Why and How Do Politicians Do Risky Reforms? On the Basic Cause and Blame Avoidance Mechanisms of Welfare State Reform

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Why and How Do Politicians Do Risky Reforms? On the Basic Cause and Blame Avoidance Mechanisms of Welfare State Reform"

Transcription

1 Why and How Do Politicians Do Risky Reforms? On the Basic Cause and Blame Avoidance Mechanisms of Welfare State Reform Paper Prepared for the Workshop Blame Avoidance and Blame Management: Institutional and Policy Implications of the ECPR Joint Sessions, Granada, Spain, April 14 19, 2005 Barbara Vis and Kees van Kersbergen Department of Political Science Vrije Universiteit Amsterdam De Boelelaan 1081 NL-1081HV Amsterdam The Netherlands Tel B.Vis@fsw.vu.nl Abstract The dynamics of welfare state reform are theoretically not well understood. In this paper we ask why and how politicians do risky reforms? Drawing on prospect theory we identify the basic cause of reform: policy-makers only take risks as the outcomes of the status quo are no longer perceived as gains but as losses. Prospect theory furthermore predicts that the condition under which welfare state reform takes place, i.e. when the status quo equals a loss, is identical across countries. To find the underlying causal mechanisms of reform, we turn to the theory of blame avoidance. We assess empirically the theoretical consequences of both theories and conclude, first, that politicians do not do risky reforms unless they consider that upholding the status quo is no longer a political (electoral) option and, second, that of the many strategies available, some are especially likely to be chosen by politicians.

2 1 Introduction One of the major puzzles of contemporary welfare state research is why and how drastic or radical reforms are taking place in spite of the institutional mechanisms and political resistance that work against change. Empirically, the field is very rich with detailed single case studies, comparative projects and large-n studies that have produced a host of hypotheses on the why s and how s of welfare state reform. On a theoretical level, however, there seems to be a problem with understanding the dynamics of reform, particularly with identifying the basic cause and the necessary causal (micro-) mechanisms that explain the link between cause and effect (reform). The central question of this paper is: why and how do politicians do risky reforms? Mainstream welfare state research informs us that it is plausible to assume that welfare state reform is always politically risky, so that there must be a very strong or convincing reason why politicians will embark upon risky reforms in the first place. We propose that prospect theory, which specifically deals with choice under uncertain and risky conditions, can give us a better grounding of the basic cause of reform. For a solution to the problem of causal mechanisms, we look for inspiration in the literature on blame-management and blame avoidance that particularly focuses on how political actors try to avoid the negative repercussions of their reform measures. We try to assess the empirical relevance of our theoretical findings against comparative data on welfare states over time. The paper is structured as follows. In section 2 we shortly discuss major studies of contemporary welfare state research and identify the basic theoretical problems that contribute to the puzzle of reform. In section 3 we turn to prospect theory to find the necessary condition under which risky welfare state reforms occur. Section 4 is devoted to the theory of blame avoidance and gives us the strategies of reform. Section 5 studies the empirical bearing of the theoretical findings. Section 6 is the conclusion. 2 Puzzles in welfare state development Theories from various intellectual backgrounds in the late 1980s and (early) 1990s forcefully argued and predicted the definitive crisis and final breakdown of the welfare state. They pointed to formidable challenges such as ageing populations, sluggish economic growth, long-term unemployment, changing family structures, the transformation of life cycle patterns, the postindustrialization of labour markets, the erosion of 1

3 systems of interest intermediation and collective bargaining, the rise of new risks and needs, and international pressures (globalisation and European integration). Such challenges and pressures necessarily would bring about major structural revisions as they threatened the welfare state s viability and subsistence. However, empirical reality contradicted these theories since the welfare state continued to exist, albeit perhaps functioning at a lower level of social and economic performance. As a result, the major explanatory puzzle in the mid-1990s became the theoretically unexpected but empirically observed persistence of the major institutions of the welfare state. Paul Pierson, one of the field s leading researchers, aptly summarized the problem: Underlining the severe pressures confronting mature welfare states does not, however, imply that the expected result is a collapse or radical retrenchment of national welfare states. Major policy reform is a political process, dependent on the mobilization of political resources sufficient to overcome organized opponents and other barriers to change (Pierson 2001: 411, our emphasis). Theoretically, and in accordance with mainstream political science, institutionalist approaches provided part of the solution to this puzzle by identifying some of the crucial mechanisms that explained welfare state persistence. Another part of the solution was found in the politics of blame avoidance (Weaver 1986). Taken together, a theoretically plausible answer was formulated to the puzzle. Major policy reform was not only very difficult because of the heavy weight of policy legacies, but also politically highly risky as it adversely affected (parts of) the electorate and vested interests. Major welfare state reform efforts time and again failed because of two major pro-status quo forces: first, the broad (electoral) support for core social programmes and accordingly the political unpopularity of cutbacks; and second, the rigidity of welfare state institutions that results from path dependent development and veto points that have the capacity to obstruct reform. Paul Pierson (1996: 178) argued that frontal assaults on the welfare state carry tremendous electoral risks and that retrenchment as a political issue should not be misunderstood as the mirror image of the growth of the welfare state. Welfare expansion usually generated a popular politics of credit claiming for extending social rights and raising benefits to an increasing number of citizens (i.e. the old politics), while austerity policies tended to affront voters and networks of organized interests and therefore triggered a politics of blame avoidance (i.e. the new politics of the welfare state). In other words, the post-1945 welfare state had produced an entirely novel institutional and political context. Once welfare programmes were solidly established, they 2

4 created their own programme specific constituencies of clients and professional interests. As a consequence, the emergence of powerful groups surrounding social programs may make the welfare state less dependent on the political parties, social movements, and labor organizations that expanded social programs in the first place (Pierson 1996: 147). Specialized social programmes in the policy areas of social housing, health care, education, public assistance, social security, and labour market management developed into institutionally separated and functionally differentiated policy domains. Therefore, a general weakening of social democratic and Christian democratic parties and the trade union movement the main historical supporters of welfare state expansion was unlikely to translate into a corresponding weakening of social policy. Supported by strong popular attachments to specific policies, professional policy networks were able to muster substantial veto powers against reform efforts. Moreover, given the political salience and popularity of social policy, it was not easy to turn a political preference of dismantling the welfare state into an electorally attractive proposition. Shifting the goals from expansion to retrenchment imposed tangible losses on concentrated groups of voters in return for diffuse and uncertain gains (Pierson 1996: 145). On average, retrenchment advocates thus confront a clash between their policy preferences and their electoral ambitions (idem: 146). Other researchers (e.g. Huber and Stephens 2001) empirically corroborated the Pierson-thesis and concluded that for austerity and retrenchment (public employment in Scandinavia is the exception) class and politics matter less and less, because an institutional rather than a political logic governed the adaptation of welfare states. However, by the late 1990s, a new puzzle was emerging: if institutional sclerosis and political deadlock were indeed so powerful in precluding change, why were there nonetheless empirical instances of (sometimes substantial or even radical) welfare state restructuring? What explained the reforms that did occur in spite of the theoretically plausible predictions of log jam? Most new analyses start from the institutionalist argument, and then try to add specific mechanisms of conditions under which substantial reform is possible. So, researchers stress the role of coalition politics (Bonoli 2000), the potential and risks of concentrated political power (e.g. in France, Great Britain and Switzerland; Bonoli 2001). They look at the particular institutional configurations that determine retrenchment (Swank 2001) or the domestic institutional refraction of international pressures (Kitschelt et al. 1999).They highlight the effect of the party system, party competition 3

5 and party strategy (Levy 1999; Ross 2000; Green-Pedersen 2001; Kitschelt 2001) and point to the role of framing, discourse, policy learning and ideational leadership in overcoming electoral and institutional resistance against major policy reform (Cox 2001; Schmidt 2000; see Green-Pedersen and Haverland 2002; Van Kersbergen 2002). The current state of affairs is such that many researchers are struggling to understand the dynamics of institutional resilience and reform. Indeed, many theoretical propositions and empirical hypotheses are proposed (and even tested), but all seem to face serious problems in elaborating the necessary causal (micro-) foundation of their argument. Let us give two examples. Scharpf (2000: 116ff) explains that the large-scale comparative project that he directed with Schmidt did not succeed in finding plausible political and institutional explanations of national adjustment strategies. He points to the unsatisfactory explanatory power of existing theories and explain their own failure to provide a better alternative by arguing that the irreducible contingency of the problem-institutions-actorspolitics-policy nexus (Scharpf 2000: 117) of national reform experiences is too complex to allow for causal inferences. But part of the complexity and contingency that the Scharpf Schmidt project suffered from was theoretically self-imposed, namely by conceptualizing in the best institutionalist tradition the causal relationship between institutions (or institutional conditions) and policy and policy outcomes as inherently of an contingent character. It seems to exclude the possibility of formulating a general theory from which specific empirical hypotheses can be derived. As Scharpf (2000: 22) himself put it: even though institutional differences may provide very powerful explanations for the success or failure of national policy responses, these explanations can be formulated only with regard to specific types of challenges. Scharpf s theoretical exercise is therefore phrased in the typical wording of challenges, vulnerabilities and institutional capabilities. It gives us the general picture of what kind of economic and social challenges national welfare states are facing, how vulnerable they are to the whims of the world market and how well adjusted the national institutional arrangements are. But it gives us very little to hold on to when we want to explain, for instance, why countries similar in institutional layout and facing comparable challenges, nevertheless perform radically different in reforming their welfare arrangements (for an interesting attempt see Kuipers 2004). A capability is a disposition, but for a causal argument one needs information on the strategy with which political actors attempt to realise the potential and avoid the likely backlash of policies that aim to reform the status quo. 4

6 A second example is taken from a co-authored work of one of us. Hemerijck and Van Kersbergen (1999) attempted to identify some of the mechanisms of reform: next to patching up institutions and transposing their use, they focused on policy learning. They argued that ideas and institutions are intimately related: institutions give us ideas; ideas are embodied in institutions. Policy learning is therefore institutionally nested. The institutional context of the welfare state is complex and consists of various policy domains, namely macroeconomic policy, industrial relations, social security and labour market policy, they may be loosely or tightly coupled. These domains vary in policy content and are governed according to different institutional logics. The relative ease and success of policy learning is contingent on the structure and character of the linkages between the different policy domains. This means that in some institutional contexts paradigmatic changes in ideas and policies happen slower and are less visible than in other contexts. They then proposed to view policy learning as informed by 1) policy failures, 2) anomalies and 3) the extent to which new information and insights into the relationships of cause and effect in various policy domains generate political windows of opportunity for reform. But although they were aware that policy making is a matter of both puzzling and powering, they treated reform to a large extent as an almost exclusively policy rather than also political issue and accordingly had very little to tell about the conditions under which those responsible and accountable for reform could be successful both in a policy sense and a political sense. In other words, theories of policy learning failed to problematise the political feedback mechanisms that either preclude learning to occur in the first place or inhibit action on the basis of new failure induced insights. So, on the one hand we have a body of literature that explains the difficulty, if not impossibility, of welfare state reform by pointing to institutional resistance and electoral risks, and on the other hand we have various fragmented hypotheses from policymaking, organizational and political-economy theories that try to identify the mechanisms, conditions and strategies of welfare state reform. It seems to us that we need stronger theory that can specify much better how under conditions of a viscous institutional context and a limited room to manoeuvre political actors succeed to overcome the resistance against change. And for this we turn to other sources of inspiration, particularly prospect theory and the literature that deals with blame-management and blame avoidance, in order to understand better the mechanisms that affect the political management of hazardous welfare state reforms. 5

7 3 Specifying the conditions of welfare state reform I: prospect theory Expected utility theory as commonly used in economics and in schools that employ economic theories such as rational choice institutionalism make predictions that do not adequately describe how people actually make choices under conditions of risk and uncertainty. More than 25 years ago, Kahneman and Tversky (1979) already offered an alternative, prospect theory, which was meant to provide a better account of choice under risk. As Levy (2003: 215) aptly summarized: Prospect theory deviates from expected-utility theory by positing that the way people frame a problem around a reference point has a critical influence on their choices, and that people tend to overweight losses with respect to comparable gains, engage in risk-averse behavior with respect to gains and risk-acceptant behavior with respect to losses, and respond to probabilities in a non-linear manner. In Political Science, prospect theory has been mainly applied in the field of International Relations (and occasionally in Comparative Politics) (see Quattrone and Tversky 2000; special issue Political Psychology 2004, issues 2 and 3), but precisely because of its stress on choice under conditions of risk and uncertainty we expect prospect theory to be particularly relevant for improving our theoretical understanding of the choices that politicians make when trying to reform welfare state programmes. There are a number of reasons why in the face of risk decision-making does not involve a rational deliberation over so-called end-states (as in expected utility theory), but rather a choice between gambles (i.e. prospects). First, there is the certainty effect, which means that people overweight outcomes that are considered certain, relative to outcomes which are merely probable (Kahneman and Tversky 1979: 265). If there is a chance of 50 per cent that one can win 300 and certainty that one wins 75, expected utility theory predicts that people choose the first option (expected utility of option 1 = 0.5 * * 0 = 150, which is higher than the expected utility of option 2 = 1.0 * 75 = 75). However, experiments show that a theoretically unexpected but statistically significant high number of people choose the second option. Second, there is the reflection effect, which suggests that the preference order in the negative domain is the exact mirror (hence the term reflection ) of the preference order in the positive domain. This implies that how choices are framed matters for how preferences are ordered. Framing is ( ) the process by which a communication source constructs and defines a social or political issue for its audience (Nelson et al. 1997: 221). For example, when people are faced with the fact that there is 10 per 6

8 cent unemployment, they probably are ready to accept tough policy measures to fight unemployment. However, when this fact is reformulated in positive terms, namely that employment is at 90 per cent, they probably are less inclined to accept harsh measures to increase further the level of employment. In other words, framing the same fact differently reverses preferences. Finally, there is the isolation effect, which tells us that ( ) to simplify a choice between alternatives, people often disregard components that the alternatives share, and focus on the components that distinguish them (Kahneman and Tversky 1979: 271). Hence, voters disregard those elements in the manifestos of political parties that they have in common (e.g. retrenchment of health care) and focus on the distinguishing aspects of the programme. This implies that voters do not consider political alternatives as a whole (i.e. a party electoral manifesto), but focus on a comparison of political differences. A vote for a party manifesto, therefore, cannot be taken as a contribution to the mandate of that party. Given these psychological processes, prospect theory states that there are two phases in the choice process: an editing phase and an evaluation phase. During the editing phase, the decision is simplified by means of all kind of editing operations like coding in gains and losses, established against some neutral reference point. In the evaluation phase, a choice is made between the prospects. These are just the basics of prospect theory: the theory is more complex (complexity that we do not need for our purposes) and surely more complex than expected utility theory. The added value is, of course, that prospect theory better reflects how choices are made. Prospect theory namely argues that policy-makers avoid risks as long as the outcomes of the status quo are perceived as gains, i.e. as still acceptable or tolerable. Paraphrasing Berejekian (1997: 793), the theory yields two predictions. First, governments will opt for the certainty of the status quo, when they view the status quo as a gain (their position of power) and are confronted with a choice between a) the status quo (no reform) and b) some gamble (reform) with both a positive expected value (e.g. electoral gain) and some smaller risk of loss (electoral punishment smaller than the expected gain). Second, governments will opt for the gamble, when they view the status quo as a loss and are confronted with a choice between a) the status quo (no reform) and b) some gamble (reform) with both an expected value of further loss (further electoral loss) and some smaller prospect for improvement (an electoral reward smaller than the expected loss). 7

9 Hence, a corollary of this reasoning is that governments will only embark upon drastic welfare state reforms with risky electoral repercussions ( gamble ) if the status quo is considered a loss. Prospect theory therefore gives us the necessary condition under which welfare state reform can occur, namely that governments view the status quo as a loss. In contrast to mainstream welfare state theory that holds that welfare state reform varies according to the different institutional logics of welfare state regimes (liberal, social democratic, conservative), prospect theory predicts that reform takes place under similar conditions (status quo equals a loss) and therefore applies to all welfare states irrespective of their regime-type. Paraphrasing Berejekian (1997: 789) governments in a gains frame pursue absolute gains and are unwilling to engage in risky reform efforts, while governments in a losses frame pursue relative gains and are more willing to accept the risks of reform. This theory, then, gives us an explanation for the fact that governments embark upon risky reforms at all, that is for the empirical fact for which institutional approaches and especially rational choice institutionalism that employs expected utility theory have no account. Stated differently, prospect theory gives us the basic cause of hazardous reforms. However, the theory tells us little about a) the causal mechanisms (except inductivist psychological findings of laboratory experiments) that connect cause (the losses frame) and effect (reform) and b) other possible conditions that enable or restrain action (e.g. institutions), c) problems of choice at the aggregate rather then the individual level. We hope to find clues for solving these problems in what is rapidly becoming a theory of blame avoidance. 4 Specifying the conditions of welfare state reform II: the theory of blame avoidance Irrespective of whether or not policymakers find themselves in a losses frame, for their decisions they can be influenced by different and mutually exclusive kinds of motivations: 1) credit claiming (assuming vote seeking), 2) good policy (assuming policy seeking) and 3) blame avoidance (assuming vote seeking) (Weaver 1986: 372). Which motivation or strategy is chosen, is affected by the structure of party competition. Weaver (1986: 378) argues that the number of parties or candidates competing for votes ( ) may influence whether a party stresses credit-claiming or blame avoiding in its electoral appeals. In a two-party system ( ), the best strategy is probably to take ambiguous stands and duck divisive issues (i.e., to minimize blame) to avoid offending 8

10 marginal voters. In a multi-party system, on the other hand, some parties may be better off by taking pointed, controversial positions (credit-claiming) in order to build a distinctive political base and avoid becoming lost in a crowded field. However, we think that in certain contexts, especially those in which established social rights are object of reform, the motivation of blame avoidance seems most relevant to focus on. Policymakers are here most likely to search for blame avoidance strategies because it promises to attain the goal that they have been forced to set (reform), whilst avoiding the well-known risk of blame that accompanies such hazardous reform. As Weaver (1986: 372) argued: ( ) when push comes to shove, most officeholders seek above all not to maximize the credit they receive but to minimize blame. But can blame avoidance strategies in this sense be politically (rather than policy) effective? There are arguments that support a positive answer. The idea of negativity effects in political behaviour is important here. A negativity effect refers to the greater weight given to negative information relative to equally extreme and equally likely positive information ( ) (Lau 1985: 119). There appears to be a rising negativity bias both among voters and politicians (Hood 2002: 20). In addition, Pierson (2001), among others, has correctly argued that the benefits of reforms are widely dispersed electorally, while the losses tend to be concentrated among voter groups. We take this to imply that voters who are negatively affected by welfare state reforms remember such reforms much better and longer than reforms that affect them positively. Or, as Weaver (1988: 21) states, voters ( ) are more sensitive to what has been done to them than what has been done for them (italics in original). So, how to do things to voters and get away with it? Many empirical studies in one way or another refer to strategies of blame avoidance as a solution to policymaking under uncertain and risky conditions. Hood (2002), focussing on the link between the risk game and the blame game, discusses three strategies of blame management. First, there are presentational strategies or impression management, that is selecting arguments to minimize or avoid blame, for example in choosing between excuses intended to mitigate blame and justifications designed to turn blame into credit (Hood 2002: 16). Second, there are policy or substantive strategies, i.e. the selection of policy positions to minimize or avoid blame, for example choosing between policies that support risk creators as against those that support risk victims (idem). Third, through agency strategies, that is the selection of institutional arrangements to minimize or avoid blame, for example in choosing between direct control and delegation (idem: 17). Hood s point is that ( ) agency strate- 9

11 gies ( ) if successful ( ) eliminate the need for presentational or policy bias to achieve blame avoidance ( ) (2002: 17). In our interpretation, however, these strategies are not so much mutually exclusive, but rather hierarchically nested. That is to say, policymakers are most likely to try, first, to choose an institutional arrangement that minimises or avoids blame, second, if this fails, to alter policy positions, and finally, to present and phrase policies in a manner which minimises or avoids blame. This means that we do need a more detailed understanding of blame management or blame avoidance strategies, because empirically they may very well overlap. The theory of blame avoidance, which can be traced back to Downs (1957) theory of electoral competition, has had a clear focus on explaining why governments have a strong incentive to refrain from pursuing policies that are unpopular among voters. It was, in fact, one of the theoretical underpinnings of the welfare state resilience thesis. Interest group theory at the same time had been informing us that in addition to resisting to vetoing reforms, strong organized interests also reinforce the blame avoidance incentives of governments because trade unions and elderly lobbies are able to mobilize large segments of voters in elections (Hering 2003: 4, referring to Weaver 1986: 394 5). Indeed and interestingly, the resistance-against-change theorem was definitively one of the specific consequences of the politics of blame avoidance that Weaver (1986: 394) pointed to: Blame avoidance ( ) helps to explain why policies are so difficult to change, even if they fail. If policymakers and their constituents perceived costs and benefits symmetrically, they would be willing to change policies quite freely, at least as long as the new policies promised at least as high a surplus of concentrated benefits over costs as the status quo. But substantial vested interests often develop around programmes. Because costs and benefits are perceived asymmetrically, policymakers fear that new policies will not win them as much support as dismantling the old ones will lose. However, we think that of the strategies that Weaver identified (see table 1) to explain why policy change is so difficult, most of them may very well be strategies that can be employed to simplify or facilitate reform. 10

12 Table 1 Strategy Blame avoiding strategies Approach to avoiding blame (1) Agenda limitation (2) Redefine the issue (3) Throw good money after Bad (4) Pass the buck (5) Find a scapegoat (6) Jump on the bandwagon Prevent blame generating by keeping potentially costly choices from being considered Prevent blame generating by developing new policy options which diffuse or obfuscate losses Prevent or delay blame generating by providing resources to prevent constituencies from suffering losses Deflect blame by forcing others to make politically costly choices Deflect blame by blaming others Deflect blame by supporting politically popular alternative (7) Diffuse blame by spreading it among as many policymakers as possible Circle the wagons (8) Prevent blame generation by keeping credit claiming opportunities that conflict with policy preferences from being considered Stop me before I kill again Source: Weaver (1986: 385), table 3. Strategy 1, limit the agenda, basically tries to avoid that the very issue of a hazardous reform is politicized and therefore is not an option if reform is considered necessary. Strategy 2, redefine the issue, is primarily an attempt to spread the costs of reform and can just as likely be used as a reform strategy. Strategy 3, throw good money after bad, is basically a strategy that tries to soften the pain of reforms by offering a small compensation and can also be a strategy to help reform. Strategy 4, pass the buck, is delegation of the blame and includes also automatic government (see Weaver 1988). This, again, is a strategy for implementing reform that may help to minimise negative consequences. Strategy 5, find a scapegoat, is shifting the responsibility for reform measures. As indicated in the context of prospect theory, the European Union and especially the Economic and Monetary Union (EMU) are probably the best examples of scapegoats in welfare state reforms. Strategy 6, jump on the bandwagon, is swinging opinion towards the direction of the winning group. In the context of welfare state reform, this seems a strategy that either is not likely to occur or reinforces the difficulty of reform. Strategy 7, circle the wagons, is used when blame is inevitable and aims to share as much blame as possible, for instance by including the opposition in a reform package that is highly unpopular. Finally, Weaver s strategy 8, stop me before I kill again, is restricting the discretion over the choice. The EU s stability and growth pact 11

13 and the introduction of an independent European Central Bank are examples of such a strategy. This strategy is also a reform reinforcer. In sum, most blame avoidance strategies that were originally thought primarily to work against reform, can, in fact, be employed by politicians to ease the reform efforts that they undertake. 5 Assessing the empirical relevance of the theoretical findings We have now established that prospect theory gives us the reason why hazardous reforms take place and that the theory of blame avoidance provides us with a list of strategies with which politicians can deflect the negative feedback of such reforms. Next, we search for ways to find out whether these theoretical results have empirical plausibility. We start with prospect theory. On the basis of the three psychological biases ( certainty effect, isolation effect, and reflection effect ), we deduced that politicians introduce drastic reforms only when the status quo is considered a loss. Is it possible to assess the empirical relevance of this supposition? Obviously, this would involve a careful conceptual discussion of what exactly is a drastic reform, a painstaking operationalization of the concept and devising a clever way of measuring it. This is still a highly controversial issue among welfare state researchers and is also known as the dependent variable problem (for an overview see e.g. Green-Pedersen 2004). In addition, it would include a comparable exercise for the main independent variable, namely risky electoral repercussions in order to be able to establish if the status quo can be considered a loss. Budget cuts that reverse the trend towards increasing public debt and budgetary deficits can be considered drastic reforms because of the expansionary political and institutional logic normally present in public finances. Moreover, such cuts can also be considered as very risky, because of the high visibility and salience of fiscal policy, not only during phases of government formation, but also during the yearly political presentation of the government s plans. Another argument is that the criteria for entry into the EMU have forced the governments of EU member states (and other states whose currency is strongly linked to the Euro) to follow more radical adjustment policies than those that seemed electorally safe from the politician s short term perspective. In the context of national social policy changes, the EU already functioned as a whipping-boy for the politics of blame 12

14 avoidance in some countries (Anderson 1995), but increasingly became a major point of reference for the Thatcherite TINA (there-is-no-alternative) arguments that underpinned proposals of more radical shifts in national policy. National governments that tried to meet the harsh criteria of Maastricht, in our view, automatically ended up in a losses status quo. Therefore, budgetary cuts that reverse the trend towards increasing public debt and budget deficits indicate the losses context. Table 2a Budget deficits , selected countries Austria Belgium Denmark Finland France Germany Greece Ireland Italy Netherlands Portugal Spain Sweden Great Britain Notes: A negative entry means that there is a deficit; a positive entry means that there is a surplus; changes are absolute changes. Source: To be added. If we look at Table 2a, we observe that of the 14 countries for which we had data, 9 were still increasing their budget deficits between 1985 and These 9 countries, however, clearly reversed this trend as a result of which every single country was reducing its budget deficit measured over the period This policy reversal can be taken to indicate that there is indeed a losses frame and that there is therefore some empirical confirmation for the basic cause of risky welfare state reform. 13

15 Table 2b Public debt , selected countries Australia Austria Belgium Canada Denmark Finland France Germany Greece a Ireland a Italy a Netherlands Norway Portugal Spain Sweden a Great Britain United States a Notes: Debt is general government gross public debt as a percentage of nominal gross domestic product; changes are absolute changes. Sources: Data for : Comparative Political Data Set [OECD Economic Outlook 75, 2004]; data for 2002: Schuknecht (2002). Table 2b summarizes the development of the public debt and basically we find the same pattern as in table 2a. Of the 14 countries for which we had data for all the years, 1o were still increasing their debt between 1985 and All countries, except Germany, however, clearly reversed this trend as a result of which 9 countries were reducing their public debt measured over the period Also this policy reversal can be taken to indicate that there is indeed a losses frame and that there is therefore some empirical confirmation for the basic cause of risky welfare state reform. As with respect to prospect theory, we need to ask if it is at all possible to assess the empirical relevance of the mechanisms of blame avoidance that may help to explain how the need to reform (in the context of the losses frame) is successfully translated. Let us, first, briefly discuss the empirical applicability of the reform concept. Pierson (2001) criticized mainstream welfare state theory for not capturing fully the multi-dimensionality of reform. He therefore reconceptualized reform as having three dimensions. First, cost containment is the attempt to keep balanced budgets through 14

16 austerity policies, including deficit reduction and tax moderation. Cost containment is a feature of all welfare states. Second, recalibration consists of reforms which seek to make contemporary welfare states more consistent with contemporary goals and demands for social provision (Pierson 2001: 425). This is an unlikely route for blame avoidance, because it belongs more to the expansion phase of the welfare state and is therefore more suitable for credit claiming. Levy (1999) has argued that some policies can turn vices into virtues. However, this is an option that can only occur if there are very (regime) specific vices that already lead to serious blaming, such as the disability scheme in the Netherlands (see Kuipers 2004). Finally, recommodification is the attempt to restrict the alternatives to participation in the labour market, either by tightening eligibility or cutting benefits (Pierson 2001: 422). Pierson (2001) argued that each regime (social democratic, liberal or conservative) is characterized by its own specific new politics of welfare state reform. So, in the liberal regime voters are less likely to be attached to the welfare state than in the conservative or social democratic models. Since the level of decommodification is fairly low already here, further restricting the alternatives to participation in the labour market (i.e. recommodification) is the politically most feasible feature of welfare state reform. In the social democratic welfare regime, voters are highly attached to, and dependent on, the welfare state. Recommodification is not so much on the political agenda of reform, but if only because of the sheer size of the public sector cost containment is. The conservative regime is probably the most ill-adapted model of the three worlds of welfare capitalism, as a result of which recalibration and cost containment are the two dimensions of reform that dominate. Here the issues are how to stimulate job growth in the underdeveloped service sector and how to contain the exploding costs of pensions, disability, and health. In contrast to Pierson, however, we think that like cost containment recommodification is a feature of all welfare reform efforts, irrespective of the regime, especially given the basic cause of reform (the losses frame) that we identified above. These are at the same time by far the most risky strategies, as a result of which the politics of blame avoidance should be most prominent here. In our empirical analysis, we therefore concentrate on recommodification and cost containment. Can we convert the expectations of blame theory to what we expect on the basis of mainstream welfare state theory? The strategy of redefining the issue, i.e. spending the costs of reform, can be recognized in recommodification policies that are presented as cost containment. Cost containment, while the demand for social expendi- 15

17 tures remains the same or increases, implies recommodification. We may assume that no government will ever defend reform policies of popular social programmes as explicitly aiming at reducing the level of protection from the market, that is as explicitly recommodifying. Instead, harsh retrenchment policies will always be portrayed as necessary efficiency measures (for impopular social programmes the opposite would apply). Although this is not uncontroversial, we conceptualise recommodification as the opposite of decommodification (cf. Bonoli 1998) and define the latter as ( ) a citizen s relative independence from pure market forces (Esping-Andersen 2000: 353). To measure the extent of decommodification, Esping-Andersen s (1990) index is widely used. This index incorporates 1) benefit replacement rates, 2) the number of qualifying weeks; 3) the numbers of waiting days; 4) the duration of the benefit; and 5) the coverage of the benefit for unemployment insurance, sick pay and pensions. The higher the score on this index, the higher the extent of decommodification. We therefore take that a lowering of this score through time indicates recommodification. Table 3 summarizes the development of the decommodification index between 1980 and On average, the changes in the three welfare regimes are rather small. 1 In the conservative regime, the extent of decommodification increased somewhat between 1980 and 1985 and then stabilised. In the social democratic regime, we see an increase between 1980 and 1985 as well, but here there is some recommodification between 1985 and 1990 and stabilisation from 1990 onwards. In the liberal regime, the extent of decommodification is stable until 1990, then converts into recommodification between 1990 and 1995 and decommodification between 1995 and To make the averages as adequate as possible, we have not included Italy and Switzerland in any of the regimes but present their data separately. Whilst Italy is often placed in the conservative welfare regime, it has been convincingly argued that the Southern European welfare states have their own logic and should therefore be seen as a separate welfare regime (Ferrera et al. 2000). Unfortunately, Scruggs (2004) does not provide data for the other Southern European countries (Spain, Portugal, Greece) so we cannot include this regime. Switzerland is often placed in the conservative regime and, equally often, in the liberal regime. The former is probably correct for the period 1980 early 1990s; the latter probably for the early 1990s onwards. 16

18 Table 3 Decommodification index , selected countries Liberal Welfare Regime Australia Canada Ireland New Zealand Gr. Britain US Average Conservative Welfare Regime Austria Belgium France Germany Netherlands Average Social Democratic Welfare Regime Denmark Finland Norway Sweden Average Italy Switzerland Notes: See for the construction of the decommodification index Esping-Andersen (1990) and Scruggs and Allan (2004). Source: Scruggs (2004); averages own calculations. This picture of rather unspectacular changes transforms in a mixed picture if we focus on the whole time series instead of on snapshots through time, and on individual countries instead of on welfare regimes averages. 2 What we can identify on the basis of these time series is, first, a group of countries (Austria, Belgium, and Denmark), where the increase of decommodification levels off over time, but where recommodification is not a feature of reform. Second, there is another group (Australia, New Zealand, Sweden, Switzerland) that is clearly characterised by recommodification. Third, the data show that there is a group of countries where either nothing changes or 17

19 the level of decommodification keeps increasing (Canada, Finland, Germany, Ireland, Netherlands, United Kingdom). The final group, then, consists of the countries that have very peculiar structural breaks in their development (France, Italy, Norway, United States). As stated, the decommodification index has different components so that a variety of reform measures can result in a change in the index. Most of the components changes are fairly transparent (replacement rates, waiting days, benefit duration, and benefit coverage) and are thus not likely candidates for blame avoidance. One, however, is much more non-transparent (qualifying weeks) and is thus a likely candidate for blame avoidance. The recently publicised Welfare State Entitlement Data Set (Scruggs 2004) presents data on the different components of the decommodification index, allowing us to see what caused the trend towards recommodification and the structural breaks identified above. Lets us begin with the countries displaying recommodification. In Australia, the only component that declines substantially is pension coverage, i.e. the portion of those above official retirement age who receive a public pension (Scruggs 2004). In New Zealand, the replacement rates for sick pay and unemployment insurance (UI) were increased between 1981 and 1986 (potentially indicating decommodification) and were then lowered (potentially indicating recommodification); the waiting days for UI were doubled in 1982 and subsequently remained the same; the waiting days for sick pay, finally, were doubled in In Sweden, a lot of changes took place but the steadily lowering of the replacement rates of UI, sick pay and pensions were probably critical. Also in Switzerland, there is a large number of changes of which the reduced sick pay coverage, measured as the percentage of the labour force with sick pay insurance (Scruggs 2004), is the most substantial. But also the increase in UI waiting days and the increased number of qualifying weeks for pensions are important here. In sum, only in Switzerland, some of the change in the decommodification index is caused by the invisible measure, qualifying weeks. Is this different in the countries that display peculiar structural breaks? The structural break in France s decommodification occurs in 1982, when the level suddenly increases substantially and remains stable until around Then another break occurs and decommodification decreases to a lower level than in the pre 1982 period. In 1982 it is the qualifying weeks for UI 2 Figures on which the statements that follow are based are available upon request from the authors. 18

20 that increase, but this recommodifying trend is offset by increased UI duration. The break in 1996 is caused by increasing UI waiting days and a lower sick pay duration. The Italian decommodification level is very low until After the break, there is a sudden increase and then stabilization between 1983 and 2000, when a further increase commences. Higher UI replacement rates cause the index to increase and offset these benefits extra waiting days. It is the withdrawal of these waiting days that caused the index s additional increase in The Norwegian decommodification index displays an increasing trend until the sudden decrease in 1990 that continues to the again sudden increase in It is difficult to precisely identify the causes of these changes because the different components show little alterations. However, the higher score in 1998 can be attributed to an extension of the UI duration. The American decommodification pattern shows a structural break in 1990, namely a decrease in the index. Like the Norwegian index, also here it is difficult to distinguish what instigated the structural rupture. Probably the lowered UI replacement rates and the lowered coverage of this benefit are the primary suspects. All in all, again, the only non-transparent measure, the qualifying weeks, are not important in the reforms. The strategy of throwing good money after bad, i.e. softening the pain of reforms, is difficult to translate into the terms of mainstream welfare state theory and also hard to operationalise and measure for quantitative comparison. However, we know that in many countries various cost containment measures were introduced varying from tightening the eligibility criteria and lowering the benefit replacement rates to the abolishment of whole social programmes that were subsequently followed by special measures to compensate partly the disadvantageous impact on income equality and poverty. However, cross-national studies of aggregate data and of survey data on income (the Luxembourg Income Study) indicate that generally speaking both incomes inequality and poverty have increased (see e.g. Huber and Stephens 2001: chapters 6 and 7). One may infer from this that most probably throwing good money after bad does not fully compensate retrenchment, but is used as a political strategy for its high symbolic positive potential. Pass the buck, i.e. delegation of the blame and/or automatic government, is another important strategy in welfare state reform. Retrenchment policies very often take the form of national framework laws that specify general objectives for lower level government to attain. To redefine competencies and delegate them to lower levels of gov- 19

THE CZECH REPUBLIC AND THE EURO. Policy paper Europeum European Policy Forum May 2002

THE CZECH REPUBLIC AND THE EURO. Policy paper Europeum European Policy Forum May 2002 THE CZECH REPUBLIC AND THE EURO Policy paper 1. Introduction: Czech Republic and Euro The analysis of the accession of the Czech Republic to the Eurozone (EMU) will deal above all with two closely interconnected

More information

The Politics of Fiscal Austerity: Can Democracies Act With Foresight? Paul Posner George Mason University

The Politics of Fiscal Austerity: Can Democracies Act With Foresight? Paul Posner George Mason University The Politics of Fiscal Austerity: Can Democracies Act With Foresight? Paul Posner George Mason University Fiscal Crisis Affects Nations Differently Group 1: Fiscal foresight includes Australia, Canada,

More information

Comparing Welfare States

Comparing Welfare States Comparing Welfare States Comparative-Historical Methods Patrick Emmenegger (University of St.Gallen) ESPAnet doctoral workshop Mannheim, July 4-6, 2013 Comparative-Historical Analysis What have Gøsta Esping-Andersen,

More information

Main findings of the joint EC/OECD seminar on Naturalisation and the Socio-economic Integration of Immigrants and their Children

Main findings of the joint EC/OECD seminar on Naturalisation and the Socio-economic Integration of Immigrants and their Children MAIN FINDINGS 15 Main findings of the joint EC/OECD seminar on Naturalisation and the Socio-economic Integration of Immigrants and their Children Introduction Thomas Liebig, OECD Main findings of the joint

More information

The Politics of Egalitarian Capitalism; Rethinking the Trade-off between Equality and Efficiency

The Politics of Egalitarian Capitalism; Rethinking the Trade-off between Equality and Efficiency The Politics of Egalitarian Capitalism; Rethinking the Trade-off between Equality and Efficiency Week 3 Aidan Regan Democratic politics is about distributive conflict tempered by a common interest in economic

More information

RESEARCH NOTE The effect of public opinion on social policy generosity

RESEARCH NOTE The effect of public opinion on social policy generosity Socio-Economic Review (2009) 7, 727 740 Advance Access publication June 28, 2009 doi:10.1093/ser/mwp014 RESEARCH NOTE The effect of public opinion on social policy generosity Lane Kenworthy * Department

More information

LABOUR-MARKET INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS IN OECD-COUNTRIES: WHAT EXPLANATIONS FIT THE DATA?

LABOUR-MARKET INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS IN OECD-COUNTRIES: WHAT EXPLANATIONS FIT THE DATA? LABOUR-MARKET INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS IN OECD-COUNTRIES: WHAT EXPLANATIONS FIT THE DATA? By Andreas Bergh (PhD) Associate Professor in Economics at Lund University and the Research Institute of Industrial

More information

The Political Economy of Health Inequalities

The Political Economy of Health Inequalities The Political Economy of Health Inequalities Dennis Raphael, PhD School of Health Policy and Management, York University, Toronto, Canada Presentation at the Conference Social Policy and Health Inequalities:

More information

IMF research links declining labour share to weakened worker bargaining power. ACTU Economic Briefing Note, August 2018

IMF research links declining labour share to weakened worker bargaining power. ACTU Economic Briefing Note, August 2018 IMF research links declining labour share to weakened worker bargaining power ACTU Economic Briefing Note, August 2018 Authorised by S. McManus, ACTU, 365 Queen St, Melbourne 3000. ACTU D No. 172/2018

More information

Resistance to Women s Political Leadership: Problems and Advocated Solutions

Resistance to Women s Political Leadership: Problems and Advocated Solutions By Catherine M. Watuka Executive Director Women United for Social, Economic & Total Empowerment Nairobi, Kenya. Resistance to Women s Political Leadership: Problems and Advocated Solutions Abstract The

More information

Address given by Lars Heikensten on the euro (Stockholm, 4 September 2003)

Address given by Lars Heikensten on the euro (Stockholm, 4 September 2003) Address given by Lars Heikensten on the euro (Stockholm, 4 September 2003) Caption: On 4 September 2003, ten days after the national referendum on the adoption of the single currency, Lars Heikensten,

More information

Bachelorproject 2 The Complexity of Compliance: Why do member states fail to comply with EU directives?

Bachelorproject 2 The Complexity of Compliance: Why do member states fail to comply with EU directives? Bachelorproject 2 The Complexity of Compliance: Why do member states fail to comply with EU directives? Authors: Garth Vissers & Simone Zwiers University of Utrecht, 2009 Introduction The European Union

More information

How Does Aid Support Women s Economic Empowerment?

How Does Aid Support Women s Economic Empowerment? How Does Aid Support Women s Economic Empowerment? OECD DAC NETWORK ON GENDER EQUALITY (GENDERNET) 2018 Key messages Overall bilateral aid integrating (mainstreaming) gender equality in all sectors combined

More information

A2 Economics. Enlargement Countries and the Euro. tutor2u Supporting Teachers: Inspiring Students. Economics Revision Focus: 2004

A2 Economics. Enlargement Countries and the Euro. tutor2u Supporting Teachers: Inspiring Students. Economics Revision Focus: 2004 Supporting Teachers: Inspiring Students Economics Revision Focus: 2004 A2 Economics tutor2u (www.tutor2u.net) is the leading free online resource for Economics, Business Studies, ICT and Politics. Don

More information

REFUGEES AND ASYLUM SEEKERS, THE CRISIS IN EUROPE AND THE FUTURE OF POLICY

REFUGEES AND ASYLUM SEEKERS, THE CRISIS IN EUROPE AND THE FUTURE OF POLICY REFUGEES AND ASYLUM SEEKERS, THE CRISIS IN EUROPE AND THE FUTURE OF POLICY Tim Hatton University of Essex (UK) and Australian National University International Migration Institute 13 January 2016 Forced

More information

The Mystery of Economic Growth by Elhanan Helpman. Chiara Criscuolo Centre for Economic Performance London School of Economics

The Mystery of Economic Growth by Elhanan Helpman. Chiara Criscuolo Centre for Economic Performance London School of Economics The Mystery of Economic Growth by Elhanan Helpman Chiara Criscuolo Centre for Economic Performance London School of Economics The facts Burundi, 2006 Sweden, 2006 According to Maddison, in the year 1000

More information

Industrial Relations in Europe 2010 report

Industrial Relations in Europe 2010 report MEMO/11/134 Brussels, 3 March 2011 Industrial Relations in Europe 2010 report What is the 'Industrial Relations in Europe' report? The Industrial Relations in Europe report provides an overview of major

More information

The Crisis of the European Union. Weakening of the EU Social Model

The Crisis of the European Union. Weakening of the EU Social Model The Crisis of the European Union Weakening of the EU Social Model Vincent Navarro and John Schmitt Many observers argue that recent votes unfavorable to the European Union are the result of specific factors

More information

ISS is the international Institute of Social Studies of Erasmus University Rotterdam

ISS is the international Institute of Social Studies of Erasmus University Rotterdam ISS is the international Institute of Social Studies of Erasmus University Rotterdam Changes in the European labour market and trades union (TU) responses John Cameron & Freek Schiphorst ISS -International

More information

European Parliament Eurobarometer (EB79.5) ONE YEAR TO GO UNTIL THE 2014 EUROPEAN ELECTIONS Institutional Part ANALYTICAL OVERVIEW

European Parliament Eurobarometer (EB79.5) ONE YEAR TO GO UNTIL THE 2014 EUROPEAN ELECTIONS Institutional Part ANALYTICAL OVERVIEW Directorate-General for Communication Public Opinion Monitoring Unit Brussels, 21 August 2013. European Parliament Eurobarometer (EB79.5) ONE YEAR TO GO UNTIL THE 2014 EUROPEAN ELECTIONS Institutional

More information

D2 - COLLECTION OF 28 COUNTRY PROFILES Analytical paper

D2 - COLLECTION OF 28 COUNTRY PROFILES Analytical paper D2 - COLLECTION OF 28 COUNTRY PROFILES Analytical paper Introduction The European Institute for Gender Equality (EIGE) has commissioned the Fondazione Giacomo Brodolini (FGB) to carry out the study Collection

More information

Measurement and Global Trends in Central Bank Autonomy (CBA)

Measurement and Global Trends in Central Bank Autonomy (CBA) Measurement and Global Trends in Central Bank Autonomy (CBA) Conference Central Bank Independence: Legal and Economic Issues Sponsored by the International Monetary Fund and the Central Reserve Bank of

More information

Comparative Political Economy. David Soskice Nuffield College

Comparative Political Economy. David Soskice Nuffield College Comparative Political Economy David Soskice Nuffield College Comparative Political Economy (i) Focus on nation states (ii) Complementarities between 3 systems: Variety of Capitalism (Hall & Soskice) Political

More information

Civil and Political Rights

Civil and Political Rights DESIRED OUTCOMES All people enjoy civil and political rights. Mechanisms to regulate and arbitrate people s rights in respect of each other are trustworthy. Civil and Political Rights INTRODUCTION The

More information

The evolution of turnout in European elections from 1979 to 2009

The evolution of turnout in European elections from 1979 to 2009 The evolution of turnout in European elections from 1979 to 2009 Nicola Maggini 7 April 2014 1 The European elections to be held between 22 and 25 May 2014 (depending on the country) may acquire, according

More information

Poznan July The vulnerability of the European Elite System under a prolonged crisis

Poznan July The vulnerability of the European Elite System under a prolonged crisis Very Very Preliminary Draft IPSA 24 th World Congress of Political Science Poznan 23-28 July 2016 The vulnerability of the European Elite System under a prolonged crisis Maurizio Cotta (CIRCaP- University

More information

Voter Turnout, Income Inequality, and Redistribution. Henning Finseraas PhD student Norwegian Social Research

Voter Turnout, Income Inequality, and Redistribution. Henning Finseraas PhD student Norwegian Social Research Voter Turnout, Income Inequality, and Redistribution Henning Finseraas PhD student Norwegian Social Research hfi@nova.no Introduction Motivation Robin Hood paradox No robust effect of voter turnout on

More information

Welfare state reform and political allegiance Kees van Kersbergen

Welfare state reform and political allegiance Kees van Kersbergen This article was downloaded by: [Vrije Universiteit, Library] On: 1 June 2011 Access details: Access Details: [subscription number 907218003] Publisher Routledge Informa Ltd Registered in England and Wales

More information

EMU, Switzerland? Marie-Christine Luijckx and Luke Threinen Public Policy 542 April 10, 2006

EMU, Switzerland? Marie-Christine Luijckx and Luke Threinen Public Policy 542 April 10, 2006 EMU, Switzerland? Marie-Christine Luijckx and Luke Threinen Public Policy 542 April 10, 2006 Introduction While Switzerland is the EU s closest geographic, cultural, and economic ally, it is not a member

More information

Upgrading workers skills and competencies: policy strategies

Upgrading workers skills and competencies: policy strategies Federation of Greek Industries Greek General Confederation of Labour CONFERENCE LIFELONG DEVELOPMENT OF COMPETENCES AND QUALIFICATIONS OF THE WORKFORCE; ROLES AND RESPONSIBILITIES Athens 23-24 24 May 2003

More information

Networks and Innovation: Accounting for Structural and Institutional Sources of Recombination in Brokerage Triads

Networks and Innovation: Accounting for Structural and Institutional Sources of Recombination in Brokerage Triads 1 Online Appendix for Networks and Innovation: Accounting for Structural and Institutional Sources of Recombination in Brokerage Triads Sarath Balachandran Exequiel Hernandez This appendix presents a descriptive

More information

David Istance TRENDS SHAPING EDUCATION VIENNA, 11 TH DECEMBER Schooling for Tomorrow & Innovative Learning Environments, OECD/CERI

David Istance TRENDS SHAPING EDUCATION VIENNA, 11 TH DECEMBER Schooling for Tomorrow & Innovative Learning Environments, OECD/CERI TRENDS SHAPING EDUCATION DEVELOPMENTS, EXAMPLES, QUESTIONS VIENNA, 11 TH DECEMBER 2008 David Istance Schooling for Tomorrow & Innovative Learning Environments, OECD/CERI CERI celebrates its 40 th anniversary

More information

Gender, age and migration in official statistics The availability and the explanatory power of official data on older BME women

Gender, age and migration in official statistics The availability and the explanatory power of official data on older BME women Age+ Conference 22-23 September 2005 Amsterdam Workshop 4: Knowledge and knowledge gaps: The AGE perspective in research and statistics Paper by Mone Spindler: Gender, age and migration in official statistics

More information

THE FUNCTIONING OF THE TROIKA : MAIN MESSAGES FROM THE ETUC REPORT. Athens, March 2014

THE FUNCTIONING OF THE TROIKA : MAIN MESSAGES FROM THE ETUC REPORT. Athens, March 2014 THE FUNCTIONING OF THE TROIKA : MAIN MESSAGES FROM THE ETUC REPORT Athens, March 2014 rjanssen@etuc.org THE PICTURE THAT EMERGES. IS A PICTURE OF A COUNTRY BEING TAKEN OVER NOT A «SILENT» TAKEOVER.. BUT

More information

BUILDING RESILIENT REGIONS FOR STRONGER ECONOMIES OECD

BUILDING RESILIENT REGIONS FOR STRONGER ECONOMIES OECD o: o BUILDING RESILIENT REGIONS FOR STRONGER ECONOMIES OECD Table of Contents Acronyms and Abbreviations 11 List of TL2 Regions 13 Preface 16 Executive Summary 17 Parti Key Regional Trends and Policies

More information

The Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism in Europe

The Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism in Europe The Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism in Europe Introduction Liberal, Social Democratic and Corporatist Regimes Week 2 Aidan Regan State institutions are now preoccupied with the production and distribution

More information

The Integer Arithmetic of Legislative Dynamics

The Integer Arithmetic of Legislative Dynamics The Integer Arithmetic of Legislative Dynamics Kenneth Benoit Trinity College Dublin Michael Laver New York University July 8, 2005 Abstract Every legislature may be defined by a finite integer partition

More information

IMPLICATIONS OF WAGE BARGAINING SYSTEMS ON REGIONAL DIFFERENTIATION IN THE EUROPEAN UNION LUMINITA VOCHITA, GEORGE CIOBANU, ANDREEA CIOBANU

IMPLICATIONS OF WAGE BARGAINING SYSTEMS ON REGIONAL DIFFERENTIATION IN THE EUROPEAN UNION LUMINITA VOCHITA, GEORGE CIOBANU, ANDREEA CIOBANU IMPLICATIONS OF WAGE BARGAINING SYSTEMS ON REGIONAL DIFFERENTIATION IN THE EUROPEAN UNION LUMINITA VOCHITA, GEORGE CIOBANU, ANDREEA CIOBANU Luminita VOCHITA, Lect, Ph.D. University of Craiova George CIOBANU,

More information

Differences in National IQs behind the Eurozone Debt Crisis?

Differences in National IQs behind the Eurozone Debt Crisis? 3 Differences in National IQs behind the Eurozone Debt Crisis? Tatu Vanhanen * Department of Political Science, University of Helsinki The purpose of this article is to explore the causes of the European

More information

EUROBAROMETER 62 PUBLIC OPINION IN THE EUROPEAN UNION

EUROBAROMETER 62 PUBLIC OPINION IN THE EUROPEAN UNION Standard Eurobarometer European Commission EUROBAROMETER 62 PUBLIC OPINION IN THE EUROPEAN UNION AUTUMN 2004 NATIONAL REPORT Standard Eurobarometer 62 / Autumn 2004 TNS Opinion & Social IRELAND The survey

More information

65. Broad access to productive jobs is essential for achieving the objective of inclusive PROMOTING EMPLOYMENT AND MANAGING MIGRATION

65. Broad access to productive jobs is essential for achieving the objective of inclusive PROMOTING EMPLOYMENT AND MANAGING MIGRATION 5. PROMOTING EMPLOYMENT AND MANAGING MIGRATION 65. Broad access to productive jobs is essential for achieving the objective of inclusive growth and help Turkey converge faster to average EU and OECD income

More information

AirPlus International Travel Management Study 2015 Part 1 A comparison of global trends and costs in business travel management.

AirPlus International Travel Management Study 2015 Part 1 A comparison of global trends and costs in business travel management. AirPlus International Travel Management Study 2015 Part 1 A comparison of global trends and costs in business travel management. SWITZERLAND Introduction Welcome to the tenth annual AirPlus International

More information

INFORMATION SHEETS: 2

INFORMATION SHEETS: 2 INFORMATION SHEETS: 2 EFFECTS OF ELECTORAL SYSTEMS ON WOMEN S REPRESENTATION For the National Association of Women and the Law For the National Roundtable on Women and Politics 2003 March 22 nd ~ 23 rd,

More information

Dr Abigail McKnight Associate Professorial Research Fellow and Associate Director, CASE, LSE Dr Chiara Mariotti Inequality Policy Manager, Oxfam

Dr Abigail McKnight Associate Professorial Research Fellow and Associate Director, CASE, LSE Dr Chiara Mariotti Inequality Policy Manager, Oxfam Hosted by LSE Works: CASE The Relationship between Inequality and Poverty: mechanisms and policy options Dr Eleni Karagiannaki Research Fellow, CASE, LSE Chris Goulden Deputy Director, Policy and Research,

More information

What factors are responsible for the distribution of responsibilities between the state, social partners and markets in ALMG? (covered in part I)

What factors are responsible for the distribution of responsibilities between the state, social partners and markets in ALMG? (covered in part I) Summary Summary Summary 145 Introduction In the last three decades, welfare states have responded to the challenges of intensified international competition, post-industrialization and demographic aging

More information

The first eleven years of Finland's EU-membership

The first eleven years of Finland's EU-membership 1 (7) Sinikka Salo 16 January 2006 Member of the Board The first eleven years of Finland's EU-membership Remarks by Ms Sinikka Salo in the Panel "The Austrian and Finnish EU-Presidencies: Positive Experiences

More information

EUROBAROMETER 71 PUBLIC OPINION IN THE EUROPEAN UNION SPRING

EUROBAROMETER 71 PUBLIC OPINION IN THE EUROPEAN UNION SPRING Standard Eurobarometer European Commission EUROBAROMETER 71 PUBLIC OPINION IN THE EUROPEAN UNION SPRING 2009 Standard Eurobarometer 71 / SPRING 2009 TNS Opinion & Social Standard Eurobarometer NATIONAL

More information

The European Parliament Campaign

The European Parliament Campaign FIFTH FRAMEWORK RESEARCH PROGRAMME (1998-2002) Democratic Participation and Political Communication in Systems of Multi-level Governance The European Parliament Campaign Fredrik Langdal Swedish Institute

More information

Economics Of Migration

Economics Of Migration Department of Economics and Centre for Macroeconomics public lecture Economics Of Migration Professor Alan Manning Professor of Economics and Director of the Centre for Economic Performance s research

More information

REFUGEES AND ASYLUM SEEKERS, THE CRISIS IN EUROPE AND THE FUTURE OF POLICY

REFUGEES AND ASYLUM SEEKERS, THE CRISIS IN EUROPE AND THE FUTURE OF POLICY REFUGEES AND ASYLUM SEEKERS, THE CRISIS IN EUROPE AND THE FUTURE OF POLICY Tim Hatton University of Essex (UK) and Australian National University Noise from America Firenze 11-12 June 2016 Introduction

More information

Introduction The Political Opportunities and Constraints of Welfare State Reform

Introduction The Political Opportunities and Constraints of Welfare State Reform 1 Introduction The Political Opportunities and Constraints of Welfare State Reform 1.1. Big Questions Thursday, 1 December 2011: in Greece schools are closed, hospitals are staffed with emergency personnel,

More information

Varieties of Welfare Capitalism in Crisis: A Qualitative Comparative Analysis of Labour Market Reforms in 18 Advanced Welfare States

Varieties of Welfare Capitalism in Crisis: A Qualitative Comparative Analysis of Labour Market Reforms in 18 Advanced Welfare States Varieties of Welfare Capitalism in Crisis: A Qualitative Comparative Analysis of Labour Market Reforms in 18 Advanced Welfare States Paper presented to the annual conference of the Sheffield Political

More information

1. Introduction. Michael Finus

1. Introduction. Michael Finus 1. Introduction Michael Finus Global warming is believed to be one of the most serious environmental problems for current and hture generations. This shared belief led more than 180 countries to sign the

More information

Flash Eurobarometer 429. Summary. The euro area

Flash Eurobarometer 429. Summary. The euro area LOGO CE_Vertical_EN_NEG_quadri rouge Summary Survey requested by the European Commission, Directorate-General for Economic and Financial Affairs and co-ordinated by the Directorate-General for Communication

More information

SUMMARY. Migration. Integration in the labour market

SUMMARY. Migration. Integration in the labour market SUMMARY The purpose of this report is to compare the integration of immigrants in Norway with immigrants in the other Scandinavian countries and in Europe. The most important question was therefore: How

More information

Aid spending by Development Assistance Committee donors in 2015

Aid spending by Development Assistance Committee donors in 2015 Aid spending by Development Assistance Committee donors in 2015 Overview of key trends in official development assistance emerging from the provisional 2015 Development Assistance Committee data release

More information

ITUC GLOBAL POLL Prepared for the G20 Labour and Finance Ministers Meeting Moscow, July 2013

ITUC GLOBAL POLL Prepared for the G20 Labour and Finance Ministers Meeting Moscow, July 2013 ITUC GLOBAL POLL 2013 Prepared for the G20 Labour and Finance Ministers Meeting Moscow, July 2013 Contents Executive Summary 2 Government has failed to tackle unemployment 4 Government prioritises business

More information

The Financial Crises of the 21st Century

The Financial Crises of the 21st Century The Financial Crises of the 21st Century Workshop of the Austrian Research Association (Österreichische Forschungsgemeinschaft) 18. - 19. 10. 2012 Economic Attitudes in Financial Crises: The Democratic

More information

REGIONAL POLICY MAKING AND SME

REGIONAL POLICY MAKING AND SME Ivana Mandysová REGIONAL POLICY MAKING AND SME Univerzita Pardubice, Fakulta ekonomicko-správní, Ústav veřejné správy a práva Abstract: The purpose of this article is to analyse the possibility for SME

More information

Only appropriately regulation for the agency work industry can effectively drive job creation, growth and competitiveness

Only appropriately regulation for the agency work industry can effectively drive job creation, growth and competitiveness Only appropriately regulation for the agency work industry can effectively drive job creation, growth and competitiveness The new European Commission needs to do more to ensure the full implementation

More information

summary fiche The European Social Fund: Women, Gender mainstreaming and Reconciliation of

summary fiche The European Social Fund: Women, Gender mainstreaming and Reconciliation of summary fiche The European Social Fund: Women, Gender mainstreaming and Reconciliation of work & private life Neither the European Commission nor any person acting on behalf of the Commission may be held

More information

CONSUMER PROTECTION IN THE EU

CONSUMER PROTECTION IN THE EU Special Eurobarometer European Commission CONSUMER PROTECTION IN THE EU Special Eurobarometer / Wave 59.2-193 - European Opinion Research Group EEIG Fieldwork: May-June 2003 Publication: November 2003

More information

ISSUE BRIEF: U.S. Immigration Priorities in a Global Context

ISSUE BRIEF: U.S. Immigration Priorities in a Global Context Immigration Task Force ISSUE BRIEF: U.S. Immigration Priorities in a Global Context JUNE 2013 As a share of total immigrants in 2011, the United States led a 24-nation sample in familybased immigration

More information

Majorities attitudes towards minorities in European Union Member States

Majorities attitudes towards minorities in European Union Member States Majorities attitudes towards minorities in European Union Member States Results from the Standard Eurobarometers 1997-2000-2003 Report 2 for the European Monitoring Centre on Racism and Xenophobia Ref.

More information

Living Together in a Sustainable Europe. Museums Working for Social Cohesion

Living Together in a Sustainable Europe. Museums Working for Social Cohesion NEMO 22 nd Annual Conference Living Together in a Sustainable Europe. Museums Working for Social Cohesion The Political Dimension Panel Introduction The aim of this panel is to discuss how the cohesive,

More information

Governments and unpopular social policy reform: Biting the bullet or steering clear?

Governments and unpopular social policy reform: Biting the bullet or steering clear? European Journal of Political Research 48: 31 57, 2009 31 doi: 10.1111/j.1475-6765.2008.00783.x Governments and unpopular social policy reform: Biting the bullet or steering clear? BARBARA VIS Department

More information

Study. Importance of the German Economy for Europe. A vbw study, prepared by Prognos AG Last update: February 2018

Study. Importance of the German Economy for Europe. A vbw study, prepared by Prognos AG Last update: February 2018 Study Importance of the German Economy for Europe A vbw study, prepared by Prognos AG Last update: February 2018 www.vbw-bayern.de vbw Study February 2018 Preface A strong German economy creates added

More information

Chapter 21 (10) Optimum Currency Areas and the Euro

Chapter 21 (10) Optimum Currency Areas and the Euro Chapter 21 (10) Optimum Currency Areas and the Euro Preview The European Union The European Monetary System Policies of the EU and the EMS Theory of optimal currency areas Is the EU an optimal currency

More information

Comparative Economic Geography

Comparative Economic Geography Comparative Economic Geography 1 WORLD POPULATION gross world product (GWP) The GWP Global GDP In 2012: GWP totalled approximately US $83.12 trillion in terms of PPP while the per capita GWP was approx.

More information

DEGREE PLUS DO WE NEED MIGRATION?

DEGREE PLUS DO WE NEED MIGRATION? DEGREE PLUS DO WE NEED MIGRATION? ROBERT SUBAN ROBERT SUBAN Department of Banking & Finance University of Malta Lecture Outline What is migration? Different forms of migration? How do we measure migration?

More information

Public finances, efficiency and equity: what are the trade-offs?

Public finances, efficiency and equity: what are the trade-offs? Lars Jonung, DG ECFIN, Public finances, efficiency and equity: what are the trade-offs? Brussels 12 November 2004. Comments on: 1. Vito Tanzi and Ludger Schuknecht: Reforming Public Expenditure in Industrialised

More information

STEPS Cluster Final Event

STEPS Cluster Final Event Investing in Human Capital: A Milestone Towards a Social Union STEPS Cluster Final Event Lille, 14 November 2014 Keynote by THIS IS A COVER TITLE Bart Vanhercke European Social Observatory & University

More information

American International Journal of Contemporary Research Vol. 4 No. 1; January 2014

American International Journal of Contemporary Research Vol. 4 No. 1; January 2014 Labour Productivity of Transportation Enterprises by Turnover per Person Employed Before and After the Economic Crisis: Economic Crisis Lessons from Europe Dr. Lembo Tanning TTK University of Applied Sciences

More information

Gertrude Tumpel-Gugerell: The euro benefits and challenges

Gertrude Tumpel-Gugerell: The euro benefits and challenges Gertrude Tumpel-Gugerell: The euro benefits and challenges Speech by Ms Gertrude Tumpel-Gugerell, Member of the Executive Board of the European Central Bank, at the Conference Poland and the EURO, Warsaw,

More information

UK Productivity Gap: Skills, management and innovation

UK Productivity Gap: Skills, management and innovation UK Productivity Gap: Skills, management and innovation March 2005 Professor John Van Reenen Director, Centre for Economic Performance, LSE 1 1. Overview The Productivity Gap (output per hour) What is it

More information

Italian Report / Executive Summary

Italian Report / Executive Summary EUROBAROMETER SPECIAL BUREAUX (2002) Italian Report / Executive Summary Survey carried out for the European Commission s Representation in ITALY «This document does not reflect the views of the European

More information

Introduction: The State of Europe s Population, 2003

Introduction: The State of Europe s Population, 2003 Introduction: The State of Europe s Population, 2003 Changes in the size, growth and composition of the population are of key importance to policy-makers in practically all domains of life. To provide

More information

INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS INTO THE LABOUR MARKET IN EU AND OECD COUNTRIES

INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS INTO THE LABOUR MARKET IN EU AND OECD COUNTRIES INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS INTO THE LABOUR MARKET IN EU AND OECD COUNTRIES AN OVERVIEW Brussels, 25 June 2015 Thomas Liebig International Migration Division Directorate for Employment, Labour and Social

More information

Letter prices in Europe. Up-to-date international letter price survey. March th edition

Letter prices in Europe. Up-to-date international letter price survey. March th edition Letter prices in Europe Up-to-date international letter price survey. March 2014 13th edition 1 Summary This is the thirteenth time Deutsche Post has carried out a study, drawing a comparison between letter

More information

Rosary Sisters High School Model United Nations ROSMUN Economic and Social Council

Rosary Sisters High School Model United Nations ROSMUN Economic and Social Council Rosary Sisters High School Model United Nations ROSMUN 2018 Economic and Social Council Bridging the Economic Gap Between Developed and Developing Countries Nicole Hazou Introduction In developing countries,

More information

THRESHOLDS. Underlying principles. What submitters on the party vote threshold said

THRESHOLDS. Underlying principles. What submitters on the party vote threshold said THRESHOLDS Underlying principles A threshold is the minimum level of support a party needs to gain representation. Thresholds are intended to provide for effective government and ensure that every party

More information

A comparative analysis of poverty and social inclusion indicators at European level

A comparative analysis of poverty and social inclusion indicators at European level A comparative analysis of poverty and social inclusion indicators at European level CRISTINA STE, EVA MILARU, IA COJANU, ISADORA LAZAR, CODRUTA DRAGOIU, ELIZA-OLIVIA NGU Social Indicators and Standard

More information

EDUCATION OUTCOMES EXPENDITURE ON EDUCATION INTERNATIONAL STUDENT ASSESSMENT TERTIARY ATTAINMENT

EDUCATION OUTCOMES EXPENDITURE ON EDUCATION INTERNATIONAL STUDENT ASSESSMENT TERTIARY ATTAINMENT EDUCATION OUTCOMES INTERNATIONAL STUDENT ASSESSMENT TERTIARY ATTAINMENT EXPENDITURE ON EDUCATION EXPENDITURE ON TERTIARY EDUCATION PUBLIC AND PRIVATE EDUCATION EXPENDITURE EDUCATION OUTCOMES INTERNATIONAL

More information

CO3.6: Percentage of immigrant children and their educational outcomes

CO3.6: Percentage of immigrant children and their educational outcomes CO3.6: Percentage of immigrant children and their educational outcomes Definitions and methodology This indicator presents estimates of the proportion of children with immigrant background as well as their

More information

3 Wage adjustment and employment in Europe: some results from the Wage Dynamics Network Survey

3 Wage adjustment and employment in Europe: some results from the Wage Dynamics Network Survey 3 Wage adjustment and in Europe: some results from the Wage Dynamics Network Survey This box examines the link between collective bargaining arrangements, downward wage rigidities and. Several past studies

More information

MEETING OF THE OECD COUNCIL AT MINISTERIAL LEVEL, PARIS 6-7 MAY 2014 REPORT ON THE OECD FRAMEWORK FOR INCLUSIVE GROWTH KEY FINDINGS

MEETING OF THE OECD COUNCIL AT MINISTERIAL LEVEL, PARIS 6-7 MAY 2014 REPORT ON THE OECD FRAMEWORK FOR INCLUSIVE GROWTH KEY FINDINGS MEETING OF THE OECD COUNCIL AT MINISTERIAL LEVEL, PARIS 6-7 MAY 2014 REPORT ON THE OECD FRAMEWORK FOR INCLUSIVE GROWTH KEY FINDINGS This document is published on the responsibility of the Secretary-General

More information

Widening of Inequality in Japan: Its Implications

Widening of Inequality in Japan: Its Implications Widening of Inequality in Japan: Its Implications Jun Saito, Senior Research Fellow Japan Center for Economic Research December 11, 2017 Is inequality widening in Japan? Since the publication of Thomas

More information

Towards an Open Functional Approach to Welfare State Change: Pressures,

Towards an Open Functional Approach to Welfare State Change: Pressures, Towards an Open Functional Approach to Welfare State Change: Pressures, Ideas, and Blame Avoidance Barbara Vis a & Kees van Kersbergen b a Department of Political Science, VU University Amsterdam, De Boelelaan

More information

ETUC Platform on the Future of Europe

ETUC Platform on the Future of Europe ETUC Platform on the Future of Europe Resolution adopted at the Executive Committee of 26-27 October 2016 We, the European trade unions, want a European Union and a single market based on cooperation,

More information

No Elections for Big Parties

No Elections for Big Parties No Elections for Big Parties Elias Dinas 1 Pedro Riera 2 1 University of Nottingham elias.dinas@nottingham.ac.uk 2 University of Strathclyde pedro.riera@strath.ac.uk EUDO Dissemination Conference Florence,

More information

OECD Strategic Education Governance A perspective for Scotland. Claire Shewbridge 25 October 2017 Edinburgh

OECD Strategic Education Governance A perspective for Scotland. Claire Shewbridge 25 October 2017 Edinburgh OECD Strategic Education Governance A perspective for Scotland Claire Shewbridge 25 October 2017 Edinburgh CERI overview What CERI does Generate forward-looking research analyses and syntheses Identify

More information

List of topics for papers

List of topics for papers General information List of topics for papers The paper has to consist of 5 000-6 000 words (including footnotes). Please consider the formatting requirements. The deadline for submission will generally

More information

Congruence in Political Parties

Congruence in Political Parties Descriptive Representation of Women and Ideological Congruence in Political Parties Georgia Kernell Northwestern University gkernell@northwestern.edu June 15, 2011 Abstract This paper examines the relationship

More information

Miracle of Estonia Entrepreneurship and Competitiveness Policy in Estonia

Miracle of Estonia Entrepreneurship and Competitiveness Policy in Estonia Miracle of Estonia Entrepreneurship and Competitiveness Policy in Estonia Signe Ratso Deputy Secretary General of EU and International Co-operation Ministry of Economic Affairs and Communications of Estonia

More information

Globalisation and flexicurity

Globalisation and flexicurity Globalisation and flexicurity Torben M Andersen Department of Economics Aarhus University November 216 Globalization Is it Incompatible with High employment Decent wages (no working poor) Low inequality

More information

Unions and the Government in Spain during the Economic Crisis. Kerstin Hamann. Department of Political Science University of Central Florida

Unions and the Government in Spain during the Economic Crisis. Kerstin Hamann. Department of Political Science University of Central Florida Cooperation and Confrontation: Unions and the Government in Spain during the Economic Crisis Kerstin Hamann Department of Political Science University of Central Florida The Changing Role of Unions Indicators

More information

Size and Development of the Shadow Economy of 31 European and 5 other OECD Countries from 2003 to 2013: A Further Decline

Size and Development of the Shadow Economy of 31 European and 5 other OECD Countries from 2003 to 2013: A Further Decline January 31, 2013 ShadEcEurope31_Jan2013.doc Size and Development of the Shadow Economy of 31 European and 5 other OECD Countries from 2003 to 2013: A Further Decline by Friedrich Schneider *) In the Tables

More information

UNDER EMBARGO UNTIL 10 APRIL 2019, 15:00 HOURS PARIS TIME. Development aid drops in 2018, especially to neediest countries

UNDER EMBARGO UNTIL 10 APRIL 2019, 15:00 HOURS PARIS TIME. Development aid drops in 2018, especially to neediest countries Development aid drops in 2018, especially to neediest countries OECD Paris, 10 April 2019 OECD adopts new methodology for counting loans in official aid data In 2014, members of the OECD s Development

More information

Final Report. For the European Commission, Directorate General Justice, Freedom and Security

Final Report. For the European Commission, Directorate General Justice, Freedom and Security Research Project Executive Summary A Survey on the Economics of Security with Particular Focus on the Possibility to Create a Network of Experts on the Economic Analysis of Terrorism and Anti-Terror Policies

More information

Improving the accuracy of outbound tourism statistics with mobile positioning data

Improving the accuracy of outbound tourism statistics with mobile positioning data 1 (11) Improving the accuracy of outbound tourism statistics with mobile positioning data Survey response rates are declining at an alarming rate globally. Statisticians have traditionally used imputing

More information