Issue voting under different institutional contexts

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Issue voting under different institutional contexts"

Transcription

1 Issue voting under different institutional contexts Political communication and effective representation in 37 countries Stefan Dahlberg Henrik Oscarsson Daniel Berlin Paper prepared for presentation at the XIV NOPSA Conference August 11-13, 2005 Reykjavik, Iceland Stefan Dahlberg, Ph. D-student. Göteborg University. +46 (0) Henrik Oscarsson, Associate Professor. Göteborg University. +46 (0) Daniel Berlin, Ph. D-student. Göteborg University. +46 (0) Abstract 1

2 The impact of electoral systems on party systems has long been regarded as one of the most important effects of electoral engineering (Duverger 1954; Lijphart 1994; Sartori 1997; 1976a). A common assumption among rational choice institutionalists is that electoral rules have a certain impact on the party systems and the patterns of competition, since the adoption of certain rules creates incentives for rational vote-seeking parties to either emphasize particularistic or programmatic benefits during the election campaigns (Downs 1957b; Sjöblom 1968). The strategies adopted by political elites are indirectly expected to influence the voting behavior among citizens. Yet, it is not quite clear to what extent electoral institutions affect voters on a micro level, only that they do. By combining contextual variables on electoral system features with cross-national surveys of voting behavior, we empirically explore how citizens are affected by the institutional context. A simultaneous modeling of macro and micro data from CSES shows a weak but significant contextual effect of type of electoral system on voting behavior. Proportional multiparty-systems seem to induce parties to communicate their policy positions by means of ideology. The parties left-right positions are more known to voters in proportional systems than in non-proportional systems and the effect of ideology on party choice is also stronger in proportional systems. The fact that the left-right dimension is not a valid operationalization of ideology in some countries does raise doubts over the validity of the findings. If only polities where the left-right dimension plays an important role are included, the support for this main finding becomes stronger. A more elaborated conclusion would be that among countries where the left-right dimension is an important distinction for voters, we find a significant effect of institutional context on the levels of ideological voting. Introduction There is a newly awakened interest among political scientists for empirically founded research on constitutional design and electoral outcome. The vast amount of research in this field have long focused on how politicians and parties are affected by different institutional factors, which in turn is believed to have a certain impact upon voters as well. According to Giovanni Sartori, electoral systems are the most specific and manipulative instrument of politics (Sartori 1997) and few would today oppose that institutions matter, both explicitly and implicitly (Reynolds 2002; Norris 2003b). Yet, it is not quite clear how electoral institutions affect voters on a micro level, only that they do. By combining contextual variables on electoral system features with cross-national surveys of voting behavior, we have the opportunity to empirically examine how citizens are affected by the institutional context. Our theoretical approach originates from rational choice 2

3 institutionalism where we are theorizing on how formal and informal rules 1 may affect the behavior of actors within a political system, which in turn is believed to influence the voting behavior among individuals. 2 Just as James Madison asserted two centuries ago, we believe that one of the keys to a well-functioning representative democracy lies in the architectural creation of political institutions (Ferejohn 1990: 6). More precisely, we are interested in how the institutional contexts affect voters perceptions of parties and how this may promote a higher degree of ideological issue voting, which we believe is normatively appealing to popular theories of effective representation. Our interest in political perceptions and ideological voting stems from the fact that these factors affect the extent to which voters are meaningfully represented in a political system, as they are important determinants of outcomes of electoral processes (Granberg 1988: 2; Brug 1997: 2). Voting behavior Several models of political representation have been developed over the years, where one of the most prominent is the responsible party model (RPM). The RPM has been the normative foundation in several studies concerning the functions of representative democratic systems, where it has been used for theorising about necessary conditions for citizens to select parties or candidates that represent their preferences, i.e. policy positions. The model presumes a prospective mandate where parties, during the election campaign, present coherent policy programs on which voters make their choices. An important prerequisite assessed by the model is that the parties should present divergent and stable policy positions so that voters are given meaningful electoral choices. Regarding voting-behavior, the RPM assumes that voters base their decisions on a comparative evaluation of the policy programmes among the competing parties. Thereafter, in order to directly influence government policies, they vote for the party or candidate whose policy-program are in best congruence with the voters own preferences (H. S. J. Thomassen 1999: 116; Adams 2001: ch. 1; Esaiasson & Holmberg 1996; Klingemann, Hofferbert & Budge 1994; Pennings 1998b). The importance of issue agreement between voters and their representatives in the RPM implies that the model easily can be incorporated in 1 Formal rules are here understood as the legislative framework embedded in official documents or constitutional conventions such as the degree of proportionality, effective thresholds etc. Among the informal rules or noninstitutional contextual factors that may influence the individual act of voting, we refer to variables such as the breadth of alternatives, the dimensionality of the ideological space and the polarization of the party system. 2 Our definition of an institution relies on B. G. Peters where: institutions are conceptualized as collections of rules and incentives that establish the conditions for bounded rationality, and therefore establish a political space within which many interdependent political actors can function Peters 1999: 44. 3

4 traditional spatial models of electoral competition, where smallest spatial distance is decisive for how voters choose to cast their ballots. An important determinant of the quality of the outcomes of electoral processes is the amount of political knowledge among voters, as it is more likely that well informed, rather that ill-informed voters make electoral decisions that reflect their attitudes toward public policies. If the process of democratic representation is to be acceptable from a normative point of view, a necessary condition that has to be fulfilled is that voters are informed about the different policy alternatives. Voters knowledge on matters of political or societal character has been the subject in several studies over the years and most of these studies have come to a similar conclusion: the amount of information among average voters is poor. The possibilities for reasoned choices, as acquired by most of the normative theories on representative democracy, may therefore be considered as being beyond the capability of the vast majority of the democratic citizenry (Delli Carpini & Keeter 1996; Campbell et al. 1960; Larry M. Bartels 1996; Page & Shapiro 1992; Converse 1964; Petersson et al. 1998; Holmberg & Oscarsson 2004; Gordon 1997; Lupia 1998). An argument why political representation in mass democracies can work at all in spite of the fact that citizens in general are not very knowledgeable about political matters is that citizen and elites often share the same belief systems (L. M. Bartels 1996; Luskin 2003). Rational voters use heuristics such as ideologies, cognitive schemas or belief systems as cost-reducing devices or shortcuts (see fc Downs 1957b; Zaller 1992; Lupia 1998; Popkin 1991). The role of belief systems in models of political representation has recently been highlighted by Jacques Thomassen (Holmberg 1999; Schmitt & Thomassen 1999; J. Thomassen 1999; van der Brug & van der Eijk 1999; van der Eijk, Franklin & van der Brug 1999). According to Thomassen, unidimensional belief systems is a desired characteristics of representative democracies as the effectiveness of the responsible party model depends on the extent to which the policy views of both the masses and elites are constrained by a one-dimensional conflict dimension, more specifically, a left-right dimension (H. S. J. Thomassen 1999: 34). His simple but strong argument is well founded. It rests upon social choice theory as well as the classic Downsian spatial theory of elections, where actors perceptual agreement of the political landscape is an important prerequisite (Downs 1957b). In short, Thomassen s statement is that simplicity in the political world is important for effective political representation. 3 According to 3 The hypothesis that simple, unidimensional party systems makes it easier to produce effective representation, leads to higher policy congruence between masses and elites and, eventually, also produce higher levels of political legitimacy is worth pursuing 4

5 this perspective, ideology provides the fundamental means of communication and constitutes a crucial linkage between citizens and elected representatives. In this perspective, it is the existence of a common political language, spoken and understood by both elites and masses that make modern mass democracies not break down. Since the ideological position of an actor can be used to trace the standpoints on a large number of underlying issues (Downs 1957b; Brug 1997), it could be argued that vote-decisions based on ideology, from a normative point of view, is desirable as it is both informative and demands some sort of issue orientation among the voters as required by the RPM. A range of studies, this included, focus on citizens abilities to perceive political messages from elites, i.e. how well policy alternatives and issue positions are being communicated to citizens. An electorate with clear and common perceptions of the party space has repeatedly been identified as one important prerequisite for successful political representation (Converse 1975; van der Brug 1996; Schmitt & Thomassen 1999). To maintain meaningful mass-elite communication, citizens need to have clear and correct perceptions of the main alternatives, or at least the most important differences between them, and what the ideological conflicts in the party system are all about (Berelson 1952). Perceptual agreement is considered to be a necessary, although not sufficient, condition for the electoral process to function as an effective channel of communication (van der Brug & van der Eijk 1999; van der Eijk, Franklin & van der Brug 1999). The more agreement over parties positions in the ideological space, the stronger the impact of ideology on voters party preferences (Oppenhuis 1995; Tillie 1995; van der Eijk & Franklin 1996). Strong agreement over party positions among voters is being interpreted as an indicator of successful communication of policy standpoints on behalf of the parties. The left-right position as a cognitive cue In this article, we will make use of the Left-Right dimension, since it has been considered as being one of the most universal and salient issue-dimensions within several political systems. It is also one of the few comparable measurements for belief systems available (Jones 2004; Budge 1987; Klingemann, Hofferbert & Budge 1994; H. S. J. Thomassen 1999). The strength with the left-right dimension is, as mentioned, that it summarizes positions on a large number of underlying issues and in the end, left-right ideology does not only structure voters preferences but may also be used as an information short cut on parties standpoints on several concrete a bit further. A European-wide analysis revealed a weak positive aggregate correlation between voters perceptual agreement over parties left-right positions and levels of political legitimacy (satisfied with democracy) (Oscarsson 2001). 5

6 issues (Downs 1957a: 98; Brug 1997: 38; 1999a; Fuchs 1990; Holmberg 2004; 1981: 192ff). This assumes that voters implicitly use a spatial image in their perceptions of political actors, issues or ideologies,(budge 1987; Oscarsson 1998; Brug 1997: 10) which favour the use of spatial models in the study of political communication. 4 The left-right distinction is probably most accurately described as a historically successful instrument of communication. Left and Right have proven to be powerful spatial metaphors that greatly help communicate political preferences and ideological standpoints between elites and masses in modern democracies one of the keystones in many popular models of political representation, such as the Responsible Party Model. Thus, the merit of the distinction is the simple distinction itself, not its content. More boldly put, the uni-dimensional mental map of the political landscape may have played a key role in the rise of well functioning representative democracies. Since its birth in the late 18 th century, the bipolar left-right construction has shown remarkable resistance, reproducing itself in new polities and in new historical and social contexts, constantly challenged and reshaped by new ideological dimensions. 5 Although the substantive meaning and interpretation of the left-right distinction have not remained the same for two hundred years albeit for the key element of equality (Bobbio 1996) the distinction has thus, played a crucial role as an information cost reducing device for political actors. Leaders have made extensive use of the left-right grammar for sending political messages that otherwise probably would have been incomprehensible for most voters. Left-Right have important orientational functions for individual citizens, and communication functions for political systems (Fuchs & Klingemann 1989; Inglehart & Klingemann 1976). Why do we expect electoral systems to have an impact on voting behavior? The impact of electoral systems on party systems has long been regarded as one of the most important effects of electoral engineering. Generally speaking, proportional systems tend to produce a greater number of parties than majoritarian systems (Duverger 1954; Sartori 1976a; 4 We know from a number of national studies that perceptual consensus over parties positions is dependent on the saliency of issue dimensions (Brug 1997; Oscarsson This means that the more intensively parties communicate their left-right positions to voters, the more common will voters perceptions of the parties left-right positions become. Therefore, aggregated measures of perceptual accuracy can be regarded as an indicator of how well the process of political representation works for left-right related issues in a political system. Working with this particular data, we have no other ideological dimensions for which parties and voters placements have been measured. 5 The absorptive power of the Left-Right semantics is impressive. For instance, religious, liberal economic and materialist values all contribute to rightist identification among citizens, while secular, economic leftist and postmaterialist values contribute to leftist identification (Knutsen 1995; Knutsen 1999.). 6

7 1997; Lijphart 1994; Golder 2005). 6 Rational choice institutionalism emphasizes that formal rules generate incentives that are shaping and constraining the rational goal-seeking behavior of the actors within a political system (Laver 1997; Peters 1999). A common assumption is then that electoral rules exerts an influence on the party systems and the patterns of competition, since the adoption of certain rules creates incentives for rational vote-seeking politicians to either emphasize particularistic or programmatic benefits during the election campaigns (Downs 1957b; Sjöblom 1968). The strategies adopted by political elites are then, indirectly expected to influence the voting behavior of citizens. 7 Consequently, proportional party-list formulas tend to produce incentives to shift the attention from individual politicians with particularistic policies to political parties with programmatic policies (Norris 2003b; Sjöblom 1968). In such a system, voters tend to vote for parties instead of single candidates. The candidates are also dependent on the parties for their election as the party leadership nominates them through the party-lists. A candidate s personal characteristics may then be considered as less important as they are acting more on behalf of the party. Party-ballots can thus, be expected to be effective in promoting party discipline, coherence and programmatic campaigning. Effective well-functioning parties may serve several important tasks in a political system by simplifying electoral choices, organize campaigns, aggregate interests, channelling the debate and select candidates (Dalton 2000) which in turn may affect voters perceptions of party positions and their voting behavior. The adoption of a proportional partylist formula may increase the number of parties in a political system and increase the incentives for the development of programmatic ideologically driven political parties and the presence of a shared belief system and a commonly spoken political language is an essential ingredient for a well functioning representative political system. 6 This division should thus not be thought of as a dichotomy since most electoral systems are a combination of functions from them both. An electoral system is therefore more or less proportional or majoritarian 7 The expectation that single member plurality systems will produce a two-party system has not gained fully empirical support. Those who want to predict the number of parties in a given political context must also consider the patterns of the social cleavages and not only the type of electoral system (Volwes 2004.) For example, Sartori argues that a proportional system do not multiply the number of parties in it self; instead, this is an indirect effect of the proportional formula. PR may in some cases remove pre-existing obstacles and thereby open up for new parties. For the same reasons, a plurality system cannot by itself produce a two party system but will help to maintain an existing one (Grofman & Lijphart 1986: 2-5.). The number of parties in a political system is also dependent on the level of the effective threshold that is applied in many proportional systems, in an attempt to decrease the party fragmentation and to promote stable governments (Lijphart 1998.) Nevertheless, it is clear that electoral formulas have a fundamental impact on the characteristics of the party systems (Sartori 1997; Lijphart 1994; Duverger In general, countries that are using any form of proportional representation have twice as many parliamentary parties than countries using any form of majoritarian electoral system (Norris 2003b: 84. 7

8 As stated earlier, electoral rules influence the patterns of competition and in line with spatial models of party competition, parties in a multiparty system will try to position themselves more ideologically and differentiate themselves as much as possible from the competing parties around in an attempt to mobilize their electoral support. While a two party system will make the parties to converge ideologically at the median voter position, parties in a multiparty system will maintain the clarity in their positions since they are not necessarily striving to attract the median voters (Downs 1957a: ; Sjöblom 1968). When more parties are encouraged in the competition, they will face centrifugal incentives to take more dispersed positions in the policy space (Cox 1990; Sartori 1976b). Reasonably, more parties mean greater polarization, which should facilitate for voters to perceive the differences between them, which should increase the degree of ideological issue voting. 8 Reasonably, there is an upper limit where the effective number of parties within a system will exceed the benefits with breadth of alternatives. If too many parties are involved in the competition, voters may find it difficult to discern the policy positions between the parties, but this is an empirical question. When certain types of electoral formulas tend to affect the number of parties, which in turn is expected to be decisive for the degree of competition, i.e. centripetal or centrifugal competition, other historical factors account for the dimensionality in a political system. 9 The number of social cleavages in a political system is not necessarily affecting the number of parties in a political system (Jones 2004) and the parties are not by themselves capable of creating societal cleavages but they may induce or suppress already existing ones (Lipset & Rokkan 1967; Bartolini 1990; O. S. Knutsen, E. 1995). Nevertheless, the number of cleavages in a society may still be decisive for the effectiveness of the communication between parties and voters. Mainly because some parties may be more attached to alternative cleavages, such as environmentalist, religious- or linguistic parties, why the clarity in their positions will be depending on the saliency of the different cleavages. However, the initial adoption of certain rules such as a proportional formula may increase the incentives for bonding strategies among the competing parties, since proportional systems tend to produce multiparty systems that in turn may maintain or even reinforce existing cleavages. In 8 In contrast to the proximity theory, the advocators of the directional theory claims that voters in general are unable to recognise slighter adjustments in policy positions among parties. Instead, voters evaluate parties policies on their direction and intensity rather than in terms of their closeness to a voters own policy position. Given these assumptions, the perceptual agreement on a party s position may be expected to be higher for parties with extremer positions, as it will be more likely that the voters know the position of a party with such a position. See (Rabinowitz 1991: ; Adams 2001: 97; MacDonald 1991; Rabinowitz 1989; Merill III 1999; Westholm 1997; Gilljam 1997.) 9 Our definition of a social cleavage rests on the work of Bartolini and Mair, where a cleavage exists if there is an interest conflict characterized by a) a social differentiation b) that is institutionalized and c) politically organized (Bartolini

9 plurality systems, on the other hand, parties may adopt bridging strategies that may suppress the group consciousness in the electoral arena and even downplay the importance of pre-existing cleavages (Norris 2003b). Something that can be expected to have far-reaching consequences, both for how voters perceive the parties but also on their voting behavior. If proportional systems imply that parties will adopt bridging strategies, then the voters within these systems should obtain higher levels of perceptual agreement and to a higher extent lean upon ideological issue voting than in plurality- or majoritarian systems. So far, we have mainly focused on effects of electoral systems in terms of the simple dichotomy between majoritarian and proportional systems. However, a constitutional order that bring large votes/seats disparities where the seat allocation is not congruent with the parties actual vote share may also reduce the incentives for individuals to be fully involved. A high degree of disproportionality may induce tactical voting where citizens are voting for their second choice instead of their first hand preferences. This may in turn decrease the incentives for gathering accurate information of the different policy alternatives (Gordon 1997). Reasonably, the more proportional a system is, the more likely it is that voters will vote on their first hand choice, which also should imply higher levels of ideological proximity. 10 This leads us toward our main hypothesis, which in a broader sense claims that it is all about simplicity. Perceptual agreement and the degree of ideological voting will be higher among voters in: a proportional, uni-dimensional political system, characterized by the occurrence of both party-list ballots and an electoral threshold and a polarized party system where several, but not too many, parties are involved in the competition, since: 1). Proportional systems tend to produce multiparty systems, and parties within such a system will adopt bridging strategies and try to differentiate and positioning them selves more ideologically in an attempt to maintain the clarity in their positions; and 2). with several parties involved in the competition, the parties will face centrifugal incentives to take more dispersed positions in an attempt to profile themselves from other competing parties and a high degree of polarization will, in turn, facilitate for the voters to apprehend the positions of the parties. 10 There is always some distortion embedded in the electoral systems due to various factors, why there are no completely proportional system. The lowest electoral threshold is to be found in the Netherlands where it is.67 percentages (Farrell 2001.) 9

10 In sum, the more proportional an electoral system is the more likely it is that the political representatives will communicate their policies in terms of ideology, which will increase the perceptual agreement and the degree of ideological voting among the voters. The purpose with these not too daring hypotheses is not as much an attempt to win new terrain, but rather to systematically examine traditional assumptions about the effect of electoral systems on voting behavior and effective representation. With access to a new cross-national dataset containing data on both voters and institutions, we now finally have the opportunity to test this empirically. Data, design and operationalizations This study uses data from the CSES (Comparative Study of Electoral Systems) which is a collaborative project of cross-national research among election studies conducted in over fifty states. The strengths with the dataset, besides that it is cross-national, is that it contains both micro-level data that include vote choice, candidate and party evaluations etc. and macro-level data on aggregate electoral returns, electoral rules and formulas. This allows us to conduct both cross-level, as well as cross-national analyses on the effects of electoral institutions on voting behavior. 11 Our analysis is based on data from CSES module 1 and 2, where respondents in some 37 countries were asked to place themselves and the parties on an eleven-point left-right scale The CSES-question was: In politics people sometimes talk of left and right. Where would you place yourself on a scale from 0 to 10 where 0 means the left and 10 means the right. 12 A universal application of such a left-right scale is not uncontroversial. We know from earlier studies that the left-right distinction obviously makes a lot more sense in some countries than in others (Huber & Inglehart 1995; Klingemann 1995). We also know that the substantive meaning of the terms left and right differ much between polities and even between decades in the same polity. So, how can we justify the use of left-right division as a world-wide operationalization of ideology? 11 The data can be downloaded from: 12 In Japan, a liberal-conservative scale was used. In the Netherlands, a ten-point scale 1-10 was used instead of an eleven-point scale. 10

11 A simple indicator of the importance of the left-right dimension in a polity is the strength of the bivariate relationship between party choice and voters self-reported ideological left-right positions (see table 1). In the CSES data, the highest correlations are found in Sweden (eta=.77), Czechoslovakia (eta=.76) and Poland (eta=.72). In these countries, we can explain large portions of the dependent variable party choice just by asking respondents about their own left-right position. Party choice is highly correlated with left-right ideology also in Spain, Iceland, Israel, Denmark, Portugal and Switzerland. In sum, 18 of 37 countries in the study have correlations higher than eta=.50. In conclusion, it is fairly unproblematic to use left-right ideology as a single indicator of ideology in these countries. 13 In general, the relationship between left-right ideology and party choice are high. The importance of left-right ideology is substantively higher on the European continent than outside Europe. Note that there are no non-european countries with high correlations, with the exception of New Zeeland (eta=.64), which undoubtedly also belong to the Western European culturalhistorical sphere. In polities as Romania, Korea, Belgian Wallonia, Taiwan and Peru, there are only weak bivariate correlations between citizens left-right orientations and party choice. Again, the left-right dimension s inability to perform well outside a Western-European cultural-political context is an important result in itself and will have consequences for the remaining analyses in this article. The rich variation of electoral systems in the world also makes it complicated for political comparativists. Many categorizations of electoral systems have been applied in contemporary research, and there is an on-going debate over what distinctions are most fruitful for empirical analysis (Powell 2000; Shugart & Wattenberg 2001; Anckar 2002). In previous analyses of CSES data, the operational classification of electoral systems has been into three large categories: proportional list systems, semi-proportional combined systems, and majoritarian systems (see Holmberg 2002; Norris 2003a). We have earlier argued that effective representation largely rests upon successful communication and that a prerequisite for ideological issue voting is that the parties actually are appealing to the voters in terms of ideology and that they have managed to communicate their ideological 13 Of course, if you dig deeper into the ideological space of national polities, you will find many reasons to expand the analysis with one, two or more important ideological dimensions, or even single issue dimensions. Even in Sweden, probably the most uni-dimensional party space in Europe (Oscarsson 2001.), more in-depth analysis must expand the number of dimensions to two (Oscarsson 1998.) 11

12 positions to the voters so that they have clear and consistent perceptions of the party positions. If ideology, i.e. left-right position, is going to work as a more or less accurate information shortcut for the different policy alternatives that a voter is facing during an election, the parties have to be able to communicate their left-right positions to the voters. Perceptual agreement among voters is not necessarily the same as perceptual accuracy. Nevertheless, if a majority of the voters are agreeing on the wrong position of a party, the communication has obviously failed. It is thus, quite unlikely that this actually will happen, and therefore we consider perceptual agreement to be a valid indicator on the degree of success in political communication (Brug 1997: 44). For measuring the degree of perceptual agreement among voters, we will use an estimate that originally was developed by Cees van der Eijk (van der Eijk 1998). The PA-measure has been employed a number of times in similar analyses (van der Eijk & Franklin 1996: 433-4; van der Brug & van der Eijk 1999: 137-9). PA is calculated for each individual party (se Appendix) and can also be aggregated into an overall measure of perceptual agreement in a political system. The measure of Perceptual Agreement is developed for ordered rating scales, such as the eleven-point left-right scale, and reflects the deviation from a unimodal distribution and ranges from 1 (perfect bimodality, where half of the voters place the party on the most leftist position and half of the voters place the party on the most rightist position) to +1 (perfect unimodality, where all voters place a party at the same position). Uniform distributions will get a PA-value of zero. The higher the PA-value gets, the higher perceptual agreement (van der Eijk 1998). 14 A high degree of agreement among voters on parties policy positions may then be interpreted as that the parties have managed to communicate their policy positions successfully. 15 In a second step, we will continue the analysis with ideological issue voting. The most straightforward way to operationalize ideological proximity is simply by calculating the absolute difference between the respondents self-reported left-right position and the parties positions along the eleven-point left-right scale. Ideological proximity will range from 0 (minimum voterparty distance) to 10 (maximum voter-party distance). To estimate the effects on probability to vote for a party, we will perform the procedure of stacking the data-set (see van der Eijk & 14 The calculations of Cees van der Eijks Measure of Perceptual Agreement were made in SAS. The syntax for calculating PA-measures for 7, 10 and 11-point ordered rating scales can be acquired by sending a mail to Henrik.Oscarsson@pol.gu.se. 15 In the CSES data set, the number of parties for which we have left-right placements are limited to six. This means that for many multi-party systems included in this study, the party systems have been truncated, in some cases dramatically so. Many multi-party systems, such as Sweden, the Netherlands, and Poland, have more than six relevant parties. In many analyses, we only include the respondents who voted for parties for which we have available data on left-right positions, which in some cases is a drastic limitation. Which parties to include in the final data set has been decided by the research teams behind the respective national election studies. A full list of what parties are included in the study can be found in the Appendix. 12

13 Franklin 1996) and thereby convert to a new unit of analyses, namely party-voter dyads. In each polity, there will be as many party-voter dyads as there are respondents times the number of parties. The party choice variable will become a binary response variable (0=did not vote for the party, 1=voted for the party), allowing to estimate the probability to vote for the party with logistic regression. Perceptual agreement and ideological voting under different institutional contexts How does the institutional context affect the political communication and the level of ideological issue voting in a polity? Do parties in proportional multiparty systems communicate in terms of ideology and are voters in these systems inclined to vote ideologically? In this analysis, we will estimate the effects of different institutional settings on the perceptual agreement among voters and the effects of ideological left-right proximity on the probability to vote for a party under different electoral systems. Consequently, we expect perceptual agreement and the effects of ideological proximity on party choice to be greater in proportional systems than in majoritarian systems. This hypothesis can be deduced from the simple fact that proportional list systems tend to offer more choices, i.e. effective number of parties (Duverger 1954), and that voters in proportional list systems more often choose between political programs of parties and not between candidates (Holmberg & Oscarsson 2003; Holmberg 2002). Thus, we expect ideology to play a more important role in multi-party list proportional systems than in two-party candidate-oriented majoritarian systems since parties in a multiparty system are prone to differentiate and positioning themselves in terms of ideology in an attempt to maintain the clarity in their positions(downs 1957b: ). If all this is correct, we also expect that the ideological positions of parties will be more well known to voters in a proportional list system than in majoritarian. The perceptual accuracy and perceptual agreement will be higher in proportional election systems than in semi-proportional or majoritarian systems, since parties in proportional systems have higher incentives to carefully communicate ideological standpoints and mark the ideological distances to other alternatives (Downs 1957b). In turn, voters in proportional list systems need to develop skills and well-functioning cognitive schemas to be able to comprehend political messages from the party elites and orient themselves ideologically. In table 1, the 37 countries in the analysis have been sorted according to the correlation (eta) between left-right orientation and party choice. Included in the table are the measure of left-right 13

14 polarization (Wing Party Distance), and the Weighted Perceptual Agreement (WPA) for each polity. We also included the type of electoral system (CSES-categorizations), along with some characteristics of the electoral systems (effective threshold, degree of disproportionality, the effective number of parties (Anckar 2002). 14

15 Table 1: Type of Election System, Effective Threshold, Disproportionality, Effective Number of Parties, Wing Party Ideological Left-Right Distance (WPD), Weighted Perceptual Agreement (WPA) 16 and Correlation between Left-Right Self Placements and Party Choice (Eta, Cramer s V) Election Year Country Election System (CSES) Effective Threshold Dis-proportionality Effective # of parties Dimensionality 17 Government Stability Wing Party Distance (WPD) Perceptual Agreement (WPA) 1998 Sweden List PR Czechoslovakia List PR Poland List PR Spain List PR Iceland List PR Israel List PR Denmark List PR Portugal List PR Switzerland List PR Lithuania Semi-Prop Norway List PR Ukraine Semi-Prop New Zeeland Quasi-Prop Mixed The Netherlands List PR Russia Semi-Prop Spain List PR Great Britain Majority Hungary Qvasi-Maj Mixed Slovenia Semi-Prop Germany Qvasi-Prop Mixed Canada Majority Japan Qvasi-Maj Mixed Australia Majority (Alt Vote) Belgium List PR Hong Kong Prop USA Majority Mexico Quasi-Maj Mixed Peru List PR Hong Kong Prop Romania List PR Korea Qvasi-Maj Mixed Taiwan Qvasi-Maj Mixed Belgium List PR Peru List PR Mexico Qvasi-Maj Mixed Belarus Majority N a 2001 Thailand Majority Note: Data on Electoral Systems are from the CSES macro data set. Data on effective threshold, disproportionality, effective number of parties and government stability is from Anckar (2003). = The effective number of parties is calculated from Herfindahl s index of concentration, 2 H i = p 1 i, where pi is the population proportion for group i of votes, where 1/H then is the effective number of parties. This measure has the pleasant feature that Eta 16 The parties, for which the perceptual agreement has been calculated, have been weighted according to the election results (percentages). 17 This variable does only refer to the degree of uni-dimensionality as such and is yet not specifically related to the left-right dimension, which it will be in the near future by a Spearman correlation between the ordering of the parties along the j-scale obtained from the unfolding analysis and the left-right ordering of the parties. For this reason it is not included in the analysis. 15

16 it will equal n when there are exactly n groups of size 1/n (Lijphart 1984: 120; Pennings 1999a: ) Polarization is a simple measure of the wing party distance, which is calculated as the difference between the means of the most leftist- and the most rightist parties 18 (see Gilljam & Oscarsson 1996). The left-right polarization is, thus, a first simple indicator of how successful an application of the left-right division is in a polity and an indicator on the degree of left-right competitiveness. The degree of proportionality has been calculated as the average deviation between the vote and the seat share of the two largest parties in each election (Pennings 1999a: 261). Dimensionality refers to the degree of uni-dimensionality and is computed with MUDFOLD 2.0, based on party evaluations where the respondents were asked to rate the parties on a scale from 0 to 10, where 0 means strongly dislike that party and 10 strongly like that party. Among the top-ten countries in table 1, nine have proportional systems, which must be regarded as a rather strong support for the hypothesis that proportional systems tend to induce ideological proximity voting. It is also evident that a high degree of perceptual agreement, with the exception of Spain and The Netherlands, seems to co-occur with a high amount of ideological issue voting. 19 A more elaborated analysis of the relationship between the institutional context and perceptual agreement confirms that voters under list proportional electoral systems tend to agree more over parties left-right positions (Average WPA=.51) than voters under majoritarian (Average WPA=.38) or mixed electoral systems (Average WPA=.38). The rather strong relationship between type of electoral system and perceptual agreement in table 2 (.48), is not very surprising since we expected that proportional electoral systems should facilitate the communication between parties and voters in terms of ideology. It was also expected that the left-right polarization should be highly correlated with perceptual agreement (r PAxWPD =.67). The greater left-right distance between the two flanking parties in a system, the higher are the levels of perceptual agreement over parties left-right positions. Obviously, polarized systems are promoting an effective representation since greater polarization seems to facilitate for voters to perceive parties ideological positions. 18 The highest levels of left-right polarization can be found in Czechoslovakia (WPD=8.33), Sweden (WPD=7.78) and Poland (WPD=6.49) (see table 3). In some other countries, the perceived left-right polarization is very low, indicating that the left-right distinction is not very important, alternatively that the terms left and right have no substantial meaning to voters, notably Hong- Kong (WPD=1.93), Taiwan (WPD=2.12), and Peru (WPD=2.35). Obviously, there are no parties in Peru that fit well into the categorization of party families used in the CSES, which indicates that the importance of the left-right distinction is negligible in the Peruan party system. Instead, religion seems to be the main ideological conflict. In Hong-Kong and Taiwan, parties compete mainly along a dimension pro-con mainland China. For these polities, left-right ideology is not a very appropriate measure of ideology, which may limit the scope of the following analyses. 19 A bivariate correlation between WPA and Eta yields a coefficient of.75, Pearson s r. 16

17 Table 2. Bivariate correlations between Weighted Perceptual Agreement and Type of Election System, Effective Threshold, Disproportionality, Effective Number of Parties, Wing Party Ideological Left-Right Distance (WPD) (Pearsons r and Eta). Perceptual Agreement Election System 1.48* Effective Threshold,-53** Disproportionality -.37 Effective # of Parties.11 Government Stablility.11 Wing Party Distance.67** Uni-dimensionality Election systems were coded for the CSES-categorization as 1 if majoritarian, 2 for Qvasi-maj, 3 for semi.prop. 4 for qvasi-prop, 5 for prop and 6 for List PR. Coefficient for Election System is Eta value. ** Correlation is significant at the 0.01 level (2-tailed). * Correlation is significant at the 0.05 level (2-tailed). ** Correlation is significant at the 0.01 level (2- tailed). The negative and significant correlation between effective threshold and PA supports the relationship between type of electoral system and PA as a high electoral threshold may have a similar effect on a party system as the majoritarian electoral formula by reducing the number of parties. The weak impact of the effective number of parties is in line with the simplicityhypothesis, since a complex party-system with a great number parties involved in the competition, should make it even harder for the voters to perceive their positions clearly, most likely the relationship is curve-linear as. According to the results in table 3, perceptual agreement seems to be promoted by party systems containing of approximately 2,5 to 5 effective number of parties (4.7 in average among the list-proportional countries). Thereafter, the PA are decreasing as the number of parties grows bigger. The degree of uni-dimensionality is positively co-varying with PA but the relationship is weak and insignificant. Reasonably because the results from the mudfold analysis are connected to the degree uni-dimensionality in general and is not specifically related to the left-right dimension as the PA-measure is. In table 3, we list the results from the logistic regression analyses performed within each polity available in the data set in order to examine the effect of ideological distance on the probability to vote for a party. We have sorted the data according to the overall fit of the regression model (Pseudo R 2 ). 17

18 Table 3 Effects of ideological left-right proximity on voting within different electoral systems (Logistic effects, Pseudo R 2 ) Election System (CSES) Voterparty dyads Logistic effect (b) Effective Inter- Year Country n cept 2002 Portugal List PR Ucraine Semi-Prop * Denmark List PR * Spain List PR Israel List PR * Sweden List PR Tjeckien List PR Hungary Qvasi-Maj * Iceland List PR * New Zeeland Quasi-Prop Canada Majority Norway List PR Switzerland List PR The Netherlands List PR Great Britain Majority Poland List PR Russia Semi-Prop Lithuania Semi-Prop * Spain List PR Australia Majority (Alt Germany Qvasi-Prop Slovenia Semi-Prop Belgium Flanders List PR Peru List PR Mexico Quasi-Maj Taiwan Qvasi-Maj * Romania List PR Korea Qvasi-Maj Belgium List PR *.00* 1997 Mexico Quasi-Maj *.00* All Countries Pseudo R 2 Note: Belarus, Hong-Kong, Japan, Peru (2000), Thailand and USA is excluded from the analysis, due to lack of data on both left-right self-placements and party-placements. * means that the coefficient is not significant (p>.05). As expected, there are significant and large negative bivariate effects of ideological distance on party choice in many of the countries where the left-right dimension is strong. The probability to vote for a party decreases with ideological distance. In concord with previous findings, the best model fit (Nagelkirkes maximum rescaled pseudo R 2 ) is found in Portugal, Ukraine, Denmark and Spain, whereas in Korea, Taiwan, Romania, Belgian Wallonia, Peru and Mexico, there are very small or non-existing effects of ideological left-right proximity on party choice. What about the effects of institutional contexts? Seven of the top ten countries in table 3 do have proportional list electoral systems, but there is no clear-cut association. In some non-proportional systems, the level of ideological left-right voting is very high, such as in Ukraina, Hungary and 18

19 New Zeeland. And there are a number of proportional systems where the levels of ideological left-right voting is very low, such as in Romania, Belgium and Peru. A more formal test of the impact of institutional context is of course possible. For all countries included in the study, we can model a multiplicative interaction effect of electoral system (0=nonproportional; 1=proportional) on the relationship between ideological proximity and probability to vote. The results show that there is a small but significant institutional effect on ideological voting, i.e. there is a larger negative effect of ideological distance on voting probability in proportional list systems than in non-proportional list systems. That the institutional effect is very small can be illustrated by the estimated probability functions in figure 1. Figure 1: Ideological Proximity x Probability to Vote in Proportional List Systems vs Semi-Proportional/Majoritarian Systems.,5,4,3,2,1 0, Note: Data are from CSES Module 1 (unweighted). The probabilites to vote are estimated from a logistic regression analysis of a stacked dataset (voter-party dyads). Only respondents voting for parties that were located on the leftright dimension is included in the analysis. The filled line represents the probability-to-vote curve among voters in proportional list systems. The dotted line represents the probability-to-vote curve proximity among voters in nonproportional list systems, i.e. semi-proportional/majoritarian systems. Figure 3 show the estimated probabilities to vote for parties that are located at different left-right distances from a voter. The probability curve is somewhat steeper in polities that have proportional list systems, i.e. the effects of ideological proximity are larger in proportional systems than in non-proportional systems. This simple analysis and the findings may not convince us that proportional list systems encourages ideological voting, but nevertheless give at least some support to the hypothesis. 19

Electoral Systems and Evaluations of Democracy

Electoral Systems and Evaluations of Democracy Chapter three Electoral Systems and Evaluations of Democracy André Blais and Peter Loewen Introduction Elections are a substitute for less fair or more violent forms of decision making. Democracy is based

More information

From Consensus to Competition? Ideological Alternatives on the EU Dimension

From Consensus to Competition? Ideological Alternatives on the EU Dimension Chapter 9 From Consensus to Competition? Ideological Alternatives on the EU Mikko Mattila and Tapio Raunio University of Helsinki and University of Tampere Abstract According to the literature on EP elections,

More information

Congruence in Political Parties

Congruence in Political Parties Descriptive Representation of Women and Ideological Congruence in Political Parties Georgia Kernell Northwestern University gkernell@northwestern.edu June 15, 2011 Abstract This paper examines the relationship

More information

parties and party systems

parties and party systems A/449268 classics Series Editor: Alan Ware University of Oxford parties and party systems a framework for analysis Giovanni Sartori with a new preface by the author and an introduction by Peter Mair contents

More information

Electoral Engineering & Turnout

Electoral Engineering & Turnout Electoral Engineering & Turnout Pippa Norris ~ UNDP Democratic Governance Details:www.undp.org/governance Electoral engineering 2 Structure I. Theoretical framework: Multilevel model of electoral turnout

More information

Do parties and voters pursue the same thing? Policy congruence between parties and voters on different electoral levels

Do parties and voters pursue the same thing? Policy congruence between parties and voters on different electoral levels Do parties and voters pursue the same thing? Policy congruence between parties and voters on different electoral levels Cees van Dijk, André Krouwel and Max Boiten 2nd European Conference on Comparative

More information

The Political Economy of Public Policy

The Political Economy of Public Policy The Political Economy of Public Policy Valentino Larcinese Electoral Rules & Policy Outcomes Electoral Rules Matter! Imagine a situation with two parties A & B and 99 voters. A has 55 supporters and B

More information

Networks and Innovation: Accounting for Structural and Institutional Sources of Recombination in Brokerage Triads

Networks and Innovation: Accounting for Structural and Institutional Sources of Recombination in Brokerage Triads 1 Online Appendix for Networks and Innovation: Accounting for Structural and Institutional Sources of Recombination in Brokerage Triads Sarath Balachandran Exequiel Hernandez This appendix presents a descriptive

More information

Polimetrics. Mass & Expert Surveys

Polimetrics. Mass & Expert Surveys Polimetrics Mass & Expert Surveys Three things I know about measurement Everything is measurable* Measuring = making a mistake (* true value is intangible and unknowable) Any measurement is better than

More information

Effect of Electoral Systems on the Quality of Political Representation

Effect of Electoral Systems on the Quality of Political Representation Martin Oost December 216 Faculty of Behavioural, Management and Social Sciences University of Twente Effect of Electoral Systems on the Quality of Political Representation Abstract: Legislatures as elected

More information

Chapter 4. Party Systems

Chapter 4. Party Systems Chapter 4 Party Systems Effective parties that work well can serve multiple functions in democracies: simplifying and structuring electoral choices; organizing and mobilizing campaigns; articulating and

More information

Introduction Why Don t Electoral Rules Have the Same Effects in All Countries?

Introduction Why Don t Electoral Rules Have the Same Effects in All Countries? Introduction Why Don t Electoral Rules Have the Same Effects in All Countries? In the early 1990s, Japan and Russia each adopted a very similar version of a mixed-member electoral system. In the form used

More information

CAN FAIR VOTING SYSTEMS REALLY MAKE A DIFFERENCE?

CAN FAIR VOTING SYSTEMS REALLY MAKE A DIFFERENCE? CAN FAIR VOTING SYSTEMS REALLY MAKE A DIFFERENCE? Facts and figures from Arend Lijphart s landmark study: Patterns of Democracy: Government Forms and Performance in Thirty-Six Countries Prepared by: Fair

More information

Sciences Po Grenoble working paper n.15

Sciences Po Grenoble working paper n.15 Sciences Po Grenoble working paper n.15 Manifestos and public opinion: a new test of the classic Downsian spatial model Raul Magni Berton, Univ. Grenoble Alpes, Sciences Po Grenoble, PACTE Sophie Panel,

More information

Long after it was proposed to be presented at IPSA 2014 World Congress it was approved for

Long after it was proposed to be presented at IPSA 2014 World Congress it was approved for Left-Right Ideology as a Dimension of Identification and as a Dimension of Competition André Freire Department of Political Science & Public Policies, ISCTE-IUL (Lisbon University Institute), Researcher

More information

Perceptions of Corruption in Mass Publics

Perceptions of Corruption in Mass Publics Perceptions of Corruption in Mass Publics Sören Holmberg QoG WORKING PAPER SERIES 2009:24 THE QUALITY OF GOVERNMENT INSTITUTE Department of Political Science University of Gothenburg Box 711 SE 405 30

More information

Party representation across multiple issue dimensions

Party representation across multiple issue dimensions Article Party representation across multiple issue dimensions Party Politics 1 14 ª The Author(s) 2015 Reprints and permission: sagepub.co.uk/journalspermissions.nav DOI: 10.1177/1354068815614515 ppq.sagepub.com

More information

The Extraordinary Extent of Cultural Consumption in Iceland

The Extraordinary Extent of Cultural Consumption in Iceland 1 Culture and Business Conference in Iceland February 18 2011 Prof. Dr. Ágúst Einarsson Bifröst University PP 1 The Extraordinary Extent of Cultural Consumption in Iceland Prof. Dr. Ágúst Einarsson, Bifröst

More information

When do parties emphasise extreme positions? How strategic incentives for policy

When do parties emphasise extreme positions? How strategic incentives for policy When do parties emphasise extreme positions? How strategic incentives for policy differentiation influence issue importance Markus Wagner, Department of Methods in the Social Sciences, University of Vienna

More information

Structure. Resource: Why important? Explanations. Explanations. Comparing Political Activism: Voter turnout. I. Overview.

Structure. Resource:  Why important? Explanations. Explanations. Comparing Political Activism: Voter turnout. I. Overview. 2 Structure Comparing Political Activism: Voter turnout I. Overview Core questions and theoretical framework Cultural modernization v. institutional context Implications? II. III. Evidence Turnout trends

More information

Party Identification and Party Choice

Party Identification and Party Choice THOMASSEN: The European Voter 05-Thomassen-chap05 Page Proof page 105 31.1.2005 7:52am 5 Party Identification and Party Choice Frode Berglund, Sören Holmberg, Hermann Schmitt, and Jacques Thomassen 5.1

More information

A Global Perspective on Socioeconomic Differences in Learning Outcomes

A Global Perspective on Socioeconomic Differences in Learning Outcomes 2009/ED/EFA/MRT/PI/19 Background paper prepared for the Education for All Global Monitoring Report 2009 Overcoming Inequality: why governance matters A Global Perspective on Socioeconomic Differences in

More information

Heather Stoll. July 30, 2014

Heather Stoll. July 30, 2014 Supplemental Materials for Elite Level Conflict Salience and Dimensionality in Western Europe: Concepts and Empirical Findings, West European Politics 33 (3) Heather Stoll July 30, 2014 This paper contains

More information

WORLDWIDE DISTRIBUTION OF PRIVATE FINANCIAL ASSETS

WORLDWIDE DISTRIBUTION OF PRIVATE FINANCIAL ASSETS WORLDWIDE DISTRIBUTION OF PRIVATE FINANCIAL ASSETS Munich, November 2018 Copyright Allianz 11/19/2018 1 MORE DYNAMIC POST FINANCIAL CRISIS Changes in the global wealth middle classes in millions 1,250

More information

Preferential votes and minority representation in open list proportional representation systems

Preferential votes and minority representation in open list proportional representation systems Soc Choice Welf (018) 50:81 303 https://doi.org/10.1007/s00355-017-1084- ORIGINAL PAPER Preferential votes and minority representation in open list proportional representation systems Margherita Negri

More information

How Electoral Systems Shape What Voters Think About Democracy

How Electoral Systems Shape What Voters Think About Democracy How Electoral Systems Shape What Voters Think About Democracy Christopher J. Anderson Department of Government 308 White Hall Cornell University Ithaca, NY 14853 christopher.anderson@cornell.edu Abstract

More information

Chapter 6 Online Appendix. general these issues do not cause significant problems for our analysis in this chapter. One

Chapter 6 Online Appendix. general these issues do not cause significant problems for our analysis in this chapter. One Chapter 6 Online Appendix Potential shortcomings of SF-ratio analysis Using SF-ratios to understand strategic behavior is not without potential problems, but in general these issues do not cause significant

More information

Value Orientations and Party Choice - A Comparative Longitudinal Study of Five Countries

Value Orientations and Party Choice - A Comparative Longitudinal Study of Five Countries Value Orientations and Party Choice - A Comparative Longitudinal Study of Five Countries by Oddbjørn Knutsen Department of Political Science, University of Oslo, and Staffan Kumlin, Department of Political

More information

Chapter 6. Party loyalties

Chapter 6. Party loyalties Chapter 6 Party loyalties Chapter 4 demonstrated the mechanical effects of the electoral rules upon party systems, but we know far less about their indirect psychological impact upon patterns of party

More information

LABOUR-MARKET INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS IN OECD-COUNTRIES: WHAT EXPLANATIONS FIT THE DATA?

LABOUR-MARKET INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS IN OECD-COUNTRIES: WHAT EXPLANATIONS FIT THE DATA? LABOUR-MARKET INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS IN OECD-COUNTRIES: WHAT EXPLANATIONS FIT THE DATA? By Andreas Bergh (PhD) Associate Professor in Economics at Lund University and the Research Institute of Industrial

More information

Income Distributions and the Relative Representation of Rich and Poor Citizens

Income Distributions and the Relative Representation of Rich and Poor Citizens Income Distributions and the Relative Representation of Rich and Poor Citizens Eric Guntermann Mikael Persson University of Gothenburg April 1, 2017 Abstract In this paper, we consider the impact of the

More information

Majority cycles in national elections

Majority cycles in national elections Majority cycles in national elections Bodo Knoll, Joan Serra 1 University of Bochum Abstract This paper provides information on cycle probabilities for 147 national elections and tests if a high level

More information

Structure. Electoral Systems. Recap:Normative debates. Discussion Questions. Resources. Electoral & party aid

Structure. Electoral Systems. Recap:Normative debates. Discussion Questions. Resources. Electoral & party aid Structure Electoral Systems Pippa Norris ~ Harvard I. Claims about electoral engineering II. The choice of electoral systems III. The effects of electoral systems IV. Conclusions and implications Recap:Normative

More information

The Determinants of Political Knowledge in Comparative Perspective

The Determinants of Political Knowledge in Comparative Perspective ISSN 0080 6757 2006 The Author(s) The Determinants of Political Knowledge in Comparative Perspective Kimmo Grönlund* and Henry Milner Political knowledge is a powerful predictor of political participation.

More information

INFORMATION SHEETS: 2

INFORMATION SHEETS: 2 INFORMATION SHEETS: 2 EFFECTS OF ELECTORAL SYSTEMS ON WOMEN S REPRESENTATION For the National Association of Women and the Law For the National Roundtable on Women and Politics 2003 March 22 nd ~ 23 rd,

More information

Parliamentary Election Turnout in Europe since 1990

Parliamentary Election Turnout in Europe since 1990 POLITICAL STUDIES: 2002 VOL 50, 916 927 Parliamentary Election Turnout in Europe since 1990 Alan Siaroff University of Lethbridge John W. A. Merer Vanderbilt University This article examines the cross-national

More information

Ballots not Bullets. Ethnic Conflict & Electoral Systems Pippa Norris KSG Harvard University

Ballots not Bullets. Ethnic Conflict & Electoral Systems Pippa Norris KSG Harvard University Ballots not Bullets Ethnic Conflict & Electoral Systems Pippa Norris KSG Harvard University Do systems reduce ethnic conflict? I. Theory: Consociational democracy Arend Lijphart II. Evidence: CSES 12 nation

More information

Output Oriented Legitimacy: Individual and System-level Influences on Democracy Satisfaction

Output Oriented Legitimacy: Individual and System-level Influences on Democracy Satisfaction Chapter 13 Output Oriented Legitimacy: Individual and System-level Influences on Democracy Satisfaction David Sanders, Harold Clarke, Marianne Stewart and Paul Whiteley Chapter prepared for inclusion in

More information

Citizens representation in the 2009 European Parliament elections

Citizens representation in the 2009 European Parliament elections Article Citizens representation in the 2009 European Parliament elections European Union Politics 0(0) 1 24! The Author(s) 2017 Reprints and permissions: sagepub.co.uk/journalspermissions.nav DOI: 10.1177/1465116516689729

More information

Analysis of public opinion on Macedonia s accession to Author: Ivan Damjanovski

Analysis of public opinion on Macedonia s accession to Author: Ivan Damjanovski Analysis of public opinion on Macedonia s accession to the European Union 2014-2016 Author: Ivan Damjanovski CONCLUSIONS 3 The trends regarding support for Macedonia s EU membership are stable and follow

More information

And Yet it Moves: The Effect of Election Platforms on Party. Policy Images

And Yet it Moves: The Effect of Election Platforms on Party. Policy Images And Yet it Moves: The Effect of Election Platforms on Party Policy Images Pablo Fernandez-Vazquez * Supplementary Online Materials [ Forthcoming in Comparative Political Studies ] These supplementary materials

More information

UC Irvine CSD Working Papers

UC Irvine CSD Working Papers UC Irvine CSD Working Papers Title Voter Satisfaction and Electoral Systems: Does Preferential Voting in Candidate-Centered Systems Make A Difference Permalink https://escholarship.org/uc/item/4c51z9mt

More information

Voter Turnout, Income Inequality, and Redistribution. Henning Finseraas PhD student Norwegian Social Research

Voter Turnout, Income Inequality, and Redistribution. Henning Finseraas PhD student Norwegian Social Research Voter Turnout, Income Inequality, and Redistribution Henning Finseraas PhD student Norwegian Social Research hfi@nova.no Introduction Motivation Robin Hood paradox No robust effect of voter turnout on

More information

Challenges to established parties: The effects of party system features on the electoral fortunes of anti-political-establishment parties

Challenges to established parties: The effects of party system features on the electoral fortunes of anti-political-establishment parties European Journal of Political Research 41: 551 583, 2002 551 Challenges to established parties: The effects of party system features on the electoral fortunes of anti-political-establishment parties AMIR

More information

Methodological and Substantive Issues in Analyses of a Dependent Nominal-Level Variable in Comparative Research. The Case of Party Choice

Methodological and Substantive Issues in Analyses of a Dependent Nominal-Level Variable in Comparative Research. The Case of Party Choice 1 Methodological and Substantive Issues in Analyses of a Dependent Nominal-Level Variable in Comparative Research The Case of Party Choice Oddbjørn Knutsen Department of Political Science University of

More information

DISSATISFIED DEMOCRATS

DISSATISFIED DEMOCRATS DISSATISFIED DEMOCRATS A Matter of Representation or Performance? STEFAN DAHLBERG JONAS LINDE SÖREN HOLMBERG WORKING PAPER SERIES 2013:8 QOG THE QUALITY OF GOVERNMENT INSTITUTE Department of Political

More information

Political Sophistication and Third-Party Voting in Recent Presidential Elections

Political Sophistication and Third-Party Voting in Recent Presidential Elections Political Sophistication and Third-Party Voting in Recent Presidential Elections Christopher N. Lawrence Department of Political Science Duke University April 3, 2006 Overview During the 1990s, minor-party

More information

Tzu-chiao Su Chinese Culture University, Taiwan

Tzu-chiao Su Chinese Culture University, Taiwan The Effect of Electoral System and Election Timing on Party System and Government Type: a Cross-Country Study of Presidential and Semi-presidential Democracies Tzu-chiao Su Chinese Culture University,

More information

NEW YORK UNIVERSITY Department of Politics V COMPARATIVE POLITICS Spring Michael Laver. Tel:

NEW YORK UNIVERSITY Department of Politics V COMPARATIVE POLITICS Spring Michael Laver. Tel: NEW YORK UNIVERSITY Department of Politics V52.0510 COMPARATIVE POLITICS Spring 2006 Michael Laver Tel: 212-998-8534 Email: ml127@nyu.edu COURSE OBJECTIVES The central reason for the comparative study

More information

Political Sophistication and Third-Party Voting in Recent Presidential Elections

Political Sophistication and Third-Party Voting in Recent Presidential Elections Political Sophistication and Third-Party Voting in Recent Presidential Elections Christopher N. Lawrence Department of Political Science Duke University April 3, 2006 Overview During the 1990s, minor-party

More information

The effects of party membership decline

The effects of party membership decline The effects of party membership decline - A cross-sectional examination of the implications of membership decline on political trust in Europe Bachelor Thesis in Political Science Spring 2016 Sara Persson

More information

The Issue Voting Triangle: The Role of Voter Salience, Party Conflict and Issue Linkage in Issue Voting

The Issue Voting Triangle: The Role of Voter Salience, Party Conflict and Issue Linkage in Issue Voting The Issue Voting Triangle: The Role of Voter Salience, Party Conflict and Issue Linkage in Issue Voting Catherine E. de Vries Department of Political Science University of Amsterdam c.e.devries@uva.nl

More information

Migration and Integration

Migration and Integration Migration and Integration Integration in Education Education for Integration Istanbul - 13 October 2017 Francesca Borgonovi Senior Analyst - Migration and Gender Directorate for Education and Skills, OECD

More information

EMPIRICAL AND NORMATIVE MODELS OF VOTERS, PARTIES, AND GOVERNMENTS

EMPIRICAL AND NORMATIVE MODELS OF VOTERS, PARTIES, AND GOVERNMENTS EMPIRICAL AND NORMATIVE MODELS OF VOTERS, PARTIES, AND GOVERNMENTS Subject Area Political representation, Voter behaviour, Voting choice, Democratic support, Political institutions Abstract This workshop

More information

South Africa - A publisher s perspective. STM/PASA conference 11 June, 2012, Cape Town Mayur Amin, SVP Research & Academic Relations

South Africa - A publisher s perspective. STM/PASA conference 11 June, 2012, Cape Town Mayur Amin, SVP Research & Academic Relations South Africa - A publisher s perspective STM/PASA conference 11 June, 2012, Cape Town Mayur Amin, SVP Research & Academic Relations 0 As a science information company, we have a unique vantage point on

More information

PISA 2006 PERFORMANCE OF ESTONIA. Introduction. Imbi Henno, Maie Kitsing

PISA 2006 PERFORMANCE OF ESTONIA. Introduction. Imbi Henno, Maie Kitsing PISA 2006 PERFORMANCE OF ESTONIA Imbi Henno, Maie Kitsing Introduction The OECD Programme for International Student Assessment (PISA) was administered in Estonian schools for the first time in April 2006.

More information

Partisan Nation: The Rise of Affective Partisan Polarization in the American Electorate

Partisan Nation: The Rise of Affective Partisan Polarization in the American Electorate Partisan Nation: The Rise of Affective Partisan Polarization in the American Electorate Alan I. Abramowitz Department of Political Science Emory University Abstract Partisan conflict has reached new heights

More information

Consideration Sets for Party Choice: Size, Content, Stability and Relevance

Consideration Sets for Party Choice: Size, Content, Stability and Relevance 2015 Gothenburg 2015-04-16 Consideration Sets for Party Choice: Size, Content, Stability and Relevance Maria Oskarson, Henrik Oscarsson & Edvin Boije Report 2015:01 Swedish National Election Studies Program

More information

Are representatives in some democracies more

Are representatives in some democracies more Ideological Congruence and Electoral Institutions Matt Golder Jacek Stramski Florida State University Florida State University Although the literature examining the relationship between ideological congruence

More information

3.3 DETERMINANTS OF THE CULTURAL INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS

3.3 DETERMINANTS OF THE CULTURAL INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS 1 Duleep (2015) gives a general overview of economic assimilation. Two classic articles in the United States are Chiswick (1978) and Borjas (1987). Eckstein Weiss (2004) studies the integration of immigrants

More information

NEW YORK UNIVERSITY Department of Politics. V COMPARATIVE POLITICS Spring Michael Laver Tel:

NEW YORK UNIVERSITY Department of Politics. V COMPARATIVE POLITICS Spring Michael Laver Tel: NEW YORK UNIVERSITY Department of Politics V52.0500 COMPARATIVE POLITICS Spring 2007 Michael Laver Tel: 212-998-8534 Email: ml127@nyu.edu COURSE OBJECTIVES We study politics in a comparative context to

More information

THE U.S. POLITICAL SYSTEM AND THE 2014 MIDTERM ELECTION. Hans Noel Georgetown University bit.ly/hansnoel

THE U.S. POLITICAL SYSTEM AND THE 2014 MIDTERM ELECTION. Hans Noel Georgetown University bit.ly/hansnoel THE U.S. POLITICAL SYSTEM AND THE 2014 MIDTERM ELECTION Hans Noel Georgetown University bit.ly/hansnoel hcn4@georgetown.edu @ProfHansNoel THE U.S. POLITICAL SYSTEM AND THE 2014 MIDTERM ELECTION 1. The

More information

BCGEU surveyed its own members on electoral reform. They reported widespread disaffection with the current provincial electoral system.

BCGEU surveyed its own members on electoral reform. They reported widespread disaffection with the current provincial electoral system. BCGEU SUBMISSION ON THE ELECTORAL REFORM REFERENDUM OF 2018 February, 2018 The BCGEU applauds our government s commitment to allowing British Columbians a direct say in how they vote. As one of the largest

More information

Anti-immigrant parties in Europe: Ideological or protest vote?

Anti-immigrant parties in Europe: Ideological or protest vote? European Journal of Political Research 37: 77 102, 2000. 2000Kluwer Academic Publishers. Printed in the Netherlands. 77 Anti-immigrant parties in Europe: Ideological or protest vote? WOUTER VAN DER BRUG

More information

Political Participation under Democracy

Political Participation under Democracy Political Participation under Democracy Daniel Justin Kleinschmidt Cpr. Nr.: POL-PST.XB December 19 th, 2012 Political Science, Bsc. Semester 1 International Business & Politics Question: 2 Total Number

More information

The evolution of turnout in European elections from 1979 to 2009

The evolution of turnout in European elections from 1979 to 2009 The evolution of turnout in European elections from 1979 to 2009 Nicola Maggini 7 April 2014 1 The European elections to be held between 22 and 25 May 2014 (depending on the country) may acquire, according

More information

Party Identification and the Vote. Six European Countries Compared

Party Identification and the Vote. Six European Countries Compared Party Identification and the Vote Six European Countries Compared by Frode Berglund, ISR Oslo Sören Holmberg, University of Gothenburg Hermann Schmitt, MZES, University of Mannheim Jacques Thomassen, University

More information

Improving the accuracy of outbound tourism statistics with mobile positioning data

Improving the accuracy of outbound tourism statistics with mobile positioning data 1 (11) Improving the accuracy of outbound tourism statistics with mobile positioning data Survey response rates are declining at an alarming rate globally. Statisticians have traditionally used imputing

More information

Rankings: Universities vs. National Higher Education Systems. Benoit Millot

Rankings: Universities vs. National Higher Education Systems. Benoit Millot Rankings: Universities vs. National Higher Education Systems Benoit Millot Outline 1. Background 2. Methodology 3. Results 4. Discussion 11/8/ 2 1. Background 11/8/ 3 Clear Shift Background: Leagues focus

More information

Party identification, electoral utilities, and voting choice

Party identification, electoral utilities, and voting choice Party identification, electoral utilities, and voting choice Romain Lachat Institute of Political Science, University of Zurich lachat@pwi.unizh.ch First draft comments are welcome Paper prepared for the

More information

Equity and Excellence in Education from International Perspectives

Equity and Excellence in Education from International Perspectives Equity and Excellence in Education from International Perspectives HGSE Special Topic Seminar Pasi Sahlberg Spring 2015 @pasi_sahlberg Evolution of Equity in Education 1960s: The Coleman Report 1970s:

More information

The Formation of National Party Systems Does it happen with age? Brandon Amash

The Formation of National Party Systems Does it happen with age? Brandon Amash The Formation of National Party Systems Does it happen with age? Brandon Amash A Senior Honors Thesis Submitted to The Department of Political Science University of California, San Diego March 31, 214

More information

MODELLING EXISTING SURVEY DATA FULL TECHNICAL REPORT OF PIDOP WORK PACKAGE 5

MODELLING EXISTING SURVEY DATA FULL TECHNICAL REPORT OF PIDOP WORK PACKAGE 5 MODELLING EXISTING SURVEY DATA FULL TECHNICAL REPORT OF PIDOP WORK PACKAGE 5 Ian Brunton-Smith Department of Sociology, University of Surrey, UK 2011 The research reported in this document was supported

More information

Representation in Context: Election Laws and Ideological Congruence

Representation in Context: Election Laws and Ideological Congruence Representation in Context: Election Laws and Ideological Congruence Between Citizens and Governments 1 G. Bingham Powell, Jr. Democratic theory assumes that successful democratic representation will create

More information

PERCEPTIONS, OPINIONS AND PARTY PREFERENCES IN THE FACE OF A REAL WORLD EVENT

PERCEPTIONS, OPINIONS AND PARTY PREFERENCES IN THE FACE OF A REAL WORLD EVENT Journal of Theoretical Politics 13(1): 53 80 Copyright 2001 Sage Publications 0951 6928[2001/01]13:1; 53 80; 015303 London, Thousand Oaks, CA and New Delhi PERCEPTIONS, OPINIONS AND PARTY PREFERENCES IN

More information

GERMANY, JAPAN AND INTERNATIONAL PAYMENT IMBALANCES

GERMANY, JAPAN AND INTERNATIONAL PAYMENT IMBALANCES Articles Articles Articles Articles Articles CENTRAL EUROPEAN REVIEW OF ECONOMICS & FINANCE Vol. 2, No. 1 (2012) pp. 5-18 Slawomir I. Bukowski* GERMANY, JAPAN AND INTERNATIONAL PAYMENT IMBALANCES Abstract

More information

Voting polarization on redistribution across democracies. John D. Huber Piero Stanig

Voting polarization on redistribution across democracies. John D. Huber Piero Stanig Voting polarization on redistribution across democracies John D. Huber Piero Stanig Department of Political Science Columbia University New York, NY 10027 Abstract. We explore how the social and political

More information

LEVELING THE PLAYING FIELD: ELECTORAL THRESHOLDS AND THE REPRESENTATION OF WOMEN TRACY QUINLAN GENERAL SITUATION OF WOMEN IN PARLIAMENTS

LEVELING THE PLAYING FIELD: ELECTORAL THRESHOLDS AND THE REPRESENTATION OF WOMEN TRACY QUINLAN GENERAL SITUATION OF WOMEN IN PARLIAMENTS LEVELING THE PLAYING FIELD: ELECTORAL THRESHOLDS AND THE REPRESENTATION OF WOMEN TRACY QUINLAN There are large cross-national differences in the percentage of women in legislatures. Institutional arrangement

More information

QGIS.org - Donations and Sponsorship Analysis 2016

QGIS.org - Donations and Sponsorship Analysis 2016 QGIS.org - Donations and Sponsorship Analysis 2016 QGIS.ORG received 1128 donations and 47 sponsorships. This equals to >3 donations every day and almost one new or renewed sponsorship every week. The

More information

European Parliament Elections and Political Representation: Policy Congruence between Voters and Parties

European Parliament Elections and Political Representation: Policy Congruence between Voters and Parties West European Politics, Vol. 35, No. 6, 1226 1248, November 2012 European Parliament Elections and Political Representation: Policy Congruence between Voters and Parties RORY COSTELLO, JACQUES THOMASSEN

More information

BRAND. Cross-national evidence on the relationship between education and attitudes towards immigrants: Past initiatives and.

BRAND. Cross-national evidence on the relationship between education and attitudes towards immigrants: Past initiatives and. Cross-national evidence on the relationship between education and attitudes towards immigrants: Past initiatives and future OECD directions EMPLOYER BRAND Playbook Promoting Tolerance: Can education do

More information

EUROBAROMETER 62 PUBLIC OPINION IN THE EUROPEAN UNION

EUROBAROMETER 62 PUBLIC OPINION IN THE EUROPEAN UNION Standard Eurobarometer European Commission EUROBAROMETER 62 PUBLIC OPINION IN THE EUROPEAN UNION AUTUMN 2004 NATIONAL REPORT Standard Eurobarometer 62 / Autumn 2004 TNS Opinion & Social IRELAND The survey

More information

Main findings of the joint EC/OECD seminar on Naturalisation and the Socio-economic Integration of Immigrants and their Children

Main findings of the joint EC/OECD seminar on Naturalisation and the Socio-economic Integration of Immigrants and their Children MAIN FINDINGS 15 Main findings of the joint EC/OECD seminar on Naturalisation and the Socio-economic Integration of Immigrants and their Children Introduction Thomas Liebig, OECD Main findings of the joint

More information

Mass-Elite Perceptions of the Policy Space: a Comparison between Norway and Sweden

Mass-Elite Perceptions of the Policy Space: a Comparison between Norway and Sweden Paper for presentation at the workshop Estimating Policy Positions of Political Actors at the ECPR Joint Sessions of Workshops, Mannheim, March 26-31 1999. Mass-Elite Perceptions of the Policy Space: a

More information

Working Paper No 51, 2009

Working Paper No 51, 2009 CIS Working Paper No 51, 2009 Published by the Center for Comparative and International Studies (ETH Zurich and University of Zurich) Is Left Right from Circleland? The issue basis of citizens ideological

More information

Civil and Political Rights

Civil and Political Rights DESIRED OUTCOMES All people enjoy civil and political rights. Mechanisms to regulate and arbitrate people s rights in respect of each other are trustworthy. Civil and Political Rights INTRODUCTION The

More information

OECD Strategic Education Governance A perspective for Scotland. Claire Shewbridge 25 October 2017 Edinburgh

OECD Strategic Education Governance A perspective for Scotland. Claire Shewbridge 25 October 2017 Edinburgh OECD Strategic Education Governance A perspective for Scotland Claire Shewbridge 25 October 2017 Edinburgh CERI overview What CERI does Generate forward-looking research analyses and syntheses Identify

More information

SKILLS, MOBILITY, AND GROWTH

SKILLS, MOBILITY, AND GROWTH SKILLS, MOBILITY, AND GROWTH Eric Hanushek Ludger Woessmann Ninth Biennial Federal Reserve System Community Development Research Conference April 2-3, 2015 Washington, DC Commitment to Achievement Growth

More information

Poznan July The vulnerability of the European Elite System under a prolonged crisis

Poznan July The vulnerability of the European Elite System under a prolonged crisis Very Very Preliminary Draft IPSA 24 th World Congress of Political Science Poznan 23-28 July 2016 The vulnerability of the European Elite System under a prolonged crisis Maurizio Cotta (CIRCaP- University

More information

Politically Competent Citizens: The Role of Predispositions and Political Context in Comparative Perspective

Politically Competent Citizens: The Role of Predispositions and Political Context in Comparative Perspective Politically Competent Citizens: The Role of Predispositions and Political Context in Comparative Perspective By Sebastian Adrian Popa Submitted to Central European University Doctoral School of Political

More information

New York County Lawyers Association Continuing Legal Education Institute 14 Vesey Street, New York, N.Y (212)

New York County Lawyers Association Continuing Legal Education Institute 14 Vesey Street, New York, N.Y (212) New York County Lawyers Association Continuing Legal Education Institute 14 Vesey Street, New York, N.Y. 10007 (212) 267-6646 Who is Who in the Global Economy And Why it Matters June 20, 2014; 6:00 PM-6:50

More information

The Integer Arithmetic of Legislative Dynamics

The Integer Arithmetic of Legislative Dynamics The Integer Arithmetic of Legislative Dynamics Kenneth Benoit Trinity College Dublin Michael Laver New York University July 8, 2005 Abstract Every legislature may be defined by a finite integer partition

More information

Conditions of Positional Policy Congruence. Kathrin Thomas, University of Exeter

Conditions of Positional Policy Congruence. Kathrin Thomas, University of Exeter Conditions of Positional Policy Congruence Kathrin Thomas, University of Exeter kt270@exeter.ac.uk This is a draft paper. Comments most welcome. Please do not cite without permission from the author. Paper

More information

Bringing democracy back in: When democracy matters for citizens

Bringing democracy back in: When democracy matters for citizens Bringing democracy back in: When democracy matters for citizens Irene Palacios Brihuega (Irene.Palacios@eui.eu) European University Institute, Florence Paper for presentation at the WAPOR Regional Conference

More information

Religious Voting and Class Voting in. 24 European Countries. A Comparative Study

Religious Voting and Class Voting in. 24 European Countries. A Comparative Study 0 Religious Voting and Class Voting in 24 European Countries A Comparative Study Oddbjørn Knutsen Department of Political Science, University of Oslo Paper prepared for presentation at the XVII International

More information

So Close But So Far: Voting Propensity and Party Choice for Left-Wing Parties

So Close But So Far: Voting Propensity and Party Choice for Left-Wing Parties (2010) Swiss Political Science Review 16(3): 373 402 So Close But So Far: Voting Propensity and Party Choice for Left-Wing Parties Daniel Bochsler and Pascal Sciarini Central European University Budapest

More information

Styles of representation, policy congruence and expectations about. This is a draft, please do not cite without permission of the author

Styles of representation, policy congruence and expectations about. This is a draft, please do not cite without permission of the author Title: Styles of representation, policy congruence and expectations about democracy: Parties and party voters Author: Eva H. Önnudóttir PhD student CDSS, Mannheim University Email: eva.onnudottir@gess.uni-mannheim.de

More information

Pre-Electoral Coalitions in Comparative Perspective: A Test of Existing Hypotheses

Pre-Electoral Coalitions in Comparative Perspective: A Test of Existing Hypotheses Pre-Electoral Coalitions in Comparative Perspective: A Test of Existing Hypotheses Sona Nadenichek Golder Florida State University 2005 Electoral Studies, Vol. 24. Abstract Despite the vast coalition literature,

More information

Elections and referendums

Elections and referendums Caramani (ed.) Comparative Politics Section III: Structures and institutions Chapter 10: Elections and referendums by Michael Gallagher (1/1) Elections and referendums are the two main voting opportunities

More information

The Importance of Left-Right Orientations in the New Democracies

The Importance of Left-Right Orientations in the New Democracies The Importance of Left-Right Orientations in the New Democracies Gabriel Badescu (Babe-Bolyai University, Romania) & Paul E. Sum (University of North Dakota, U.S.A.) 1. Draft Paper prepared for Presentation

More information