A TimeSpace for electoral geography: economic restructuring, political agency and the rise of the Nazi party

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "A TimeSpace for electoral geography: economic restructuring, political agency and the rise of the Nazi party"

Transcription

1 Political Geography 20 (2001) A TimeSpace for electoral geography: economic restructuring, political agency and the rise of the Nazi party Colin Flint * Department of Geography, Pennsylvania State University, University Park, PA 16803, USA Abstract Using the electoral rise of the Nazi party in Weimar Germany as an example, this paper proposes the use of cyclico-ideological TimeSpace from Immanuel Wallerstein for the analysis of electoral geography. Elections are viewed as acts of political agency within structural constraints. From a world-systems perspective, the temporal dynamics and spatial structure of the capitalist world-economy are used to identify Weimar Germany as a semi-peripheral country during a period of global economic stagnation and restructuring, a Kondratieff B-phase. The structure and dynamics of the world-economy are expected to mobilize three classes in the semi-periphery; the national bourgeoisie, professionals, and skilled workers. Conflicts between factions of capital in Weimar Germany, defined by the economic restructuring, created a period of political instability exploited by the Nazi party. Furthermore, the Nazi party pursued policies to capture the votes of the three classes mobilized in the semi-periphery. However, electoral politics was mediated by regional contextual settings so that different classes supported the Nazi party in different regions of Germany. The regional specificity of the Nazi party s ability to capture the votes of people disaffected by the dynamics of the world-economy is modeled using spatial regression models. Consideration of a cyclico-ideological TimeSpace allows electoral geography to analyze how voters in contextual settings react to global processes Elsevier Science Ltd. All rights reserved. Keywords: World-systems analysis; Electoral geography; Nazi party; TimeSpace * Tel.: ; fax: address: flint@geog.psu.edu (C. Flint) /01/$ - see front matter 2001 Elsevier Science Ltd. All rights reserved. PII: S (00)

2 302 C. Flint / Political Geography 20 (2001) Introduction Electoral geography and electoral studies have focused on particular and constrained dimensions of time and space, namely, a single election or series of elections within a particular state or smaller political jurisdiction. Attempts by electoral geographers to break out of these temporal and spatial scales of analysis have theorized space rather than time. Space, or the geographic context of political behavior, has been theorized by electoral geographers as either a place-specific (Agnew, 1987), neighborhood (Johnston & Pattie, 1998) or regional (Archer & Shelley, 1986) dimension. Also, global spaces of democratic and non-democratic regimes have been mapped (O Loughlin et al., 1998). However, these conceptualizations of space are incomplete without a consideration of time. Wallerstein (1998) defines the concept of TimeSpace to show that time and space are intertwined into a single dimension. In other words, the spaces defined by electoral geographers are imbued with a particular temporal domain. Interpreting electoral geographies within a TimeSpace broader than the single event of a particular election promotes electoral geography as the study of political agency within structural constraints. In other words, electoral geography is the analysis of visible manifestations of political choices and strategies within the dynamics of the world-economy. This essay illustrates the benefits of conceptualizing electoral geography in a cyclico-ideological TimeSpace by reference to global economic restructuring and the subsequent crisis of the state in Weimar Germany that led to the electoral rise of the Nazi party (NSDAP or National Socialist German Workers Party). Criticisms of electoral geography have characterized the sub-discipline as data driven and divorced from theoretical innovations regarding the social construction of space and place (Ó Tuathail 1996, 1998; Reynolds, 1993). Electoral geography is in danger of being left behind as the rest of the discipline engages the spatial turn in the social sciences. On the other hand, electoral geography is uniquely positioned to inform theoretical debates by providing empirical analysis and evaluation of theoretical frameworks. Thus, electoral geography may play a pivotal role by showing the spatiality of the political manifestations of a variety of social theories. One such social theory, and the one I have chosen to adopt, is Immanuel Wallerstein s worldsystems theory. Wallerstein (1998) identifies five varieties of TimeSpace; episodic geopolitical, cyclico-ideological, structural, eternal, and transformational. Of these five, the episodic geopolitical and cyclico-ideological TimeSpaces are most relevant to this paper. Episodic geopolitical TimeSpaces are the categories used to discuss immediate history or events (Wallerstein, p. 72). The key point is those conceptualizing elections, for example, as events can divorce them from broader but related processes, such as economic change. Cyclico-ideological TimeSpace is the category used to discuss phenomena by reference to the dynamics of the capitalist world-economy (Wallerstein, p. 73). Interpreting an event, such as an election, in a cyclico-ideological TimeSpace allows for the inclusion of processes operating at other temporal and spatial scales. Conceptualizing electoral geography within a cyclico-ideological

3 C. Flint / Political Geography 20 (2001) TimeSpace leads to an analysis of electoral politics as local collective responses within a global structural setting. Structural TimeSpace refers to the long-term structures and institutions that define historical systems, such as the capitalist world-economy (Wallerstein, 1998, p. 73). For example, a core-periphery hierarchy is a necessary and constant feature of the capitalist world-economy and the spatial manifestations of core and peripheral processes constrain the possibilities of electoral politics (Taylor, 1986). Transformational TimeSpaces are particular moments when social action may profoundly affect the institutions and structures of historical systems (Wallerstein, p. 72). If the Nazis had been successful then one could hypothesize the attempted establishment of a worldempire to challenge the capitalist world-economy. However, the Nazis failure prevented such transformational action. Finally, eternal TimeSpaces are constant and pervasive relationships such as the perceived aggressive instincts of human beings (Wallerstein, p. 73), and hence act as ideological constructs. The particular usefulness of Wallerstein s framework lies in its ability to transgress the dominant view of social science that time and space are exogenous, and, therefore unimportant in social actions (Wallerstein, 1998, p. 79). Instead, the spatial extent of elections at the national scale, for example, is a social construct and a means to limit the impact of social change. The state, an institution of the capitalist worldeconomy, limits the scope of electoral politics to within its borders and also promotes a national rather than a global agenda. On the other hand, consideration of a cyclicoideological TimeSpace situates elections within the dynamics of the capitalist worldeconomy. Hence, electoral behavior is a means to react to and influence structural developments through the control of one institution of the historical system. Within the framework of TimeSpaces, electoral geography becomes the analysis of creating limited spaces of power within the constraints of the capitalist world-economy. The focus of the paper is upon an appropriate TimeSpace for electoral geography, one that allows electoral geography to engage political agency and the structure and dynamics of the capitalist world-economy simultaneously. The structure and cyclical dynamics of the capitalist world-economy will be described to define a TimeSpace to explain electoral behavior. Specifically, electoral politics in the semi-periphery at a time of global economic restructuring will be discussed. Structural and cyclicoideological TimeSpaces have been used to interpret electoral politics at a time of economic growth and/or in other parts of the world-economy [for example, see Osei- Kwame and Taylor (1984) and Archer and Taylor (1981)]. However, the electoral rise of the Nazi party in Weimar Germany offers a particularly fertile exemplification of political agency within global dynamics and state institutions via the mobilization of voters within local spatial settings. The paper is organized in the following way. First a brief summary of the relevant dynamics and processes of the capitalist world-economy will be given. Then a discussion of the state as an institution within the capitalist world-economy will demonstrate the concept of maneuverability, crisis, and the implications for electoral dynamics. Third particular manifestations of these dynamics and processes in Weimar Germany are explored through an examination of economic and social data and, fourth, the role of political agency is explored through a discussion of state crises

4 304 C. Flint / Political Geography 20 (2001) and the response of political coalitions. Finally, data showing the electoral support for the Nazi party within particular spatial settings is reported and interpreted within a context of global economic restructuring. In conclusion, it is argued that the particular economic and political constraints faced by the established parties became opportunities for the Nazi party. These opportunities were exploited by the Nazi party and resulted in the mobilization of electoral support in local spatial settings. By applying Wallerstein s cyclico-ideological TimeSpace to theorize the construction of electoral politics at the local scale, electoral geography shows how the global scale is implicated in the construction of place-specific politics. TimeSpace and the politics of the world-economy The temporal and spatial elements of a cyclico-ideological TimeSpace relevant to electoral geography can be defined by reference to world-systems theory (Wallerstein, 1979; Wallerstein, 1984a). Kondratieff waves regulate the temporal dynamic of the capitalist world-economy. These are 50 year economic fluctuations at the global scale consisting of 25 years of economic growth (an A-phase) followed by 25 years of economic stagnation and restructuring (a B-phase) (Wallerstein, 1984b). Associated with each A-phase is a new technological innovation that leads to a new round of investment. The B-phase is a period in which the capitalist worldeconomy reorganizes to allow for another period of economic growth (Wallerstein, 1984b). The formation of electoral politics within states is a manifestation of political agency within the constraints of the world-system set by these dynamics. There are four features of restructuring during a Kondratieff B-phase: the peripheralization of core-like activities to reduce costs, the creation of new core-like activities to attract new investment, conflicts between classes within states and within classes between states that serve to increase overall consumer demand, and the expansion of the borders of the world-economy to incorporate new pools of cheap workers (Wallerstein, 1984a, pp ). In combination, the features of B-phase restructuring allow for a renewed round of economic growth and capital accumulation by simultaneously reducing the production costs of established economic activities, creating new lead sectors to attract investment, and reorganizing the geographic pattern of consumption such that more people in the world-economy can consume at high levels to produce consumer demand for the new innovation (Wallerstein, p. 16). Two significant political economic implications result from these processes. First, the peripheralization of established industries and the creation of new lead sectors leads to tensions and differences of interest within the capitalist class. That section of the capital elite related to new core-like industries will favor policies facilitating free-trade, minimal government subsidies, and the creation of an educated if expensive workforce. On the other hand, capital interests related to the declining industries are likely to favor protectionist policies and a further reduction of costs via a disciplined workforce. Each of these capital interests will require something different out of the state apparatus and so will be unable to unite in a political alliance.

5 C. Flint / Political Geography 20 (2001) Second, the working class is also divided between those employed in the emerging industries and those with jobs in industries that are being peripheralized. However, all workers and members of the working class are likely to experience acute difficulties because of the global economic downturn. In such a situation, members of the electorate may look to the state to provide respite, but the state may not have the funds to offer assistance. Economic crisis and political impotency can then provoke new political agendas, ones that offer alternative visions of state, society, and economics. The spatial component of the TimeSpace context requires reference to the different processes in operation in the capitalist world-economy. Wallerstein (1984a, p. 16) identifies two types of processes in the capitalist world-economy. Core processes are economic activities that add a large amount of value to a product (such as services and skilled manufacturing), command high wages, and, therefore, are associated with high levels of consumption (Wallerstein, p. 4). On the other hand, peripheral processes are the exact opposites, the social relations of peasant agriculture for example. The tendency for the core and peripheral processes to cluster in particular parts of the world leads to the definition of core or peripheral zones (Wallerstein, p. 15). Countries or zones in the world-economy where there is a relatively even mixture of core and peripheral processes are classified as the semi-periphery. Wallerstein (1979) identifies three major class dynamics that occur in the semiperiphery during a Kondratieff B-phase. First, the national bourgeoisie (or the internal property-owning bourgeoisie) seek security in a strong state to defend their position (Wallerstein, p. 102). Second, the state plays an important role in providing the guarantees and mechanisms for middle-class professionals to become small-property owners (Wallerstein, p. 105). This leads to the expectation that the selfemployed and professionals would support a political party aimed at expanding and strengthening state institutions. Third, the semi-periphery is the venue for a class struggle over the amount of surplus value to be appropriated by the proletariat. Either the proletariat s demands are kept in check by utilizing cheaper, or semi-proletarianized labor, or the demands are met and additional appropriation is extracted from the semi-proletariat (Wallerstein, p. 107). In Weimar Germany the former strategy was dominant. Though workers were able to bargain effectively for better wages and working conditions in the 1920s they were soon undermined by the effects of the Great Depression and the subsequent increase in the use of semi-skilled and unskilled labor (Kele, 1972; Childers, 1983). Thus, we would also expect skilled workers to support a political party with an agenda that suppressed the demands of manual workers. Though Wallerstein provides us with an expectation of the class dynamics within the semi-periphery, he offers no discussion of their interaction with politics and the state. The adoption of a cyclico-ideological TimeSpace results in a consideration of the state as an institution within the capitalist world-economy, and so subject to the constraints of the structure and dynamics of that historical system (Taylor 1991a,b, 1994). Political parties represent the interests of social groups seeking to control the state to maneuver it for their perceived benefit within the constraints of the worldeconomy (Taylor & Flint, 2000, p. 183). The changing nature of those constraints

6 306 C. Flint / Political Geography 20 (2001) will have an impact upon the efficacy of political parties to deliver on the programs designed for their constituents. However, particular cyclico-ideological TimeSpaces will negate the ability of traditionally dominant parties to maneuver the state effectively. Furthermore, during a Kondratieff B-phase, the broad class strategies identified by Wallerstein are fractured by the trajectory of different industrial sectors in the capitalist world-economy. Class interests are complicated by self-interest based upon employment in either a peripheralizing and stagnant industry or a dynamic and innovative sector (for examples of Weimar Germany see Brustein, 1996; Abraham, 1986). 1 The fracture of social class interests produces a particular crisis of the state, one that established electoral alliances are unable to accommodate. By considering a cyclico-ideological TimeSpace, electoral politics are seen as the means to gain access to the state apparatus to maneuver it within an inter-state context. The nature of that context is defined by the cycles and structures of the capitalist world-economy. Electoral dynamics are the geopolitical episodic manifestation of domestic political challenges and opportunities emanating from change within a cyclico-ideological TimeSpace. From this perspective, electoral geography analyzes the response of voters in localized spatial settings to global dynamics while also considering the way the structure of the world-economy limits political options (Taylor 1986, 1990; Osei-Kwame & Taylor, 1984). For example, the economic crisis within Weimar Germany is understood as the turbulence facing a country containing a mixture of core and peripheral processes at a time of economic restructuring. On the other hand, political ideologies, programs, parties, and constituencies are acts of political agency. In other words, global and cyclical contexts offer opportunities and constraints for political actors. The opportunities and constraints facing politicians and voters in Weimar Germany will be addressed in the following section. Empirical support for the argument that electoral behavior can be explained from a cyclico-ideological perspective requires a number of steps. First, social and economic data must be used to establish Weimar Germany as a semi-peripheral zone. Second, the nature of the economic conflicts within Weimar Germany is described, followed by their translation into party politics. Finally, the ability of the Nazi party to use the economic and political dynamics to their advantage is examined. Following Wallerstein s identification of the class dynamics within the semi-periphery during a period of restructuring, the professional and national middle-class, and skilled workers, are expected to have supported the Nazi party. A spatial analysis of the socio-economic composition of the Nazi party electorate examines how the structural processes of class conflict were mediated within spatial settings to create regionallyspecific electorates. 1 David Abraham s (1986) book has been the topic of intense and troubling criticism [see Abraham (1983, 1984), Turner (1983), Mason (1983) and Feldman (1984) for details]. However, I have avoided the empirical details of Abraham s work that have been the most hotly contested. More important, it is not Abraham s factual detail that is important to this paper but his question regarding how divided elites create national projects (Abraham, 1984, p. 186). It is this theoretical framework that is important for my own regarding electoral support and state maneuverability in the capitalist world-economy.

7 C. Flint / Political Geography 20 (2001) Weimar Germany and the semi-periphery In his history of the Weimar Republic, Peukert (1993) identifies inter-war Germany as a society at the crossroads facing modernization and its tribulations. Looking past the developmentalist tone of these phrases, Peukert identified the tensions and dynamics of a semi-peripheral zone at a time of economic restructuring and as it was harnessing a greater share of core processes. For example, German society had been experiencing demographic changes since about 1900 with increasing life-expectancy, a declining birth rate, and growing acceptance of the two-child family model (Peukert, p. 7 12). In other words, Germany was undergoing a move toward demographic patterns associated with core countries. Underlying these demographic changes were changes in the pattern of employment across industrial sectors. The general trend was a decline in the percentage of workers employed in the primary sector, from about 48% of the workforce in 1880 to 25% in 1939 (Peukert, 1993, p. 9). Employment in the tertiary sector grew from just more than 20% in 1880 to about 32% in 1939 and employment in the secondary sector fluctuated over this period but by 1939 was at just less than 40%, up from 29% of the workforce in 1880 (Peukert, p. 9). In conjunction with these trends, the class structure also changed dramatically. The proportion of the workforce who were selfemployed fell from 20% in 1907 to 16% in 1925 (Peukert, p. 10). On the other hand, the percentage of white-collar workers and public officials rose from 10% to 17% in the same period (Peukert, p. 10). Not surprisingly, rural to urban migration continued, though the rate declined from the period at the turn of the century. In 1925, about one-third of the German population fell into each of the categories of city-dweller, small-town resident or rural resident (Peukert, p. 10). Further evidence for Germany s semi-peripheral status is found in the mosaic of modes of production to be found in Weimar Germany. Particular regions were the location of agriculture, industry, or services in which the relations of production were defined by core or peripheral processes. In aggregation, at the national scale the relatively balanced mosaic of core and peripheral processes produced a semiperipheral state. Alongside industrial capitalism there also existed vestiges of feudalism as well as family-peasant, and small-commodity production (Abraham, 1986, p. 10). With regard to agriculture, the eastern provinces of East Prussia, Pommerania, Grenzmark, Posen, Brandenburg, and Silesia (Fig. 1) were dominated by large grainproducing farms owned by Junkers and employing salaried agricultural workers (Brustein, 1996, p. 64). The states of Middle Germany (Saxony, Thuringia and Anhalt) (Fig. 1) contained a high proportion of independent small- and mediumsized farms producing a variety of crops (Brustein, p. 64). Farms in the northwest region of Germany (Hannover, Schleswig Holstein, Mecklenburg, Oldenburg, Braunschweig, and Schaumburg Lippe) (Fig. 1) were mainly independently owned, medium-sized and specialized in animal husbandry (Brustein, p. 65). Agriculture in the three remaining regions of Rhineland Westphalia, Hesse and southern Germany (Fig. 1) was distinguished by the practice of partible inheritance, whereby land was divided amongst heirs (Brustein, p. 65). Thus, the diversity of modes of production

8 308 C. Flint / Political Geography 20 (2001) Fig. 1. Regions and cities of Weimar Germany. in agriculture was defined by economic factors, such as farm size and ownership, but also by the maintenance of different social relations. The dominance of the Junker classes as well as the existence of peasant agriculture produced a complex mixture of modes of production, such that Abraham argues that Weimar Germany still suffered not only from the development of capitalist production, but also from its incompleteness. Alongside of modern evils, a whole series of inherited evils oppress us, arising from the survival of antiquated modes of production (Marx, 1967, p. 9 quoted in Abraham, 1986, p. 10). Within industry, different attitudes toward free-trade, labor relations, and the role of the state produced a variety of relations of production (Abraham, pp ). The German state was defining new core-like economic practices by playing an advanced role in the management and control of the economy and increasing workers involvement in decision-making, a relationship that was to define the post-1945 core economies under the title of Keynesian economics (Haimson, 1989). The definition of these new state-economy relationships at the same time as the vestiges of feudalism were being maintained in the Junker estates is the most vivid illustration of the existence of core and peripheral processes in Weimar Germany. Changes were also occurring in the service sector. A tension existed between an old middle class of shopkeepers and artisans and a new middle class of white collar employees (clerical staff and civil servants) (Brustein, 1996). The expansion of a German welfare state and the increased profile of department stores and consumer cooperatives threatened the way of life and livelihood of shopkeepers and owners of other small businesses as they had to compete with bigger enterprises and provide

9 C. Flint / Political Geography 20 (2001) contributions to pay for state benefits (Abraham, 1986). On the other hand, the new middle classes employed by the government were dependent upon those contributions for their salaries. In Weimar Germany, the increased role of the state and processes of rationalization were threatening the traditional independence and status of the old middle class, while a new class of salaried employees was forming. The mixture of demographic change, modes of production, industrial dynamics and class formation in Weimar Germany give support for the contention that it was a country in the 1920s and 1930s with a mixture of core and peripheral processes. Furthermore, all the trends affirm that core processes were beginning to outweigh peripheral processes. The transition from semi-peripheral to core status occurs during a period of B-phase restructuring when semi-peripheral countries have greater relative power toward core countries (Wallerstein, 1979, p. 100). Thus, the full story of flux and division within Weimar Germany requires concentration upon the implications of the processes of B-phase restructuring. Economic restructuring and Weimar Germany Kondratieff B-phase restructuring is a periodic crisis aimed at reversing periods of over-accumulation by devaluing capital. Idle fixed capital, inflation, unemployment, and the destruction of fixed capital are all means of devaluing capital (Harvey, 1982, p. 194). Specific examples of these processes were to be found in Weimar Germany. The presence of idle fixed capital is evident by the production index in being half of what it was in (Petzina, 1969). Between 1918 and 1923, inflation was rampant. In 1923, the currency was stabilized by the introduction of the Rentenmark when the paper mark exchanged at the rate of 4,200,000,000,000 to the dollar. In 1932, the official unemployment figure was six million, but many once entitled to unemployment benefit could no longer claim at that time, and one in three of the workforce were estimated to be without employment (Petzina, p. 60). The destruction of fixed capital was also prevalent. In 1931, disinvestment decreases in inventory and the wearing down of industrial plant amounted to approximately five billion marks (Stolper, 1967, p. 119). B-phase restructuring is also a period where new core-like activities are defined and old ones peripheralized. A major cleavage within the German bourgeoisie existed during the Weimar Republic based on the different trajectory of industries (Abraham, 1986). On the one hand were capital interests in the new and dynamic electrical, chemical, machine and textile industries. These industries can be equated with the new core-like innovations in Wallerstein s (1979, 1984a) language. On the other hand were the older iron and steel and extractive industries which were facing pressures of peripheralization. The different fortunes facing these industries are reflected in production and employment figures. The peripheralization of the mining industry is exemplified by the large declines in output and the size of the workforce. The number of coal mines declined from 350 in 1913 to 223 in 1932, and the size of the workforce and output dropped by about 50% in the same period (Statistisches Jahrbuch für das Deutsche Reich (SJDR),

10 310 C. Flint / Political Geography 20 (2001) ). In the steel industry, the number of plants using the Thomas and Bessemer methods declined as core-industries while the number of plants using the new electric oven method rose from 27 in 1913 to 48 in 1931 (SJDR, 1933). Economic rationalization was evident in the chemical industry as the number of sulfuric acid plants declined, from 107 in 1913 to 67 in 1931, and the size of the workforce was reduced to a third of its original size in the same period, while output remained steady (SJDR, 1933). Oil-refining, at this time, began to impose itself as a new core process, as the size of the workforce rose from 1958 in 1913 to 6816 in 1931 (SJDR, 1933). Within the textile industry, high value products such as silk were doing well, with the number of plants and size of the workforce increasing, compared to the same trends in flax (SJDR, 1933). These trends illustrate the broad processes of German economic transition within the constraints and opportunities of Kondratieff B-phase restructuring. New sectors of industry were becoming dominant over the older ones, such as mining and the majority of the iron and steel industry, and these new sectors had the ability and desire to compete in the world-economy. The older sectors wanted to remain domestically oriented behind protectionist tariffs. Another difference between the dynamic and stagnating industries in Weimar Germany was the form of labor relations. Following on from government involvement in the economy during the First World War, the Weimar economy saw the development of corporatist policies (Haimson, 1989). One manifestation of this process was the growth in collective contracts, a written contract between employers and employees regulating working conditions. Two million employees were working under collective contracts before World War One in comparison to twelve to fourteen million in the Weimar Republic (Reich, 1938, p. 107). Comparison of the number of employees per collective contract across industrial sectors indicates a disparity between the agricultural, mining, and metal sectors versus the machines and tools, chemical, textiles, and woodwork sectors (SJDR, 1929). Broadly speaking, the dynamic industries were more likely to adopt collective contracts than those facing peripheralization within the world-economy. The pattern of collective contracts is evidence that core processes were being redefined in some sections of German industry and not others. The dynamic exportoriented industries adopted new mechanized production processes which reduced the necessary labor input (Abraham, 1986, p. 13). Consequently, the relative cost of labor input in the production process declined, but the amount of surplus value gained by the worker increased. For example, wages grew in the oil-refining sector, compared to the decline of wages in the coal mining industry (SJDR, 1933). Differences in the adoption of collective contracts and wage increases across industrial sectors reflect the class struggles within Kondratieff B-phase restructuring. Collective contracts were part of innovative labor relations that produced higher wages and higher consumption. Therefore, augmenting world effective demand (Wallerstein, 1984a, p. 17). Another component of the innovation of new core-like activities is the development of new production processes. Such new processes were introduced under the title of rationalization which, in Weimar Germany, took the form of the managerial principles of Taylorism and labor- or time-saving forms of investment (Peukert,

11 C. Flint / Political Geography 20 (2001) , p. 113). Rationalization was perceived differently by entrepreneurs in the dynamic and declining industries. Elites in heavy industry saw rationalization as a means of maintaining power over the workforce, while those in the chemical and electrical industries viewed it as a means of securing the cooperation of workers (Peukert, 1993, p. 112). The macrochanges occurring in the service sector have already been described. In the agricultural sector livestock and dairy farmers had made investments to make their enterprises more capital intensive. The result was increasing indebtedness as agricultural prices fell in the late 1920s (Brustein, 1996, p. 66). For the agricultural sector, global restructuring meant a shift from national markets to global competition. New economic imperatives favored the importation of cheaper agricultural products from neighboring countries and the influx of American capital went mainly to the industrial sector (Abraham, 1986, p. 44). The result was that global capitalism was intruding into German agriculture where anticapitalist sentiments and vestiges of feudal practices existed (Abraham, p. 171). Economic stagnation and restructuring were evident in Weimar Germany. The tensions between fractions of capital within Germany, the growth of collective bargaining, and the devaluation of capital illustrate the conflicts that emanated from Kondratieff B-phase restructuring. However, the specific nature of these processes did not simply emerge from structural necessities, but were defined by political struggles. Though restructuring was necessary, such a transition was contingent upon political action within states. The following section shows that in Weimar Germany the outcome was political impotency on behalf of established parties and aggressive agency and opportunism by parties of the extreme left and right. TimeSpace and coalition building in Weimar Germany The key rift within the Weimar bourgeoisie ran between those with a global export-oriented perspective and those preferring an autarkic stance. Abraham (1986) argues that the new and dynamic industries were interested in low prices for basic industrial goods, pacific expansion through trade treaties, and did not perceive wage and social costs as important as long as international economic preeminence was gained. In contrast, the older industries, focused upon the domestic market, wanted higher prices and low costs, and faced a higher share of total costs in the form of wages. Cleavage also existed within German agriculture between the large estates who wanted self-sufficiency in grain at relatively high prices versus the smallholders who wanted to import feed from Germany s neighbors at cheaper prices (Abraham). However, peasants and estate owners managed to maintain a united political front until The established political parties neglected the political interests of the new middle class and concentrated upon industrial and agricultural issues instead (Brustein, 1996). This neglect was to have grave consequences as the Nazi party began to tap into the political concerns of civil servants as well as the old middle class. With specific reference to trade policies, W.D. Smith supports Abraham s argument by saying:

12 312 C. Flint / Political Geography 20 (2001) On the whole, the heavy-industrial organizations tended to accept the idea of autarky more readily than did the representatives of the other major agglomerations, both because they had a long history of attempting to accommodate the agrarian right and because their export aims were still largely directed toward continental Europe and thus could be to some extent encompassed within an autarkic economic policy. On the other hand, banks, industries dependent on extra- European imports, and industries with diversified markets abroad found the prospect of an autarkic economic policy less attractive under normal circumstances (W.D. Smith, 1986, p. 211). The fractures within the Weimar bourgeoisie led to the construction of political coalitions to form governments that could maneuver the state to the perceived benefit of particular interests. The dynamic and export branches preferred coalitions with organized labor and salaried employees, while heavy industry favored cooperation with the conservative rural sector (Abraham, 1986). The tensions between the different factions of industry were based upon their position on the world-economy, and the role of labor in the production process. The chief point of contention was the cost of labor as a result of the Republic s experimentation with industrial democracy as a means of negating socialist movements (Peukert, 1993, p. 127). The split within German industry was first manifested in 1895 when the Central League of German Industrialists split into two hostile organizations, supplemented by a host of regional, specialty, and commercial groups (Abraham, 1986, p. 107). The interests of dynamic export oriented industry tended to be dominant prior to 1931 while inter-industrial agreements were formed to maintain cohesion (Abraham, p. 108). However, in 1930, the three matters of inter-industry dispute labor costs, trade policies, and reparation payments could no longer be balanced. Chancellor Brüning s government required the support of the Social Democrats while promising lower wages, reduced state expenditures, a revision of reparation payments, austerity, and expanded trade (Abraham, p. 109). The contradictions of such a program came to a head when Brüning did not alter labor s economic gains and made moves to lower industrial payments to facilitate an export drive to fund rescheduled reparation payments. However, a decline in global trade after the Wall Street Crash of 1929 led to a shift in the political power of the different fractions of capital. Heavy industry believed that it could offer a united voice and outmaneuver dynamic industry, but the situation was one where the political interests of industry were divided and each sought alternative alliance partners (Abraham, pp ). Within the agricultural sector the lines of conflict ran between estate owners and peasants, though this was complicated by regionally-specific cultural practices of inheritance (Brustein, 1996, p. 93). However, though these groups had competing economic interests, rural social relations were more symbiotic than conflictual (Abraham, 1986, p. 43). The result was that peasants, on the whole, supported the rural elites, who acted as patrician. The basic economic divide between the two rural factions focused upon trade. Broadly speaking, the Junker class of estate owners wanted policies maintaining self-sufficiency in grain while promoting the import of dairy and livestock products (Brustein, p. 67). On the other hand, peasant farmers

13 C. Flint / Political Geography 20 (2001) wanted to import grain to provide cheap imputs for dairy and livestock production (Abraham, p. 68). These divisions led to an obvious alliance between heavy industry and estate owners on the one hand and export industry and peasants on the other. However, the relationship between peasants and owners resulted in combined support of organized agricultural interests until the agricultural crisis of 1928 (Abraham, p. 72). The agricultural crises affected peasants more adversely than the grain producers. The political implication was that estate owners could no longer provide a voice for all of German agriculture and the peasants switched their political allegiance to the bloc led by export industry. The old middle class was represented by the conservative DNVP (German Nationalist People s Party) and the two liberal parties, the DDP (German Democratic Party) and the DVP (German People s Party). These parties favored the established order and mixed desires for agricultural tariffs with an ideology of private enterprise and concern over increased costs for urban consumers (Brustein, 1996, p ). These parties also tried to woo the new middle class by cooperating with white collar unions and advocating free trade (Brustein, pp ). However, support for established middle class practices necessarily required an attack on new developments such as department stores and consumer cooperatives. The liberal parties were unable to represent both the old and new middle classes and the result was that neither the DVP nor DDP was able to offer many concrete policies that would have excited the new middle class (Brustein, p. 110). Hence, the new middle classes were looking for a party that would recognize their concerns. Tensions also existed between the capitalist and working classes in Weimar Germany, despite the tendency for the dynamic export oriented fraction of capital to be more accommodative toward the demands of an organized working class. The SPD (German Social Democratic Party) was not part of a ruling coalition from 1924 to 1928, but it still retained political influence as governments needed its support. Aided by an improvement in Germany s economic situation in the mid 1920s, the SPD was able to make gains for the working class in social welfare (Sozialpolitik) and labor legislation (Abraham, 1986, p. 221). Heavy industry, with its greater dependence upon labor inputs, became fearful of the gains made by the working class and began to attack it in However, it was not until global economic collapse and its impact on the export-oriented industries that capital interests formed a united front against the concessions gained by the working class. In December 1929, the League of German Industry published a report that signaled the end of a commitment toward Sozialpolitik and a move toward Wirtschaftpolitik, or policies more favorable to accumulation (Abraham, p. 252). At a time of economic downturn, the interests of capital and labor could not be blended into a form of society that balanced an imperative for accumulation and the need for legitimization (Habermas, 1975). After 1929, Weimar Germany had reached a crisis of the state in which neither capital nor labor interests believed that the established political parties could maneuver the state within the world-economy to their satisfaction. Furthermore, both interests were divided internally such that neither could form an alliance of parties. The working class was divided between supporters of the KPD (Communist Party of Germany) and the SPD, or a revolutionary and reformist stance (Nicholls, 1968,

14 314 C. Flint / Political Geography 20 (2001) p. 140). The bourgeois parties were split because of the gains made by white-collar workers as part of Sozialpolitik, as opposed to the self-employed who felt they were being overtaxed to pay for government policies favoring big business and organized labor (Brustein, 1996, p. 73). Economic restructuring and stagnation within Germany, as part of a global dynamic, had resulted in challenges to the particular form of the state, the Weimar Republic. In addition, a complex pattern of electoral alliances and conflicts had ebbed and flowed. The processes behind the collapse of these coalitions were the increasing strength of organized capital over organized labor (Anderson, 1945), the consequent loss of the need for cooperation between employers and employees, and the slowly growing dominance of capital interests involved in core processes and products over those being peripheralized. Thus, the imperatives of global economic restructuring, understood through a cyclico-ideological TimeSpace, created a context of political crisis. This context was seen as a window of opportunity for political agency by the Nazi party as they tailored their policies to the material needs of the German population. The NSDAP created political programs that promised to alleviate the specific economic concerns facing particular groups (Brustein, 1996). In addition, Lipset (1960) argues that the economic stresses being experienced by the lower middle classes in Germany made them particularly susceptible to the Nazi party s appeal. Alternatively, other scholars found the disaffected and alienated to be attracted to the NSDAP (Arendt, 1958; Kornhauser, 1959). In other words, the changes in Weimar society created a sense of anomie that the Nazi party was able to counter through membership in its organizations. Falter and Zintl (1988) provide evidence for a mixed cause hypothesis, that the middle class was radicalized by the economic changes to support the Nazis while, on the other hand, working class support for the Nazi party was the result of protests against the dire economic situation. Other authors have noted the relationship between economic and political crisis in Weimar Germany and the rise of the Nazi party (for examples see Geiger, 1930; Petzina, 1969; Borchardt, 1984). These contributions can be phrased as theories predicting the socio-economic basis of Nazi party electoral support. Lipset s (1960) theory leads to a prediction that white collar workers and the self-employed would have supported the Nazi party. The work of Arendt (1958) and Kornhauser (1959) suggests that the unemployed and previous non-voters supported the NSDAP. Falter s (1990) work has evolved into the notion of the Nazi party being a catch-all party, hence no particular socio-economic groups should stand out in the Nazi electorate. Brustein s (1996) rational choice approach demands that the basis of regionally-specific electorates be evaluated on the basis of the perception of the NSDAP as a party that could solve economic problems particular to different localities. Finally, Burnham (1972) notes that Catholic voters and the working class were relatively immune to the Nazis appeal. Though these theories may be evaluated by the empirical analysis below [see also O Loughlin, Flint, and Anselin (1994) and Flint (1998a)], they all view elections in Weimar as an episodic TimeSpace and do not situate Weimar electoral behavior within broader temporal and spatial scales.

15 C. Flint / Political Geography 20 (2001) Nazi party electoral support within a cyclico-ideological TimeSpace The Nazi party s national socialist agenda was one that could appeal to a broad spectrum of society faced with the challenges and uncertainties of B-phase restructuring in the semi-periphery. Specifically, the Nazi party offered a political program that appealed to the three classes identified by Wallerstein (1979, p. 103) as under most stress during economic restructuring. The notion of a strong state that would be assertive in the world-economy while also maintaining order and traditional privileges would appeal to the middle-class and the more skilled workers (Wallerstein, pp. 103 and 107; Mayer & Pois, 1990). However, reference to a cyclico-ideological TimeSpace predicts such class politics at a national scale. The contribution of electoral geography is to explain how national and global processes are mediated within local and regional spatial settings. The analysis of the spatial patterns in aggregate voting behavior shows how places with particular characteristics were susceptible to radical political mobilization at a time of economic restructuring. Brustein s (1996) rational choice approach to Nazi party membership offers a compelling argument as to why different socio-economic groups supported the Nazi party because of particular economic policies. The geographic dimension to this argument is added by showing how particular regional modes of production created local interests which were either represented by the Nazi party or not (Brustein, 1996; Ault & Brustein, 1998). Translating Brustein s (1996) rational choice approach into the analysis of electoral support illustrates one aspect of the state maneuverability thesis (Taylor & Flint, 2000, p. 183), namely that social groups facing particular issues sought control of the state by parties perceived to be sympathetic to their needs. Brustein s detailed analysis shows how people embedded within regionally-specific social and economic practices were either able to take advantage of global economic conditions or, on the other hand, were adversely affected. Further, the focus of their political activity was a party that could gain control of the state and, so the Nazi party supporters believed, maneuver the German state within the world-economy to their advantage. However, looking solely at the regional and state scales does not allow for an exploration of the sources of those concerns. In other words, only a consideration of a cyclico-ideological TimeSpace allows for questions of why a particular place (Weimar Germany) and why a particular time (1920s and 1930s)? Consideration of global economic restructuring and its impact upon political behavior in localized spatial settings forms a more complete consideration of both political agency and structural constraints. Scholars have reached a consensus that the Nazi party gained electoral support from a broad socio-economic spectrum of voters (Childers, 1983; Falter, 1990, 1991; O Loughlin et al., 1994; Flint 1998a). Though the Nazi party was less effective in prying Catholic voters away from the Center party and industrial workers from the Communist party (Burnham, 1972), it was able to attract significant electoral support from all other social groups. More specifically, the social groups looking for radical solutions, given Wallerstein s (1979) interpretation of semi-peripheral class dynamics, formed the foundation of the NSDAP s electoral support. Both the middle and working classes supported the Nazi party, with the working-class accounting for

IV. Social Stratification and Class Structure

IV. Social Stratification and Class Structure IV. Social Stratification and Class Structure 1. CONCEPTS I: THE CONCEPTS OF CLASS AND CLASS STATUS THE term 'class status' 1 will be applied to the typical probability that a given state of (a) provision

More information

ECONOMICS CHAPTER 11 AND POLITICS. Chapter 11

ECONOMICS CHAPTER 11 AND POLITICS. Chapter 11 CHAPTER 11 ECONOMICS AND POLITICS I. Why Focus on India? A. India is one of two rising powers (the other being China) expected to challenge the global power and influence of the United States. B. India,

More information

MARXISM AND INTERNATIONAL RELATIONS ELİF UZGÖREN AYSELİN YILDIZ

MARXISM AND INTERNATIONAL RELATIONS ELİF UZGÖREN AYSELİN YILDIZ MARXISM AND INTERNATIONAL RELATIONS ELİF UZGÖREN AYSELİN YILDIZ Outline Key terms and propositions within Marxism Marxism and IR: What is the relevance of Marxism today? Is Marxism helpful to explain current

More information

Types of Economies. 10x10learning.com

Types of Economies. 10x10learning.com Types of Economies 1 Economic System and Types of Economies Economic System An Economic System is the broad institutional framework, within which production and consumption of goods and services takes

More information

Labor Migration in the Kyrgyz Republic and Its Social and Economic Consequences

Labor Migration in the Kyrgyz Republic and Its Social and Economic Consequences Network of Asia-Pacific Schools and Institutes of Public Administration and Governance (NAPSIPAG) Annual Conference 200 Beijing, PRC, -7 December 200 Theme: The Role of Public Administration in Building

More information

Dependency theorists, or dependentistas, are a group of thinkers in the neo-marxist tradition mostly

Dependency theorists, or dependentistas, are a group of thinkers in the neo-marxist tradition mostly Dependency theorists and their view that development in the North takes place at the expense of development in the South. Dependency theorists, or dependentistas, are a group of thinkers in the neo-marxist

More information

MARXISM AND INTERNATIONAL RELATIONS ELİF UZGÖREN AYSELİN YILDIZ

MARXISM AND INTERNATIONAL RELATIONS ELİF UZGÖREN AYSELİN YILDIZ MARXISM AND INTERNATIONAL RELATIONS ELİF UZGÖREN AYSELİN YILDIZ Outline Key terms and propositions within Marxism Different approaches within Marxism Criticisms to Marxist theory within IR What is the

More information

World Systems Analysis

World Systems Analysis World Systems Analysis genealogy of the world-systems school c a b d a. Febvre & Bloch (1922/1929) b. Braudel (1949) c. Kondratieff (1925) d. Gunder Frank (1967) e. Wallerstein (1973) f. Taylor (1982/1985)

More information

Introducing Marxist Theories of the State

Introducing Marxist Theories of the State In the following presentation I shall assume that students have some familiarity with introductory Marxist Theory. Students requiring an introductory outline may click here. Students requiring additional

More information

Capitalists and Industrialization in India Surajit Mazumdar Historically industrialization has had a strong association with capitalism and

Capitalists and Industrialization in India Surajit Mazumdar Historically industrialization has had a strong association with capitalism and Capitalists and Industrialization in India Surajit Mazumdar Historically industrialization has had a strong association with capitalism and profit-oriented capitalist firms have been its important instruments

More information

GEOG 4712: Political Geography. Lecture 13: World Systems Analysis

GEOG 4712: Political Geography. Lecture 13: World Systems Analysis GEOG 4712: Political Geography Lecture 13: World Systems Analysis genealogy of the world-systems school c a b d a. Febvre & Bloch (1922/1929) b. Braudel (1949) c. Kondratieff (1925) d. Gunder Frank (1967)

More information

QUANTITATIVE ANALYSIS OF RURAL WORKFORCE RESOURCES IN ROMANIA

QUANTITATIVE ANALYSIS OF RURAL WORKFORCE RESOURCES IN ROMANIA QUANTITATIVE ANALYSIS OF RURAL WORKFORCE RESOURCES IN ROMANIA Elena COFAS University of Agricultural Sciences and Veterinary Medicine of Bucharest, Romania, 59 Marasti, District 1, 011464, Bucharest, Romania,

More information

Political Economy of. Post-Communism

Political Economy of. Post-Communism Political Economy of Post-Communism A liberal perspective: Only two systems Is Kornai right? Socialism One (communist) party State dominance Bureaucratic resource allocation Distorted information Absence

More information

CH 17: The European Moment in World History, Revolutions in Industry,

CH 17: The European Moment in World History, Revolutions in Industry, CH 17: The European Moment in World History, 1750-1914 Revolutions in Industry, 1750-1914 Explore the causes & consequences of the Industrial Revolution Root Europe s Industrial Revolution in a global

More information

Is Economic Development Good for Gender Equality? Income Growth and Poverty

Is Economic Development Good for Gender Equality? Income Growth and Poverty Is Economic Development Good for Gender Equality? February 25 and 27, 2003 Income Growth and Poverty Evidence from many countries shows that while economic growth has not eliminated poverty, the share

More information

Soci250 Sociological Theory

Soci250 Sociological Theory Soci250 Sociological Theory Module 3 Karl Marx I Old Marx François Nielsen University of North Carolina Chapel Hill Spring 2007 Outline Main Themes Life & Major Influences Old & Young Marx Old Marx Communist

More information

Imperialism and War. Capitalist imperialism produces 3 kinds of wars: 1. War of conquest to establish imperialist relations.

Imperialism and War. Capitalist imperialism produces 3 kinds of wars: 1. War of conquest to establish imperialist relations. Imperialism and War Capitalist imperialism produces 3 kinds of wars: 1. War of conquest to establish imperialist relations. 2. War of national liberation to force out the imperial master. 3. War of inter-imperial

More information

Rural Labor Force Emigration on the Impact. and Effect of Macro-Economy in China

Rural Labor Force Emigration on the Impact. and Effect of Macro-Economy in China Rural Labor Force Emigration on the Impact and Effect of Macro-Economy in China Laiyun Sheng Department of Rural Socio-Economic Survey, National Bureau of Statistics of China China has a large amount of

More information

SHOULD THE UNITED STATES WORRY ABOUT LARGE, FAST-GROWING ECONOMIES?

SHOULD THE UNITED STATES WORRY ABOUT LARGE, FAST-GROWING ECONOMIES? Chapter Six SHOULD THE UNITED STATES WORRY ABOUT LARGE, FAST-GROWING ECONOMIES? This report represents an initial investigation into the relationship between economic growth and military expenditures for

More information

PHILOSOPHY OF ECONOMICS & POLITICS

PHILOSOPHY OF ECONOMICS & POLITICS PHILOSOPHY OF ECONOMICS & POLITICS LECTURE 4: MARX DATE 29 OCTOBER 2018 LECTURER JULIAN REISS Marx s vita 1818 1883 Born in Trier to a Jewish family that had converted to Christianity Studied law in Bonn

More information

Developing the Periphery & Theorising the Specificity of Peripheral Development

Developing the Periphery & Theorising the Specificity of Peripheral Development Developing the Periphery & Theorising the Specificity of Peripheral Development From modernisation theory to the different theories of the dependency school ADRIANA CERDENA CALDERON LAURA MALAJOVICH SHAHANA

More information

The Impact of Global Economic Crisis on Migrant Workers in Middle East

The Impact of Global Economic Crisis on Migrant Workers in Middle East 2012 2 nd International Conference on Economics, Trade and Development IPEDR vol.36 (2012) (2012) IACSIT Press, Singapore The Impact of Global Economic Crisis on Migrant Workers in Middle East 1 H.R.Uma

More information

GEOG 4712: Political Geography

GEOG 4712: Political Geography GEOG 4712: Political Geography Lecture 13: World Systems Analysis genealogy of the world-systems school c a b d a. Febvre & Bloch (1922/1929) b. Braudel (1949) c. Kondratieff (1925) d. Gunder Frank (1967)

More information

Special characteristics of socialist oriented market economy in Vietnam

Special characteristics of socialist oriented market economy in Vietnam Special characteristics of socialist oriented market economy in Vietnam Vu Van Phuc* Developing a market economy plays an important role. For Vietnam, during the transition to socialism from a less developed

More information

From Collected Works of Michał Kalecki Volume II (Jerzy Osiatinyński editor, Clarendon Press, Oxford: 1991)

From Collected Works of Michał Kalecki Volume II (Jerzy Osiatinyński editor, Clarendon Press, Oxford: 1991) From Collected Works of Michał Kalecki Volume II (Jerzy Osiatinyński editor, Clarendon Press, Oxford: 1991) The Problem of Effective Demand with Tugan-Baranovsky and Rosa Luxemburg (1967) In the discussions

More information

Lecture 1. Overview of the Ghanaian Economy. Michael Insaidoo

Lecture 1. Overview of the Ghanaian Economy. Michael Insaidoo Lecture 1 Overview of the Ghanaian Economy Michael Insaidoo After completing this lecture, you will: Outline and explain the basic characteristics of the Ghanaian economy Compare Ghana with other developed

More information

Volume 8. Occupation and the Emergence of Two States, Political Principles of the Social Democratic Party (May 1946)

Volume 8. Occupation and the Emergence of Two States, Political Principles of the Social Democratic Party (May 1946) Volume 8. Occupation and the Emergence of Two States, 1945-1961 Political Principles of the Social Democratic Party (May 1946) Issued a few weeks after the merger of the SPD and the KPD in the Soviet occupation

More information

Measuring Common Ground

Measuring Common Ground Social Cohesion Radar Measuring Common Ground Social Cohesion in Germany Executive Summary Social Cohesion Radar Measuring Common Ground Social Cohesion in Germany Executive Summary Autoren Georgi Dragolov,

More information

and with support from BRIEFING NOTE 1

and with support from BRIEFING NOTE 1 and with support from BRIEFING NOTE 1 Inequality and growth: the contrasting stories of Brazil and India Concern with inequality used to be confined to the political left, but today it has spread to a

More information

Low-Skill Jobs A Shrinking Share of the Rural Economy

Low-Skill Jobs A Shrinking Share of the Rural Economy Low-Skill Jobs A Shrinking Share of the Rural Economy 38 Robert Gibbs rgibbs@ers.usda.gov Lorin Kusmin lkusmin@ers.usda.gov John Cromartie jbc@ers.usda.gov A signature feature of the 20th-century U.S.

More information

Post-Secondary Education, Training and Labour September Profile of the New Brunswick Labour Force

Post-Secondary Education, Training and Labour September Profile of the New Brunswick Labour Force Post-Secondary Education, Training and Labour September 2018 Profile of the New Brunswick Labour Force Contents Population Trends... 2 Key Labour Force Statistics... 5 New Brunswick Overview... 5 Sub-Regional

More information

Taking a long and global view

Taking a long and global view Morten Ougaard Taking a long and global view Paper for Friedrich Ebert Stiftung s Marx 200 Years Conference: Capitalism forever or is there any utopian potential left? London, 8 September 2017. Marx s

More information

1929 The CRASH. Aim: How did the Wall Street Crash lead to the growth of the Nazi Party?

1929 The CRASH. Aim: How did the Wall Street Crash lead to the growth of the Nazi Party? 1929 The CRASH Aim: How did the Wall Street Crash lead to the growth of the Nazi Party? What issues did the Weimar Republic face in 1928? International relations Locarno, Kellogg-Briand, League of Nations

More information

Conference Against Imperialist Globalisation and War

Conference Against Imperialist Globalisation and War Inaugural address at Mumbai Resistance 2004 Conference Against Imperialist Globalisation and War 17 th January 2004, Mumbai, India Dear Friends and Comrades, I thank the organizers of Mumbai Resistance

More information

Migration, Employment, and Food Security in Central Asia: the case of Uzbekistan

Migration, Employment, and Food Security in Central Asia: the case of Uzbekistan Migration, Employment, and Food Security in Central Asia: the case of Uzbekistan Bakhrom Mirkasimov (Westminster International University in Tashkent) BACKGROUND: CENTRAL ASIA All four countries experienced

More information

ENTREPRENEURSHIP AND TOURISM DEVELOPMENT IN RURAL AREAS: CASE OF ROMANIA

ENTREPRENEURSHIP AND TOURISM DEVELOPMENT IN RURAL AREAS: CASE OF ROMANIA 138 Entrepreneurship and tourism development in rural areas: case of Romania ENTREPRENEURSHIP AND TOURISM DEVELOPMENT IN RURAL AREAS: CASE OF ROMANIA Nicolae Nemirschi, Adrian Craciun 1 Abstract Interest

More information

Policy brief ARE WE RECOVERING YET? JOBS AND WAGES IN CALIFORNIA OVER THE PERIOD ARINDRAJIT DUBE, PH.D. Executive Summary AUGUST 31, 2005

Policy brief ARE WE RECOVERING YET? JOBS AND WAGES IN CALIFORNIA OVER THE PERIOD ARINDRAJIT DUBE, PH.D. Executive Summary AUGUST 31, 2005 Policy brief ARE WE RECOVERING YET? JOBS AND WAGES IN CALIFORNIA OVER THE 2000-2005 PERIOD ARINDRAJIT DUBE, PH.D. AUGUST 31, 2005 Executive Summary This study uses household survey data and payroll data

More information

POPULATION STUDIES RESEARCH BRIEF ISSUE Number

POPULATION STUDIES RESEARCH BRIEF ISSUE Number POPULATION STUDIES RESEARCH BRIEF ISSUE Number 2008021 School for Social and Policy Research 2008 Population Studies Group School for Social and Policy Research Charles Darwin University Northern Territory

More information

The Politics of Egalitarian Capitalism; Rethinking the Trade-off between Equality and Efficiency

The Politics of Egalitarian Capitalism; Rethinking the Trade-off between Equality and Efficiency The Politics of Egalitarian Capitalism; Rethinking the Trade-off between Equality and Efficiency Week 3 Aidan Regan Democratic politics is about distributive conflict tempered by a common interest in economic

More information

Jens Thomsen: The global economy in the years ahead

Jens Thomsen: The global economy in the years ahead Jens Thomsen: The global economy in the years ahead Statement by Mr Jens Thomsen, Governor of the National Bank of Denmark, at the Indo- Danish Business Association, Delhi, 9 October 2007. Introduction

More information

GLOBALISATION AND WAGE INEQUALITIES,

GLOBALISATION AND WAGE INEQUALITIES, GLOBALISATION AND WAGE INEQUALITIES, 1870 1970 IDS WORKING PAPER 73 Edward Anderson SUMMARY This paper studies the impact of globalisation on wage inequality in eight now-developed countries during the

More information

Immanuel Wallerstein (b. 1930) dependency perspective modernization perspective

Immanuel Wallerstein (b. 1930) dependency perspective modernization perspective Immanuel Wallerstein (b. 1930) Received degrees from Columbia (Ph.D. in 1959) Has been on faculty of SUNY-Binghamton since 1976. Major work: The Modern World System (first volume in 1974) There have been

More information

SSWH 15 Presentation. Describe the impact of industrialization and urbanization.

SSWH 15 Presentation. Describe the impact of industrialization and urbanization. SSWH 15 Presentation Describe the impact of industrialization and urbanization. Vocabulary Industrial Revolution Industrialization Adam Smith Capitalism Laissiez-Faire Wealth of Nations Karl Marx Communism

More information

NEW POVERTY IN ARGENTINA

NEW POVERTY IN ARGENTINA 252 Laboratorium. 2010. Vol. 2, no. 3:252 256 NEW POVERTY IN ARGENTINA AND RUSSIA: SOME BRIEF COMPARATIVE CONCLUSIONS Gabriel Kessler, Mercedes Di Virgilio, Svetlana Yaroshenko Editorial note. This joint

More information

Communism. Marx and Engels. The Communism Manifesto

Communism. Marx and Engels. The Communism Manifesto Communism Marx and Engels. The Communism Manifesto Karl Marx (1818-1883) German philosopher and economist Lived during aftermath of French Revolution (1789), which marks the beginning of end of monarchy

More information

Analysis of Gender Profile in Export Oriented Industries in India. Bansari Nag

Analysis of Gender Profile in Export Oriented Industries in India. Bansari Nag Analysis of Gender Profile in Export Oriented Industries in India Bansari Nag Introduction The links between gender, trade and development are increasingly being recognised. Women all over the world are

More information

Economic Change and The Bi-Polar World Economy

Economic Change and The Bi-Polar World Economy Economic Change and The Bi-Polar World Economy During the late Middle Ages and into early modern times, all economic patterns were constrained by a demographic fact: there were two great peaks of population

More information

EXECUTIVE SUMMARY. Executive Summary

EXECUTIVE SUMMARY. Executive Summary Executive Summary This report is an expedition into a subject area on which surprisingly little work has been conducted to date, namely the future of global migration. It is an exploration of the future,

More information

National Farmers Federation

National Farmers Federation National Farmers Federation Submission to the 457 Programme Temporary Skilled Migration Income Threshold (TSMIT) 8 March 2016 Page 1 NFF Member Organisations Page 2 The National Farmers Federation (NFF)

More information

Notes on the Industrial Revolution ( ) A. Machines start to replace human & animal power in production and manufacturing of goods

Notes on the Industrial Revolution ( ) A. Machines start to replace human & animal power in production and manufacturing of goods I. Overview of Industrial Revolution (IR) Notes on the Industrial Revolution (1780-1850) A. Machines start to replace human & animal power in production and manufacturing of goods B. Europe gradually transforms

More information

Unit Four: Historical Materialism & IPE. Dr. Russell Williams

Unit Four: Historical Materialism & IPE. Dr. Russell Williams Unit Four: Historical Materialism & IPE Dr. Russell Williams Essay Proposal due in class, October 8!!!!!! Required Reading: Cohn, Ch. 5. Class Discussion Reading: Robert W. Cox, Civil Society at the Turn

More information

STRENGTHENING RURAL CANADA: Fewer & Older: Population and Demographic Crossroads in Rural Saskatchewan. An Executive Summary

STRENGTHENING RURAL CANADA: Fewer & Older: Population and Demographic Crossroads in Rural Saskatchewan. An Executive Summary STRENGTHENING RURAL CANADA: Fewer & Older: Population and Demographic Crossroads in Rural Saskatchewan An Executive Summary This paper has been prepared for the Strengthening Rural Canada initiative by:

More information

Chapter 9: Fundamentals of International Political Economy

Chapter 9: Fundamentals of International Political Economy Chapter 9: Fundamentals of International Political Economy MULTIPLE CHOICE 1. International political economy can be defined as a. the international organizations such as the International Monetary Fund

More information

China s Reform and Opening-up

China s Reform and Opening-up China s Reform and Opening-up Yan ZHANG ( 张晏 ) China Center for Economic Studies School of Economics Fudan University Instructor s Information v Yan Zhang v Office: Room 704, School of Economics v Tel:

More information

The Common Program of The Chinese People's Political Consultative Conference, 1949

The Common Program of The Chinese People's Political Consultative Conference, 1949 The Common Program of The Chinese People's Political Consultative Conference, 1949 Adopted by the First Plenary Session of the Chinese People's PCC on September 29th, 1949 in Peking PREAMBLE The Chinese

More information

Financial Crisis. How Firms in Eastern and Central Europe Fared through the Global Financial Crisis: Evidence from

Financial Crisis. How Firms in Eastern and Central Europe Fared through the Global Financial Crisis: Evidence from Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized World Bank Group Enterprise Note No. 2 21 Enterprise Surveys Enterprise Note Series Introduction

More information

SOCIAL IMPACT OF THE INDUSTRIAL REVOLUTION

SOCIAL IMPACT OF THE INDUSTRIAL REVOLUTION SOCIAL IMPACT OF THE INDUSTRIAL REVOLUTION I REPLACED THE TRADITION HIERACHRY WITH A NEW SOCIAL ORDER II THE GOLDEN AGE OF THE MIDDLE CLASS. 1. A new class of factory owners emerged in this period: the

More information

CHAPTER 10: Fundamentals of International Political Economy

CHAPTER 10: Fundamentals of International Political Economy 1. China s economy now ranks as what number in terms of size? a. First b. Second c. Third d. Fourth 2. China s economy has grown by what factor each year since 1980? a. Three b. Five c. Seven d. Ten 3.

More information

The Second Industrial Revolution 13.1

The Second Industrial Revolution 13.1 The Second Industrial Revolution 13.1 Things to know... Westerners in the 1800s worshiped progress due to the amazing material growth from the Second Industrial Revolution. Steel, chemicals, electricity,

More information

* Economies and Values

* Economies and Values Unit One CB * Economies and Values Four different economic systems have developed to address the key economic questions. Each system reflects the different prioritization of economic goals. It also reflects

More information

Provincial Review 2016: Western Cape

Provincial Review 2016: Western Cape Provincial Review 2016: Western Cape The Western Cape s real economy is dominated by manufacturing and commercial agriculture. As a result, while it did not benefit directly from the commodity boom, it

More information

STRENGTHENING RURAL CANADA: Fewer & Older: The Coming Demographic Crisis in Rural Ontario

STRENGTHENING RURAL CANADA: Fewer & Older: The Coming Demographic Crisis in Rural Ontario STRENGTHENING RURAL CANADA: Fewer & Older: The Coming Demographic Crisis in Rural Ontario An Executive Summary 1 This paper has been prepared for the Strengthening Rural Canada initiative by: Dr. Bakhtiar

More information

Right-Wing extremism in unified Germany

Right-Wing extremism in unified Germany Right-Wing extremism in unified Germany Unified Germany in Perspective Outline The Post-War years The Second Wave Unified Germany in Perspective Right-Wing Extremism (0/21) What is right, what is extremism?

More information

THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF HYDROCARBON REVENUE CYCLING IN TRINIDAD AND TOBAGO

THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF HYDROCARBON REVENUE CYCLING IN TRINIDAD AND TOBAGO THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF HYDROCARBON REVENUE CYCLING IN TRINIDAD AND TOBAGO Richard Auty (Lancaster University) 1. Rent Cycling Theory and Growth Collapses 2. Initial Conditions Render T+T Vulnerable 3.

More information

The Politics of Market Discipline in Latin America: Globalization and Democracy *

The Politics of Market Discipline in Latin America: Globalization and Democracy * Globalization and Democracy * by Flávio Pinheiro Centro de Estudos das Negociações Internacionais, Brazil (Campello, Daniela. The Politics of Market Discipline in Latin America: Globalization and Democracy.

More information

Rising inequality in China

Rising inequality in China Page 1 of 6 Date:03/01/2006 URL: http://www.thehindubusinessline.com/2006/01/03/stories/2006010300981100.htm Rising inequality in China C. P. Chandrasekhar Jayati Ghosh Spectacular economic growth in China

More information

Working women have won enormous progress in breaking through long-standing educational and

Working women have won enormous progress in breaking through long-standing educational and THE CURRENT JOB OUTLOOK REGIONAL LABOR REVIEW, Fall 2008 The Gender Pay Gap in New York City and Long Island: 1986 2006 by Bhaswati Sengupta Working women have won enormous progress in breaking through

More information

Name Date Period Class Parliamentary Elections of Germany

Name Date Period Class Parliamentary Elections of Germany Name Date Period Class Parliamentary Elections of Germany - 1932 Parliamentary elections of 1932 were spirited, for German voters had to decide which party offered the best solution to the nation s seemingly

More information

Karl Marx ( )

Karl Marx ( ) Karl Marx (1818-1883) Karl Marx Marx (1818-1883) German economist, philosopher, sociologist and revolutionist. Enormous impact on arrangement of economies in the 20th century The strongest critic of capitalism

More information

There is a seemingly widespread view that inequality should not be a concern

There is a seemingly widespread view that inequality should not be a concern Chapter 11 Economic Growth and Poverty Reduction: Do Poor Countries Need to Worry about Inequality? Martin Ravallion There is a seemingly widespread view that inequality should not be a concern in countries

More information

The occupational structure and mobility of migrants in the Greek rural labour markets

The occupational structure and mobility of migrants in the Greek rural labour markets Working Group 17. Demographic issues of Rural Subpopulation: Fertility, Migration and Mortality The occupational structure and mobility of migrants in the Greek rural labour markets Introduction As Europe

More information

Palestinian Women s Reality in Labor Market:

Palestinian Women s Reality in Labor Market: Int. Statistical Inst.: Proc. 58th World Statistical Congress, 2011, Dublin (Session STS039) p.2928 Palestinian Central Bureau of Statistics Palestinian Women s Reality in Labor Market: 2000-2010 Jawad

More information

O Joint Strategies (vision)

O Joint Strategies (vision) 3CE335P4 O 3.3.5 Joint Strategies (vision) Work package Action Author 3 Identifying Rural Potentials 3.3 Definition of relevant criteria / indicators / strategy. External expert: West Pannon Regional and

More information

A 13-PART COURSE IN POPULAR ECONOMICS SAMPLE COURSE OUTLINE

A 13-PART COURSE IN POPULAR ECONOMICS SAMPLE COURSE OUTLINE A 13-PART COURSE IN POPULAR ECONOMICS SAMPLE COURSE OUTLINE By Jim Stanford Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives, 2008 Non-commercial use and reproduction, with appropriate citation, is authorized.

More information

GEOG 4712: Political Geography. Lecture 17: World Systems Analysis

GEOG 4712: Political Geography. Lecture 17: World Systems Analysis GEOG 4712: Political Geography Lecture 17: World Systems Analysis Outline 1) Wally World, re-visited 2) Waves + Cycles 3) Hegemonies, re-visited 4) Modelskiʼs Models 5) Modelskiʼs Metrics 6) Concluding

More information

8AMBER WAVES VOLUME 2 ISSUE 3

8AMBER WAVES VOLUME 2 ISSUE 3 8AMBER WAVES VOLUME 2 ISSUE 3 F E A T U R E William Kandel, USDA/ERS ECONOMIC RESEARCH SERVICE/USDA Rural s Employment and Residential Trends William Kandel wkandel@ers.usda.gov Constance Newman cnewman@ers.usda.gov

More information

CHAPTER 2: SECTION 1. Economic Systems

CHAPTER 2: SECTION 1. Economic Systems Three Economic Questions CHAPTER 2: SECTION 1 Economic Systems All nations in the world must decide how to answer three economic questions about the production and distribution of goods. (See Transparency

More information

Introduction to World Trade. Economia Internacional I International Trade theory August 15 th, Lecture 1

Introduction to World Trade. Economia Internacional I International Trade theory August 15 th, Lecture 1 Introduction to World Trade Economia Internacional I International Trade theory August 15 th, 2012 Lecture 1 Free Trade Free Trade occurs when a government does not attempt to influence, through quotas

More information

Interview. Austerity Is Useless. Interviewed by Mauro Lacentini. Epoca (Milan), 27 October 1976), pp English translation by Maria Torchio.

Interview. Austerity Is Useless. Interviewed by Mauro Lacentini. Epoca (Milan), 27 October 1976), pp English translation by Maria Torchio. Interview. Austerity Is Useless. Interviewed by Mauro Lacentini. Epoca (Milan), 27 October 1976), pp. 28 30. English translation by Maria Torchio. Epoca: I have the feeling that Italy is no longer happy

More information

CER INSIGHT: Populism culture or economics? by John Springford and Simon Tilford 30 October 2017

CER INSIGHT: Populism culture or economics? by John Springford and Simon Tilford 30 October 2017 Populism culture or economics? by John Springford and Simon Tilford 30 October 2017 Are economic factors to blame for the rise of populism, or is it a cultural backlash? The answer is a bit of both: economic

More information

The Principal Contradiction

The Principal Contradiction The Principal Contradiction [Communist ORIENTATION No. 1, April 10, 1975, p. 2-6] Communist Orientation No 1., April 10, 1975, p. 2-6 "There are many contradictions in the process of development of a complex

More information

Executive summary. Strong records of economic growth in the Asia-Pacific region have benefited many workers.

Executive summary. Strong records of economic growth in the Asia-Pacific region have benefited many workers. Executive summary Strong records of economic growth in the Asia-Pacific region have benefited many workers. In many ways, these are exciting times for Asia and the Pacific as a region. Dynamic growth and

More information

NEOLIBERALISM, PEASANTISM AND PROTECTIONISM IN ROMANIA

NEOLIBERALISM, PEASANTISM AND PROTECTIONISM IN ROMANIA NEOLIBERALISM, PEASANTISM AND PROTECTIONISM IN ROMANIA IN THE INTERWAR PERIOD CORNELIA NISTOR UNIVERSITY OF BUCHAREST BUCHAREST, ROMANIA NISTOR.CORNELIA@YAHOO.COM ABSTRACT The objective of this research

More information

The character of the crisis: Seeking a way-out for the social majority

The character of the crisis: Seeking a way-out for the social majority The character of the crisis: Seeking a way-out for the social majority 1. On the character of the crisis Dear comrades and friends, In order to answer the question stated by the organizers of this very

More information

The Politics of Emotional Confrontation in New Democracies: The Impact of Economic

The Politics of Emotional Confrontation in New Democracies: The Impact of Economic Paper prepared for presentation at the panel A Return of Class Conflict? Political Polarization among Party Leaders and Followers in the Wake of the Sovereign Debt Crisis The 24 th IPSA Congress Poznan,

More information

Export Oriented Manufacturing and Job Creation in Sri Lanka. Vishvanathan Subramaniam

Export Oriented Manufacturing and Job Creation in Sri Lanka. Vishvanathan Subramaniam Export Oriented Manufacturing and Job Creation in Sri Lanka Vishvanathan Subramaniam Outline Sri Lanka s post independence growth trajectory has been shackled by volatility instigated by policy uncertainty

More information

Selected macro-economic indicators relating to structural changes in agricultural employment in the Slovak Republic

Selected macro-economic indicators relating to structural changes in agricultural employment in the Slovak Republic Selected macro-economic indicators relating to structural changes in agricultural employment in the Slovak Republic Milan Olexa, PhD 1. Statistical Office of the Slovak Republic Economic changes after

More information

Economies of South Africa & Nigeria

Economies of South Africa & Nigeria Economies of South Africa & Nigeria Essential Question How do the African economies of South Africa and Nigeria compare and contrast? I CAN Explain how the African economies of South Africa and Nigeria

More information

The Scope for Attracting Foreign Investors to Eastern Germany

The Scope for Attracting Foreign Investors to Eastern Germany The Scope for Attracting Foreign Investors to Eastern Germany As eastern Germany seeks to catch up economically with the West of the country, the region must expand its economic base and overcome its structural

More information

Openness and Poverty Reduction in the Long and Short Run. Mark R. Rosenzweig. Harvard University. October 2003

Openness and Poverty Reduction in the Long and Short Run. Mark R. Rosenzweig. Harvard University. October 2003 Openness and Poverty Reduction in the Long and Short Run Mark R. Rosenzweig Harvard University October 2003 Prepared for the Conference on The Future of Globalization Yale University. October 10-11, 2003

More information

Chapters 30 and 31: The Interwar Period ( )

Chapters 30 and 31: The Interwar Period ( ) Chapters 30 and 31: The Interwar Period (1919-1938) Postwar Germany Unstable democracies Weimar Republic in Germany Democratic government formed after WWI Was blamed for signing Treaty of Versailles Cost

More information

Rewriting the Rules of the Market Economy to Achieve Shared Prosperity. Joseph E. Stiglitz New York June 2016

Rewriting the Rules of the Market Economy to Achieve Shared Prosperity. Joseph E. Stiglitz New York June 2016 Rewriting the Rules of the Market Economy to Achieve Shared Prosperity Joseph E. Stiglitz New York June 2016 Enormous growth in inequality Especially in US, and countries that have followed US model Multiple

More information

Note Taking Study Guide DAWN OF THE INDUSTRIAL AGE

Note Taking Study Guide DAWN OF THE INDUSTRIAL AGE SECTION 1 DAWN OF THE INDUSTRIAL AGE Focus Question: What events helped bring about the Industrial Revolution? As you read this section in your textbook, complete the following flowchart to list multiple

More information

Analysis of public opinion on Macedonia s accession to Author: Ivan Damjanovski

Analysis of public opinion on Macedonia s accession to Author: Ivan Damjanovski Analysis of public opinion on Macedonia s accession to the European Union 2014-2016 Author: Ivan Damjanovski CONCLUSIONS 3 The trends regarding support for Macedonia s EU membership are stable and follow

More information

Since this chapter looks at economics systems and globalization, we will also be adding Chapter 15 which deals with international trade.

Since this chapter looks at economics systems and globalization, we will also be adding Chapter 15 which deals with international trade. Monday, January 30 Tuesday, January 31 Since this chapter looks at economics systems and globalization, we will also be adding Chapter 15 which deals with international trade. Three Economic Questions

More information

Rise in Populism: Economic and Social Perspectives

Rise in Populism: Economic and Social Perspectives Rise in Populism: Economic and Social Perspectives Damien Capelle Princeton University 6th March, Day of Action D. Capelle (Princeton) Rise of Populism 6th March, Day of Action 1 / 37 Table of Contents

More information

IMPACT OF GLOBALIZATION ON POVERTY: CASE STUDY OF PAKISTAN

IMPACT OF GLOBALIZATION ON POVERTY: CASE STUDY OF PAKISTAN Romain Pison Prof. Kamal NYU 03/20/06 NYU-G-RP-A1 IMPACT OF GLOBALIZATION ON POVERTY: CASE STUDY OF PAKISTAN INTRODUCTION The purpose of this paper is to examine the effect of globalization in Pakistan

More information

ECONOMY AND DEVELOPMENT FROM THEN TO NOW TAKEN FROM

ECONOMY AND DEVELOPMENT FROM THEN TO NOW TAKEN FROM ECONOMY AND DEVELOPMENT FROM THEN TO NOW TAKEN FROM HTTP://MISSVHISTORY.BLOGSPOT.CA/ FIRST OCCUPANTS 1. TRADE NETWORKS BARTER BETWEEN NATIVES; NOMADIC GROUPS EXCHANGED GOODS WITH OTHERS, LIKE SEDENTARY

More information

The State of Rural Minnesota, 2019

The State of Rural Minnesota, 2019 P.O. Box 3185 Mankato, MN 56002-3185 (507)934-7700 www.ruralmn.org The State of Rural Minnesota, 2019 January 2019 By Kelly Asche, Research Associate Each year, the Center for Rural Policy and Development

More information

EC 454. Lecture 3 Prof. Dr. Durmuş Özdemir Department of Economics Yaşar University

EC 454. Lecture 3 Prof. Dr. Durmuş Özdemir Department of Economics Yaşar University EC 454 Lecture 3 Prof. Dr. Durmuş Özdemir Department of Economics Yaşar University Development Economics and its counterrevolution The specialized field of development economics was critical of certain

More information