RACE AND TURNOUT IN U.S. ELECTIONS EXPOSING HIDDEN EFFECTS

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "RACE AND TURNOUT IN U.S. ELECTIONS EXPOSING HIDDEN EFFECTS"

Transcription

1 Public Opinion Quarterly, Vol. 74, No. 2, Summer 2010, pp RACE AND TURNOUT IN U.S. ELECTIONS EXPOSING HIDDEN EFFECTS BENJAMIN J. DEUFEL ORIT KEDAR* Abstract We demonstrate that the use of self-reported data often results in misleading inferences about racial differences in. We theorize about the mechanism driving report of and, utilizing ANES data in presidential elections from 1976 to 1988 (all years for which comparable validated data are available), we empirically model report of as well as the relationship between reported and actual. We apply the model to the two subsequent presidential elections in which validated data are not available, 1992 and Our findings suggest that African Americans turned out almost 20 percentage points less than did Whites in the 1992 and 1996 U.S. presidential elections almost double the gap that the self-reported data indicates. In contrast with previous research, we show that racial differences in factors predicting make African Americans less likely to vote compared to Whites and thus increase their probability of overreporting. At the same time, when controlling for this effect, other things equal, African Americans overreport electoral participation more than Whites. BENJAMIN J. DEUFEL directs quantitative analysis for the Financial Services Practice at the Corporate Executive Board, Arlington, VA, USA. ORIT KEDAR is an Associate Professor in the Department of Political Science at the Massachusetts Institute of Technology, Cambridge, MA, USA, and the Hebrew University of Jerusalem, Jerusalem, Israel. Benjamin Deufel benefited from financial support by the Jacob K. Javits Fellowship Program of the U.S. Department of Education and the Multidisciplinary Program in Inequality and Social Policy at Harvard University, sponsored by the National Science Foundation. Orit Kedar benefited from the V.O.K. Fellowship and Dellon Fellowship, Harvard University. The authors would like to thank the Center for American Political Studies at Harvard University for a seed grant. For helpful comments and suggestions, they thank Chris Achen, Barry Burden, Don Green, Jonathan Katz, Gary King, Matthew Lebo, Skip Lupia, Jonathan Nagler, Ken Scheve, Nick Valentino, Lynn Vavreck, and Jonathan Wand. They also thank Greg Distelhorst and Mike Sances for superb research assistance. Accompanying materials can be found on the authors Web site at okedar/www/. *Address correspondence to Orit Kedar, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, Department of Political Science, 77 Massachusetts Ave., E53-429, Cambridge, MA 02139, USA; okedar@mit.edu. doi: /poq/nfq017 Advance Access publication April 22, 2010 The Author Published by Oxford University Press on behalf of the American Association for Public Opinion Research. All rights reserved. For permissions, please journals.permissions@oxfordjournals.org

2 Race and Turnout in U.S. Elections 287 Introduction The question Who votes? has been the focus of numerous studies. Out of both positive and normative motivations, political scientists have examined voter over time, across electoral institutions, and across segments of the population. For the most part, however, the secret ballot prevents political scientists from observing what we seek to explain; we know who reports voting in surveys, but we do not know who actually votes. The vast majority of studies simply assume that the missing piece individual is identical to the observed piece self-reported. In the absence of any further information, this is, of course, a reasonable assumption. However, auxiliary information reveals not only that a substantial proportion of American survey respondents report turning out when they do not, but also that their propensity to misreport is related to their propensity to vote, which may lead to mistaken inferences. Two steps are thus required in order to explain who votes. First, we need to comprehend the mechanism that drives the observed piece reported. And second, the relationship between the observed and unobserved, reported and actual, should be modeled. Although much energy has been focused on the former, the latter has been largely ignored. In this study, we take up this challenge, focusing on racial differences in. Numerous studies provide evidence that African Americans overreport at higher rates than Whites. Building on these studies, we develop a theoretical account that explicitly models both the reporting process and its relationship to actual. We employ this theory to model the relationship between and report of in those years in which the two are available at the individual level. We contend that African Americans overreport their more than Whites for two reasons. First, African Americans overreport more because they simply have more of an opportunity to do so. Group differences in other predictors of, such as socioeconomic status, cause African Americans to be less likely to turn out compared to Whites, and a lower propensity to vote actually makes African Americans more likely to overreport. Furthermore, holding constant other predictors of, African Americans still overreport more than Whites. We argue that, because of the importance of race in American politics and elections in particular, the social desirability of voting is higher for African Americans. After establishing our theory empirically, we employ it to deflate selfreported figures in the 1990s where validated data are not available. Our findings suggest that throughout the 1980s and 1990s, the overreporting bias in self-reports masks a large gap between Whites and African Americans. On the other hand, this gap narrows considerably after accounting for other predictors of.

3 288 Deufel and Kedar Finally, a side benefit of our venture to expose hidden effects is methodological. Modeling the relationship between validated and self-reported in the 1970s and 1980s, we produce a function that probabilistically deflates reported. We test the performance of our deflating function and show that our algorithm predicts more accurately than self-reports. WHAT WE KNOW (AND DON T KNOW) ABOUT OVERREPORTING Studies of voter are in agreement that misreporting of exists and is almost entirely in one direction. The fraction of respondents voting but reporting they did not ( underreporters ) is negligible and, importantly, these discrepancies are usually random (Silver, Anderson, and Abramson 1986; Presser and Traugott 1992). Overreporting of is different: it is of substantial magnitude and, most students of voting behavior agree, it is systematically related to voters characteristics. However, several issues make it difficult to develop theories about the relationship between self-reports (R) and verified (V). The appropriate quantities of interest, the mechanism that generates overreporting, and the substantive effects of overreporting are all disputed in the literature. While these issues are mostly empirical, they muddle the theoretical waters. Before we outline our theory, we need to first wrestle with these issues. The first hurdle is determining the population of interest, as choices on this front may change inferences about the nature of overreporting. Focusing on overreporting as their ultimate variable of interest, some (e.g., Silver et al., 1986) argue that overreporting should be calculated among nonvoters only, the actual group at risk of overreporting. Another advantage of this procedure is that it controls for rate. Given our motivation, however, a different strategy is in order. Because our goal is to explain voter rather than overreporting, we estimate the hypothetical probability of all respondents to overreport. In line with standard treatment of binary variables (Greene 1993, pp ), we acknowledge that every observed binary variable (here, both validated and reported ) is a realization of an unobserved continuous proclivity (a probability of actually turning out, and a probability of reporting turning out). Therefore, every individual has both an underlying unobserved probability, and a realization the observed binary outcome. Whether they turned out or not, it is possible for an individual to have a probability of turning out of, say, 0.65, and a probability of reporting of, say, Thus, the relevant group by which we calculate overreporting of is the general voting-eligible population, and in the sample, the entire group of respondents eligible to vote. The second hurdle is understanding the sources of systematic components of overreporting. The standard argument, perhaps most clearly represented in

4 Race and Turnout in U.S. Elections 289 Silver et al. (1986), employs the concept of social desirability. The basic idea is that respondents report their behavior untruthfully because they wish to portray themselves as engaged in a socially desirable activity. This wish is unevenly felt across respondents; the very factors that make respondents likely to vote also reinforce their desire to portray themselves as voters, regardless of their actual behavior. 1 Thus, those who are more likely to vote are more likely to misreport when they did not actually participate. 2 This argument implies that the use of self-reported (R) data will lead to overestimation of partial correlations with regard to (Cassel 2003). For example, if education makes people both more likely to vote and more likely to exaggerate the extent of their participation, use of R will result in overestimation of the effect of education on the propensity to turn out. Indeed, Presser and Traugott (1992) show that, using R, political scientists overestimate partial correlations with regard to. Nonetheless, Sigelman (1982) argues that substantive conclusions about the predictors of voting, despite biased coefficients, are mostly unchanged by the use of validated as opposed to reported voting data. Racial effects are a seeming exception to this general pattern. Repeated studies have shown that African Americans are more likely to overreport than Whites, despite possibly being less likely to turn out (Sigelman 1982; Hill and Hurley 1984; Bernstein, Chadha, and Montjoy 2001). In a series of articles, Abramson and Claggett (1984, 1986, 1989, 1991) find that although selfreported data indicate no racial difference in after accounting for education and region, use of validated data reveals otherwise. In other words, African Americans overreport at higher rates, yet are less likely to turn out compared to Whites. These two gaps in opposite directions mask each other, leading researchers using R to underestimate the effect of race on and often conclude that there is no relationship or even that African Americans turn out at higher rates than Whites do. 3 While much attention has been dedicated to empirical descriptions of this pattern, to our knowledge there has been no attempt to model how the relationship between and reported varies by race. Doing so allows 1. In the only comparative study of overreporting we are aware of, Karp and Brockington (2005) make a distinction between social desirability and opportunity of overreporting. Examining overreporting in Britain, New Zealand, Norway, Sweden, and the United States, the authors show that where is high, social desirability is higher as well, yet high also leaves fewer nonvoters with the opportunity to overreport their participation. 2. Bernstein, Chadha, and Montjoy (2001) propose an alternate possibility. They argue that respondents misreport out of guilt from failure to fulfill a social obligation. 3. A review of the APSR, AJPS, JOP, and Political Behavior between 1993 and 2008 for studies estimating in U.S. presidential elections, employing individual-level data, and having race on the right-hand side yielded 13 studies; among them, five found no effect of race on, two found mixed effect, and among the six which found an effect, five found that African Americans were more likely to participate than Whites.

5 290 Deufel and Kedar us to understand how differential overreporting affects our inference of racial differences in. It is to this task that we now turn. Explaining the Reporting Gap: Two Mechanisms We expect the impact of social desirability to be nonlinear, where overreporting first increases and then decreases with propensity to vote. Those with the highest likelihood of voting have low levels of overreporting because they often actually do turn out. Those respondents who are moderately likely to turn out are those who overreport at the highest rates. They turn out at the polls less often than do those most likely to vote, which gives them more of an opportunity to overreport (for similar intuition, see also McDonald 2003, p. 185). These mid-range potential voters feel a greater need to report socially desirable behavior than those with a low likelihood of voting, and thus their level of overreporting is also higher than that of those who vote at low rates. In sum, opportunity to overreport, along with social desirability, produces a nonlinear relationship between propensity to vote and overreporting. Figure 1 graphically illustrates this relationship. Let us begin by examining curve I only. The top panel (panel A) presents the probability of turning out on the horizontal axis against the probability of overreporting on the vertical axis. This curve graphically presents the social desirability argument we discussed above. It asserts that as the probability of voting increases, the tendency to overreport, measured vertically, first increases and then decreases. (If one voted for sure, she has no chance of overreporting, and if we assume that people do not underreport, someone with zero probability of reporting having voted has an identical probability of actually voting.) If curve I holds for everyone in the population, the effect of race on reporting should diminish as more factors that account for the tendency to turn out are included in the analysis. In other words, any potential racial difference in overreporting is a product of opportunity and social desirability (on-the-curve effect). Panel B (still curve I) presents the latent propensity of turning out on the horizontal axis and the respondent s latent propensity to report having voted on the vertical axis. The diagonal represents the relationship between the two had there been no overreporting. The vertical difference between the curve and the 45-degree line is the overreporting gap presented in the first panel on the vertical axis. Suppose that on average Whites score higher on predictors of (e.g., homeownership) such that they are located around point A and that African Americans are located on average at a point like C or E. While an E-type voter is both less likely to vote and less likely to overreport than an A-type, C is less likely to vote yet more likely to overreport than A. This latter possibility is consistent with the empirical findings that African Americans may be more likely to overreport but less likely to vote. In sum, the account in curve I alone suggests that African Americans may overreport more than Whites because they are less likely to vote, not because of any

6 Race and Turnout in U.S. Elections 291 Figure 1. (a) Possible Relationships between Voting and Overreporting. (b) Possible Relationships between Voting and Report of Voting

7 292 Deufel and Kedar special propensity to overreport relative to Whites they are on a different point on the same overreporting function (curve I). However, previous studies also note that overreporting by African Americans may have an additional source (Bernstein et al., 2001). Because most African Americans effectively gained the right to vote in the 1960s after a hard-fought struggle that drew heavily upon group resources, other things equal, voting may be more of a socially desirable act for African Americans than for Whites. A high percentage of African American disenfranchisement compared to Whites (Uggen and Manza 2002) potentially serves as an additional source of social desirability, reducing the likelihood that those who did not turn out will report so to the pollster. More generally, though, American electoral politics is often about race. Electoral districts are drawn explicitly with race in mind, and race is important for electoral mobilization and demobilization (see, for example, Rosenstone and Hansen 1993; Dawson 1994; Tate 1994; and Kinder and Sanders 1996). According to this argument, African Americans have a different tendency to overreport, controlling for predictors of. Therefore, unlike the previous on-the-curve explanation, curve I represents overreporting for Whites and curve II represents overreporting for African Americans. For example, take two voters of different races but identical in their likelihood of voting E is White and D is African American. Although they are equally likely to vote, D is more likely to overreport than E. Technically, African Americans are located on a different reporting curve. We allow for both accounts and, therefore, for both on-the-curve and offthe-curve effects to affect racial differences in reporting. For example, perhaps the average White is at point A and the average African American is at point B. In this case, African Americans would be more likely to overreport because of the relationship between race and overreporting and because of differences in the values of predictors of between Whites and African Americans. A side issue we need to address is the consistency of the relationship over time. The relationship may change systematically as we move away from the height of civil rights movement activity, 4 or idiosyncratically, with events that alter the social desirability of voting by race. 5 This highlights the need to establish whether any of our expectations are met in the data before we can make inferences about race and. Analysis of survey and validation data will allow us to determine the extent of racial differences in reporting and voting, and the degree to which the two mechanisms account for gaps in reporting of. 4. For discussion of a related issue, the relationship between group consciousness and participation, see Verba, Schlozman, and Brady (1995, pp ), and their discussion of the departure of their findings from those of Verba and Nie (1972). 5. See Dawson (1994, pp ) for discussion of the effect of Jackson s candidacy and his treatment by the party. See also Tate (1994) and Kinder, Mendelberg, Dawson, et al. (1989).

8 Race and Turnout in U.S. Elections 293 REPORTED AND OFFICIAL TURNOUT: HOW BIG IS THE PROBLEM? The American National Election Studies (ANES) conducted vote validation studies in the 1964, , and election studies. In this article, we utilize validated data from the four most recent presidential elections where these data are available: 1976, 1980, 1984, and In appendix A, we justify the quality of the validation procedure and offer evidence that it provides an accurate means to address our research questions, and in appendices B and C, we report the question wording and sampling procedures along with response rates, respectively. Table 1 shows the official rate, the proportion of respondents reporting having voted (R), and the proportion validated as voting (V), with the latter two quantities broken down by race. 7 Each row presents these quantities for one of the four presidential elections: The first obvious point is that in the full sample, V is closer to figures of official than R is in all years. 9 Although at first glance there is still roughly a 10-percentage-point difference between validated in the full sample and official figures, this is not surprising, both because the latter includes in its denominator many who are ineligible to vote (McDonald and Popkin 2001) 10 and because of potential systematic nonresponse to the ANES. Examination of the differences between validated and reported over time in the full sample (as well as the gap between the two measures and official ) suggests no apparent secular trend across the four elections. The difference between R and V is around 10 percentage points in each elec- 6. We do not use the 1964 validation study since the validation procedure in that year was changed in the subsequent studies. 7. The respondent was included in our validation sample if her validation record indicated that she voted (coded as 1), did not vote, or no record of voting or registering was found, or if the respondent reported that she had not registered or SDR (coded as 0), but not if one of the latter four was found and the status of the office voting records was such that some or none of the records were inaccessible. The respondent was included in our reported sample if she reported that she had voted or that she did not vote. 8. In 1976 and 1980, the ANES attempted to validate each self-report, but in 1984 and 1988, selfreports were validated only if the respondent indicated that she was registered or had voted in localities without registration requirements. In (and for some respondents in 1976), the ANES also validated those who completed the pre-election interview but not the post-election one (leaving such respondents without R data), leading to the possibility of a V sample size greater than that of R (as is indeed the case in 1980, 1984, and 1988). 9. On this point, see also Clausen (1968). 10. In most official measures, the denominator is the Voting Age Population (VAP) as reported by the Bureau of the Census in their Current Population Reports, Series P-25. VAP includes all persons over the age of 18, including those ineligible to vote in federal elections, such as legal and illegal aliens, convicted felons, and individuals legally declared non compos mentis. The VAP is therefore considerably larger than the pool of potential voters (McDonald and Popkin 2001, although see Burden 2000). For related articles, see Burden (2003), Martinez (2003), and McDonald (2003).

9 294 Deufel and Kedar Table 1. Self-Reported Turnout, Validated Turnout, and Official Turnout by Year (95-percent confidence intervals in parentheses) Year Official Turnout* (R) Full Sample** Whites African Americans Validated (V) (R) Validated (V) (R) Validated (V) (71.3, 75.3) n =1, (69.4, 74.1) n = 1, (72.1, 76.0) n = 1, (68.2, 72.6) n = 1, (62.5, 66.9) n = 1, (56.4, 61.4) n = 1, (61.3, 65.5) n = 2, (60.9, 65.4) n = 1, (72.8, 76.0) n = 1, (69.8, 74.9) n = 1, (73.1, 77.2) n = 1, (69.7, 74.2) n = 1, (63.8, 68.4) n = 1, (57.3, 62.7) n = 1, (63.4, 67.7) n = 1, (63.3, 68.1) n = 1, (58.9, 73.2) n = (59.4, 73.9) n = (59.2, 72.0) n = (53.1, 66.3) n = (44.5, 59.7) n = (41.6, 57.2) n = (41.0, 53.6) n = (39.2, 52.3) n = 225 NOTE. Cell entries include rate, 95-percent confidence interval, and number of respondents, respectively. The R sample includes respondents who have reported data, while the V sample includes all those with validated data. This table does not use the post-stratification weights provided by the ANES. *Official figures are from the Federal Election Commission, **The full sample includes respondents who indicated they were either African American or White.

10 Race and Turnout in U.S. Elections 295 tion. Among African Americans, however, the gap is considerably greater than among Whites, falling between roughly 14 and 18 percentage points across the four elections. 11 Finally, note that at first glance there seems to be no trend in overreporting of African Americans over time. 12 While these figures expose a potential reporting gap, they do not provide a theoretical framework for understanding the sources of racial differences in reported or validated. In particular, the differences do not tell us whether the gap is simply a reflection of African Americans lower propensity to vote given other predictors of (an on-the-curve effect) or whether African Americans are more likely to overreport, even accounting for predictors of (an off-the-curve effect related to differing social desirability), or both. To get at this issue, we must model the relationship between reported and actual. UNMASKING RACIAL EFFECTS: REVEALING THE REPORTING GAP We now turn to examining whether our theory holds empirically. What is the underlying relationship between reported and actual? To capture this relationship, in each of the four years we first estimate a logistic model of and a model of reporting using validated (V) and self-reported (R), respectively, as dependent variables. We rely on an established empirical and theoretical literature in choosing our explanatory variables for these models (Rosenstone and Hansen 1993; Verba et al., 1995). These variables capture resources, in addition to social and political experiences and attachments that raise the benefits and lower the costs of voting, as well as standard demographic controls. In particular, the model includes party contact, church attendance, party attachment, age, education, income, homeownership, race, and gender. The estimated coefficients of the eight regressions are too much to be discussed in detail here and can be found in table D2 (appendix D). Nonetheless, some effects hold throughout the eight models, reflecting the systemic effects discussed in the literature. Resources such as education and income make voting more likely, as does community embeddedness measured as homeownership. By the same token, young adults (usually more mobile and less immersed in a stable community) are less likely to vote. Attachment to a party, voter mobilization, and church attendance all have a positive effect on the likelihood of turning out. Finally, once controlling for these effects, living in the South has a partial negative effect on one s likelihood of turning out. 11. In a thorough analysis combining data from both presidential and congressional elections, Belli, Traugott, and Beckmann (2001) find that non-whites overreport at higher rates than Whites do. 12. The inferences we make here are identical if one looks at only those respondents who have both reported and validated data.

11 296 Deufel and Kedar Figure 2. Discounting Functions: Next, we map the relationship between voting and reported voting. We pool the resulting predicted probabilities over the four years and model the relationship between voting and reporting as a quadratic function, allowing it to vary by race and year (including all relevant interaction effects for maximum flexibility). 13 The quadratic specification and the interactions allow us to examine if the relationship expected between overreporting and (as specified in figure 1) is found in the data and whether it varies by race and over time. Figure 2 presents this relationship for all four years by race. On the horizontal axis are the probabilities of voting using validated data, and on the vertical axis are predicted probabilities of reporting having voted. As in figure 1b, the 45-degree line in figure 2 represents a hypothetical relationship with no reporting gap. The four dashed lines present the relationship for Whites, while the four solid lines present the relationship for African Americans in the four years. The vertical gaps between the diagonal line and each of the eight lines are the respective overreporting gaps. The figure illuminates several aspects of the relationship between reported and actual. Examine the relationship for Whites first. The pattern is consistent with the theory 13. The full specification and coefficients are presented in table E1 of appendix E.

12 Race and Turnout in U.S. Elections 297 specified above: the line is, in general, above the diagonal, and the relationship is nonlinear; as the probability of voting increases, the probability of overreporting one s likelihood of voting first increases and then declines. Individuals in the middle range have a higher likelihood of overreporting than either those who are unlikely to vote or those who almost surely vote. Consistent with our expectation, the relationship between and report of for Whites is constant over time. The functions for 1976, 1980, and 1984 are almost identical, and the data expose no trend in the relationship. However, the overreporting function for 1988 is a curious exception to this stable pattern. The relationship for African Americans tells an even clearer story. Here, too, overreporting is in quadratic relation to voting, but the magnitude of overreporting is greater; the vertical gaps between the diagonal and each of the functions reaches almost 20 percentage points. Overreporting is not orthogonal to race. Although the coefficients bear large standard errors (partly because of the many interaction terms included), the point estimates (presented in figure 2) consistently suggest that African Americans reporting function is different than Whites (off-the-curve effect). Furthermore, the nature of overreporting by African Americans appears roughly similar across all four elections. Based on this consistency, in the next stage we eliminate the year variables, resulting in reduced estimation uncertainty and similar results (column 2 in table E1). In summary, we have presented evidence for two mechanisms at play. First is a quadratic relationship between voting and report of voting, supporting the importance of opportunity to overreport and social desirability. Second is a racial difference, which may be attributed to an additional social desirability variable related to racial history. Both effects are constant over time. Implications of the Reporting Gap So far we have established that there is a nonlinear tendency to overreport, and that this tendency differs for African Americans and for Whites. Our next step is to analyze the consequences of these patterns for inference about. To accomplish this task, we rely on three models of voter. The first two models come from Abramson and Claggett s studies of racial differences in overreporting and (1984, 1986, 1989, 1991). 14 Their first ( thin ) model has race only on the right-hand side. Their second ( thick ) model controls for education and region (South). Finally, based on recent advances in the study of (Rosenstone and Hansen 1993; Verba et al., 1995), we extend our analysis to a third ( full ) model that is identical to 14. Abramson and Claggett (1984, 1986, 1989, 1991) code the race variable as a dichotomous 1, 1 variable, while we employ the more common dummy approach (0, 1). Despite this difference, our results are very similar.

13 298 Deufel and Kedar the model of voting we used to construct figure 2 (for estimates, see tables D1 and D2 in appendix D). To reiterate, in addition to region and education, this model also includes variables that capture resources, social and political experience, and attachment that raise the benefits and lower the costs of voting, as well as standard demographic controls. 15 While the inclusion of these particular variables is not novel, in the context of our unpacking of overreporting, a comparison of the three models sheds light on our theoretical argument. Our theory implies that effects relating to opportunity and social desirability account for part of the racial reporting gap. According to this argument, as we move from the thin to the thick to the full model and control for more of the determinants of, and hence opportunity to overreport, using R, the reporting gap between the two racial groups should decline. In other words, if as we account for more factors that disproportionately reduce African Americans likelihood of voting, the gap in overreporting diminishes, then we may infer that African Americans overreport more because they vote less (on-the-curve effect). However, if the gap between reported and actual data holds even as we control for such factors, then it is an indication that African Americans indeed have a different reporting function, likely because of additional social desirability, as we discuss above. We focus below on 1984 and 1988, the two most recent presidential elections in which validated data are available. 16 Table 2 presents the results for The first and second rows in each section present the mean predicted probabilities for African Americans and Whites, respectively, with the values of other explanatory variables held at their mean. The third entry is the mean difference in between the two racial groups. A positive number indicates that Whites are estimated to turn out at higher rates than African Americans. As the table shows, in 1984, R and V (in the first and second columns, respectively) lead to different inferences about racial gaps in. In model 1, both R and V suggest that African Americans are less likely to turn out, yet using V, the racial difference is substantially greater (10 percentage points using R as opposed to 19 using V). In other words, validated data reveal a large effect of race on, an effect that is masked by selfreported data. The results of model 2 make an even stronger case: using R, there is no statistically significant racial gap in, and the predicted probabilities for both races are inflated (73 percentage points for African Americans, and 76 for Whites). V, however, exposes a different picture. First note that the predicted probability of African Americans turning out is substantially lower (57 percentage points) and significantly different from R. The figure for Whites is lower as well (69 percentage points). Most importantly, while 15. Likelihood Ratio Tests comparing the full model to the thick and the thin models are statistically significant in all years. 16. Results for 1976 and 1980 are similar to those reported below.

14 Race and Turnout in U.S. Elections 299 Table 2. Predicted Probabilities of Turning Out by Race: 1984 Presidential Elections (95-percent confidence intervals in parentheses) (R) Validated (V) Discounted self-reported ( ) Deflated self-reported ( , out of sample) Model 1 ( thin ) African Americans (0.595, 0.730) (0.429, 0.573) (0.338, 0.578) (0.354, 0.622) Whites (0.735, 0.777) (0.662, 0.709) (0.622, 0.713) (0.619, 0.708) Difference b/w African Americans and Whites (0.019, 0.166) (0.110, 0.260) (0.081, 0.331) (0.040, 0.323) Model 2 ( thick ) African Americans (0.665, 0.792) (0.484, 0.634) (0.414, 0.656) (0.431, 0.688) Whites (0.740, 0.786) (0.661, 0.710) (0.633, 0.717) (0.631, 0.713) Difference b/w African Americans and Whites (-0.035, 0.102) (0.046, 0.203) (0.012, 0.272) (-0.016, 0.243) Model 3 ( full ) African Americans (0.760, 0.872) (0.564, 0.727) (0.533, 0.764) (0.551, 0.775) Whites (0.781, 0.828) (0.682, 0.737) (0.673, 0.762) (0.676, 0.758) Difference b/w African Americans and White (-0.072, 0.044) (-0.022, 0.148) (-0.051, 0.190) (-0.069, 0.168) NOTE. Entries in the table are predicted probabilities of turning out. All other variables in the model are held at their respective means. Model 1: Race. Model 2: Race, education, and region (South vs. other). Model 3: Full model; see specification in table D2. For all models, see N and coefficients in tables D1 and D2.

15 300 Deufel and Kedar Table 3. Predicted Probabilities of Turning Out by Race: 1988 Presidential Elections (95-percent confidence intervals in parentheses) (R) Validated (V) Deflated self-reported ( ) Deflated self-reported ( , out of sample) Model 1 ( thin ) African Americans (0.528, 0.664) (0.386, 0.541) (0.283, 0.523) (0.304, 0.562) Whites (0.690, 0.739) (0.645, 0.697) (0.610, 0.697) (0.573, 0.666) Difference b/w African Americans and Whites (0.046, 0.193) (0.125, 0.287) (0.112, 0.387) (0.048, 0.331) Model 2 ( thick ) African Americans (0.587, 0.727) (0.389, 0.560) (0.339, 0.587) (0.363, 0.637) Whites (0.703, 0.753) (0.650, 0.706) (0.622, 0.709) (0.584, 0.680) Difference b/w African Americans and Whites (-0.010, 0.143) (0.114, 0.293) (0.072, 0.340) (-0.008, 0.273) Model 3 ( full ) African Americans (0.670, 0.839) (0.437, 0.614) (0.422, 0.690) (0.454, 0.733) Whites (0.746, 0.803) (0.674, 0.733) (0.663, 0.747) (0.638, 0.732) Difference b/w African Americans and White (-0.070, 0.105) (0.082, 0.275) (0.006, 0.297) (-0.058, 0.237) NOTE. Entries in the table are predicted probabilities of turning out. All other variables in the model are held at their respective means. Model 1: Race. Model 2: Race, education, and region (South vs. other). Model 3: Full model, see specification in table D2. For all models, see N and coefficients in tables D1 and D2.

16 Race and Turnout in U.S. Elections 301 Table 4. The Challenge of Partial Observation of Turnout Data available/period t t Validated +? using R alone there is no statistically significant effect of race on, V reveals an effect of 12 percentage points reporting is correlated with race. Finally, the full model shows the same trend, although the results fall slightly short of standard levels of statistical significance. As in the previous two models, the point estimates indicate that the racial gap hidden using self-reported figures is greater when is measured with validated figures, and the racial gap (which is six percentage points) is exposed by the use of validated figures. Table 3 repeats this exercise in The results are consistent with those of 1984, and we describe them here only briefly. Within each model, the racial difference exposed by V is substantively greater than the difference suggested by R. Even in the full model, use of validated data suggests an 18-percent gap while self-reported data suggests no difference. The findings using validated data are consistent with the findings of Dawson (1994) and Kinder and Sanders (1996) previously noted. In sum, with regard to our substantive issue of interest racial differences in a strong case can be made that the use of self-reported data can lead to mistaken inferences. Both opportunity and social desirability (on-thecurve effects) and an additional desirability related to race (off-the-curve effect) lead to biased inferences. As we control for opportunity to overreport, the gap declines, yet because of differing social desirability, some racial differences remain. Having revealed these effects, in the next section we devise a remedy for the biases produced by conventional investigation. DEFLATING SELF-REPORTS Table 4 summarizes the challenge we face. In some periods (t) both selfreported and verified data are observed, while in others (t + 1) only self-reported data are available. While the literature on overreporting bias is extensive, almost no attention has been given to potential solutions. Suggestions of measurement improvements ex ante (Belli et al. 1999; Duff, Hammer, Park, et al. 2007; Holbrook and Krosnick forthcoming), discussing issues such as poor memory and face-saving response options, produce more accurate reports, but the problem of bias with already collected data still holds. Our proposed algorithm is simple. Based on our theory and empirical evidence for the joint roles of opportunity and desirability, we model the relationship between voting and reporting of voting using all years in which reported and validated data from presidential elections are available (1976,

17 302 Deufel and Kedar 1980, 1984, and 1988). We then use the estimated relationship to deflate selfreported data at time t + 1 (1992 and 1996), where validated data are not available. We now turn to presenting our algorithm in greater detail. The Deflating Algorithm STEP 1: MODEL THE RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN VOTING AND REPORTING OF VOTE AT TIME t 1.1. We estimate a model of reported at time t: R t = f X1 t ; βt 1 ; ð1þ where X t 1 is a vector of voter characteristics, β t 1 is a vector of coefficients, and f ðþis a logistic function. 17 We then calculate the predicted probability of reported voting for each individual, P^rðR t =1Þ 1.2. Similarly, we estimate a model of validated at time t: V t = f X2 t ; βt 2 ; ð2þ and calculate the predicted probability of turning out for each individual P^rðV t =1Þ The deflating function: We model the relationship between voting (V) and reporting of vote (R) where the dependent variable is the estimated probability of actually voting calculated from equation (2). Given the racial differences in voting and report of voting established above, we let the voting be a quadratic function of selfreported voting and vary interactively by race. The right-hand side, then, is a vector of covariates such that P^rðV t =1Þ= δ t 0 + δt 1 racet + δ t 2 P^r ðr t =1Þ+ δ t 3 P^r 2 ðr t =1Þ h i h i + δ t 4 racet P^rðR t =1Þ + δ t 5 racet P^r 2 ðr t =1Þ ð3þ Equation (3) reflects how social desirability and opportunity affect racial differences in overreporting. The coefficients δ 0, δ 2,andδ 3 represent the quadratic relationship between voting and report of voting among Whites. 17. In our case, based on the observed consistent relationships observed over time, we pool data from 1976, 1980, 1984, and In our case, we use the same functional form and vector of voter characteristics as in equation 1, reported in table D2.

18 Race and Turnout in U.S. Elections 303 The coefficients δ 1, δ 4, and δ 5 represent the difference between the curve for Whites and the curve for African Americans. The additional effect of social desirability (off-the-curve) is carried out by the latter set of coefficients. The estimated coefficients are reported in the second column of table E1. We will next use these coefficients to deflate reported. STEP 2: DEFLATE REPORTED DATA AT t +1 In this stage, we first estimate the probability of turning out using reported data (the only data we have at t + 1). We then employ our deflator to deflate the estimated probabilities Similar to step 1.1, we estimate a model of reported at time t +1: R t +1 = f X3 t +1 ; β t 3 +1 ð4þ (in our case, 1992 or 1996). Here, too, we use a logistic function. We then compute predicted probabilities of reported for two hypothetical individuals: White ðp^rðr t +1 j W =1ÞÞ and African American ðp^rðr t +1 j Af :A =1ÞÞ, with all other variables held at their mean (six hypothetical individuals altogether). We repeat this step for three different model specifications corresponding with the models above ( thin, thick, and full ). The estimates are reported in tables D1 and D We apply the deflating function to the predicted probabilities generated in the previous step. For example, for a White individual: D t +1 = δ^t 0 + δ^t 1 ðrace = W Þ t +1 + δ^t 2 P^r R t +1 j W h + δ^t 4 ðrace = WÞ t +1 h P^r R t +1 j W Š + δ^t5 ðrace = W + δ^t3 P^r 2 R t +1 j W Þ t +1 P^r 2 R t +1 j W Šð5Þ The outcome D t+1 is the estimated individual s deflated probability of turning out. Multiple-Step Estimation The logic of our algorithm is straightforward. It is important to keep in mind, however, that each step produces a layer of uncertainty that should be taken into account. The first source is the uncertainty around the Maximum Likelihood estimates at time t (β^t andβ^t 1 2 ), which in turn produce the predicted probabilities for thetwo variables V and R (steps 1.1 and 1.2). We assume that β t 1 = f Multivar: Normal β^ t 1 ;, and drawing randomly from this distribution, β^t 1 we get a sample distribution of β^ t 1 (in this step, as in all other steps described below, we draw 1,000 times). We repeat the same procedure for β^ t 2, producing 1,000 predicted probabilities of turning out and 1,000 predicted

19 304 Deufel and Kedar probabilities of reporting to have turned out for each individual. Therefore, in step 1.3, we estimate 1,000 deflating functions. Similarly, we draw on the respective distribution of the coefficients on R at time t +1(β^t +1 3 ) and calculate predicted probabilities of two hypothetical respondents to be deflated. Finally, we employ the sets of coefficients of the deflating function δ^ to these 1,000 predicted probabilities and get deflated probabilities. The results we present are the mean of those deflated probabilities. 19 Evaluating Our Algorithm To evaluate our algorithm, we pose two questions. First, we examine whether the inferences we make about racial differences in using our method come closer to V than those we would make using R. Our measure of ought to produce quantities of interest that are closer to those produced by the use of V than those produced by the use of R, conditioning on the same model. Focusing on racial differences in, we turn back to tables 2 and 3. Recall that the use of R coefficients often led to underestimated effects of race on. We perform both in-sample and out-of-sample tests to examine the performance of our measure. For the in-sample tests, we deflate self-reports using the deflating function produced by validated data from For our out-of-sample tests, we estimate our deflating function in 1976 and use it to deflate self-reported data in These tests are particularly demanding for two reasons. First, we use auxiliary information from 1976 to correct bias in data produced eight and 12 years later. Second, we know from figure 2 that Whites overreported in a unique manner in 1988 compared to other years. Results of these estimations are presented in the third (in-sample) and fourth (out-of-sample) columns of table 2. We then repeat this exercise for 1988 (table 3). Tables 2 and 3 reveal that using information from 1976 to deflate self-reports in 1984 and 1988 produces substantially more accurate estimates of racial differences in than the use of R does. As expected, the results for 1984 are somewhat more accurate than those of 1988, but in all cases the point estimates using the deflated data (D) are considerably closer to V than those produced by R (the multiple stages of estimation acknowledge the uncertainty in these point estimates, leading to a few cases where the D confidence intervals overlap with zero). Notice in particular the figures for African American produced by our algorithm in the full model for While self-reports suggest no racial gap in, our algorithm exposes the particularly low of African Americans, consistent with previously cited accounts of alienation felt among the African American population in In sum, while keeping in mind the caveat that the same 19. We compute 95-percent confidence intervals by sorting the deflated probabilities and taking the 25th and 975th probabilities.

20 Race and Turnout in U.S. Elections 305 Figure 3. a and b. Model Fit Based on Self-Reported, Validated, and Deflated Data for 1984 (Panel a) and 1988 (Panel b)

21 306 Deufel and Kedar sampling frame was used both in 1976 and in 1984 and 1988, our method produces point estimates superior to those produced by R, although as expected, a fair amount of noise created in the process increases uncertainty. Second, we examine how well our model fits the data. In particular, we evaluate how predicted probabilities of turning out based on D produced by the out-of-sample procedure match observed data of based on validated figures. Figure 3 presents this evaluation for 1984 and 1988 in the top and bottom panels, respectively. To evaluate our model fit, for each of three measures, V, R, and D, we sort our observations by predicted probability of turning out produced by the respective measure (based on estimates in table D2), group them into 20 equal-length intervals, and plot on the horizontal axis the average predicted probability for that group, and on the vertical axis the actual observed fraction of votes in that group as indicated by validated data. A perfect fit (on average) will result in all points aligned right on the 45-degree line. As can be seen for 1984, results produced by the self-reported model do not fit the data well and overestimate the observed vote by up to 20 percentage points. Consistent with figure 2, the inaccuracy is largest in the middle range. It is reassuring that our model for validated data produces a good fit predicted probabilities are aligned close to the 45-degree line, and importantly, in cases where our predictions diverge from the line, they reveal no systematic bias but rather are scattered equally above and below the line. Finally, results produced by the deflated data are tightly clustered around the 45-degree line with no systematic deviation. Results for 1988 are similar. Recall that this is our hardest case: the out-ofsample test is based on data 12 years prior to the election, and the reporting pattern in 1988 is different than in other years. And although our prediction does involve more noise than in 1984, here too, while the prediction based on self-reports differs systematically from the observed vote, prediction based on our algorithm is in line with observed patterns. Exposing Hidden Effects in the 1990s Having established its validity, we reach the final stage of our analysis, applying our algorithm to deflate self-reports in the 1992 and 1996 presidential elections where validated data are unavailable. We do so exactly as we describe above: we estimate a model based on self-reports for 1992 (and 1996), calculate the predicted probability of turning out for each individual, and apply our deflator to those predicted probabilities. Table 5 compares the results based on self-reports to those based on the deflated self-reports produced by our algorithm for each of the three models, as above. The table presents two main findings. First, it shows that predicted probabilities produced by R are inflated compared to D across models in both elections. More importantly, our use of D exposes a larger racial gap in turn-

If Turnout Is So Low, Why Do So Many People Say They Vote? Michael D. Martinez

If Turnout Is So Low, Why Do So Many People Say They Vote? Michael D. Martinez If Turnout Is So Low, Why Do So Many People Say They Vote? Michael D. Martinez Department of Political Science University of Florida P.O. Box 117325 Gainesville, Florida 32611-7325 phone (352) 392-0262

More information

Social Desirability and Response Validity: A Comparative Analysis of Overreporting Voter Turnout in Five Countries

Social Desirability and Response Validity: A Comparative Analysis of Overreporting Voter Turnout in Five Countries Social Desirability and Response Validity: A Comparative Analysis of Overreporting Voter Turnout in Five Countries Jeffrey A. Karp Texas Tech University and University of Twente, The Netherlands David

More information

Supplementary Materials A: Figures for All 7 Surveys Figure S1-A: Distribution of Predicted Probabilities of Voting in Primary Elections

Supplementary Materials A: Figures for All 7 Surveys Figure S1-A: Distribution of Predicted Probabilities of Voting in Primary Elections Supplementary Materials (Online), Supplementary Materials A: Figures for All 7 Surveys Figure S-A: Distribution of Predicted Probabilities of Voting in Primary Elections (continued on next page) UT Republican

More information

Class Bias in the U.S. Electorate,

Class Bias in the U.S. Electorate, Class Bias in the U.S. Electorate, 1972-2004 Despite numerous studies confirming the class bias of the electorate, we have only a limited number of studies of changes in class bias over the past several

More information

Learning from Small Subsamples without Cherry Picking: The Case of Non-Citizen Registration and Voting

Learning from Small Subsamples without Cherry Picking: The Case of Non-Citizen Registration and Voting Learning from Small Subsamples without Cherry Picking: The Case of Non-Citizen Registration and Voting Jesse Richman Old Dominion University jrichman@odu.edu David C. Earnest Old Dominion University, and

More information

Robert H. Prisuta, American Association of Retired Persons (AARP) 601 E Street, N.W., Washington, D.C

Robert H. Prisuta, American Association of Retired Persons (AARP) 601 E Street, N.W., Washington, D.C A POST-ELECTION BANDWAGON EFFECT? COMPARING NATIONAL EXIT POLL DATA WITH A GENERAL POPULATION SURVEY Robert H. Prisuta, American Association of Retired Persons (AARP) 601 E Street, N.W., Washington, D.C.

More information

Non-Voted Ballots and Discrimination in Florida

Non-Voted Ballots and Discrimination in Florida Non-Voted Ballots and Discrimination in Florida John R. Lott, Jr. School of Law Yale University 127 Wall Street New Haven, CT 06511 (203) 432-2366 john.lott@yale.edu revised July 15, 2001 * This paper

More information

Youth Voter Turnout has Declined, by Any Measure By Peter Levine and Mark Hugo Lopez 1 September 2002

Youth Voter Turnout has Declined, by Any Measure By Peter Levine and Mark Hugo Lopez 1 September 2002 Youth Voter has Declined, by Any Measure By Peter Levine and Mark Hugo Lopez 1 September 2002 Measuring young people s voting raises difficult issues, and there is not a single clearly correct turnout

More information

Supplementary/Online Appendix for:

Supplementary/Online Appendix for: Supplementary/Online Appendix for: Relative Policy Support and Coincidental Representation Perspectives on Politics Peter K. Enns peterenns@cornell.edu Contents Appendix 1 Correlated Measurement Error

More information

Case Study: Get out the Vote

Case Study: Get out the Vote Case Study: Get out the Vote Do Phone Calls to Encourage Voting Work? Why Randomize? This case study is based on Comparing Experimental and Matching Methods Using a Large-Scale Field Experiment on Voter

More information

One. After every presidential election, commentators lament the low voter. Introduction ...

One. After every presidential election, commentators lament the low voter. Introduction ... One... Introduction After every presidential election, commentators lament the low voter turnout rate in the United States, suggesting that there is something wrong with a democracy in which only about

More information

Experiments to Reduce the Over-reporting of Voting: A Pipeline to the Truth. Michael J. Hanmer Antoine J. Banks University of Maryland

Experiments to Reduce the Over-reporting of Voting: A Pipeline to the Truth. Michael J. Hanmer Antoine J. Banks University of Maryland Experiments to Reduce the Over-reporting of Voting: A Pipeline to the Truth Michael J. Hanmer Antoine J. Banks University of Maryland Ismail K. White The Ohio State University Abstract Voting is a fundamental

More information

A Behavioral Measure of the Enthusiasm Gap in American Elections

A Behavioral Measure of the Enthusiasm Gap in American Elections A Behavioral Measure of the Enthusiasm Gap in American Elections Seth J. Hill April 22, 2014 Abstract What are the effects of a mobilized party base on elections? I present a new behavioral measure of

More information

Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US

Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US Ben Ost a and Eva Dziadula b a Department of Economics, University of Illinois at Chicago, 601 South Morgan UH718 M/C144 Chicago,

More information

Report for the Associated Press: Illinois and Georgia Election Studies in November 2014

Report for the Associated Press: Illinois and Georgia Election Studies in November 2014 Report for the Associated Press: Illinois and Georgia Election Studies in November 2014 Randall K. Thomas, Frances M. Barlas, Linda McPetrie, Annie Weber, Mansour Fahimi, & Robert Benford GfK Custom Research

More information

What Leads to Voting Overreports? Contrasts of Overreporters to Validated Voters and Admitted Nonvoters in the American National Election Studies

What Leads to Voting Overreports? Contrasts of Overreporters to Validated Voters and Admitted Nonvoters in the American National Election Studies Journal of Of cial Statistics, Vol. 17, No. 4, 2001, pp. 479±498 What Leads to Voting Overreports? Contrasts of Overreporters to Validated Voters and Admitted Nonvoters in the American National Election

More information

1. The Relationship Between Party Control, Latino CVAP and the Passage of Bills Benefitting Immigrants

1. The Relationship Between Party Control, Latino CVAP and the Passage of Bills Benefitting Immigrants The Ideological and Electoral Determinants of Laws Targeting Undocumented Migrants in the U.S. States Online Appendix In this additional methodological appendix I present some alternative model specifications

More information

Case 1:17-cv TCB-WSD-BBM Document 94-1 Filed 02/12/18 Page 1 of 37

Case 1:17-cv TCB-WSD-BBM Document 94-1 Filed 02/12/18 Page 1 of 37 Case 1:17-cv-01427-TCB-WSD-BBM Document 94-1 Filed 02/12/18 Page 1 of 37 REPLY REPORT OF JOWEI CHEN, Ph.D. In response to my December 22, 2017 expert report in this case, Defendants' counsel submitted

More information

Benefit levels and US immigrants welfare receipts

Benefit levels and US immigrants welfare receipts 1 Benefit levels and US immigrants welfare receipts 1970 1990 by Joakim Ruist Department of Economics University of Gothenburg Box 640 40530 Gothenburg, Sweden joakim.ruist@economics.gu.se telephone: +46

More information

New Attempts to Reduce Overreporting of Voter Turnout and Their Effects. Eva Zeglovits and Sylvia Kritzinger

New Attempts to Reduce Overreporting of Voter Turnout and Their Effects. Eva Zeglovits and Sylvia Kritzinger International Journal of Public Opinion Research Vol. 26 No. 2 2014 ß The Author 2013. Published by Oxford University Press on behalf of The World Association for Public Opinion Research. This is an Open

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES HOMEOWNERSHIP IN THE IMMIGRANT POPULATION. George J. Borjas. Working Paper

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES HOMEOWNERSHIP IN THE IMMIGRANT POPULATION. George J. Borjas. Working Paper NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES HOMEOWNERSHIP IN THE IMMIGRANT POPULATION George J. Borjas Working Paper 8945 http://www.nber.org/papers/w8945 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge,

More information

A positive correlation between turnout and plurality does not refute the rational voter model

A positive correlation between turnout and plurality does not refute the rational voter model Quality & Quantity 26: 85-93, 1992. 85 O 1992 Kluwer Academic Publishers. Printed in the Netherlands. Note A positive correlation between turnout and plurality does not refute the rational voter model

More information

Online Appendix for Redistricting and the Causal Impact of Race on Voter Turnout

Online Appendix for Redistricting and the Causal Impact of Race on Voter Turnout Online Appendix for Redistricting and the Causal Impact of Race on Voter Turnout Bernard L. Fraga Contents Appendix A Details of Estimation Strategy 1 A.1 Hypotheses.....................................

More information

THE RATIONAL VOTER IN AN AGE OF RED AND BLUE STATES: THE EFFECT OF PERCEIVED CLOSENESS ON TURNOUT IN THE 2004 PRESIDENTIAL ELECTION

THE RATIONAL VOTER IN AN AGE OF RED AND BLUE STATES: THE EFFECT OF PERCEIVED CLOSENESS ON TURNOUT IN THE 2004 PRESIDENTIAL ELECTION THE RATIONAL VOTER IN AN AGE OF RED AND BLUE STATES: THE EFFECT OF PERCEIVED CLOSENESS ON TURNOUT IN THE 2004 PRESIDENTIAL ELECTION A Thesis submitted to the Graduate School of Arts and Sciences at Georgetown

More information

Online Appendix: Robustness Tests and Migration. Means

Online Appendix: Robustness Tests and Migration. Means VOL. VOL NO. ISSUE EMPLOYMENT, WAGES AND VOTER TURNOUT Online Appendix: Robustness Tests and Migration Means Online Appendix Table 1 presents the summary statistics of turnout for the five types of elections

More information

PROBABILISTIC POLLING AND VOTING IN THE 2008 PRESIDENTIAL ELECTION EVIDENCE FROM THE AMERICAN LIFE PANEL

PROBABILISTIC POLLING AND VOTING IN THE 2008 PRESIDENTIAL ELECTION EVIDENCE FROM THE AMERICAN LIFE PANEL Public Opinion Quarterly, Vol. 74, No. 3, Fall 2010, pp. 433 459 PROBABILISTIC POLLING AND VOTING IN THE 2008 PRESIDENTIAL ELECTION EVIDENCE FROM THE AMERICAN LIFE PANEL ADELINE DELAVANDE CHARLES F. MANSKI*

More information

1. A Republican edge in terms of self-described interest in the election. 2. Lower levels of self-described interest among younger and Latino

1. A Republican edge in terms of self-described interest in the election. 2. Lower levels of self-described interest among younger and Latino 2 Academics use political polling as a measure about the viability of survey research can it accurately predict the result of a national election? The answer continues to be yes. There is compelling evidence

More information

IS THE MEASURED BLACK-WHITE WAGE GAP AMONG WOMEN TOO SMALL? Derek Neal University of Wisconsin Presented Nov 6, 2000 PRELIMINARY

IS THE MEASURED BLACK-WHITE WAGE GAP AMONG WOMEN TOO SMALL? Derek Neal University of Wisconsin Presented Nov 6, 2000 PRELIMINARY IS THE MEASURED BLACK-WHITE WAGE GAP AMONG WOMEN TOO SMALL? Derek Neal University of Wisconsin Presented Nov 6, 2000 PRELIMINARY Over twenty years ago, Butler and Heckman (1977) raised the possibility

More information

RBS SAMPLING FOR EFFICIENT AND ACCURATE TARGETING OF TRUE VOTERS

RBS SAMPLING FOR EFFICIENT AND ACCURATE TARGETING OF TRUE VOTERS Dish RBS SAMPLING FOR EFFICIENT AND ACCURATE TARGETING OF TRUE VOTERS Comcast Patrick Ruffini May 19, 2017 Netflix 1 HOW CAN WE USE VOTER FILES FOR ELECTION SURVEYS? Research Synthesis TRADITIONAL LIKELY

More information

WP 2015: 9. Education and electoral participation: Reported versus actual voting behaviour. Ivar Kolstad and Arne Wiig VOTE

WP 2015: 9. Education and electoral participation: Reported versus actual voting behaviour. Ivar Kolstad and Arne Wiig VOTE WP 2015: 9 Reported versus actual voting behaviour Ivar Kolstad and Arne Wiig VOTE Chr. Michelsen Institute (CMI) is an independent, non-profit research institution and a major international centre in

More information

Elite Polarization and Mass Political Engagement: Information, Alienation, and Mobilization

Elite Polarization and Mass Political Engagement: Information, Alienation, and Mobilization JOURNAL OF INTERNATIONAL AND AREA STUDIES Volume 20, Number 1, 2013, pp.89-109 89 Elite Polarization and Mass Political Engagement: Information, Alienation, and Mobilization Jae Mook Lee Using the cumulative

More information

VoteCastr methodology

VoteCastr methodology VoteCastr methodology Introduction Going into Election Day, we will have a fairly good idea of which candidate would win each state if everyone voted. However, not everyone votes. The levels of enthusiasm

More information

On the Causes and Consequences of Ballot Order Effects

On the Causes and Consequences of Ballot Order Effects Polit Behav (2013) 35:175 197 DOI 10.1007/s11109-011-9189-2 ORIGINAL PAPER On the Causes and Consequences of Ballot Order Effects Marc Meredith Yuval Salant Published online: 6 January 2012 Ó Springer

More information

Model of Voting. February 15, Abstract. This paper uses United States congressional district level data to identify how incumbency,

Model of Voting. February 15, Abstract. This paper uses United States congressional district level data to identify how incumbency, U.S. Congressional Vote Empirics: A Discrete Choice Model of Voting Kyle Kretschman The University of Texas Austin kyle.kretschman@mail.utexas.edu Nick Mastronardi United States Air Force Academy nickmastronardi@gmail.com

More information

Case: 3:15-cv jdp Document #: 87 Filed: 01/11/16 Page 1 of 26. January 7, 2016

Case: 3:15-cv jdp Document #: 87 Filed: 01/11/16 Page 1 of 26. January 7, 2016 Case: 3:15-cv-00324-jdp Document #: 87 Filed: 01/11/16 Page 1 of 26 January 7, 2016 United States District Court for the Western District of Wisconsin One Wisconsin Institute, Inc. et al. v. Nichol, et

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE LABOR MARKET IMPACT OF HIGH-SKILL IMMIGRATION. George J. Borjas. Working Paper

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE LABOR MARKET IMPACT OF HIGH-SKILL IMMIGRATION. George J. Borjas. Working Paper NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE LABOR MARKET IMPACT OF HIGH-SKILL IMMIGRATION George J. Borjas Working Paper 11217 http://www.nber.org/papers/w11217 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts

More information

The Cook Political Report / LSU Manship School Midterm Election Poll

The Cook Political Report / LSU Manship School Midterm Election Poll The Cook Political Report / LSU Manship School Midterm Election Poll The Cook Political Report-LSU Manship School poll, a national survey with an oversample of voters in the most competitive U.S. House

More information

NH Statewide Horserace Poll

NH Statewide Horserace Poll NH Statewide Horserace Poll NH Survey of Likely Voters October 26-28, 2016 N=408 Trump Leads Clinton in Final Stretch; New Hampshire U.S. Senate Race - Ayotte 49.1, Hassan 47 With just over a week to go

More information

Bias Correction by Sub-population Weighting for the 2016 United States Presidential Election

Bias Correction by Sub-population Weighting for the 2016 United States Presidential Election American Journal of Applied Mathematics and Statistics, 2017, Vol. 5, No. 3, 101-105 Available online at http://pubs.sciepub.com/ajams/5/3/3 Science and Education Publishing DOI:10.12691/ajams-5-3-3 Bias

More information

Political Participation

Political Participation Political Participation THEME A: POPULAR PARTICIPATION IN ELECTIONS From State to Federal Control Initially, states decided who could vote and for which offices This led to wide variation in federal TIFF

More information

The result of the 2015 UK General Election came as a shock to most observers. During the months and

The result of the 2015 UK General Election came as a shock to most observers. During the months and 1. Introduction The result of the 2015 UK General Election came as a shock to most observers. During the months and weeks leading up to election day on the 7 th of May, the opinion polls consistently indicated

More information

The League of Women Voters of Pennsylvania et al v. The Commonwealth of Pennsylvania et al. Nolan McCarty

The League of Women Voters of Pennsylvania et al v. The Commonwealth of Pennsylvania et al. Nolan McCarty The League of Women Voters of Pennsylvania et al v. The Commonwealth of Pennsylvania et al. I. Introduction Nolan McCarty Susan Dod Brown Professor of Politics and Public Affairs Chair, Department of Politics

More information

Quantitative Prediction of Electoral Vote for United States Presidential Election in 2016

Quantitative Prediction of Electoral Vote for United States Presidential Election in 2016 Quantitative Prediction of Electoral Vote for United States Presidential Election in 2016 Gang Xu Senior Research Scientist in Machine Learning Houston, Texas (prepared on November 07, 2016) Abstract In

More information

Ohio State University

Ohio State University Fake News Did Have a Significant Impact on the Vote in the 2016 Election: Original Full-Length Version with Methodological Appendix By Richard Gunther, Paul A. Beck, and Erik C. Nisbet Ohio State University

More information

Appendix: Uncovering Patterns Among Latent Variables: Human Rights and De Facto Judicial Independence

Appendix: Uncovering Patterns Among Latent Variables: Human Rights and De Facto Judicial Independence Appendix: Uncovering Patterns Among Latent Variables: Human Rights and De Facto Judicial Independence Charles D. Crabtree Christopher J. Fariss August 12, 2015 CONTENTS A Variable descriptions 3 B Correlation

More information

Congruence in Political Parties

Congruence in Political Parties Descriptive Representation of Women and Ideological Congruence in Political Parties Georgia Kernell Northwestern University gkernell@northwestern.edu June 15, 2011 Abstract This paper examines the relationship

More information

Incumbency as a Source of Spillover Effects in Mixed Electoral Systems: Evidence from a Regression-Discontinuity Design.

Incumbency as a Source of Spillover Effects in Mixed Electoral Systems: Evidence from a Regression-Discontinuity Design. Incumbency as a Source of Spillover Effects in Mixed Electoral Systems: Evidence from a Regression-Discontinuity Design Forthcoming, Electoral Studies Web Supplement Jens Hainmueller Holger Lutz Kern September

More information

Turnout and Strength of Habits

Turnout and Strength of Habits Turnout and Strength of Habits John H. Aldrich Wendy Wood Jacob M. Montgomery Duke University I) Introduction Social scientists are much better at explaining for whom people vote than whether people vote

More information

Volume 35, Issue 1. An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach

Volume 35, Issue 1. An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach Volume 35, Issue 1 An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach Brian Hibbs Indiana University South Bend Gihoon Hong Indiana University South Bend Abstract This

More information

POLI 300 Fall 2010 PROBLEM SET #5B: ANSWERS AND DISCUSSION

POLI 300 Fall 2010 PROBLEM SET #5B: ANSWERS AND DISCUSSION POLI 300 Fall 2010 General Comments PROBLEM SET #5B: ANSWERS AND DISCUSSION Evidently most students were able to produce SPSS frequency tables (and sometimes bar charts as well) without particular difficulty.

More information

CALIFORNIA INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY

CALIFORNIA INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY DIVISION OF THE HUMANITIES AND SOCIAL SCIENCES CALIFORNIA INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY PASADENA, CALIFORNIA 91125 THE EFFECT OF VOTER IDENTIFICATION LAWS ON TURNOUT R. Michael Alvarez California Institute of

More information

Schooling and Cohort Size: Evidence from Vietnam, Thailand, Iran and Cambodia. Evangelos M. Falaris University of Delaware. and

Schooling and Cohort Size: Evidence from Vietnam, Thailand, Iran and Cambodia. Evangelos M. Falaris University of Delaware. and Schooling and Cohort Size: Evidence from Vietnam, Thailand, Iran and Cambodia by Evangelos M. Falaris University of Delaware and Thuan Q. Thai Max Planck Institute for Demographic Research March 2012 2

More information

Colorado 2014: Comparisons of Predicted and Actual Turnout

Colorado 2014: Comparisons of Predicted and Actual Turnout Colorado 2014: Comparisons of Predicted and Actual Turnout Date 2017-08-28 Project name Colorado 2014 Voter File Analysis Prepared for Washington Monthly and Project Partners Prepared by Pantheon Analytics

More information

Reducing overreporting of voter turnout in seven European countries results from a survey experiment

Reducing overreporting of voter turnout in seven European countries results from a survey experiment Reducing overreporting of voter turnout in seven European countries results from a survey experiment Sylvia Kritzinger (University of Vienna, sylvia.kritzinger@univie.ac.at) Steve Schwarzer (TNS Opinion,

More information

Electoral Surprise and the Midterm Loss in US Congressional Elections

Electoral Surprise and the Midterm Loss in US Congressional Elections B.J.Pol.S. 29, 507 521 Printed in the United Kingdom 1999 Cambridge University Press Electoral Surprise and the Midterm Loss in US Congressional Elections KENNETH SCHEVE AND MICHAEL TOMZ* Alberto Alesina

More information

GEORG-AUGUST-UNIVERSITÄT GÖTTINGEN

GEORG-AUGUST-UNIVERSITÄT GÖTTINGEN GEORG-AUGUST-UNIVERSITÄT GÖTTINGEN FACULTY OF ECONOMIC SCIENCES CHAIR OF MACROECONOMICS AND DEVELOPMENT Bachelor Seminar Economics of the very long run: Economics of Islam Summer semester 2017 Does Secular

More information

Supplementary Materials for Strategic Abstention in Proportional Representation Systems (Evidence from Multiple Countries)

Supplementary Materials for Strategic Abstention in Proportional Representation Systems (Evidence from Multiple Countries) Supplementary Materials for Strategic Abstention in Proportional Representation Systems (Evidence from Multiple Countries) Guillem Riambau July 15, 2018 1 1 Construction of variables and descriptive statistics.

More information

Table A.2 reports the complete set of estimates of equation (1). We distinguish between personal

Table A.2 reports the complete set of estimates of equation (1). We distinguish between personal Akay, Bargain and Zimmermann Online Appendix 40 A. Online Appendix A.1. Descriptive Statistics Figure A.1 about here Table A.1 about here A.2. Detailed SWB Estimates Table A.2 reports the complete set

More information

The Youth Vote 2004 With a Historical Look at Youth Voting Patterns,

The Youth Vote 2004 With a Historical Look at Youth Voting Patterns, The Youth Vote 2004 With a Historical Look at Youth Voting Patterns, 1972-2004 Mark Hugo Lopez, Research Director Emily Kirby, Research Associate Jared Sagoff, Research Assistant Chris Herbst, Graduate

More information

Effects of Photo ID Laws on Registration and Turnout: Evidence from Rhode Island

Effects of Photo ID Laws on Registration and Turnout: Evidence from Rhode Island Effects of Photo ID Laws on Registration and Turnout: Evidence from Rhode Island Francesco Maria Esposito Diego Focanti Justine Hastings December 2017 Abstract We study the effect of photo ID laws on voting

More information

Turnout Effects from Vote by Mail Elections

Turnout Effects from Vote by Mail Elections Turnout Effects from Vote by Mail Elections Andrew Menger Rice University Robert M. Stein Rice University Greg Vonnahme University of Missouri Kansas City Abstract: Research on how vote by mail election

More information

Labor Market Dropouts and Trends in the Wages of Black and White Men

Labor Market Dropouts and Trends in the Wages of Black and White Men Industrial & Labor Relations Review Volume 56 Number 4 Article 5 2003 Labor Market Dropouts and Trends in the Wages of Black and White Men Chinhui Juhn University of Houston Recommended Citation Juhn,

More information

Experiments in Election Reform: Voter Perceptions of Campaigns Under Preferential and Plurality Voting

Experiments in Election Reform: Voter Perceptions of Campaigns Under Preferential and Plurality Voting Experiments in Election Reform: Voter Perceptions of Campaigns Under Preferential and Plurality Voting Caroline Tolbert, University of Iowa (caroline-tolbert@uiowa.edu) Collaborators: Todd Donovan, Western

More information

Patterns of Poll Movement *

Patterns of Poll Movement * Patterns of Poll Movement * Public Perspective, forthcoming Christopher Wlezien is Reader in Comparative Government and Fellow of Nuffield College, University of Oxford Robert S. Erikson is a Professor

More information

Strengthening Protection of Labor Rights through Preferential Trade Agreements (PTAs)

Strengthening Protection of Labor Rights through Preferential Trade Agreements (PTAs) Strengthening Protection of Labor Rights through Preferential Trade Agreements (PTAs) Moonhawk Kim moonhawk@gmail.com Executive Summary Analysts have argued that the United States attempts to strengthen

More information

CSI Brexit 2: Ending Free Movement as a Priority in the Brexit Negotiations

CSI Brexit 2: Ending Free Movement as a Priority in the Brexit Negotiations CSI Brexit 2: Ending Free Movement as a Priority in the Brexit Negotiations 18 th October, 2017 Summary Immigration is consistently ranked as one of the most important issues facing the country, and a

More information

Supplementary Materials for

Supplementary Materials for www.sciencemag.org/cgi/content/full/science.aag2147/dc1 Supplementary Materials for How economic, humanitarian, and religious concerns shape European attitudes toward asylum seekers This PDF file includes

More information

Immigrant Legalization

Immigrant Legalization Technical Appendices Immigrant Legalization Assessing the Labor Market Effects Laura Hill Magnus Lofstrom Joseph Hayes Contents Appendix A. Data from the 2003 New Immigrant Survey Appendix B. Measuring

More information

RUSSELL SAGE FOUNDATION

RUSSELL SAGE FOUNDATION RUSSELL SAGE FOUNDATION Working Paper #201 POLITICAL POLARIZATION AND INCOME INEQUALITY Nolan McCarty Keith T. Poole Howard Rosenthal February 2003 Russell Sage Working Papers have not been reviewed by

More information

The Case of the Disappearing Bias: A 2014 Update to the Gerrymandering or Geography Debate

The Case of the Disappearing Bias: A 2014 Update to the Gerrymandering or Geography Debate The Case of the Disappearing Bias: A 2014 Update to the Gerrymandering or Geography Debate Nicholas Goedert Lafayette College goedertn@lafayette.edu May, 2015 ABSTRACT: This note observes that the pro-republican

More information

Who Would Have Won Florida If the Recount Had Finished? 1

Who Would Have Won Florida If the Recount Had Finished? 1 Who Would Have Won Florida If the Recount Had Finished? 1 Christopher D. Carroll ccarroll@jhu.edu H. Peyton Young pyoung@jhu.edu Department of Economics Johns Hopkins University v. 4.0, December 22, 2000

More information

Party Responsiveness and Mandate Balancing *

Party Responsiveness and Mandate Balancing * Party Responsiveness and Mandate Balancing * James Fowler Oleg Smirnov University of California, Davis University of Oregon May 05, 2005 Abstract Recent evidence suggests that parties are responsive to

More information

Who Votes Without Identification? Using Affidavits from Michigan to Learn About the Potential Impact of Strict Photo Voter Identification Laws

Who Votes Without Identification? Using Affidavits from Michigan to Learn About the Potential Impact of Strict Photo Voter Identification Laws Using Affidavits from Michigan to Learn About the Potential Impact of Strict Photo Voter Identification Laws Phoebe Henninger Marc Meredith Michael Morse University of Michigan University of Pennsylvania

More information

Iowa Voting Series, Paper 4: An Examination of Iowa Turnout Statistics Since 2000 by Party and Age Group

Iowa Voting Series, Paper 4: An Examination of Iowa Turnout Statistics Since 2000 by Party and Age Group Department of Political Science Publications 3-1-2014 Iowa Voting Series, Paper 4: An Examination of Iowa Turnout Statistics Since 2000 by Party and Age Group Timothy M. Hagle University of Iowa 2014 Timothy

More information

Lab 3: Logistic regression models

Lab 3: Logistic regression models Lab 3: Logistic regression models In this lab, we will apply logistic regression models to United States (US) presidential election data sets. The main purpose is to predict the outcomes of presidential

More information

Research Note: Toward an Integrated Model of Concept Formation

Research Note: Toward an Integrated Model of Concept Formation Kristen A. Harkness Princeton University February 2, 2011 Research Note: Toward an Integrated Model of Concept Formation The process of thinking inevitably begins with a qualitative (natural) language,

More information

Proposal for the 2016 ANES Time Series. Quantitative Predictions of State and National Election Outcomes

Proposal for the 2016 ANES Time Series. Quantitative Predictions of State and National Election Outcomes Proposal for the 2016 ANES Time Series Quantitative Predictions of State and National Election Outcomes Keywords: Election predictions, motivated reasoning, natural experiments, citizen competence, measurement

More information

Retrospective Voting

Retrospective Voting Retrospective Voting Who Are Retrospective Voters and Does it Matter if the Incumbent President is Running Kaitlin Franks Senior Thesis In Economics Adviser: Richard Ball 4/30/2009 Abstract Prior literature

More information

Report on Citizen Opinions about Voting & Elections

Report on Citizen Opinions about Voting & Elections Center for Public Opinion Dr. Joshua J. Dyck and Dr. Francis Talty, Co-Directors http://www.uml.edu/polls Report on Citizen Opinions about Voting & Elections Results of 2 surveys Polls Conducted by YouGov

More information

Appendix for Citizen Preferences and Public Goods: Comparing. Preferences for Foreign Aid and Government Programs in Uganda

Appendix for Citizen Preferences and Public Goods: Comparing. Preferences for Foreign Aid and Government Programs in Uganda Appendix for Citizen Preferences and Public Goods: Comparing Preferences for Foreign Aid and Government Programs in Uganda Helen V. Milner, Daniel L. Nielson, and Michael G. Findley Contents Appendix for

More information

Every Eligible Voter Counts: Correctly Measuring American Turnout Rates

Every Eligible Voter Counts: Correctly Measuring American Turnout Rates Every Eligible Voter Counts: Correctly Measuring American Turnout Rates Dr. Michael P. McDonald Dr. Michael P. McDonald is a Visiting Fellow at the Brookings Institution and an Assistant Professor at George

More information

Uncovering patterns among latent variables: human rights and de facto judicial independence

Uncovering patterns among latent variables: human rights and de facto judicial independence 605343RAP0010.1177/2053168015605343Research & PoliticsCrabtree and Fariss research-article2015 Research Article Uncovering patterns among latent variables: human rights and de facto judicial independence

More information

Journals in the Discipline: A Report on a New Survey of American Political Scientists

Journals in the Discipline: A Report on a New Survey of American Political Scientists THE PROFESSION Journals in the Discipline: A Report on a New Survey of American Political Scientists James C. Garand, Louisiana State University Micheal W. Giles, Emory University long with books, scholarly

More information

U.S. Family Income Growth

U.S. Family Income Growth Figure 1.1 U.S. Family Income Growth Growth 140% 120% 100% 80% 60% 115.3% 1947 to 1973 97.1% 97.7% 102.9% 84.0% 40% 20% 0% Lowest Fifth Second Fifth Middle Fifth Fourth Fifth Top Fifth 70% 60% 1973 to

More information

corruption since they might reect judicial eciency rather than corruption. Simply put,

corruption since they might reect judicial eciency rather than corruption. Simply put, Appendix Robustness Check As discussed in the paper, many question the reliability of judicial records as a proxy for corruption since they might reect judicial eciency rather than corruption. Simply put,

More information

RESEARCH NOTE The effect of public opinion on social policy generosity

RESEARCH NOTE The effect of public opinion on social policy generosity Socio-Economic Review (2009) 7, 727 740 Advance Access publication June 28, 2009 doi:10.1093/ser/mwp014 RESEARCH NOTE The effect of public opinion on social policy generosity Lane Kenworthy * Department

More information

Chapter 1 Introduction and Goals

Chapter 1 Introduction and Goals Chapter 1 Introduction and Goals The literature on residential segregation is one of the oldest empirical research traditions in sociology and has long been a core topic in the study of social stratification

More information

Missing Voices: Polling and Health Care

Missing Voices: Polling and Health Care Forum Missing Voices: Polling and Health Care Adam J. Berinsky Michele Margolis Massachusetts Institute of Technology Abstract Examining data on the recent health care legislation, we demonstrate that

More information

THE EFFECT OF EARLY VOTING AND THE LENGTH OF EARLY VOTING ON VOTER TURNOUT

THE EFFECT OF EARLY VOTING AND THE LENGTH OF EARLY VOTING ON VOTER TURNOUT THE EFFECT OF EARLY VOTING AND THE LENGTH OF EARLY VOTING ON VOTER TURNOUT Simona Altshuler University of Florida Email: simonaalt@ufl.edu Advisor: Dr. Lawrence Kenny Abstract This paper explores the effects

More information

The Effect of Ballot Order: Evidence from the Spanish Senate

The Effect of Ballot Order: Evidence from the Spanish Senate The Effect of Ballot Order: Evidence from the Spanish Senate Manuel Bagues Berta Esteve-Volart November 20, 2011 PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE Abstract This paper analyzes the relevance of ballot order in

More information

oductivity Estimates for Alien and Domestic Strawberry Workers and the Number of Farm Workers Required to Harvest the 1988 Strawberry Crop

oductivity Estimates for Alien and Domestic Strawberry Workers and the Number of Farm Workers Required to Harvest the 1988 Strawberry Crop oductivity Estimates for Alien and Domestic Strawberry Workers and the Number of Farm Workers Required to Harvest the 1988 Strawberry Crop Special Report 828 April 1988 UPI! Agricultural Experiment Station

More information

Voter and non-voter survey report

Voter and non-voter survey report Voter and non-voter survey report Proposal prepared for: Colmar Brunton contact The Electoral Commission Ian Binnie Date: 27 February 2012 Level 1, 6-10 The Strand PO Box 33690 Takapuna 0740 Auckland.

More information

IV. Labour Market Institutions and Wage Inequality

IV. Labour Market Institutions and Wage Inequality Fortin Econ 56 Lecture 4B IV. Labour Market Institutions and Wage Inequality 5. Decomposition Methodologies. Measuring the extent of inequality 2. Links to the Classic Analysis of Variance (ANOVA) Fortin

More information

REPORT AN EXAMINATION OF BALLOT REJECTION IN THE SCOTTISH PARLIAMENTARY ELECTION OF DR CHRISTOPHER CARMAN

REPORT AN EXAMINATION OF BALLOT REJECTION IN THE SCOTTISH PARLIAMENTARY ELECTION OF DR CHRISTOPHER CARMAN REPORT AN EXAMINATION OF BALLOT REJECTION IN THE SCOTTISH PARLIAMENTARY ELECTION OF 2007 DR CHRISTOPHER CARMAN christopher.carman@strath.ac.uk PROFESSOR JAMES MITCHELL j.mitchell@strath.ac.uk DEPARTMENT

More information

Response to the Evaluation Panel s Critique of Poverty Mapping

Response to the Evaluation Panel s Critique of Poverty Mapping Response to the Evaluation Panel s Critique of Poverty Mapping Peter Lanjouw and Martin Ravallion 1 World Bank, October 2006 The Evaluation of World Bank Research (hereafter the Report) focuses some of

More information

DATA ANALYSIS USING SETUPS AND SPSS: AMERICAN VOTING BEHAVIOR IN PRESIDENTIAL ELECTIONS

DATA ANALYSIS USING SETUPS AND SPSS: AMERICAN VOTING BEHAVIOR IN PRESIDENTIAL ELECTIONS Poli 300 Handout B N. R. Miller DATA ANALYSIS USING SETUPS AND SPSS: AMERICAN VOTING BEHAVIOR IN IDENTIAL ELECTIONS 1972-2004 The original SETUPS: AMERICAN VOTING BEHAVIOR IN IDENTIAL ELECTIONS 1972-1992

More information

Forecasting the 2018 Midterm Election using National Polls and District Information

Forecasting the 2018 Midterm Election using National Polls and District Information Forecasting the 2018 Midterm Election using National Polls and District Information Joseph Bafumi, Dartmouth College Robert S. Erikson, Columbia University Christopher Wlezien, University of Texas at Austin

More information

The Effect of North Carolina s New Electoral Reforms on Young People of Color

The Effect of North Carolina s New Electoral Reforms on Young People of Color A Series on Black Youth Political Engagement The Effect of North Carolina s New Electoral Reforms on Young People of Color In August 2013, North Carolina enacted one of the nation s most comprehensive

More information

FOREIGN FIRMS AND INDONESIAN MANUFACTURING WAGES: AN ANALYSIS WITH PANEL DATA

FOREIGN FIRMS AND INDONESIAN MANUFACTURING WAGES: AN ANALYSIS WITH PANEL DATA FOREIGN FIRMS AND INDONESIAN MANUFACTURING WAGES: AN ANALYSIS WITH PANEL DATA by Robert E. Lipsey & Fredrik Sjöholm Working Paper 166 December 2002 Postal address: P.O. Box 6501, S-113 83 Stockholm, Sweden.

More information

Practice Questions for Exam #2

Practice Questions for Exam #2 Fall 2007 Page 1 Practice Questions for Exam #2 1. Suppose that we have collected a stratified random sample of 1,000 Hispanic adults and 1,000 non-hispanic adults. These respondents are asked whether

More information