To the ones in need or the ones you need?

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "To the ones in need or the ones you need?"

Transcription

1 preliminary version: please do not cite or circulate without the authors permission To the ones in need or the ones you need? The Political Economy of Central Discretionary Grants: Empirical Evidence from Indonesia Gerrit J. Gonschorek, Günther G. Schulze and Bambang Suharnoko Sjahrir Institute of Economics Department of International Economic Policy University of Freiburg, Germany 30. June 2017 Abstract: We analyze the allocation of discretionary grants from the central government to local governments in Indonesia. Using OLS and Fixed Effects models on an unbalanced panel data set for more than 400 Indonesian districts covering the period , we investigate whether the allocation of the grants are determined by the need of a district, by political alignment of the central government with the local district heads, or by reelection motives of the incumbent president. We find that grants are hardly determined by need characteristics and that political considerations matter significantly. Districts with low support for the president received significantly more than the core supporting districts. This effect is limited to the first term of the president. In the second term, after which reelection is impossible, political considerations were largely absent. This pattern is consistent with the view that the incumbent president considers discretionary grants as an instrument to increase reelection probabilities. Unlike the evidence for most countries, we find no effect for political party alignment with local district heads. Our results are robust to the inclusion of a number of other variables capturing competing motives. Acknowledgments: We would like to thank Krisztina Kis-Katos, Jürgen Rüland, Christian von Lübke, Volker Lindenthal, Nikita Zakharov and Antonio Farfán Vallespin for valuable comments. We thank Marcus Mietzner, Kevin Evans, Titi Anggraini (PERLUDEM), as well as the people at SMERU, KPPOD in Jakarta for their support and valuable expertise as well as many more friends and colleagues in Indonesia. We thank all participants of the Doctoral Workshop on Development Economics of the German Economic Association (University of Zürich, Switzerland, 2016), at the Annual Meeting of the European Public Choice Society (EPCS) (University of Groening, Netherlands, 2015) plus researchers of Gadjah Madah University (UGM), University of Indonesia (UI), Australian National University (ANU), KITLV at Leiden University, the Arnold Bergstraesser Institute, the Freiburg Institute of Advanced Studies (FRIAS) and the Southeast Asian Studies Group at Freiburg University for their helpful comments. We would also like to thank the German Federal Ministry of Education and Research (BMBF) and the Wissenschaftliche Gesellschaft Freiburg for partially funding this project and Fabrizio Kuruc for his excellent research assistance. All errors are our own. 1

2 1. Introduction This paper analyzes the allocation determinants of a particular grant program, 'Tugas pembantuan (TP), from the central government to the regions in Indonesia. The program is designed to fund physical infrastructure, including agricultural infrastructure, and is allocated to the regions at the discretion of the central government. Every funded project needs the presidential approval. This raises the question whether the president approves allocations according to a specific rationale. Allocations could be made on a needs basis, given that Indonesia's 510 (in 2014) districts vary tremendously in prosperity and economic activity and that many districts are lagging behind. Poverty rates span from 1.75 percent to percent with a mean of and a standard deviation of A second prime candidate for such a rationale is to support politically aligned district heads in order to secure their reelection and to broaden the party basis in the regions and thus indirectly also at the national level. There is substantial evidence for developed countries that politically aligned regions receive preferential treatment from the central government (inter alia Berry et al. (2010) and Larcinese et al. (2006) for the US, Bracco et al. (2015) for Italy, Kauder et al. (2016) for Germany, Solé-Ollé and Sorribas-Navarro (2008) for Spain, Veiga and Pinho (2007) and Veiga and Veiga (2013) for Portugal). There is less evidence for developing and threshold countries (Arulampalam et al. (2009) for India, Brollo and Nannicini (2012) for Brazil and Francken et al. (2012) for Madagaskar). Lastly, the transfers could be distributed with the objective of enhancing the reelection probabilities of the incumbent president directly. There is ample empirical evidence that incumbents spend public funds in order to enhance reelection probabilities, in particular before election years, which gives rise to political business cycles (PBC, Nordhaus, 1975). These cycles depend on the characteristics of the political system, notably they are strong in young democracies while they tend to be less pronounced or even disappear in mature democracies (Brender and Drazen (2005), DeHaan and Klomp (2013), Shi and Svensson (2006)). Pork barrel politics may be less pronounced also in the presence of term limits (Aidt and Shvets, 2012). While PBCs have been intensely researched, 2 it has not been analyzed whether intergovernmental fiscal transfers could serve the purpose of supporting the reelection bid of 1 Data refer to 2013, source World Bank (DAPOER), 2 Cf. Sjahrir et al. (2013) for an analysis of PBCs in Indonesia at the local level. 2

3 the central government s CEO. We provide such an analysis for Indonesia. The transfer system Tugas pembantuan is ideally suited for this purpose as it is allocated at the discretion of the central government and, being earmarked for capital goods, has a great visibility by the public. Our data allow to test different hypotheses on a possible rationale behind the allocation of the discretionary intergovernmental fiscal transfers. If transfers were allocated based on neediness, needs parameters such as poverty rate, HDI, or the status of the infrastructure in a district should be significantly correlated with the transfers received. If political alignment played a significant role, the party affiliation of the district head (or the composition of the local parliament) should turn out significant. If the reelection motivation of the president guided the allocation, the transfers should go to the districts where they would mobilize most additional votes; this would be the districts that did not strongly vote for the incumbent in the first elections, as voters might be persuaded to support the president by improved infrastructure services. Yet, this should be limited to the first term as the president can be reelected only once. Our panel data set of Indonesian districts covers the period , which coincides with the two terms of former president Susilo Bambang Yudhoyono. Indonesia is not only an important case study as it is the fourth most populous nation and the third largest democracy in the world and the dominating country in Southeast Asia. Its particular features make the analysis of Indonesia interesting beyond the country as such and sets it apart from the cases analyzed so far. Indonesia is a strongly decentralized, very diverse presidential democracy with little party loyalty and strong clientelistic elements. It has turned into a democracy only in 1998, after long-time dictator Suharto stepped down; in 2001, it decentralized in a big bang, delegating major government functions such as health, primary and secondary education, infrastructure, and environmental protection to the district level, while provinces received mostly backstopping and supervisory functions. As a consequence, almost 40 percent of the budgetary responsibilities were devolved to the regions (World Bank, 2008). Whereas the expenditure authority has been devolved to a large extent, regions still heavily rely on fiscal transfers from the center (Lewis 2014). The fiscal and administrative decentralization was complemented by a political decentralization with free elections of local parliaments in 2001 and asynchronous elections of the district heads first by local parliaments and, beginning in 2005, directly by local electorates. Indonesia is a presidential democracy with a multiparty system. Since 2004, the president has been elected directly by the voters; the lower house (Dewan Perwakilan Rakyat, DPR) is 3

4 elected by proportional representation and is quite fragmented, which requires coalition building on part of the president. Ideological differences between parties are relatively small and party loyalty of voters, but also of candidates for political offices, is comparatively weak (Mietzner, 2013). The political system is often characterized as highly clientelistic with voters expecting tangible material benefits in exchange for their votes (Mietzner (2011), Aspinall and van Klinken (2011)). While the lacking ideological divisions and the clientelistic nature of politics is not uncommon in many developing countries, studies on the political-economic determinants of transfers to regions have focused on advanced countries with mature political systems. The two democratic developing countries that have been studied Brazil and India are characterized by strong ideological divides ((Arulampalam et al. (2009) and Brollo and Nannicini (2012)). Hence Indonesia is an ideal case for analyzing politically motivated transfers in a developing country s context also because of its large number of districts, its great diversity in economic development, its political system, political constellations at the local level, and high data quality. Moreover elections of district heads are asynchronous and exogenously timed which allows to clearly identify a party alignment effect. Our paper is the first to study central government transfers to the regions in Indonesia from a political-economic perspective. Previous analyses have either exclusively focused on the formula-based transfers that disallow decisions at the discretion of the central government (Brodjonegoro and Martinez-Vazquez (2004), McLeod and Fadliya, 2010)) or tested for a possible needs orientation of discretionary transfers and their effects on service delivery but disregarded potential political-economic motivations (Lewis, 2016). We use a pooled OLS and fixed effects models on a unique unbalanced panel data set for more than 400 Indonesian districts from , representing around 90 percent of Indonesia s population in Our results show that central discretionary grants are hardly influenced by needs characteristics and that political considerations matter significantly. Unlike the evidence for most other countries studied, we find no effect for political party alignment between the central and the district government on grant allocation which is explained by the political system. In contrast the allocations are determined by political support considerations of the president facing reelection: Districts with low support for the president received significantly more per capita grants than the core supporting districts as they offer the biggest opportunities for increasing the vote share for the incumbent. This effect is limited to the president s first term in office because after the first term reelection is not possible, and 4

5 therefore political considerations should be absent (Aidt and Shvets, 2012). Indeed there is no evidence for politically motivated grant allocations in the second term. This pattern is consistent with the view that discretionary grants are used as an instrument to increase the reelection probabilities of the president (Cox and McCubbins, (1986), Lindbeck and Weibull (1987), Dixit and Londregan (1996)). Our results are robust to the inclusion of potential local political budget cycles, the political concentration at the local parliaments, regional favoritism by the incumbent president, the existing service infrastructure, the importance of the agricultural sector and the cost of providing services at the district level. The paper proceeds as follows: Section 2 provides a brief background on Indonesia s political system, especially on the presidential elections and the fiscal structure relevant for our analysis. Section 3 discusses the theoretical argument for the determinants of centralgovernment transfers in a decentralized system, relates them to the Indonesian context, and presents four testable hypotheses. In Section 4, we describe the data, our empirical approach, and the main results. Section 5 presents additional robustness checks and discusses the limitations of our approach. Section 6 concludes. 2. Institutional Background 2.1 Elections Indonesia is a presidential democracy. The president has veto power over all legislation; by constitution, laws must be made by joint agreement with the House of Representatives (DPR) (Sherlock,2010). The president appoints his cabinet members and is directly elected for a maximum of two 5-year terms. Since 2004 the president has been elected directly by popular vote. 3 Presidential elections are held in two rounds if no ticket receives the absolute majority in the first round. Since a political party must have a minimum of 20 percent of the votes or 15 percent of the seats in the House of Representatives (DPR) to nominate a presidential candidate (Ufen, 2009) presidential elections take place after the legislative elections. 4 The DPR consists of 560 members and is elected by proportional representation at the district 3 Constitutional Amendment in Before 2004, the Indonesian President was appointed by Indonesia s House of Representatives (DPR). Since he/she is directly elected, the power of the DPR has decreased significantly (Schmidt (2010). According to Schmidt (2010), the appointed members of the DPR elected Suharto in engineered elections to be president seven consecutive times ( ). 4 In 2004, parties that received at least 5 percent of the total vote or 3 percent of the parliamentary seats at the DPR were allowed to nominate a presidential or vice-presidential candidate (Law 23/2003 Article 101). For 2009, this minimum was changed to 15 percent of the seats or 20 percent of the votes. 5

6 level. Since 2008, seats are allocated through an open party list system, all candidates must run for a certain political party, but voters can vote for a party or an individual candidate (Sherlock, 2010). The second chamber of parliament is the Regional Representative Council (Dewan Perwakilan Daerah, DPD). It consist of 132 members, four from each of Indonesia`s provinces and is elected at the provincial level. It has only a participating and advisory function to the DPR. The MPR (Majelis Permusyawaratan Rakyat) consists of the DPR and DPD members and oversees presidential decisions. Elections for the national, provincial, and district parliaments are held simultaneously every five years (2004 and 2009 in our observation period). The local parliaments at the district level, the DPRDs (Dewan Perwaklian Rakyat Daerah), are also elected by proportional representation with an open party list (Ananta et al., 2005). Provincial governors, mayors (walikotas), and regents (bupatis) have been elected directly by popular vote since 2005 (Law No.32/2004). The timing of the district heads elections were determined exogenously and independently from the timing of the national executive and legislative elections. They took place asynchronously after the 5-year term of a local official had ended, which is a legacy from the Suharto era as district heads were appointed at different points in time and were allowed to serve out their term after Suharto's demise and the democratization that followed. The asynchronous nature of district head elections allow us to clearly identify any effect of political party alignment or political business cycle on transfer decisions. 5 Only political parties or coalitions with at least 15 percent of seats in the local DPRD are allowed to nominate candidates; the candidates need at least 25 percent of the votes to win the election in the first round, otherwise they face a run-off election against the candidate with the second largest vote share in the first round (Choi and Nankyung, 2009). 6 Local government heads, in particular district mayors, are the ones defining local policy making in contrast to the rather weakly influential local parliaments (Buehler, 2016). In the 2004 presidential elections, Susilo Bambang Yudhoyono and Yusuf Kalla, nominated by Partai Demokrat (PD), were elected as President and Vice-president of Indonesia (60.6 percent). They defeated Megawati Sukarnoputri (the incumbent president) and her running- 5 Only since December 2015, district head elections have been held simultaneously across all district experiencing a term limit of their local government head in that year. 6 Since 2008, independent candidates are allowed to run for office at local executive elections (Law 12/2008). However, due to the high costs of an electoral campaign and costly requirements to withdraw a nomination (Law 12/2008, Article 62), only a few independent candidates have contested in local direct elections (Buehler, 2010). 6

7 mate Hasyim Muzadi (39.4 percent), nominated by PDI-P (Ananta et al., 2005). These were the first direct elections in Indonesia s history. 7 Yudhoyono and Kalla, both former ministers in President Megawati s cabinet were supported by the People s Coalition (Koalisi Kerakyatan) formed by PD, PBB, PKIP, and PKS. Megawati Soekarnoputri, daughter of Indonesia s first President Soekarno (in office ), and Hasyim Muzadi, a leader of the Al-Hikam Islamic Boarding School, were supported by the National Coalition (Koalisi Kebangsaan), consisting of Golkar, PDI-P, and PPP (Ananta et al., 2005). 8 In the 2009 presidential elections, Yudhoyono was reelected for his second (and final) term as president with the Indonesian central bank's governor Boediono as his running mate. Supported by his own party PD as well as by PKS, PAN, PPP, and PKB (Sukma, 2009), he won in a landslide victory (60.8 percent) in the first round. 9 Megawati Soekarnoputri (PDI-P) and her running mate Prabowo (26.8 percent) as well as Yudhoyono s first-term vice president Jusuf Kalla (head of the Golkar Party) and his running mate Wiranto (Partai Hanura) (12.4 percent) were defeated. Figures B1-B5 in Appendix B show the regional distribution of votes for Yudhoyono in the 2004 and 2009 presidential elections across Indonesian districts, showing stark regional differences in vote support for Yudhoyono in 2004 and 2009 (see Appendix B) Fiscal Transfers Indonesia has three levels of government, the central, the provincial level and the district level. Indonesia s central government is responsible for judiciary, law enforcement, monetary and macroeconomic policies, religious affairs, defense, foreign relations and security policy. Sub-national governments are responsible for all remaining functions, especially for decentralized service sectors like education (excluding tertiary education), health, and infrastructure. Provinces have limited responsibilities compared to district governments, they are responsible for supervision and cross-district cooperation. Districts provide core services; they receive the lion s share of their overall revenue from transfers from the center. In In the DPR elections, Golkar had received the highest share of votes (21.6 percent), followed by PDI-P (18.5 percent), PKB (10.57 percent), PPP (8.15 percent), and the presidential party PD (7.45 percent).for more information on each of the political parties in Indonesia see Mietzner (2013), Ananta et al. (2005), Aspinall and Mietzner (2010) or Bünte and Ufen (2009). 8 The fact, that Yusuf Kalla a former Golkar official was not supported by Golkar in the 2004 presidential elections, illustrates how blurry party lines in Indonesia sometimes are. 9 In the 2009 national DPR elections a few month before, the presidential party PD won in a landslide receiving 20.9 percent of the votes. Followed by Golkar (14.5 percent), PDI-P (14.0 percent), PKS (7.9 percent), PAN (6 percent), PPP (5.3 percent), PKB (4.9 percent), Gerindra (4.5 percent) and Hanura 3.8 percent (Sukma, 2009). 10 For more information on the 2009 presidential elections see Sukma, (2009); Tomsa, (2010); Fealy, (2011) and Aspinall et al., (2015). 7

8 central government transfers accounted for 54 percent of provincial and 93 percent of district expenditures (Shah, 2012). Indonesia s major government transfers (DAU, DBH, DAK) are non-discretionary; they are either determined by tax revenue generated at the sub-national level, specific criteria, or by a formula. 11 The general allocation grant DAU (Dana Alokasi Umum) is a non-earmarked, formula-based general purpose grant and the most important sources of sub-national government revenue in Indonesia. DAU transfers accounted for 52 percent of total subnational government revenue between 2001 and 2009 (Agustina et al. (2012)). The DAU formula takes into account fiscal capacity and fiscal needs of a district (for details see Agustina et al. (2012), McLeod and Fadliya (2010)). The specific allocation grant DAK (Dana Alokasi Khusus) is earmarked for national priorities. Its allocation is determined by general criteria such as the financial capacity of a subnational government, technical criteria such as guidelines established by the responsible line ministry) and special criteria (e.g. specific characteristics of a region). The DBH (Dana Bagi Hasil) is Indonesia s tax and natural resource revenue-sharing system and is allocated according to a formula (Agustina et al. (2012)). 12 It is motivated by political-economic considerations, to give national resource rich regions a larger share of resource rents (Harjowiryono, 2011). Compared to these non-discretionary transfers, TP (Tugas pempantuan, Co-Administration and Assistance Tasks Funding) is a discretionary central-government grant under authority of the president. 13 Since 2001, line ministries of the central government which are not responsible for the five core responsibilities foreign affairs, defense, justice, fiscal/monetary policy and religion have to delegate implementation of their tasks to sub-national governments, which act as a representative of the central government. 14 TP grants are not part of the local budget, but they are spent locally and are co-administered with a provincial governor and/or district head. TP grants should be allocated to tasks of `physical nature` (Government Regulation 7/2008). Even though the allocations should be in accordance to some general principles such as 11 Indonesia s Law No. 33/2004 on fiscal decentralization, Law No. 32/2004 on sub-national governance, and Law No. 25/1999 on fiscal balance between central government and regions. Besides these transfer mechanisms, there are: Special Autonomy Funds (for Papua and Aceh) based on Law No. 35/2008, Law No. 11/2006, Law No. 21/2001, Adjustment Funds for financial ad hoc assistance, Hibah-transfers for assistance in the infrastructure sector, a special Incentive grant (DID) as well as the some smaller performance based grant schemes. 12 Since the beginning of 2014 the property tax (Territory and Building Tax, PBB and Property Title Transfer Fees, BPHTB) has been devolved to the subnational level. This excludes mining, plantation and the forestry sector. 13 Government Regulation 7/2008 Article 6 paragraph Government Regulation No. 52/2001, Government Regulation No. 7./2008 and Government Regulation No.106/

9 `harmonious national and regional development` (Government Regulation 7/2008) there are no clear allocation criteria in place leaving the allocation at the discretion of the central government. The line ministries planning to establish a TP funded project have to consult with the National Development Planning Agency (BAPPENAS), which is responsible for the coordination and planning of projects. 15 However, every project needs the approval of the president. 16 After presidential approval the Ministry of Finance disburses the funds, and the Ministry of Home Affairs has a supervisory function. Figure 1 shows the allocation of TP per capita by district for the year While districts on the economically most prosperous Island Java receive lower grants per capita, there are distinct differences in the allocation to neighboring and economically similar districts. This suggests that political factors may play an important role in explaining the allocation of central discretionary government grants across Indonesia. The fact that TP grants should be allocated to tasks of `physical nature` (Government Regulation 7/2008) would ensure good visibility of the results of TP transfers to the voters. 15 The National Development Planning Agency meets with local governments once a year in order to discuss priorities of local development for the following year. There is no other official channel for a proposal of grants by the local governments. 16 Government Regulation 7/2008 Article 6 paragraph 2 9

10 Figure 2: Geographical distribution of Tp per capita in 2007 source: authors illustration 10

11 3. Theoretical Considerations From an efficiency perspective central government transfers to the region are regarded as an instrument that allows benefitting from the advantages of decentralization while minimizing the costs of decentralization in terms of fiscal inequity or negative external effects (Boadway, 2007). Decentralization is advantageous for governance and public service delivery because it allows for better preference matching of geographically heterogeneous population as local governments have an informational advantages over the central government, their actions are more transparent to the local electorate and thus participation of local constituency is higher (Oates, 1972). Moreover, in decentralized states mobile individuals can sort themselves into local jurisdictions that offer the best mix of public services and taxes (Tiebout, 1956). Decentralization can also be seen as creating a laboratory for policy solutions (Hayek, 1945) and giving rise to competition between districts, which increases their performances (Besely and Case, 1995). Yet this competition may create negative externalities as local governments do not take into considerations the effects of their policies on other local jurisdictions, for instance the erosion of local tax bases (Wilson, 1999) or may bias public expenditure composition (Keen and Marchand, 1997). Oates (1999) argues that central government transfers have the normative objectives of fiscal equalization, securing national public service standards and the internalization of spillover benefits of local public services (see also Boadway, 2007). As a consequence, central government transfers should account for differences in fiscal capacity, in the costs of providing public services of a jurisdiction as well as for different development levels. Indeed Government Regulation 7/2008 on Deconcentration and Co-Administration Funds stipulates that the allocation of TP should be determined by the district s financial capacity, the need of providing public services, and the district s development. We thus formulate our first hypothesis: Hypothesis 1 ("Needs orientation"): Central discretionary grants are lower for districts with higher fiscal capacity and better socioeconomic development. This hypothesis is testable as data for development levels, such as human development index, GDP per capita, price indexes and fiscal variables are available at the local level (and differ 11

12 very substantially between districts). In the Indonesian context only Lewis (2016) has tested for a possible needs orientation of TP transfers; he finds very mixed results. In contrast to this normative point of view, government transfers from a positive point of view are motivated by maximizing the probability of reelection. The distribution of transfers is based on tactical and strategic considerations in order to maximize votes, seen as political capital (Grossman, 1994). The incumbent may target swing voters (Lindbeck and Weibull, 1987), core supporters (Cox and McCubbins, 1986) or either swing or core supporters depending on the relative effectiveness of this political investment (Dixit and Londregan, 1996). 17 The allocation depends also on an incumbent s attitude towards risk (Cox and McCubbins, 1986), whether there are systematic (observable) party preferences in the electorate (Lindbeck and Weibull, 1987), and on the ability to target transfers to any certain group of the electorate (Dixit and Londregan, 1996). Additionally, Arulampalam et al. (2009) assume voters to vote along party lines whereas Dixit and Londregan (1998) distinguish voting behavior between different government levels. For Arulampalam et al. (2009) transfers are used to finance public projects at the state level, increasing the popularity (electoral benefit) of the central incumbent party. Through these projects, the incumbent of the state receives some electoral benefit as well. If both the central and state incumbent are from the same party, a party receives the total additional electoral benefit from such additional expenditure at the state level. If, however, they are from different parties, some of the electoral benefit at the state level might leak to the opposition. Here the incumbent focuses on swing states if the transfers provide information on their source, known as targeted grants. Otherwise the electorate, by mistake, accounts any electoral benefit to the opposition in charge at the local level. Indonesia s district government level however is characterized by local district heads that often only have a loose (institutional) attachment to a political party. Local candidates often see political parties just as a provider for nomination (Qodari, 2010). They are often no official party members or switch their party background to a party with a stronger local network and better financial opportunities (Ufen, 2009). Political parties in turn tend to sell nominations to 17 According to Drazen (2000) a swing voter can be defined as a voter with weak ideological party preferences or a voter likely to change its voting behavior due to received economic benefits, since he is close to the margin of indifference between the political parties policies. A core voter in contrast with strong ideological political party preferences that was loyal to a party in past elections. 12

13 promising, well-endowed independent local candidates that do not have any backing of a political party yet (Buehler (2010), Mietzner (2009)). As Mietzner (2013, p: 224) puts it While formally nominated by parties, these local officials [ ] have no or only weak institutional party connections. 18 Thus one could think that a president might support a local district head as long as he/she runs under his political party banner. Due to the rather low political party attachment however, unlike most empirical evidence on other countries, we do not expect to find a significant influence of political alignment between the president and a local district head for Indonesia. Hypothesis 2 ( Political alignment ): Central discretionary grants are higher for districts that are politically aligned with the president. Indonesia also does not have a two-party system and strict politico-ideological lines. Instead it is characterized by a multiparty system with changing rainbow coalitions at the central government level (Aspinall et al., 2015), decreasing politico-ideological party lines (Mietzner, 2013), political party platforms hardly distinguishable (Mujani and Liddle, 2010) and an increasing importance of candidate-popularity (Mietzner, 2013). According to Ufen (2009) the two ticket, two round system of the direct presidential elections implemented in 2004 (Section 2.1) has decreased ideological party differences. The candidates often just represent different levels of religiosity or a geographic area. According to Ananta et al. (2005) e.g. the mixture of Javanese/non-Javanese, secular/islamic, as well as Kalla s civilian and SBY s military background made them an promising pair for the presidency from the start. Here personal popularity of a candidate often matters more for electoral success than political party strengthen or a candidates political ideology (Mujani and Liddle (2010), Qodari, (2010), Mietzner (2009)). 19 In the past parties aligned based on ideology, today parties start to align themselves more based on their electoral interests (Basewedan, 2007). As his predecessor SBY also created 18 At the central level, the political party Partai Demkorat (PD) is also seen solely as a presidential party, used as an electoral vehicle to win presidential office by the Yudhoyono in 2004 (Aspinall et al., 2015). Lacking a real political platform and an organizational structure at the local level (Ufen, 2009). A part from the at least branches in 60 percent of all provinces every local political party in Indonesian needs by law (Palmer,2010) 19 However, at the same time the backing of Yusuf Kalla and its Golkar party in the run up to 2004 presidential elections helped SBY to gain office the first time, since PD had just received 7.5 percent in the DPR elections (Ufen, 2009). 13

14 large rainbow coalitions, political party coalitions across ideologies and in changing combinations, with the only aim to stay or get in power. 20 SBY s first cabinet ( ) and second cabinet ( ) included among technocrats, members of seven and six parties respectively (Aspinall et al., 2015). Accounting for 73 ( ) and 75 percent ( ) of the seats in parliament. Due these pragmatic rainbow coalitions across all politicoideological lines, often no clear distinction between the opposition and the government was possible (Ufen, 2009). In contrast to most other emerging democracies there is also no classical left-right divide between Indonesian parties at the regional level, ideological lines rather run along the role of Islam in state affairs (Mietzner, 2013). 21 Hence Mietzner (2013) argues that politicoideological party differences have decreased, leading to some dealignment of electoral politics as Indonesia moves from a party-based to a candidate-driven system. 22 However this would not lead to the full abolishment of established parties and their embedded roots in specific constituencies (Mietzner, 2013). Here Mietzner (2013) argues that although party identification of the electorate has decreased and party networks have been weakened, most parties still have deep roots in specific constituencies and most party leaders still represent long-standing politico-ideological camps. 23 Most Indonesian parties still seem to have core constituencies providing them with electoral support and networks and political supporters embedded in particular milieus aliran (streams) (Ufen, 2009). Although Mujani and Liddle (2010) find no evidence for a polarization of voters based on aliran and religiosity in the legislative or presidential elections of Pratikno (2009) argues, that although the importance of ideological lines for the candidacy in local government elections has declined (see above), members of each political party still use their ideological lines and networks to mobilize votes. Meaning parties have a well-defined support bases along particular religious, regional or socioeconomic characteristics (Sherlock, 2004). However, although political parties have well-defined supporters with respect to religion, region or socio-economic background there often is no focus on well-defined policies to cater the specific needs of those 20 Sherlock argued in 2004 already, that due to Indonesia s strong fragmentation of the electorate, presidential candidates must have to build a coalition to win the first past the post system leading to backroom deals over other important positions e.g. in the cabinet (Sherlock, 2004). 21 Mietzner (2013, p. 219): To be sure, Indonesia does not fit into the left-right scheme that political theorists often view as a precondition for solidly structured parties and party systems. Instead the main cleavage in Indonesia s party landscape separates advocates from opponents of politico-social Islamization. This cleavage has instilled an ideological sense of purpose into party politics, and sets it apart from most other new democracies. 22 Mietzner (2013, p. 220): assessments diagnosing the disappearances of aliran-or politico-ideological streams-have been premature. There is no doubt that some form of dealignment in electoral politics has taken place, as the rise of presidential parties has demonstrated (Mujani and Liddle (2010)). But this has not led to the exodus of established parties with deep roots in specific societal constituencies. 23 Especially if you compare Indonesia to other East Asian countries like Thailand and the Philippines (Mietzner, 2013). 14

15 communities (Sherlock, 2004). In the 2004 elections the political differences between the president and the challengers in terms of their political agenda was blurry and most voters were not aware of any party differences (Mujani and Liddle, 2010). A survey on Indonesia s electorate, done by the Asia Foundation, showed that 66 percent of the eligible voters in 2003 saw no differences between the contesting parties, 9 percent said there were, but were not able to name any differences. In 2009 however, Yudhoyono and its PD were clearly challenged by Megawati and the PDI-P (Mujani and Liddle, 2010). In contrast however, political patronage and clientelism in Indonesia is very prevalent (Mietzner (2013), Aspinall and Sukmajati (2016)), votes are often given to a candidate or party as a reward for services ( service-based candidate-voter relationship) (Palmer, 2010), the introduction of direct elections in 2004 have increased the need to maximize votes (Ufen (2009), Qodari (2010)) and voters show an increasing importance of their perception of the economic situation. Referring to a study by the Indonesian Survey Institute (Lembaga Survey Indonesia, LSI) Mujani and Liddle (2010) argue that leadership, candidate appeal (especially in the media), self-identification with a political party, and demographics determined voting behavior in Indonesia s 2004 election rather than the perception of the economy, religion, region ethnicity, social class, or location of residency (Java/Non-Java). In contrast political economic factors, rather than leadership appeal and campaign advertising, were identified as one factor explaining the 2009 parliamentary vote in Indonesia (Mujani and Liddle, 2010). Indonesians with a positive view of the national economy or government performance were more likely to vote for PD in the parliamentary elections compared to for example PDI-P, enabling Yudhoyono to get re-elected in 2009 (Mujani and Liddle, 2010). Hence in 2009 political economy factors played an increasing role in determining electoral preferences. All this makes Indonesia a particular interesting case for testing the classical determinants of central discretionary grants prevalent in the literature. Biasing grants towards districts showing a larger vote support for the president could secure past electoral support for the future. Alternatively, the president could also have an interest to bias his grants to weaker supporters giving him larger potential returns of his investment in votes. Here this bias towards weaker supports is more likely than a bias towards swing districts. Since in an incumbent president in Indonesia needs to maximize votes across all districts (does not have to win a district majority like e.g. in the US). Due to the increasing importance of political 15

16 economic factors and Indonesia s service-based candidate-voter relationship this could secure voting support in the next elections. Potentially also leading to better voting results at the local (DPRD) and national parliamentary elections (DPR). 24 This would facilitate a potential renomination of the incumbent president as a presidential candidate by his party and allow PD to govern more effectively once SBY gets reelected (e.g. having higher support in passing legislations in the DPR and maintaining a stable cabinet). 25 We are aware that Indonesia s central government has the possibility to distribute strategic favors using implicit transfers (subsidies, licensing) as well of course. However, given Indonesia s large scale of nondiscretionary transfer schemes the question remains why such a discretionary grant mechanism scheme actually exits, if not for political reasons. Hypothesis 3 ( Reward hypothesis ): Central discretionary grants are biased towards electoral core supporters of the president in the past. Additionally, if any type of this vote maximization calculus exits, it would most likely to be detected in the first term of the president, when reelection was still possible ( ) not during his second term ( ) once the president was facing his term limit. Hypothesis 4 ( Political investment ): (a) Central discretionary grants are biased towards districts with low support for the president. (b) This bias exists only in the first term, when reelection is possible. 24 Based on empirical evidence by Basewedan (2007), Indonesians voted for the same political party across different levels of government in the 2004 elections. For 2004, an increase in votes for PD at the national level, increased votes at the district level by 0.922, significant at the 1 percent level 24. From those voters voting for the PD in the 2004 parliamentary elections, almost 100 percent voted for candidates running for PD (Yudhoyono-Kalla) in the second round of presidential elections (Ananta et al., 2005)) 25 According to Sukma (2010) and Sherlock (2004) the president of Indonesia is still interested in the composition of the parliament (DPR) in order to achieve his legislative goals, despite him being elected directly by popular vote and not by the DPR. 16

17 4. Empirical Evidence for Indonesia 4.1 Data To test these 4 Hypotheses, we collected a unique unbalanced panel dataset including 497 Indonesian districts from , representing more than 90 percent of Indonesia s population in Our main sources of data are the Indonesian Database for Policy and Economic Research (DAPOER) of the World Bank Indonesia, Indonesia s Election Commission (KPU), the Ministry of Home Affairs, Ministry of Finance and the Statistical Office (BPS). For descriptive statistics, variable definitions and all corresponding data sources see Appendix A. All districts of the special autonomy provinces Aceh Darussalam are not included. 26 Province DKI Jakarta is excluded since as the capital region it has a special legal status and its districts are not autonomous. Papua had to be excluded due to data restrictions. Hence our main restricted sample includes 428 districts. 4.2 Empirical Model We use a pooled ordinary least squares model pooled OLS (1), clustering standard errors at the district level to account for serial correlation of unobserved variables within a district. Additionally, we use a fixed effects (FE) model (2) to control for unobservable time-invariant district characteristics. The dependent variable is defined as the total natural logarithm of the central discretionary government grant Tp per capita in district d at time t, ( ). Our Baseline controls for a districts fiscal capacity from other (non-discretionary) revenue sources and its overall socioeconomic development. All time-variant variables are lagged by one year, since budgetary decisions are usually made one year in advance. measures the fiscal capacity of a district as the natural logarithm of the total revenue per capita by other (nondiscretionary) revenue sources (own source revenue, DAU, DBH and DAK) in the year before. controls for a district s overall socioeconomic development. It consists of the natural logarithm of real GRDP per capita (excluding oil and gas), and the Human Development Index (HDI) at the district level. Plus we control for district size using population density (district population/area size) and for year fixed effects ( ) to account for common macroeconomic shocks. In the pooled-ols estimation (1) we include provincial dummies ( ) to control for unobservable time-constant factors at the province 26 According to Law No. 35 (2008), Law No. 11 (2006), Law No. 21 (2001) districts in these regions receive special autonomy funds. Our main results however do not change once we include Aceh Darussalam. 17

18 level, our omitted category being Bali Province. We add a dummy equal to one if a district is a city-district (kota), since more rural regencies (kabupatens) are likely to differ in need characteristics compared to urban areas. Plus we add a dummy for coastal regions ( ) to account for the difference between more landlocked districts and the once with a direct coastline. Due to the common district splits in Indonesia (permekaran) we add a Dummy equal one if a district lost parts of it administrative area within our observation period ( ). All these time-invariant district fixed effects are automatically controlled under a fixed effects model, thus they are excluded in specification (2).! is the error term. Base Specifications: (1) = # +% ! (2) ''''''''''' = #( ''''''''')+%( '''''''''''''+ ) +!! ''' To test the effect of political alignment between the president and district heads we add a dummy variable (( ) equal to one for all the years the head of a district was formally affiliated to the presidential party (PD), meaning nominated by the presidential party (PD) in the last local district head elections, zero otherwise. Since local direct district head elections are independently conducted from national elections and at different points in time across districts, we have a within-district time varying measure of political alignment with the president. Thus we are able to run all our specifications in a fixed effects model, automatically controlling for all unobservable time-invariant district fixed effects (Table 2). To test for the effect of presidential vote support we define a dummy (()* ) equal to one, if a district supports the president and its party by more than 70 percent in the final round of the last direct presidential elections for all the years until the next presidential election (including the election year), zero otherwise 27. We also include various dummies for different vote share groups and a swing dummy, being equal to one if the incumbent president lost or won a district by less than 5 percent of the votes in the last presidential elections (Table 3-4). 27 Mean support for president in 2004 and 2009: percent, standard deviation percent. Minimum: 8.37 percent Maximum: percent. In 2004: Mean percent, standard deviation percent. Minimum: percent Maximum: percent In 2009: Mean percent, standard deviation percent. Minimum: 8.37 percent Maximum: percent 18

19 4.3 Empirical Results Baseline Our Baseline specification (Table 1) show the overall socioeconomic development of a district is not significantly correlated with the actual grant allocation. Larger areas with a more dense population receive less per capita grants, most likely explained by economies of scale. In contrast to the according government regulation (Government Regulation 7/2008) however, the fiscal capacity of a district by other non-discretionary revenue sources is not correlated with discretionary grant allocations. Same accounts for the Human Development Index and and the GRDP of a district in the past. These results on the weak influence of these main need characteristics on Tp grant allocations are in line with Lewis (2016). In a detailed analysis for the need determinants of Tp grants for a different time period Lewis (2016) shows: transfers, local government spending and local service access are all positively associated with Tp grant allocations. Hence also not in the way predicted by normative theory and/or the according government regulation. This could be an indication for potential political factors at play, for which we are going to test for in the following Political Alignment Political Alignment between a district head and the president does not have any significant effect on the distribution of grants. According to our results testing Hypothesis 2 (Table 2), if a district head was nominated by the presidential party is not significantly correlate to the amount of central discretionary grants towards this district (1-10). 29 However districts holding local direct elections receive between 7-9 percent less grants per capita compared to two or more years before. This could be explained by uncertainty about the election outcome at the local level or limited lobbying capacity from the local level due to upcoming elections, both reducing the amount of grants allocated to districts. However there is no indication of a local political budget cycle or a preferential treatment of politically aligned district heads facing a local direct election. Grants one year before local direct elections are not significantly higher (3-4), and mayors from the presidential party do not receive more grants in a local election year (5-6). Plus district heads from one of Indonesia s highly entrenched political parties or 28 The fact that in all years before and after the national presidential elections in 2009 per capita grants towards districts are significantly smaller could be a first indication for this. 29 The amount of district heads between only nominated and elected into office by the presidential party is low (10 districts). Hence the overall amount of observations with a district head affiliated with the presidential party only accounts for 49 observations. However we also find no bias towards districts heads nominated by a coalition including the presidential party (PD). 19

20 the main opposition party to the president do not receive significantly more or less grants (7-10). Golkar is one of Indonesia s most established parties, in power for many years under Suharto, hence most likely still well connected within Indonesia s government structure and according to Mietzner (2013), often described as having a large patronage capacity. Our results show that district heads from Golkar also do not receive more grants. If there is no preferential treatment of the district heads close to the central government or well entrenched in the government system, one could suspect a potential discrimination of the opposition party. Our results show however that district heads from PDIP, strongest opposition and competitor to the presidential party over our observation period, do not receive significantly less grants (9-10) either. To control for a potential political alignment at the provincial level we also controlled for districts under authority of a governor (province level) nominated by a coalition including the presidential party PD, showing no significant influence. 30 As expected (Hypothesis 2), we find no evidence for the political party background or political alignment of a district head with the president influencing the distribution of central discretionary grants in Indonesia Past Presidential Support Core supporting districts of the president in the last presidential elections receive significantly less grants per capita, in particular in a national election year. Instead the weak supporters of the president are targeted, not the swing districts. Core districts are defined as showing a vote support for the incumbent president of larger than 70 percent in the last local direct presidential elections. Here on top of our baseline controls all specifications are controlled for a possible change in the political composition of a district due to a district split (permekaran). We add dummies equal to one if a district split between (incl. 04 and 08) and between (incl. 09). If for example a district split in 2007, this dummy accounts for a potential change in the district s political composition up until 2009 (next presidential elections). After 2009 the district gets treated as its own new observation, categorized based on its own according presidential vote support in the 2009 elections. Since an incumbent president in Indonesia does not have to maximize district majorities but the total amount of votes we also control for the amount of eligible voters in the 2009 and 2014 presidential elections. 30 There was no governor only nominated by PD in our whole observation period from

21 According to our results testing Hypothesis 3 (Table 3), being a core supporting district in the last presidential elections decreases grants per capita by around 19 percent per year (1-2), an additional percent per capita in the year of the national presidential election in 2009 (3-4). Instead weaker supporters, showing an electoral support of less than 70 percent for the president receive significantly more grants. Districts having a vote support of 0-30 percent in the last presidential elections receive percent more discretionary grants per capita per year than a core supporting district (5-6), and even more in the national election year 2009 (7-8). As expected, districts hardly won or hardly lost in the last presidential elections are not targeted significantly, also not in the national election year 2009 (9-12). Swing districts are defined as districts were the president lost or won by a vote margin of 5 percent. In summary, central grants are significantly targeted towards districts supporting the opposition candidate in the last presidential elections. Table 3 shows grants are invested in districts that showed the weakest vote support, having a higher return in the investment of votes. This is especially the case in the year of the direct national presidential elections 2009, were the incumbent president was running for reelection. If this vote maximization behavior by the incumbent government exists however, it should only be prevalent once the incumbent can actually run for reelection (Hypothesis 4). Splitting our observation period into a period where reelection of the president was possible ( ) and one were not ( ) gives us the results presented in Table 4a and 4b. Our results show, in the period where reelection was possible districts showing lower support in the 2004 national presidential elections receive significantly more Tp per capita grants (Table4a), in particular in the national election year of 2009 (2-4). In contrast, once the president cannot can for reelection anymore (Table4b), weaker supporters do not receive significantly more grants anymore (3). In summary, once the incumbent president still can be reelected central grants focus on his weaker supporters of past presidential elections, at the cost of the top core supporters. Once the president faces his term limit however, past electoral vote support does not seem to have this influence anymore. If any, moderate supporters are rewarded (Table 4b, Specification (2)). This is consistent with the view that discretionary grants are seen as an instrument by the president to increase his reelection probabilities. 21

22 Table 1: Baseline regression Discretionary Grants per capita ( ) Natural Logarithm of Tp per capita (1) OLS (2) FE Log of GRDP per capita (ex. Oil/Gas) [0.063] [0.253] Log of Fiscal Capacity pc. (non-discretionary) [0.124] [0.093] Human Development Index [0.010] [0.009] Log of Population Density *** *** [0.093] [0.311] Log of Area Size *** *** [0.095] [0.290] Dummy Any District Split [0.060] Dummy Urban District * [0.134] Dummy Coastline [0.054] *** *** [0.128] [0.124] *** *** [0.100] [0.096] *** *** [0.060] [0.061] *** *** [0.038] [0.041] *** *** [0.049] [0.049] *** *** [0.052] [0.056] *** *** [0.061] [0.073] *** * [0.078] [0.084] Province Fixed Effects Yes No _cons *** *** [2.845] [4.269] R N Note: Pooled OLS (1) and Fixed Effect Model (2). Robust standard errors clustered at the district level are reported in brackets. DKI Jakarta and Special autonomy regions (Aceh) are excluded from the analysis. Papua is excluded. The base category for this Province Dummy is Bali, the base year for the time fixed effects is Al time-variant controls are lagged by one year. * p<0.1; ** p<0.05; *** p<

23 Table 2: Political Alignment and Discretionary Grants per capita ( ) Natural Logarithm of Tp per capita (1)OLS (2)FE (3)OLS (4)FE (5)OLS (6)FE (7)OLS (8)FE (9)OLS (10)FE Dmy PD Mayor [0.190] [0.254] [0.189] [0.251] [0.208] [0.275] [0.190] [0.251] [0.190] [0.250] DmyLocalDirectElection *** ** *** ** *** ** *** ** [0.031] [0.032] [0.031] [0.032] [0.031] [0.032] [0.030] [0.032] DmyLocalDirectElection in t [0.042] [0.040] [0.042] [0.040] [0.042] [0.040] [0.042] [0.040] Dmy PD Mayor X DmyLocalElec [0.201] [0.201] Dmy Golkar Mayor [0.062] [0.066] [0.064] [0.066] Dmy PDI-P Mayor [0.098] [0.107] Year Fixed Effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Province Fixed Effects Yes No Yes No Yes No Yes No Yes No _cons *** *** *** *** *** *** *** *** *** *** [2.878] [3.865] [2.884] [3.917] [2.884] [3.918] [2.859] [3.916] [2.832] [3.924] R N Note: Pooled OLS (OLS) and Fixed Effects models (FE). Robust standard errors clustered at the district level are reported in brackets. DKI Jakarta and Special autonomy regions (Aceh) are excluded from the analysis. Papua is excluded. All Baseline controls are included. * p<0.1; ** p<0.05; *** p<

24 Table 3: Past Presidential Vote Support and Discretionary Grants per capita ( ) Natural Logarithm of Tp per capita (1)OLS (2)FE (3)OLS (4)FE (5)OLS (6)FE (7)OLS (8)FE (9)OLS (10)FE (11)OLS (12)FE DmyCorePresident (>70%) *** *** ** ** [0.068] [0.066] [0.070] [0.068] DmyCorePresidentXNational Election *** *** [0.087] [0.088] DmyElectoralSupportPresident1(0-30%) 0.335*** 0.476*** 0.262*** 0.410*** [0.092] [0.085] [0.090] [0.091] DmyElectoralSupportPresident2(30-40%) 0.222*** 0.221** 0.187** 0.196* [0.081] [0.100] [0.084] [0.101] DmyElectoralSupportPresident3(40-50%) * [0.073] [0.079] [0.074] [0.080] DmyElectoralSupportPresident4(50-60%) 0.173** 0.168** 0.135* 0.133* [0.077] [0.074] [0.079] [0.076] DmyElectoralSupportPresident5(60-70%) 0.211** ** [0.083] [0.079] [0.084] [0.080] DmyElectoralSupportPresident1XNationalElection 0.572*** 0.470** [0.181] [0.185] DmyElectoralSupportPresident2XNationalElection 0.323** 0.242* [0.127] [0.130] DmyElectoralSupportPresident3XNationalElection 0.252** 0.202* [0.128] [0.122] DmyElectoralSupportPresident4XNationalElection 0.339*** 0.319*** [0.111] [0.112] DmyElectoralSupportPresident5XNationalElection [0.133] [0.132] DmySwingPresident (+/-5% votemargin) [0.071] [0.089] [0.071] [0.087] DmySwingPresidentXNationalElection [0.155] [0.147] Year Fixed Effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Province Fixed Effects Yes No Yes No Yes No Yes No Yes No Yes No _cons *** *** *** *** *** *** *** *** *** *** *** *** [3.138] [5.269] [3.141] [5.245] [3.120] [5.017] [3.121] [4.879] [3.112] [4.974] [3.115] [4.978] R N Note: Pooled OLS and Fixed Effect Model (FE). Robust standard errors clustered at the district level are reported in brackets. DKI Jakarta and Special autonomy regions (Aceh) are excluded from the analysis. Papua is excluded. All specifications include Province Dummies (omitted category: Prov. Bali). A district is defined as a core supporter of the president if it showed an electoral support of larger than 70.0 percent for SBY (mean+ sd) in the last direct presidential elections of 2004 and/or All Baseline controls are included. * p<0.1; ** p<0.05; *** p<

25 Table 4a: Past Presidential Support in 2004 and Discretionary Grants per capita ( ), reelection possible Natural Logarithm of Tp per capita (1) OLS (2) OLS (3) OLS (4) OLS DmyCoreSupporterPresident (>70%) * [0.118] DmyElectoralSupportPresident1(0-30%) 0.554*** 0.439** [0.187] [0.176] DmyElectoralSupportPresident2(40-50%) 0.381*** 0.321** [0.147] [0.151] DmyElectoralSupportPresident3(50-60%) [0.131] [0.130] DmyElectoralSupportPresident4(50-60%) 0.264** [0.128] [0.133] DmyElectoralSupportPresident5(60-70%) [0.126] [0.130] DmyElectoralSupportPresident1XNationalElection 0.509*** [0.185] DmyElectoralSupportPresident2XNationalElection 0.281** [0.138] DmyElectoralSupportPresident3XNationalElection [0.128] DmyElectoralSupportPresident4XNationalElection 0.284** [0.123] DmyElectoralSupportPresident5XNationalElection [0.141] DmySwingPresident (+/-5% votemargin) [0.085] _cons *** *** *** *** [3.771] [3.728] [3.742] [3.731] R N Note: Pooled OLS. Robust standard errors clustered at the district level are reported in brackets. DKI Jakarta and Special autonomy regions (Aceh) are excluded from the analysis. Papua is excluded. All specifications include Province and Year Fixed Effects. All Baseline controls are included. * p<0.1; ** p<0.05; *** p<

26 Table 4b: Presidential Support in 2009 and Discretionary Grants per capita ( ), no reelection possible Natural Logarithm of Tp per capita (1)OLS (2)OLS (3)OLS DmyCoreSupporterPresident (>70%) [0.088] DmyElectoralSupportPresident1(0-30%) [0.143] DmyElectoralSupportPresident2(40-50%) [0.109] DmyElectoralSupportPresident3(50-60%) [0.105] DmyElectoralSupportPresident4(50-60%) [0.097] DmyElectoralSupportPresident5(60-70%) 0.208** [0.098] DmySwingPresident (+/-5% votemargin) [0.110] _cons *** *** *** [3.584] [3.531] [3.620] R N Note: Pooled OLS. Robust standard errors clustered at the district level are reported in brackets. DKI Jakarta and Special autonomy regions (Aceh) are excluded from the analysis. Papua is excluded. All specification include Province and Year fixed effects. All Baseline controls are lagged by one year. * p<0.1; ** p<0.05; *** p< Robustness Checks Ministry of Finance Recommendation The absence of an investment in weak supporters once the president faces his term limit (Table 4b) could be driven by a change in the discretionary scope for the incumbent government. Since 2010 the Ministry of Finance gives a nonbinding allocation recommendation which districts are of higher priority for the allocation of grants. According to the Ministry of Finance this recommendation was implemented for grants to become more effective, transparent, proportionate, efficient and most importantly not concentrated in a particular (geographic) area. 31 Here districts are separated into 4 categories, the highest priority districts in time t are those that have a fiscal per capita capacity (based on nondiscretionary transfers and own source revenue) below the national average in t-2 and below the national average of the Human Development Index (HDI) in t-1. Second priority are those districts that have a fiscal capacity per capita larger the national average but a HDI below the 31 Recommendations on the Regional Balance of Funding, Ministry of Finance Indonesia (published in June 2017) 26

27 national average. Districts above the national average in HDI are of non-priority, independent of their fiscal capacity per capita. 32 Controlling for this (although rather limited) theoretical decrease in the discretionary scope by an unbinding recommendation of the Ministry of Finance does not change our results. District that are by definition of the Ministry of Finance top priority for the allocation of grants (below the national mean of HDI) do receive around 20 percent more Tp per capita grants compared to districts in the two lowest priority groups (below national HDI) (Table RB1). However, we also find this effect for the period , when the policy was not yet implemented. Here districts within this group receive significantly more and even by larger magnitude. Plus as we can see in Figure 3-4 below, although the priority group (priority 1 and 2) receives significantly more (Table RB1), there are still districts within this group receiving very different TP allocations. For the years after 2010 districts in the priority group 1 and 2 are only in the 4 th quartile of Tp per capita grant allocations. Plus some districts that should be non-priority cases are among the top recipients. Our main results do not change once we control for the presence of this allocation recommendation by the Ministry of Finance. 32 If their fiscal capacity per capita is above/below national average they are accounted as non-priority group 4/group 3. 27

28 Table RB1: Ministry of Finance Recommendation Natural Logarithm of Tp per capita (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) DmyCoreSupporterPresident (>70%) ** [0.086] [0.111] DmyElectoralSupportPresident1 (0-30%) * 0.588*** 0.469*** [0.139] [0.185] [0.174] DmyElectoralSupportPresident2 (30-40%) ** 0.292** [0.105] [0.142] [0.145] DmyElectoralSupportPresident3 (40-50%) [0.103] [0.136] [0.132] DmyElectoralSupportPresident4 (50-60%) ** 0.246** [0.095] [0.119] [0.124] DmyElectoralSupportPresident6 (60-70%) 0.201** [0.095] [0.119] [0.119] DmyElectoralSupportPresident1XNationaElection 0.419** [0.177] DmyElectoralSupportPresident2XNationaElection 0.273** [0.118] DmyElectoralSupportPresident3XNationaElection [0.113] DmyElectoralSupportPresident4XNationaElection 0.205* [0.115] DmyElectoralSupportPresident5XNationaElection [0.124] DmyPriority (Q1,Q2) 0.182** 0.199** 0.242*** 0.239*** 0.238*** [0.083] [0.081] [0.077] [0.078] [0.078] _cons *** *** *** *** *** [3.686] [3.598] [4.481] [4.446] [4.460] R N Note: Pooled OLS. Robust standard errors clustered at the district level are reported in brackets. DKI Jakarta and Special autonomy regions (Aceh) are excluded from the analysis. Papua is excluded. All specifications included Province Dummies, omitted category Prov. Bali. The base year for the time fixed effects is All Baseline Controls are included. Non-Priority districts are the omitted category. p<0.1; ** p<0.05; *** p<

29 Figure 3 source: authors illustration Note: Marked in red the top 25 percent recipients of Tp per capita allocations. In orange the third quartile, in blue and green the second and first quartile. Figure 4 source: authors illustration Note: Marked in red the top 25 percent recipients of Tp per capita allocations. In orange the third quartile, in blue and green the second and first quartile. 29

To the ones in need or the ones you need?

To the ones in need or the ones you need? University of Freiburg Department of International Economic Policy Discussion Paper Series Nr. 36 To the ones in need or the ones you need? The Political Economy of Central Discretionary Grants Empirical

More information

Philips Vermonte CSIS December The 2014 Election and Democracy in Indonesia

Philips Vermonte CSIS December The 2014 Election and Democracy in Indonesia Philips Vermonte CSIS December 2014 The 2014 Election and Democracy in Indonesia Political Reform Competitive electoral democracy Economic Reform Growth Recovery Decentralization Fiscal and Public Service

More information

4/25/2014. Population: 253 million (World Population Review) Number of Voters: million (The Guardian)

4/25/2014. Population: 253 million (World Population Review) Number of Voters: million (The Guardian) 1 Indonesia is the world s third largest democracy, South-east Asia s largest economy, a G20 member, and home to the world s largest Muslim population. It matters. (The Guardian) Population: 253 million

More information

The Impact of an Open-party List System on Incumbency Turnover and Political Representativeness in Indonesia

The Impact of an Open-party List System on Incumbency Turnover and Political Representativeness in Indonesia The Impact of an Open-party List System on Incumbency Turnover and Political Representativeness in Indonesia An Open Forum with Dr. Michael Buehler and Dr. Philips J. Vermonte Introduction June 26, 2012

More information

RESULTS FROM WAVE XIV OF TRACKING SURVEYS. 1 July 2004

RESULTS FROM WAVE XIV OF TRACKING SURVEYS. 1 July 2004 RESULTS FROM WAVE XIV OF TRACKING SURVEYS 1 July 2004 Methodology Waves I, II, IX, and X surveys were conducted using face-to-face interviews with 1250 respondents (each wave), selected by multi-stage

More information

Presidentialism and Political Parties in Indonesia: Why Are All Parties Not Presidentialized?

Presidentialism and Political Parties in Indonesia: Why Are All Parties Not Presidentialized? INSTITUTE OF DEVELOPING ECONOMIES IDE Discussion Papers are preliminary materials circulated to stimulate discussions and critical comments IDE DISCUSSION PAPER No. 409 Presidentialism and Political Parties

More information

CRS Report for Congress

CRS Report for Congress CRS Report for Congress Received through the CRS Web Order Code RS21874 Updated May 20, 2005 Summary Indonesian Elections Bruce Vaughn Analyst in Southeast and South Asian Affairs Foreign Affairs, Defense,

More information

Intergovernmental Fiscal Transfers and Tactical Political Maneuverings: Evidence from Ghana s District Assemblies Common Fund ABEL FUMEY

Intergovernmental Fiscal Transfers and Tactical Political Maneuverings: Evidence from Ghana s District Assemblies Common Fund ABEL FUMEY Intergovernmental Fiscal Transfers and Tactical Political Maneuverings: Evidence from Ghana s District Assemblies Common Fund ABEL FUMEY 7/7/2017 1 Order of Presentation Introduction The Problem Objectives

More information

Andreas Ufen Democratisation & new voter mobilisation in Southeast Asia: forms of campaigning and the transformation of political parties in Indonesia

Andreas Ufen Democratisation & new voter mobilisation in Southeast Asia: forms of campaigning and the transformation of political parties in Indonesia Andreas Ufen Democratisation & new voter mobilisation in Southeast Asia: forms of campaigning and the transformation of political parties in Indonesia Report Original citation: Ufen, Andreas (2010) Democratisation

More information

RESULTS FROM WAVE XVIII OF TRACKING SURVEYS. 19 October 2004

RESULTS FROM WAVE XVIII OF TRACKING SURVEYS. 19 October 2004 RESULTS FROM WAVE XVIII OF TRACKING SURVEYS 19 October 2004 Survey Implementation This survey was conducted between 22 September and 29 September 2004, using face to face interviews with 1250 respondents

More information

Does Political Competition Reduce Ethnic Discrimination?

Does Political Competition Reduce Ethnic Discrimination? Does Political Competition Reduce Ethnic Discrimination? Evidence from the Samurdhi Food Stamp Program in Sri Lanka Iffath Sharif Senior Economist South Asia Social Protection February 14, 2011 Presentation

More information

personalities, parties, and voters

personalities, parties, and voters Indonesia personalities, parties, and voters Saiful Mujani and R. William Liddle Saiful Mujani is the principal investigator and a founder of the Indonesian Survey Institute (LSI) and associate professor

More information

Public Opinion in Indonesia. Post-Presidential Election Public Opinion Survey October 2014

Public Opinion in Indonesia. Post-Presidential Election Public Opinion Survey October 2014 Public Opinion in Indonesia Post-Presidential Election Public Opinion Survey October 2014 Key Finding Indonesians generally have very positive views on the conduct of the presidential elections, with large

More information

This document is downloaded from DR-NTU, Nanyang Technological University Library, Singapore.

This document is downloaded from DR-NTU, Nanyang Technological University Library, Singapore. This document is downloaded from DR-NTU, Nanyang Technological University Library, Singapore. Title The East Java gubernatorial race : dead heat but non - controversial Author(s) Arifianto, Alexander Raymond;

More information

A 2014 Indonesian Election Primer. Nathan Allen

A 2014 Indonesian Election Primer. Nathan Allen A 2014 Indonesian Election Primer Nathan Allen In 2014 Indonesian voters will select a new government in a series of legislative and presidential elections. Susilo Bambang Yudhoyono (SBY), who has governed

More information

SOME QUESTIONS ABOUT THE ELECTORAL SYSTEM FOR THE 2004 INDONESIAN GENERAL ELECTION ANSWERED

SOME QUESTIONS ABOUT THE ELECTORAL SYSTEM FOR THE 2004 INDONESIAN GENERAL ELECTION ANSWERED SOME QUESTIONS ABOUT THE ELECTORAL SYSTEM FOR THE 2004 INDONESIAN GENERAL ELECTION ANSWERED Jakarta July 2003 INDEX Why Change The Electoral System Used at the 1999 Election 2 What Is The Date For The

More information

RESULTS FROM WAVES I THROUGH IV OF TRACKING SURVEY. IFES 1 March 2004

RESULTS FROM WAVES I THROUGH IV OF TRACKING SURVEY. IFES 1 March 2004 RESULTS FROM WAVES I THROUGH IV OF TRACKING SURVEY IFES 1 March 2004 Methodology Both the Wave I and Wave II surveys were conducted using face-to-face interviews with 1,250 respondents (per wave) selected

More information

RESULTS FROM WAVE XV OF TRACKING SURVEYS. 4 August 2004

RESULTS FROM WAVE XV OF TRACKING SURVEYS. 4 August 2004 RESULTS FROM WAVE XV OF TRACKING SURVEYS 4 August 2004 Methodology This survey was conducted between 7 July and 14 July 2004, using face to face interviews with 1250 respondents in all 32 provinces. Respondents

More information

Indonesia - Political Risk Outlook

Indonesia - Political Risk Outlook March 2014 Indonesia - Political Risk Outlook www.politicalmonitor.com.au Country overview Indonesia is perhaps the most important but underestimated country in the South East Asia region. An archipelago

More information

Does opportunism pay off?

Does opportunism pay off? Does opportunism pay off? Linda G. Veiga, Francisco José Veiga Universidade do Minho and NIPE, Portugal Received 22 June 2006; received in revised form 1 December 2006; accepted 20 December 2006 Available

More information

Political Competition and Local Government Performance: Evidence from Indonesia

Political Competition and Local Government Performance: Evidence from Indonesia Political Competition and Local Government Performance: Evidence from Indonesia Jahen F. Rezki December 2018 Abstract This paper analyses the impact of political competition on local government performance

More information

RESULTS FROM WAVE XI - XII OF TRACKING SURVEYS

RESULTS FROM WAVE XI - XII OF TRACKING SURVEYS RESULTS FROM WAVE XI - XII OF TRACKING SURVEYS 1 June 2004 International Foundation for Election Systems Methodology Both the Wave I and Wave II surveys were conducted using face-to-face interviews with

More information

Decentralisation Policy in Indonesia After 2001

Decentralisation Policy in Indonesia After 2001 Decentralisation Policy in Indonesia After 2001 Wahyudi Kumorotomo, Ph.D Master in Public Policy and Administration Programme Gadjah Mada University Indonesia 2010 www.kumoro.staff.ugm.ac.id kumoro@map.ugm.ac.id

More information

REPORTING AND PUBLIC DISCLOSURE OF FINANCIAL ACTIVITY OF POLITICAL PARTIES AND ELECTORAL PARTICIPANTS

REPORTING AND PUBLIC DISCLOSURE OF FINANCIAL ACTIVITY OF POLITICAL PARTIES AND ELECTORAL PARTICIPANTS Campaign Finance, Regulation and Public Disclosure in the Republic of Indonesia REPORTING AND PUBLIC DISCLOSURE OF FINANCIAL ACTIVITY OF POLITICAL PARTIES AND ELECTORAL PARTICIPANTS November 2004 The opinions

More information

Rumayya. UWA Business School. Economics

Rumayya. UWA Business School. Economics Three essays in political economy of decentralization in Indonesia Rumayya This thesis is presented for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy of The University of Western Australia UWA Business School Economics

More information

NATIONAL PUBLIC OPINION SURVEY. Republic of Indonesia. August 2003

NATIONAL PUBLIC OPINION SURVEY. Republic of Indonesia. August 2003 . NATIONAL PUBLIC OPINION SURVEY 2003 Republic of Indonesia August 2003 Table of Contents INTRODUCTION 3 SUMMARY 4 Overall Situation 4 Satisfaction with Institutions and Leaders 5 Representative Bodies

More information

Syahrul Hidayat Democratisation & new voter mobilisation in Southeast Asia: moderation and the stagnation of the PKS in the 2009 legislative election

Syahrul Hidayat Democratisation & new voter mobilisation in Southeast Asia: moderation and the stagnation of the PKS in the 2009 legislative election Syahrul Hidayat Democratisation & new voter mobilisation in Southeast Asia: moderation and the stagnation of the PKS in the 2009 legislative election Report Original citation: Hidayat, Syahrul (2010) Democratisation

More information

Fractionalization, Political Competition and Local Budgeting in Indonesia

Fractionalization, Political Competition and Local Budgeting in Indonesia Fractionalization, Political Competition and Local Budgeting in Indonesia Sherry Tao Kong Peking University Thomas Pepinsky Cornell University Russell Toth University of Sydney November, 2012 Abstract

More information

Distributive politics depend on powerful actors. This study tries to identify in

Distributive politics depend on powerful actors. This study tries to identify in Distributive Politics in Developing Federal Democracies: Compensating Governors for Their Territorial Support Lucas I. González Ignacio Mamone ABSTRACT Using original data from the period 1999 2011 on

More information

RESULTS FROM WAVE XVI OF TRACKING SURVEYS. 25 August 2004

RESULTS FROM WAVE XVI OF TRACKING SURVEYS. 25 August 2004 RESULTS FROM WAVE XVI OF TRACKING SURVEYS 25 August 2004 Survey Implementation This survey was conducted between 7 August and 14 August 2004, using face to face interviews with 1250 respondents in all

More information

Personnel Politics: Elections, Clientelistic Competition, and Teacher Hiring in Indonesia

Personnel Politics: Elections, Clientelistic Competition, and Teacher Hiring in Indonesia Personnel Politics: Elections, Clientelistic Competition, and Teacher Hiring in Indonesia Jan H. Pierskalla and Audrey Sacks Department of Political Science, The Ohio State University GPSURR, World Bank

More information

Runoff Elections and the Number of Presidential Candidates A Regression Discontinuity Design Using Brazilian Municipalities

Runoff Elections and the Number of Presidential Candidates A Regression Discontinuity Design Using Brazilian Municipalities Runoff Elections and the Number of Presidential Candidates A Regression Discontinuity Design Using Brazilian Municipalities Timothy J. Power University of Oxford Rodrigo Rodrigues-Silveira University of

More information

Effect of Socio-economic Conditions, Coalition, and Party Identification toward Voter Choice in Indonesian Legislative Election

Effect of Socio-economic Conditions, Coalition, and Party Identification toward Voter Choice in Indonesian Legislative Election Effect of Socio-economic Conditions, Coalition, and Party Identification toward Voter Choice in Indonesian Legislative Election Erasmus University Rotterdam Erasmus School of Economics Department of Economics

More information

Constitution and Human Rights Provisions in Indonesia: an Unfinished Task in the Transitional Process

Constitution and Human Rights Provisions in Indonesia: an Unfinished Task in the Transitional Process Constitution and Human Rights Provisions in Indonesia: an Unfinished Task in the Transitional Process Bivitri Susanti Introduction Indonesia is now facing the important moment of constructing a new foundation

More information

This document is downloaded from DR-NTU, Nanyang Technological University Library, Singapore.

This document is downloaded from DR-NTU, Nanyang Technological University Library, Singapore. This document is downloaded from DR-NTU, Nanyang Technological University Library, Singapore. Title Paradox of Indonesia's "Post-Majapahit" presidency : historic direct election makes Yudhoyono most popular

More information

3 rd International Conference. Panel T03 P08 Session 2. Democracy Institutions and Public Policy Performance. Title of the paper

3 rd International Conference. Panel T03 P08 Session 2. Democracy Institutions and Public Policy Performance. Title of the paper " 3 rd International Conference on Public Policy (ICPP3) June 28-30, 2017 Singapore " " " Panel T03 P08 Session 2 Democracy Institutions and Public Policy Performance Title of the paper Poverty, Education,

More information

Subhasish Dey, University of York Kunal Sen,University of Manchester & UNU-WIDER NDCDE, 2018, UNU-WIDER, Helsinki 12 th June 2018

Subhasish Dey, University of York Kunal Sen,University of Manchester & UNU-WIDER NDCDE, 2018, UNU-WIDER, Helsinki 12 th June 2018 Do Political Parties Practise Partisan Alignment in Social Welfare Spending? Evidence from Village Council Elections in India Subhasish Dey, University of York Kunal Sen,University of Manchester & UNU-WIDER

More information

Pork Barrel as a Signaling Tool: The Case of US Environmental Policy

Pork Barrel as a Signaling Tool: The Case of US Environmental Policy Pork Barrel as a Signaling Tool: The Case of US Environmental Policy Grantham Research Institute and LSE Cities, London School of Economics IAERE February 2016 Research question Is signaling a driving

More information

The 2009 elections in Indonesia led to a significant increase in women s participation in politics

The 2009 elections in Indonesia led to a significant increase in women s participation in politics WOMEN S VOICE IN POLITICS AND DECISION-MAKING The 2009 elections in Indonesia led to a significant increase in women s participation in politics (elected office) and decision-making with the help of affirmative

More information

This document is downloaded from DR-NTU, Nanyang Technological University Library, Singapore.

This document is downloaded from DR-NTU, Nanyang Technological University Library, Singapore. This document is downloaded from DR-NTU, Nanyang Technological University Library, Singapore. Title Indonesian presidential elections : how the five candidates measure up Author(s) Irman G. Lanti Citation

More information

Research Statement. Jeffrey J. Harden. 2 Dissertation Research: The Dimensions of Representation

Research Statement. Jeffrey J. Harden. 2 Dissertation Research: The Dimensions of Representation Research Statement Jeffrey J. Harden 1 Introduction My research agenda includes work in both quantitative methodology and American politics. In methodology I am broadly interested in developing and evaluating

More information

-1- BY THE BLESSINGS OF ALMIGHTY GOD THE CHAIRMAN OF THE ELECTION SUPERVISORY BOARD OF THE REPUBLIC OF INDONESIA,

-1- BY THE BLESSINGS OF ALMIGHTY GOD THE CHAIRMAN OF THE ELECTION SUPERVISORY BOARD OF THE REPUBLIC OF INDONESIA, -1- REGULATION OF THE ELECTION SUPERVISORY BOARD OF THE REPUBLIC OF INDONESIA NUMBER 2 OF 2015 ON AMENDMENT TO THE REGULATION OF THE ELECTION SUPERVISORY BOARD OF THE REPUBLIC OF INDONESIA NUMBER 11 OF

More information

INDONESIAN DEMOCRACY: TRANSITION TO CONSOLIDATION. R. William Liddle The Ohio State University Saiful Mujani Lembaga Survei Indonesia

INDONESIAN DEMOCRACY: TRANSITION TO CONSOLIDATION. R. William Liddle The Ohio State University Saiful Mujani Lembaga Survei Indonesia INDONESIAN DEMOCRACY: TRANSITION TO CONSOLIDATION R. William Liddle The Ohio State University Saiful Mujani Lembaga Survei Indonesia TRANSITION: 1998-2004 FOUR LINZ AND STEPAN REQUIREMENTS: AGREEMENT ABOUT

More information

Inequality in Indonesia: Trends, drivers, policies

Inequality in Indonesia: Trends, drivers, policies Inequality in Indonesia: Trends, drivers, policies Taufik Indrakesuma & Bambang Suharnoko Sjahrir World Bank Presented at ILO Country Level Consultation Hotel Borobudur, Jakarta 24 February 2015 Indonesia

More information

political budget cycles

political budget cycles P000346 Theoretical and empirical research on is surveyed and discussed. Significant are seen to be primarily a phenomenon of the first elections after the transition to a democratic electoral system.

More information

This document is downloaded from DR-NTU, Nanyang Technological University Library, Singapore.

This document is downloaded from DR-NTU, Nanyang Technological University Library, Singapore. This document is downloaded from DR-NTU, Nanyang Technological University Library, Singapore. Title Megawati's re-election in 2004 not a sure bet Author(s) Irman G. Lanti Citation Date 2002 URL http://hdl.handle.net/10220/3948

More information

Indonesia: Middle Income Country in Transition

Indonesia: Middle Income Country in Transition Indonesia: Middle Income Country in Transition A Special Open Forum and Lunch with Sri Mulyani Indrawati Managing Director, World Bank Former Minister of Finance, Republic of Indonesia February 29, 2012

More information

Campaign Spending and Political Outcomes in Lombardy

Campaign Spending and Political Outcomes in Lombardy Campaign Spending and Political Outcomes in Lombardy Piergiorgio M. Carapella Università Cattolica del Sacro Cuore Preliminary Draft The question of how financing can affect politics has found great interest

More information

Voting Behavior in Indonesia from 1999 to 2014

Voting Behavior in Indonesia from 1999 to 2014 INSTITUTE OF DEVELOPING ECONOMIES IDE Discussion Papers are preliminary materials circulated to stimulate discussions and critical comments IDE DISCUSSION PAPER No. 512 Voting Behavior in Indonesia from

More information

Unit 1 Introduction to Comparative Politics Test Multiple Choice 2 pts each

Unit 1 Introduction to Comparative Politics Test Multiple Choice 2 pts each Unit 1 Introduction to Comparative Politics Test Multiple Choice 2 pts each 1. Which of the following is NOT considered to be an aspect of globalization? A. Increased speed and magnitude of cross-border

More information

Publicizing malfeasance:

Publicizing malfeasance: Publicizing malfeasance: When media facilitates electoral accountability in Mexico Horacio Larreguy, John Marshall and James Snyder Harvard University May 1, 2015 Introduction Elections are key for political

More information

Table A.2 reports the complete set of estimates of equation (1). We distinguish between personal

Table A.2 reports the complete set of estimates of equation (1). We distinguish between personal Akay, Bargain and Zimmermann Online Appendix 40 A. Online Appendix A.1. Descriptive Statistics Figure A.1 about here Table A.1 about here A.2. Detailed SWB Estimates Table A.2 reports the complete set

More information

Corruption, Political Instability and Firm-Level Export Decisions. Kul Kapri 1 Rowan University. August 2018

Corruption, Political Instability and Firm-Level Export Decisions. Kul Kapri 1 Rowan University. August 2018 Corruption, Political Instability and Firm-Level Export Decisions Kul Kapri 1 Rowan University August 2018 Abstract In this paper I use South Asian firm-level data to examine whether the impact of corruption

More information

The State of Democratic Governance in Asia. The State of Indonesia Democratic Governance: A Popular Assessment

The State of Democratic Governance in Asia. The State of Indonesia Democratic Governance: A Popular Assessment An Asian Barometer Conference on The State of Democratic Governance in Asia Session III. Young Democracies in Southeast Asia The State of Democratic Governance: A Popular Assessment By Saiful Mujani Lembaga

More information

Who s Turn to Eat? The Political Economy of Roads in Kenya

Who s Turn to Eat? The Political Economy of Roads in Kenya Who s Turn to Eat? The Political Economy of Roads in Kenya Robin Burgess (LSE), Remi Jedwab (PSE/LSE), Edward Miguel (UC-Berkeley) and Ameet Morjaria (LSE) Infrastructure and Economic Development Conference

More information

Vote Buying and Clientelism

Vote Buying and Clientelism Vote Buying and Clientelism Dilip Mookherjee Boston University Lecture 18 DM (BU) Clientelism 2018 1 / 1 Clientelism and Vote-Buying: Introduction Pervasiveness of vote-buying and clientelistic machine

More information

Asian Democracy Index 2014: Dynamics in Civic Participation and the Continuing Economic Inequality in Indonesia

Asian Democracy Index 2014: Dynamics in Civic Participation and the Continuing Economic Inequality in Indonesia Asian Democracy Index 2014: Dynamics in Civic Participation and the Continuing Economic Inequality in Indonesia SRI BUDI EKO WARDANI, DIRGA ARDIANSA, ANNA MARGRET, YOLANDA PANDJAITAN Background Democracy

More information

Analysis of public opinion on Macedonia s accession to Author: Ivan Damjanovski

Analysis of public opinion on Macedonia s accession to Author: Ivan Damjanovski Analysis of public opinion on Macedonia s accession to the European Union 2014-2016 Author: Ivan Damjanovski CONCLUSIONS 3 The trends regarding support for Macedonia s EU membership are stable and follow

More information

INDONESIA INDONESIA ANNUAL PUBLIC OPINION SURVEYS 2007 REPORT

INDONESIA INDONESIA ANNUAL PUBLIC OPINION SURVEYS 2007 REPORT INDONESIA INDONESIA ANNUAL PUBLIC OPINION SURVEYS 2007 REPORT FEBRUARY 2008 This publication was produced for review by the United States Agency for International Development by Democracy International,

More information

The Electoral System and its Impact on Electoral Behaviour: Is Taiwan s Experience Unusual?

The Electoral System and its Impact on Electoral Behaviour: Is Taiwan s Experience Unusual? The Electoral System and its Impact on Electoral Behaviour: Is Taiwan s Experience Unusual? Chia-hung Tsai Election Study Center, NCCU June 21, 2014 Presented at The Ordinary and the Extraordinary in Taiwan

More information

RECRUITMENT OF CANDIDATE OF REGION HEAD BASED ON LAW NUMBER 10 OF 2016

RECRUITMENT OF CANDIDATE OF REGION HEAD BASED ON LAW NUMBER 10 OF 2016 RECRUITMENT OF CANDIDATE OF REGION HEAD BASED ON LAW NUMBER 10 OF 2016 Wiredarme, Institute of Domestic Governance (IPDN) ABSTRACT In the 1945 Constitution of 1945, Article 22E states that general elections

More information

This document is downloaded from DR-NTU, Nanyang Technological University Library, Singapore.

This document is downloaded from DR-NTU, Nanyang Technological University Library, Singapore. This document is downloaded from DR-NTU, Nanyang Technological University Library, Singapore. Title Ideology and the presidency : the forces of aliran behind Indonesia's 2004 Presidential Election. Author(s)

More information

Party Ideology and Policies

Party Ideology and Policies Party Ideology and Policies Matteo Cervellati University of Bologna Giorgio Gulino University of Bergamo March 31, 2017 Paolo Roberti University of Bologna Abstract We plan to study the relationship between

More information

PANCHAYATI RAJ AND POVERTY ALLEVIATION IN WEST BENGAL: SUMMARY OF RESEARCH FINDINGS. Pranab Bardhan and Dilip Mookherjee.

PANCHAYATI RAJ AND POVERTY ALLEVIATION IN WEST BENGAL: SUMMARY OF RESEARCH FINDINGS. Pranab Bardhan and Dilip Mookherjee. PANCHAYATI RAJ AND POVERTY ALLEVIATION IN WEST BENGAL: SUMMARY OF RESEARCH FINDINGS Pranab Bardhan and Dilip Mookherjee December 2005 The experience of West Bengal with respect to Panchayat Raj has been

More information

Incumbency Advantages in the Canadian Parliament

Incumbency Advantages in the Canadian Parliament Incumbency Advantages in the Canadian Parliament Chad Kendall Department of Economics University of British Columbia Marie Rekkas* Department of Economics Simon Fraser University mrekkas@sfu.ca 778-782-6793

More information

CAN FAIR VOTING SYSTEMS REALLY MAKE A DIFFERENCE?

CAN FAIR VOTING SYSTEMS REALLY MAKE A DIFFERENCE? CAN FAIR VOTING SYSTEMS REALLY MAKE A DIFFERENCE? Facts and figures from Arend Lijphart s landmark study: Patterns of Democracy: Government Forms and Performance in Thirty-Six Countries Prepared by: Fair

More information

Corruption, Governance, and Inequality in Indonesia Mayang Rizky, Ahmad Zuhdi, Veto Tyas, Teguh Dartanto. Forum Kajian Pembangunan 31 October 2017

Corruption, Governance, and Inequality in Indonesia Mayang Rizky, Ahmad Zuhdi, Veto Tyas, Teguh Dartanto. Forum Kajian Pembangunan 31 October 2017 Corruption, Governance, and Inequality in Indonesia Mayang Rizky, Ahmad Zuhdi, Veto Tyas, Teguh Dartanto Forum Kajian Pembangunan 31 October 2017 Outline Background Stylised Facts Empirical Evidence Preliminary

More information

The California Primary and Redistricting

The California Primary and Redistricting The California Primary and Redistricting This study analyzes what is the important impact of changes in the primary voting rules after a Congressional and Legislative Redistricting. Under a citizen s committee,

More information

AP US GOVERNMENT: CHAPER 7: POLITICAL PARTIES: ESSENTIAL TO DEMOCRACY

AP US GOVERNMENT: CHAPER 7: POLITICAL PARTIES: ESSENTIAL TO DEMOCRACY AP US GOVERNMENT: CHAPER 7: POLITICAL PARTIES: ESSENTIAL TO DEMOCRACY Before political parties, candidates were listed alphabetically, and those whose names began with the letters A to F did better than

More information

THE EMPLOYABILITY AND WELFARE OF FEMALE LABOR MIGRANTS IN INDONESIAN CITIES

THE EMPLOYABILITY AND WELFARE OF FEMALE LABOR MIGRANTS IN INDONESIAN CITIES SHASTA PRATOMO D., Regional Science Inquiry, Vol. IX, (2), 2017, pp. 109-117 109 THE EMPLOYABILITY AND WELFARE OF FEMALE LABOR MIGRANTS IN INDONESIAN CITIES Devanto SHASTA PRATOMO Senior Lecturer, Brawijaya

More information

Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation

Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation S. Roy*, Department of Economics, High Point University, High Point, NC - 27262, USA. Email: sroy@highpoint.edu Abstract We implement OLS,

More information

KEY FINDINGS: IFES INDONESIA ELECTORAL SURVEY 2010

KEY FINDINGS: IFES INDONESIA ELECTORAL SURVEY 2010 KEY FINDINGS: IFES INDONESIA ELECTORAL SURVEY 2010 September 2010 Funded by the Australian Agency for International Development (AUSAID) In August 2010, IFES contracted Polling Center of Jakarta to conduct

More information

Name: Class: Date: ID: A

Name: Class: Date: ID: A Class: Date: Chapter 5 Test Matching IDENTIFYING KEY TERMS Match each item with the correct statement below. You will not use all the terms. Some terms may be used more than once. a. coalition b. political

More information

Political Decentralization and Legitimacy: Cross-Country Analysis of the Probable Influence

Political Decentralization and Legitimacy: Cross-Country Analysis of the Probable Influence Political Decentralization and Legitimacy: Cross-Country Analysis of the Probable Influence Olga Gasparyan National Research University Higher School of Economics April 6, 2014 Key aspects of the research

More information

POLITICAL LITERACY. Unit 1

POLITICAL LITERACY. Unit 1 POLITICAL LITERACY Unit 1 STATE, NATION, REGIME State = Country (must meet 4 criteria or conditions) Permanent population Defined territory Organized government Sovereignty ultimate political authority

More information

'Wave riding' or 'Owning the issue': How do candidates determine campaign agendas?

'Wave riding' or 'Owning the issue': How do candidates determine campaign agendas? 'Wave riding' or 'Owning the issue': How do candidates determine campaign agendas? Mariya Burdina University of Colorado, Boulder Department of Economics October 5th, 008 Abstract In this paper I adress

More information

The Impact of the Interaction between Economic Growth and Democracy on Human Development: Cross-National Analysis

The Impact of the Interaction between Economic Growth and Democracy on Human Development: Cross-National Analysis Edith Cowan University Research Online ECU Publications 2012 2012 The Impact of the Interaction between Economic Growth and Democracy on Human Development: Cross-National Analysis Shrabani Saha Edith Cowan

More information

CDI Policy Papers on Political Governance

CDI Policy Papers on Political Governance CDI Policy Papers on Political Governance 2009/01 centre for democratic institutions Indonesia s 2009 Elections: The New Electoral System and the Competing Parties Stephen Sherlock www.cdi.anu.edu.au Introduction

More information

Democratic Support among Youth in Some East Asian Countries

Democratic Support among Youth in Some East Asian Countries Panel III : Paper 6 Democratic Support among Youth in Some East Asian Countries Organized by the Institute of Political Science, Academia Sinica (IPSAS) Co-sponsored by Asian Barometer Survey September

More information

An Overview Across the New Political Economy Literature. Abstract

An Overview Across the New Political Economy Literature. Abstract An Overview Across the New Political Economy Literature Luca Murrau Ministry of Economy and Finance - Rome Abstract This work presents a review of the literature on political process formation and the

More information

Rise in Populism: Economic and Social Perspectives

Rise in Populism: Economic and Social Perspectives Rise in Populism: Economic and Social Perspectives Damien Capelle Princeton University 6th March, Day of Action D. Capelle (Princeton) Rise of Populism 6th March, Day of Action 1 / 37 Table of Contents

More information

Explaining the Regional Heterogeneity of Poverty: Evidence from Decentralized Indonesia

Explaining the Regional Heterogeneity of Poverty: Evidence from Decentralized Indonesia Java WORKING PAPER Explaining the Regional Heterogeneity of Poverty: Evidence from Decentralized Indonesia Sudarno Sumarto The SMERU Research Institute and National Team for the Acceleration of Poverty

More information

Combating Corruption in Yudhoyono s Indonesia: An Insider s Perspective1

Combating Corruption in Yudhoyono s Indonesia: An Insider s Perspective1 Combating Corruption in Yudhoyono s Indonesia: An Insider s Perspective1 Denny Indrayana Faculty of Law, University of Gadjah Mada, Visiting Professor at the Melbourne Law School and Faculty of Arts -

More information

Chapter I THE CONSTITUTION

Chapter I THE CONSTITUTION Chapter I THE CONSTITUTION A. THE CONSTITUTION The legal basis of the Indonesian state is the 1945 Constitution was promulgated the day after the 17 August 1945 proclamation of independence. The Constitution

More information

Remittances and the Brain Drain: Evidence from Microdata for Sub-Saharan Africa

Remittances and the Brain Drain: Evidence from Microdata for Sub-Saharan Africa Remittances and the Brain Drain: Evidence from Microdata for Sub-Saharan Africa Julia Bredtmann 1, Fernanda Martinez Flores 1,2, and Sebastian Otten 1,2,3 1 RWI, Rheinisch-Westfälisches Institut für Wirtschaftsforschung

More information

Chapter 1. Introduction

Chapter 1. Introduction Chapter 1 Introduction 1 2 CHAPTER 1. INTRODUCTION This dissertation provides an analysis of some important consequences of multilevel governance. The concept of multilevel governance refers to the dispersion

More information

What Is A Political Party?

What Is A Political Party? What Is A Political Party? A group of office holders, candidates, activists, and voters who identify with a group label and seek to elect to public office individuals who run under that label. Consist

More information

GENDER EQUALITY IN THE LABOUR MARKET AND FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT

GENDER EQUALITY IN THE LABOUR MARKET AND FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT THE STUDENT ECONOMIC REVIEWVOL. XXIX GENDER EQUALITY IN THE LABOUR MARKET AND FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT CIÁN MC LEOD Senior Sophister With Southeast Asia attracting more foreign direct investment than

More information

Julie Lenggenhager. The "Ideal" Female Candidate

Julie Lenggenhager. The Ideal Female Candidate Julie Lenggenhager The "Ideal" Female Candidate Why are there so few women elected to positions in both gubernatorial and senatorial contests? Since the ratification of the nineteenth amendment in 1920

More information

Gerrymandering Decentralization: Political Selection of Grants Financed Local Jurisdictions Stuti Khemani Development Research Group The World Bank

Gerrymandering Decentralization: Political Selection of Grants Financed Local Jurisdictions Stuti Khemani Development Research Group The World Bank Gerrymandering Decentralization: Political Selection of Grants Financed Local Jurisdictions Stuti Khemani Development Research Group The World Bank Decentralization in Political Agency Theory Decentralization

More information

Amy Tenhouse. Incumbency Surge: Examining the 1996 Margin of Victory for U.S. House Incumbents

Amy Tenhouse. Incumbency Surge: Examining the 1996 Margin of Victory for U.S. House Incumbents Amy Tenhouse Incumbency Surge: Examining the 1996 Margin of Victory for U.S. House Incumbents In 1996, the American public reelected 357 members to the United States House of Representatives; of those

More information

Pavel Yakovlev Duquesne University. Abstract

Pavel Yakovlev Duquesne University. Abstract Ideology, Shirking, and the Incumbency Advantage in the U.S. House of Representatives Pavel Yakovlev Duquesne University Abstract This paper examines how the incumbency advantage is related to ideological

More information

SIERRA LEONE 2012 ELECTIONS PROJECT PRE-ANALYSIS PLAN: INDIVIDUAL LEVEL INTERVENTIONS

SIERRA LEONE 2012 ELECTIONS PROJECT PRE-ANALYSIS PLAN: INDIVIDUAL LEVEL INTERVENTIONS SIERRA LEONE 2012 ELECTIONS PROJECT PRE-ANALYSIS PLAN: INDIVIDUAL LEVEL INTERVENTIONS PIs: Kelly Bidwell (IPA), Katherine Casey (Stanford GSB) and Rachel Glennerster (JPAL MIT) THIS DRAFT: 15 August 2013

More information

By Any Means Necessary: Multiple Avenues of Political Cycles

By Any Means Necessary: Multiple Avenues of Political Cycles By Any Means Necessary: Multiple Avenues of Political Cycles Andrew 2014 EITM Summer Institute University of Houston June 22, 2014 Motivation Are Political Budget Cycles (PBCs) the only tool an incumbent

More information

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr Abstract. The Asian experience of poverty reduction has varied widely. Over recent decades the economies of East and Southeast Asia

More information

Chapter Four: Chamber Competitiveness, Political Polarization, and Political Parties

Chapter Four: Chamber Competitiveness, Political Polarization, and Political Parties Chapter Four: Chamber Competitiveness, Political Polarization, and Political Parties Building off of the previous chapter in this dissertation, this chapter investigates the involvement of political parties

More information

Hungary. Basic facts The development of the quality of democracy in Hungary. The overall quality of democracy

Hungary. Basic facts The development of the quality of democracy in Hungary. The overall quality of democracy Hungary Basic facts 2007 Population 10 055 780 GDP p.c. (US$) 13 713 Human development rank 43 Age of democracy in years (Polity) 17 Type of democracy Electoral system Party system Parliamentary Mixed:

More information

GOVERNMENT & POLITICS UNIT 1 GLOSSARY

GOVERNMENT & POLITICS UNIT 1 GLOSSARY NAME: GOVERNMENT & POLITICS UNIT 1 GLOSSARY TASK Over the summer holiday complete the definitions for the words for the FOUR topics AND more importantly learn these key words with their definitions! There

More information

Does Political Business Cycle exist in India? By

Does Political Business Cycle exist in India? By Does Political Business Cycle exist in India? By Ashok K Nag* Extended Abstract There exists a vast literature inquiring and modelling the nexus between politics and macroeconomic policy making. Mostly

More information

Supporting Information for Representation and Redistribution in Comparative Perspective. Tiberiu Dragu and Jonathan Rodden

Supporting Information for Representation and Redistribution in Comparative Perspective. Tiberiu Dragu and Jonathan Rodden Supporting Information for Representation and Redistribution in Comparative Perspective Tiberiu Dragu and Jonathan Rodden December 17, 2010 1 Data Below we list information regarding the source of our

More information