a framework to think about the post-2015 agenda Inclusive global growth: a framework to think about the post-215 agenda François Bourguignon Paris School of Economics Angus Maddison Lecture, Oecd, Paris, April 213 1 Outline 1) Inclusion and exclusion

More information

Globalization and the portuguese enterprises

Globalization and the portuguese enterprises International Sourcing 2009-2011, 2012-2015 25 November, 2013 Globalization and the portuguese enterprises In the period 2009-2011, 15.3% of Portuguese enterprises with 100 or more persons employed carried

More information

Congruence in Political Parties

Congruence in Political Parties Descriptive Representation of Women and Ideological Congruence in Political Parties Georgia Kernell Northwestern University gkernell@northwestern.edu June 15, 2011 Abstract This paper examines the relationship

More information

EU Ornamental Fish Import & Export Statistics 2016 (Third Countries & Intra-EU Community trade)

EU Ornamental Fish Import & Export Statistics 2016 (Third Countries & Intra-EU Community trade) ORNAMENTAL AQUATIC TRADE ASSOCIATION LTD. "The Voice of the Ornamental Fish Industry" 1 st Floor Office Suite, Wessex House 40 Station Road, Westbury, Wiltshire United Kingdom BA13 3JN T: +44 (0)1373 301353

More information

The National Police Immigration Service (NPIS) returned 444 persons in August 2018, and 154 of these were convicted offenders.

The National Police Immigration Service (NPIS) returned 444 persons in August 2018, and 154 of these were convicted offenders. Monthly statistics August 2018 Forced returns from Norway The National Police Immigration Service (NPIS) returned 444 persons in August 2018, and 154 of these were convicted offenders. The NPIS is responsible

More information

DATA PROTECTION EXECUTIVE SUMMARY

DATA PROTECTION EXECUTIVE SUMMARY Special Eurobarometer European Commission DATA PROTECTION Fieldwork: September 2003 Publication: December 2003 Special Eurobarometer 196 Wave 60.0 - European Opinion Research Group EEIG EXECUTIVE SUMMARY

More information

Supplementary Materials for

Supplementary Materials for www.sciencemag.org/cgi/content/full/science.aag2147/dc1 Supplementary Materials for How economic, humanitarian, and religious concerns shape European attitudes toward asylum seekers This PDF file includes

More information

GLOBAL RISKS OF CONCERN TO BUSINESS WEF EXECUTIVE OPINION SURVEY RESULTS SEPTEMBER 2017

GLOBAL RISKS OF CONCERN TO BUSINESS WEF EXECUTIVE OPINION SURVEY RESULTS SEPTEMBER 2017 GLOBAL RISKS OF CONCERN TO BUSINESS WEF EXECUTIVE OPINION SURVEY RESULTS SEPTEMBER 2017 GLOBAL RISKS OF CONCERN TO BUSINESS Results from the World Economic Forum Executive Opinion Survey 2017 Survey and

More information

1 THICK WHITE SENTRA; SIDES AND FACE PAINTED TO MATCH WALL PAINT: GRAPHICS DIRECT PRINTED TO SURFACE; CLEAT MOUNT TO WALL CRITICAL INSTALL POINT

1 THICK WHITE SENTRA; SIDES AND FACE PAINTED TO MATCH WALL PAINT: GRAPHICS DIRECT PRINTED TO SURFACE; CLEAT MOUNT TO WALL CRITICAL INSTALL POINT Map Country Panels 1 THICK WHITE SENTRA; SIDES AND FACE PAINTED TO MATCH WALL PAINT: GRAPHICS DIRECT PRINTED TO SURFACE; CLEAT MOUNT TO WALL CRITICAL INSTALL POINT GRAPHICS PRINTED DIRECT TO WHITE 1 THICK

More information

Translation from Norwegian

Translation from Norwegian Statistics for May 2018 Forced returns from Norway The National Police Immigration Service (NPIS) forcibly returned 402 persons in May 2018, and 156 of these were convicted offenders. The NPIS is responsible

More information

Country pairings for the second cycle of the Mechanism for the Review of Implementation of the United Nations Convention against Corruption

Country pairings for the second cycle of the Mechanism for the Review of Implementation of the United Nations Convention against Corruption Country pairings for the second cycle of the Mechanism for the Review of Implementation of the United Nations Convention against Corruption In year 1, a total of 29 reviews will be conducted: Regional

More information

How Democracies Die. A Full Spectrum of Indicators 11/5/ minutes then Q&A:

How Democracies Die. A Full Spectrum of Indicators 11/5/ minutes then Q&A: How Democracies Die Professor Staffan I. Lindberg Principal Investigator, Director, V- Dem Institute xlista@gu.se & Wallenberg Academy Fellow European Research Council Consolidator Young Academy of Sweden,

More information

Volume 35, Issue 1. An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach

Volume 35, Issue 1. An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach Volume 35, Issue 1 An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach Brian Hibbs Indiana University South Bend Gihoon Hong Indiana University South Bend Abstract This

More information

The WTO Trade Effect and Political Uncertainty: Evidence from Chinese Exports

The WTO Trade Effect and Political Uncertainty: Evidence from Chinese Exports Abstract: The WTO Trade Effect and Political Uncertainty: Evidence from Chinese Exports Yingting Yi* KU Leuven (Preliminary and incomplete; comments are welcome) This paper investigates whether WTO promotes

More information

Rule of Law Index 2019 Insights

Rule of Law Index 2019 Insights World Justice Project Rule of Law Index 2019 Insights Highlights and data trends from the WJP Rule of Law Index 2019 Trinidad & Tobago Tunisia Turkey Uganda Ukraine United Arab Emirates United Kingdom

More information

Statistical Appendix 2 for Chapter 2 of World Happiness Report March 1, 2018

Statistical Appendix 2 for Chapter 2 of World Happiness Report March 1, 2018 Statistical Appendix 2 for Chapter 2 of World Happiness Report 2018 March 1, 2018 1 Table 1: Average ladder and number of observations by domestic or foreign born in 2005-17 surveys - Part 1 Domestic born:

More information

Human capital transmission and the earnings of second-generation immigrants in Sweden

Human capital transmission and the earnings of second-generation immigrants in Sweden Hammarstedt and Palme IZA Journal of Migration 2012, 1:4 RESEARCH Open Access Human capital transmission and the earnings of second-generation in Sweden Mats Hammarstedt 1* and Mårten Palme 2 * Correspondence:

More information

Development Economics Lecture 1

Development Economics Lecture 1 Development Economics Lecture 1 Anne Mikkola Partly using slides of Prof. Haaparanta EXAMS (one of the following) Date: 11.12.2007: Time: 12-14 Place: Porthania II Date: 16.1.2008: Time: 12-14 Place: Economicum

More information

AUSTRALIA S REFUGEE RESPONSE NOT THE MOST GENEROUS BUT IN TOP 25

AUSTRALIA S REFUGEE RESPONSE NOT THE MOST GENEROUS BUT IN TOP 25 19 July 2013 AUSTRALIA S REFUGEE RESPONSE NOT THE MOST GENEROUS BUT IN TOP 25 Australia is not the world s most generous country in its response to refugees but is just inside the top 25, according to

More information

Rankings: Universities vs. National Higher Education Systems. Benoit Millot

Rankings: Universities vs. National Higher Education Systems. Benoit Millot Rankings: Universities vs. National Higher Education Systems Benoit Millot Outline 1. Background 2. Methodology 3. Results 4. Discussion 11/8/ 2 1. Background 11/8/ 3 Clear Shift Background: Leagues focus

More information

Settling In 2018 Main Indicators of Immigrant Integration

Settling In 2018 Main Indicators of Immigrant Integration Settling In 2018 Main Indicators of Immigrant Integration Settling In 2018 Main Indicators of Immigrant Integration Notes on Cyprus 1. Note by Turkey: The information in this document with reference to

More information

1. Global Disparities Overview

1. Global Disparities Overview 1. Global Disparities Overview The world is not an equal place, and throughout history there have always been inequalities between people, between countries and between regions. Today the world s population

More information

Civil and Political Rights

Civil and Political Rights DESIRED OUTCOMES All people enjoy civil and political rights. Mechanisms to regulate and arbitrate people s rights in respect of each other are trustworthy. Civil and Political Rights INTRODUCTION The

More information

The globalization of inequality

The globalization of inequality The globalization of inequality François Bourguignon Paris School of Economics Public lecture, Canberra, May 2013 1 "In a human society in the process of unification inequality between nations acquires

More information

QGIS.org - Donations and Sponsorship Analysis 2016

QGIS.org - Donations and Sponsorship Analysis 2016 QGIS.org - Donations and Sponsorship Analysis 2016 QGIS.ORG received 1128 donations and 47 sponsorships. This equals to >3 donations every day and almost one new or renewed sponsorship every week. The

More information

ISSUE BRIEF: U.S. Immigration Priorities in a Global Context

ISSUE BRIEF: U.S. Immigration Priorities in a Global Context Immigration Task Force ISSUE BRIEF: U.S. Immigration Priorities in a Global Context JUNE 2013 As a share of total immigrants in 2011, the United States led a 24-nation sample in familybased immigration

More information

However, a full account of their extent and makeup has been unknown up until now.

However, a full account of their extent and makeup has been unknown up until now. SPECIAL REPORT F2008 African International Student Census However, a full account of their extent and makeup has been unknown up until now. or those who have traveled to many countries throughout the world,

More information

Protests under non-democratic regimes: contingent democrats versus genuine democrats

Protests under non-democratic regimes: contingent democrats versus genuine democrats Protests under non-democratic regimes: contingent democrats versus genuine democrats Margarita Zavadskaya PhD Researcher European University Institute (Florence, Italy) European University at Saint Petersburg

More information

Learning from Other Countries---and from Ourselves: the case of demography. Cliff Adelman, Institute for Higher Education Policy March 5, 2013

Learning from Other Countries---and from Ourselves: the case of demography. Cliff Adelman, Institute for Higher Education Policy March 5, 2013 Learning from Other Countries---and from Ourselves: the case of demography Cliff Adelman, Institute for Higher Education Policy March 5, 2013 What are we going to talk about? Demography in a new key: an

More information

2017 Social Progress Index

2017 Social Progress Index 2017 Social Progress Index Central Europe Scorecard 2017. For information, contact Deloitte Touche Tohmatsu Limited In this pack: 2017 Social Progress Index rankings Country scorecard(s) Spotlight on indicator

More information

Table A.1. Jointly Democratic, Contiguous Dyads (for entire time period noted) Time Period State A State B Border First Joint Which Comes First?

Table A.1. Jointly Democratic, Contiguous Dyads (for entire time period noted) Time Period State A State B Border First Joint Which Comes First? Online Appendix Owsiak, Andrew P., and John A. Vasquez. 2016. The Cart and the Horse Redux: The Timing of Border Settlement and Joint Democracy. British Journal of Political Science, forthcoming. Appendix

More information

Bulletin. Networking Skills Shortages in EMEA. Networking Labour Market Dynamics. May Analyst: Andrew Milroy

Bulletin. Networking Skills Shortages in EMEA. Networking Labour Market Dynamics. May Analyst: Andrew Milroy May 2001 Bulletin Networking Skills Shortages in EMEA Analyst: Andrew Milroy In recent months there have been signs of an economic slowdown in North America and in Western Europe. Additionally, many technology

More information

Question Q204P. Liability for contributory infringement of IPRs certain aspects of patent infringement

Question Q204P. Liability for contributory infringement of IPRs certain aspects of patent infringement Summary Report Question Q204P Liability for contributory infringement of IPRs certain aspects of patent infringement Introduction At its Congress in 2008 in Boston, AIPPI passed Resolution Q204 Liability

More information

Explaining case selection in African politics research

Explaining case selection in African politics research JOURNAL OF CONTEMPORARY AFRICAN STUDIES, 2017 https://doi.org/10.1080/02589001.2017.1387237 Explaining case selection in African politics research Ryan C. Briggs Department of Political Science, Virginia

More information

Gender pay gap in public services: an initial report

Gender pay gap in public services: an initial report Introduction This report 1 examines the gender pay gap, the difference between what men and women earn, in public services. Drawing on figures from both Eurostat, the statistical office of the European

More information

Constitution of the ICPO-INTERPOL

Constitution of the ICPO-INTERPOL OFFICE OF LEGAL AFFAIRS Constitution of the ICPO-INTERPOL [I/CONS/GA/1956(2008)] REFERENCES The Constitution of the ICPO-INTERPOL adopted by the General Assembly at its 25th session (Vienna - 1956). Articles

More information

RESEARCH NOTE The effect of public opinion on social policy generosity

RESEARCH NOTE The effect of public opinion on social policy generosity Socio-Economic Review (2009) 7, 727 740 Advance Access publication June 28, 2009 doi:10.1093/ser/mwp014 RESEARCH NOTE The effect of public opinion on social policy generosity Lane Kenworthy * Department

More information

World Peace Index Its Significance and Contribution to the Scientific Study of World Peace

World Peace Index Its Significance and Contribution to the Scientific Study of World Peace World Peace Index Its Significance and Contribution to the Scientific Study of World Peace The 3 rd OECD WORLD FORUM October 29, 2009, BUSAN, KOREA Sang-Hyun Lee Acting Director, The World Peace Forum

More information

SLOW PACE OF RESETTLEMENT LEAVES WORLD S REFUGEES WITHOUT ANSWERS

SLOW PACE OF RESETTLEMENT LEAVES WORLD S REFUGEES WITHOUT ANSWERS 21 June 2016 SLOW PACE OF RESETTLEMENT LEAVES WORLD S REFUGEES WITHOUT ANSWERS Australia and the world s wealthiest nations have failed to deliver on promises to increase resettlement for the world s neediest

More information

Perceptions of Corruption in Mass Publics

Perceptions of Corruption in Mass Publics Perceptions of Corruption in Mass Publics Sören Holmberg QoG WORKING PAPER SERIES 2009:24 THE QUALITY OF GOVERNMENT INSTITUTE Department of Political Science University of Gothenburg Box 711 SE 405 30

More information

Determinants of the Trade Balance in Industrialized Countries

Determinants of the Trade Balance in Industrialized Countries Determinants of the Trade Balance in Industrialized Countries Martin Falk FIW workshop foreign direct investment Wien, 16 Oktober 2008 Motivation large and persistent trade deficits USA, Greece, Portugal,

More information

The Multidimensional Financial Inclusion MIFI 1

The Multidimensional Financial Inclusion MIFI 1 2016 Report Tracking Financial Inclusion The Multidimensional Financial Inclusion MIFI 1 Financial Inclusion Financial inclusion is an essential ingredient of economic development and poverty reduction

More information

8 Absolute and Relative Effects of Interest Groups on the Economy*

8 Absolute and Relative Effects of Interest Groups on the Economy* 8 Absolute and Relative Effects of Interest Groups on the Economy* Dennis Coates and Jac C. Heckelman The literature on growth across countries, regions and states has burgeoned in recent years. Mancur

More information

Mapping physical therapy research

Mapping physical therapy research Mapping physical therapy research Supplement Johan Larsson Skåne University Hospital, Revingevägen 2, 247 31 Södra Sandby, Sweden January 26, 2017 Contents 1 Additional maps of Europe, North and South

More information

Contracting Parties to the Ramsar Convention

Contracting Parties to the Ramsar Convention Contracting Parties to the Ramsar Convention 14/12/2016 Number of Contracting Parties: 169 Country Entry into force Notes Albania 29.02.1996 Algeria 04.03.1984 Andorra 23.11.2012 Antigua and Barbuda 02.10.2005

More information

Part 1: The Global Gender Gap and its Implications

Part 1: The Global Gender Gap and its Implications the region s top performers on Estimated earned income, and has also closed the gender gap on Professional and technical workers. Botswana is among the best climbers Health and Survival subindex compared

More information

The Extraordinary Extent of Cultural Consumption in Iceland

The Extraordinary Extent of Cultural Consumption in Iceland 1 Culture and Business Conference in Iceland February 18 2011 Prof. Dr. Ágúst Einarsson Bifröst University PP 1 The Extraordinary Extent of Cultural Consumption in Iceland Prof. Dr. Ágúst Einarsson, Bifröst

More information

EU Ornamental Fish Import & Export Statistics 2017 (Third Countries & Intra-EU Community trade)

EU Ornamental Fish Import & Export Statistics 2017 (Third Countries & Intra-EU Community trade) ORNAMENTAL AQUATIC TRADE ASSOCIATION LTD. "The Voice of the Ornamental Fish Industry" 1 st Floor Office Suite, Wessex House 40 Station Road, Westbury, Wiltshire United Kingdom BA13 3JN T: +44 (0)1373 301353

More information

What Are the Social Outcomes of Education?

What Are the Social Outcomes of Education? Indicator What Are the Social Outcomes of Education? Adults aged 25 to 64 with higher levels of al attainment are, on average, more satisfied with life, engaged in society and likely to report that they

More information

Community Well-Being and the Great Recession

Community Well-Being and the Great Recession Pathways Spring 2013 3 Community Well-Being and the Great Recession by Ann Owens and Robert J. Sampson The effects of the Great Recession on individuals and workers are well studied. Many reports document

More information

The National Police Immigration Service (NPIS) forcibly returned 375 persons in March 2018, and 136 of these were convicted offenders.

The National Police Immigration Service (NPIS) forcibly returned 375 persons in March 2018, and 136 of these were convicted offenders. Statistics March 2018: Forced returns from Norway The National Police Immigration Service (NPIS) forcibly returned 375 persons in March 2018, and 136 of these were convicted offenders. The NPIS is responsible

More information

REFUGEES AND ASYLUM SEEKERS, THE CRISIS IN EUROPE AND THE FUTURE OF POLICY

REFUGEES AND ASYLUM SEEKERS, THE CRISIS IN EUROPE AND THE FUTURE OF POLICY REFUGEES AND ASYLUM SEEKERS, THE CRISIS IN EUROPE AND THE FUTURE OF POLICY Tim Hatton University of Essex (UK) and Australian National University International Migration Institute 13 January 2016 Forced

More information

2010 Human Development Report: 40-year Trends Analysis Shows Poor Countries Making Faster Development Gains

2010 Human Development Report: 40-year Trends Analysis Shows Poor Countries Making Faster Development Gains Strictly embargoed until 4 November 2010, 10:00 AM EDT (New York), 14:00PM GST 2010 Human Development Report: 40-year Trends Analysis Shows Poor Countries Making Faster Development Gains 20th anniversary

More information

How does education affect the economy?

How does education affect the economy? 2. THE ECONOMIC AND SOCIAL BENEFITS OF EDUCATION How does education affect the economy? More than half of the GDP growth in OECD countries over the past decade is related to labour income growth among

More information