Concurrent Elections and Voter Attention: How voters search for political information in crowded campaign environments

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Concurrent Elections and Voter Attention: How voters search for political information in crowded campaign environments"

Transcription

1 Concurrent Elections and Voter Attention: How voters search for political information in crowded campaign environments David J. Andersen PhD Candidate Rutgers, The State University of New Jersey New Brunswick, NJ

2 Concurrent Elections and Voter Attention: How voters search for political information in crowded campaign environments In this paper, I use an experiment run in the dynamic process-tracing environment (DPTE) to examine how voters change their search for information about candidates in different offices based simply upon the electoral environment. I find that voters tend to not change their overall information search for political information, but alter the rate at which they search for each office they encounter. They do gravitate towards certain offices more than others, so that the more offices appear on the ballot, the less information is encountered about each set of candidates. This does, however, hurt lower offices to a greater extent than higher offices. Representative governments rely upon voters to voluntarily expend time and energy learning about candidates and issues, evaluate the various options against their own personal preferences, and then cast a ballot registering all of their candidate preferences. The simple fact that some voters meet these expectations has captivated political scientists for decades. The costs of voting - the effort to learn, the cognitive energy to evaluate, and the physical effort to register to vote, locate a polling center or obtain an absentee ballot, and then physically vote - seem to vastly outweigh the benefits of participating (Riker and Ordeshook 1968). It also is extremely unlikely that in any large-scale democracy a single voter could expect to cast the pivotal vote in any contest, further narrowing the enticement to participate. Even if voters are able to surmount the obstacles to participation and cast a vote, there is an additional challenge to the elections process how many votes can people really make at once? Each vote decision relies upon unique information about the candidates for a particular office. Voters must invest the time and energy to gather information about each office, develop preferences and then cast votes. Completing this task for a single office may be possible, but what about for multiple offices all at once? 1

3 The curious fact that people do participate and vote, even for a single contest, seems unusual when voters are confronted and asked to explain their understanding of the political system and the candidates they vote on. Citizens and voters consistently fail to demonstrate the most rudimentary knowledge about politics, either in its structure, functioning or even the names of people currently holding power (Delli Carpini and Keeter 1996). How, given a lack of incentives to participate, and clear evidence that voters are uninformed, can a democratic electoral system function? And even if people demonstrate that they are able to make a vote decision, can they make multiple simultaneous vote decisions all at once? Research has already demonstrated that concurrent campaigns decrease what voters can recall about congressional candidates after an election (Wolak 2009, Andersen 2009), so is there a point at which voters simply can no longer keep all the candidates straight, and must simply cast arbitrary votes? Low Information, Rational Voting The widespread solution to the participatory dilemma in voting where voters apparently know very little about politics, yet still vote has been that voters rely upon cues and heuristics to streamline the effort required to vote competently into a manageable size. By relying upon shortcuts, voters are able to assess candidates by simple cues, such as their political party membership (Campbell et al 1960), personal likeability (Sniderman, Brody and Tetlock 1991), outside endorsements (Lupia 1994) or by relying on retrospective evaluations of incumbents and the current state of the world (Key 1966, Fiorina 1981). A small cornucopia of shortcuts are recognized as being available to voters, all permitting decisions to be made regarding candidates with lessthan-full sets of information. 2

4 Among the very first identified was from the iconic American Voter, pointing to the clear cue of political identification when making vote decisions (Campbell et al 1960). Voters aware of which party they preferred, or identified with, are spared the burden of learning the details of policy space and candidate issue stances, because the simple information of which party a candidate represented would provide general indications for them. This alone can account for the vast majority of low information political decision-making witnessed in society. So long as people understand the political parties, can recognize a preferred party and identify the party a candidate represents, decision-making can be reduced to the simplest of functions. Party identification provides a prospective cue, allowing voters to select a candidate aligned with their own preferences. Another easy way to select a candidate without even having to understand parties is to simply evaluate the state of the world and reward/punish the party in power for that state (Key 1966, Fiorina 1981). This retrospective evaluation requires less work for a voter, because evaluating the state of the world requires no special knowledge on their part and can be done with simple pocketbook evaluations. If you feel that your life is better today than it was four years ago, you should probably retain the party in power. If not, you should probably replace them. The key information necessary, aside from recognizing the state of the world and whether it is preferable today compared to during the previous election, is the simple ability to recognize which candidates are the incumbents. Such retrospective voting may minimize the role of political campaigns too completely though, leaving little to no room for candidates themselves to influence their election. Clearly, campaigns play a role and candidates clearly are important figures, 3

5 drawing support in part by conveying a positive image among the electorate. Without relying upon issue stances, party cues or past evaluations, some voters seem willing and able to select preferred candidates based upon their personal likeability, or based upon their individual issue stances or by who else is supporting them (Sniderman, Brody and Tetlock 1991, Lupia 1994, Popkin 1994). By all of these measures, voters can learn a little about a candidate allowing them to surmise how they will behave once in office. Such shortcuts permit voters to use a bare minimum of knowledge to guess at future behavior of candidates, allowing them to select that candidate who will hopefully represent their preferences best. Weaknesses to Cognitive Shortcuts These shortcuts, while efficient, are not perfect, nor are they necessarily easy to use. Party knowledge, for example, is not a perfect proxy for candidate issue stances and likely becomes less accurate when used farther down the hierarchy of offices. Current party platforms are generated primarily by presidential candidates, forcing their political beliefs upon the rest of the party. On a national level, knowing the party platform or general stance of the party may simplify presidential selection, because of the close association of the two. For lower ballot candidates, even those proximal such as Governors, Senators and House members, the clear association may be lacking. A simple look at popular ratings of members of Congress, such as NOMINATE scores, reveals great variance within parties on the voting habits of their members. Party membership may connote closeness among its members, but only represents a general indication of individual candidate stances. This association, presumably, becomes weaker in lower offices that have less impact in the development of party stances. Within any specific 4

6 congressional district, knowing a candidates party identification may not reveal a great deal about that candidate s political beliefs or priorities. Particularly when voting for representatives that are expected to focus on local concerns, being able to associate a candidate with a national party (which by definition focuses on national concerns) may not provide sufficient insight into what the candidate represents. Using party identification in a less precise way, by simply identifying the party in power with the general tone of the country, rewarding that party and its members when things are going well, punishing them when things are poor, also suffers some weaknesses (Key 1966, Fiorina 1981, Rahn 2000). While simplifying voter decisionmaking, the rationality of such a heuristic for all levels of office is questionable. Selecting, for example, which party members are to blame for a faulty economy or disagreeable public policy may be far more complex than a specific candidates incumbency provides (Popkin et al 1976, Rudolph 2003). Nevertheless, voters do appear to use incumbency as a tool for selecting candidates, often punishing members of the President s party during midterm elections, and rewarding Presidential candidates and their Congressional running mates during positive economic times (MacKuen et al 1989). Rational or not, party identification and incumbency together provide two powerful cues facilitating vote choice. For more candidate specific cues, such as issue stances, personal likeability or other candidate-specific information, voters would require a much greater store of information when making a selection. In light of the recurrent finding that American voters typically lack much political information, this would seem beyond most voters, but this may not be the case. When dealing with candidate specific information, voters may 5

7 rely upon running tallies about candidates, aggregating likes and dislikes about the candidate to help them form a general impression, while discarding the individual bits of information after they are processed (Lodge 1989). In this way, voters form educated judgments about candidates, even while being unable to recall from where exactly those judgments arise, explaining the general low levels of political knowledge found on surveys. For on-line processing to be effective however, voters must first encounter information in sufficient degree to form these preferences between the candidates. There remains a minimum level of information that is required to make the shortcut effective. For all of these cognitive shortcuts, the assumption is that voters have encountered a sufficient level of information to form distinctions between the candidates in each particular elective office. Whether relying upon partisan cues, retrospective evaluations or some more particular candidate evaluations, voters must have at least encountered enough information to know something about candidates for each office. That information, in a candidate-centered election system, must be unique to each candidate and also applicable to the particular office they are competing for if it is to be truly relevant to the vote decision. The Electoral Environment When discussing the public s ability to make vote decisions, and especially vote decisions concurrently, one more factor is extremely relevant the distribution of political knowledge across offices. In campaigning and the spread of information, all offices are clearly not equal. Higher offices generally have much greater finances at hand that enable them to campaign. Gaining additional information about candidates and offices requires an effort upon the part of the voter to search out information, or at least 6

8 be receptive to that which is brought directly to them. This creates two interacting efforts during an election cycle that contribute to political knowledge: 1) campaigns attempts to educate voters about a candidate and 2) an individual s attempt to learn about all of the races they will be asked to vote on. Both of these processes differ by office, or at least are likely to. Campaigns widely differ based upon the office in question, in large part because candidates for higher offices typically have larger financial backing with which to advertise themselves. Higher offices spend many times the money spent by lower races, allowing them to get their information out to more voters, more often. In 2008, spending by all 27 Presidential candidates totaled $1.8 billion, while all 435 House races combined, totaling 1374 candidates, remained a mere fraction of that amount nationwide, $977 million. The average Senate candidate had $2.4 million to spend in 2008, while the average House candidate had less than a third of that, $700, Higher races also benefit from the relative ease of reaching their constituent base efficiently via mass media, whereas lower races must struggle to reach their audiences via media markets that are not contiguous with their districts. Every advertising dollar spent in a Presidential race is nearly assured to reach potential voters, whereas House candidates risk spending campaign dollars advertising in markets that overlap outside their constituency, wasting their efforts on citizens who cannot vote for them. Finally, Presidential candidates and Senate candidates benefit from notoriety and prestige, granting them access to free press in the media that lower candidates can only aspire to. The information environment simply is not as rich farther down the ballot. 1 According to Opensecrets.org, 7

9 A sufficiently motivated citizenry may overcome this. If voters are completely passive when living through campaigns, they will receive only those messages that they encounter. The great bulk of these will be from higher offices, that have greater finances and capability to get their messages out. Only if voters are willing to put in the effort to seek out information about lower offices will they obtain a comparable level of information about all of the offices they face. A major unanswered question is how voters attempt to learn about candidates, especially in regards to when multiple offices appear on the ballot. Motivated citizens who want to make informed vote decisions must attempt to learn something about the candidates in each race they will cast a vote in, overcoming differences in the information environment. Since the information environment tends to be skewed in favor of higher office candidates, voters would have to work harder to learn a comparable level of information about lower office candidates, because less information is available about them. If voters fail to do so, they will encounter less information about candidates for lower office, making even cognitive shortcuts even harder to use effectively. It is this search for information that I am concerned with. Little to no research exists on how voters seek out information about different types of offices, or what those search strategies are affected by. Voter decision-making on all levels requires a minimal base of knowledge about each office that is voted on. On the presidential level, political psychology has demonstrated that voters often rely upon cognitive shortcuts to make their vote choice manageable amid low levels of political information. For such strategies to also work for other offices, at a minimum we would have to see that voters seek out information about those offices in a similar manner as for presidential candidates. Based 8

10 upon the availability of information that is typical in most real-world campaigns, voters would actually have to search more actively for lower office information if they were to assemble a comparable level of information as encountered for higher offices. Even if they were to use the same cognitive short cuts for all races, voters have to put in a greater effort in gathering information in lower races to make such strategies effective. Methods In order to assess how voters search for information about candidates, I rely on the Dynamic Process Tracing Environment (DPTE), a web-based software application developed by Richard Lau and David Redlawsk with support from the National Science Foundation. DPTE permits researchers to create experiments using dynamic information boards that mimic a campaign and monitor how subjects choose to learn about the various candidates. Lau and Redlawsk have used similar designs to study Correct Voting (Lau and Redlawsk 1997), and voter information searches (Lau and Redlawsk 2006, Redlawsk 2004). Those studies looked solely at presidential elections, however. The DPTE system allows researchers to create fictional political candidates, complete with demographic information, political identities, issue stances and realistic backgrounds. Each distinct piece of information about the candidates is located within an information box. During the campaign portion of the experiment, these boxes scroll down the screen at a steady pace. If the subject decides to learn the information within the box, they click on it using the mouse and the box opens, filling the screen. When the subject has read the information, they then click the box again, closing it and returning them to the view of scrolling boxes. This is the standard method Lau and Redlawsk have 9

11 used over the past decade in exploring both Correct Voting and voter information searches. The primary contribution I make to Lau and Redlawsk s experimental design is the inclusion of additional contests into the electoral scenario. Their work has focused exclusively on candidates at the presidential level, running in isolation from other contests. In my scenario, I created a 2 x 2 x 2 research design creating 8 possible electoral scenarios that subjects could experience, but all of which included at least 2 offices simultaneously. Thus, subjects were forced to divide their information search among candidates and among offices as well, adding external validity to the scenario and allowing me to monitor what strategies subjects adopted to accomplish this, and how effective those strategies were. Sample In the spring of 2010, 279 research subjects were recruited from various political science courses at Rutgers University to participate in this study. Subjects participated either as a course requirement or to receive extra credit, depending on the course they were enrolled in. After arriving at the experimental lab, each subject was brought to a workstation, given a description of the experiment and an informed consent form, and then started on the program. Participation typically took about 1 hour. Of those original 279 subjects, data from 12 subjects were eliminated from the final data set; 4 because they experienced a flawed election 2 and 8 because they apparently discovered the ability to access the internet from the computers and did not actually participate in the 2 Due to a design error on my part, several election scenarios permitted subjects to view information about candidates whom did not actually appear on the ballot. The ability to access this outside information makes the data on how they structured their information search unusable. 10

12 campaign scenario, opening fewer than 10 information boxes over the course of the 20 minute campaign. The use of college students as subjects is always a risky proposition in experimental research and has its positives and negatives (Sears 1986). When looking at strictly cognitive or neurological functions college students can often be considered representative of the population as a whole, because such functions are typically outside of conscious control and thus factors such as age and experience become irrelevant. When asking subjects to make conscious choices however, including choosing how to search for information about political candidates, factors such as age and experience can make a difference. With age may come better understanding of how to cope with concurrent elections, or perhaps just different strategies. Even in recognition of this fact, with this research the ready availability and low cost of using college students was the prime motivation in their selection. As a first look, college students were selected as the natural choice. Manipulations and Innovation to Previous Research Each of the 8 scenarios to which subjects could be assigned presented multiple offices for subjects to learn about and then vote for. In each version, a race for the House of Representatives was contested, as well as an election for an executive office (either the President or Governor). Additionally, some subjects viewed a Senate race, as well. These four offices the House, Senate, President and Governor were chosen because they are typically the most visible races on a given ballot, providing voters with the most available information. In addition to the information boxes for the candidates for each political office, boxes for Current Events also appeared, filling in space during the campaign 11

13 and acting as a distraction (for more on Current Events, see below). The 3 major manipulations embedded in this experiment were: Senate Race 1. Presence of a Senate Race 2. Executive at top of the ballot President or Governor 3. Distribution of Information Equal or Realistic The presence of a Senate race on the ballot manipulates the number of offices subjects are asked to learn about. With no Senate race on the ballot subjects witness contests for two political offices, while in the Senate race manipulation they witness three. The difference between two and three races is not huge, but provides leverage for seeing how search patterns for information about one set of candidates differs based simply upon the presence of another set of candidates. Larger affects are likely to occur as greater numbers of offices, and less familiar offices are added to the ballot, but this design first examines these affects among the more prominent offices. President or Governor Manipulating what appears at the top of the ballot is achieved by manipulating the executive office being contested subjects vote for either the president or the governor. Presidential contests have been the norm in previous dynamic information board research and are what we know most about. In midterm election cycles however, 36 states typically contest their governor s election, adding this to the biannual federal races. Thus, in most areas of the country, voters must balance learning about congressional candidates with either presidential campaigns during one cycle, and gubernatorial campaigns during the midterms. This provides leverage in seeing whether the type of office that appears on the top of the ballot influences how people search for information about the candidates farther down the ballot does the presence of a presidential race 12

14 alter information searches about House candidates in different ways the presence of a gubernatorial race? Equal vs. Realistic A final manipulation embedded within this experiment altered the availability of information about the candidates. In every manipulation, each unique piece of information about each candidate appears at least once. In most campaigns however, information is available more than just once, but its availability often hinges upon campaign resources. Indeed, the current understanding of why voters can recall more about higher-office candidates than lower-office candidates is that higher offices, particularly the presidency, receive and can purchase much greater media attention than lower offices, particularly the House. To explore this question, some subjects received an equal amount of information about all of the candidates, with each box of information for each candidate appearing twice. For other subjects, a more realistic distribution of information was presented. For House candidates, each piece of information was only presented a single time, for senate and gubernatorial candidates they appeared twice, and presidential candidates had their information boxes appear four times each. While this does not precisely match the distribution of information typically available in campaigns, is does approximate it. 3 Current Events 3 Determining what would be a realistic distribution of information is exceedingly difficult, because the information environment is highly responsive to incumbency, candidate-specific attributes, region of the country and state and the competitiveness of the electoral environment. In general though, senate candidates typically at least double the spending of house candidates in any given area, while presidential candidates at least double the spending of senate candidates within a state. 13

15 An added feature of this experiment that has not been used before is the inclusion of Current Events boxes. 50 current events were created that had as little bearing on the political world as possible. They were mainly entertainment news ( MTV plays first music video in 10 years ), sports news ( Rutgers joins the Big 10 Conference ), or technology news ( Apple unveils new ithing ). They operate in an identical manner as the political information boxes, and opened when clicked, but rather than provide information on a candidate would explain the current event listed on the label. These boxes serve two functions: 1. Filler 2. Distractions The first function is to allow each manipulation to have the exact same number of boxes flow through the campaign and keep their length identical. Regardless of the offices on the ballot, this keeps each campaign at 20-minutes in length, giving all subjects identical time constraints to work under. The time left in a campaign until the election appeared on the screen in the upper right hand corner, counting down the minutes and seconds subjects had left to learn about the candidates. As a result of the inclusion of different numbers of candidates (senate manipulation) and from showing different amounts of repeat boxes (distribution of information manipulation) the campaign times could potentially be longer or shorter than one another based upon the manipulations a subject was assigned. In the real world, campaigns do not grow longer or shorter as a result of the length of the ballot, so in order to compensate for this current event boxes are used to fill in the gaps, making each campaign 20 minutes long. These boxes were designed to be as politically neutral as possible, so that reading them would have no conceivable impact on how the viewer perceived the ongoing campaigns. 14

16 The other role of the current events was to allow subjects to ignore and escape the campaigns. Most political science experiments lock subjects into a political task, forcing them to focus upon the objective at hand. This clearly weakens the external validity of an experiment in important ways. It forces the subject to perform at their maximum capabilities, focusing upon political stimuli in a manner that simply does not exist in the real world. This biases results, often in the researcher s favor, because it only provides feedback on what subjects are capable of when they experience politics in isolation and solely focus on the matter before them. In the real world however, people opt to focus on politics as a matter of choice. Most people endure a long workday and then come home to enjoy relaxation and calm, following politics alongside other more enjoyable activities. Thus, the current events are here designed to mimic the distractions of life they are designed to be funny, lighthearted and amusing. They are time-wasters. Just like surfing the internet or watching TV, they are present as a more enjoyable and enticing distraction than learning political information about candidates. Subjects are free to view as many or as few as they wish, but doing so prevents them for learning more about the candidates they will be asked to vote for. Summary In total, the 279 subjects were randomly assigned into one of eight conditions formed by the 2x2x2 presence of the manipulations. In each scenario, an equal number of total information boxes were available (400), and each attribute about every candidate was viewable at least once. It was completely up to the subjects to choose which and how many attributes about which candidate they wished to view. This design permits 15

17 information searches to be compared between matching scenarios, where similar number of candidates (though of different types), similar sets of candidates (though sometimes with an additional contest as well) and similar complete ballot structures (though with different rates of information availability for the offices) compete against each other in a total information environment that presents an identical set of total information boxes. Hypotheses I expect that voters approaching concurrent elections will react rationally towards the information environment they encounter, seeking out as much information as they can about campaigns before they have to make a vote decision. However, I believe that voters are also limited in how much political information they are willing to consume at once, creating a cap on the total level of information search they will conduct. Further, I feel that these limitations will lead voters to gravitate to focus a greater level of attention on those offices that are perceived as more important, or more powerful, than others. From these basic precepts, I derive several hypotheses about how voters will react to my experimental manipulations listed in table 1, below. <<<<<< Insert Table 1 about here >>>>>> Results Three-way Analysis of Variance In order to control for the three major manipulations present in this experiment - the presence or absence of a senate race, the presence of either a governor or president as the lead executive office, and the distribution of information between the offices - I employ three-way analyses of variance. Three-way ANOVA s provide both statistical tests of the effects of the manipulations as well as descriptive results by controlling for 16

18 the presence of the various manipulations and testing for both main and interaction effects. Table 2, below, shows the descriptive statistics for the number of attributes viewed in total, and for each office, in each of the manipulation conditions. <<<<<< Insert Table 2 about here >>>>>> The descriptive statistics reveal a great deal of movement between the average number of attributes subjects viewed for each set of candidates, depending upon which set of manipulations they experienced. The total information encountered ranged from a high of attributes in the fourth column when the presidency, a senate and congressional contest were fought with equal information - to a minimum of attributes when only the presidency and congress were contested, but under with realistic information availability. This is a vast difference in the average information encountered between these conditions, amounting to more than a 20% shift in information from the minimum to maximum. In a real-world environment, this implies that under different conditions voters overall level of political information may fluctuate by a similarly large degree under different electoral scenarios. The differences withinoffices are also dramatic. Views of the executives attributes range from a minimum of to a high of a greater than 50% increase in information access depending on the manipulation conditions. Senate searches are more stable, which is expected considering its very presence is a manipulation and that its information availability does not change. It experiences only a slight shift from to views at its extremes. Congressional information searches also show wide variability, gaining the deepest search when contested only alongside the presidency in the equal information condition (

19 attributes viewed) and falling below half of that rate when contested alongside both the gubernatorial and senatorial candidates in the realistic condition (14.04 attributes viewed). <<<<<< Insert Figure 1 about here >>>>>> These findings are also viewable graphically. Figure 1 presents a bar graph separating the average total attributes viewed by subjects into their component parts, by manipulation. The bar chart allows quick comparison between the depth of information search for each office, and with total information search in general, and appears to show large differences. In order to determine if these differences are actually statistically significant, I also use the significance tests generated by the three-way ANOVA procedure, presented below in table 3. <<<<<< Insert Table 3 about here >>>>>> Subjects responded to the manipulations in many ways. One of the interesting findings here is that not all of the manipulations affected all of the various information searches. Each manipulation had effects on particular types of searches, and each search responded to different manipulations. The one exception to this was the depth of search for Senate candidates, which produced no substantive findings here. Both the lack of true manipulations in this condition, alongside the low number of subjects who experienced a Senate contest, made it unlikely that statistically significant results will appear here. The other offices provide much more information about how changes in the electoral environment can alter information searches. Table 3 shows that subjects altered their total search for information in response to only one of the manipulations, the distribution of information. Looking at both table 2 18

20 and table 3 together can explain both the significance and the direction of changes, but it is much easier to understand how information searches responded to the manipulations by plotting these results graphically. In order to see how subjects altered each search, I plotted the estimated marginal means, taking into account the three manipulations present. The results for the overall information search are presented below in Figure 2. <<<<<<Insert Figure 2 about here >>>>>> As Figure 2 shows, the information distribution manipulations had significant effects upon how many attributes subjects viewed in total, decreasing the number of attributes viewed when there was a more realistic, rather than equal, availability of information about the various offices. While it made no statistical difference whether the Governor or President was on the ballot, or whether the Senate also was contested, subjects did view significantly fewer items when there was a realistic distribution of information rather than an equal distribution. The direction of all four lines in figure 2 also suggests that when the senatorial contest appeared, subjects did view more information, though table 2 indicates that it is not a significantly greater amount. This is surprising, because with the senate race on the ballot, the number of total attributes available to view increases by 25%. Subjects did not respond to this by altering their overall information search however, but instead average a statistically identical number of attributes viewed. Hypothesis H1 proposed that when an additional contest was added to the ballot subjects would seek out more information overall, but this is not what this analysis reveals. Hypothesis H2 further suggested that when the presidency was contested subjects would also seek out greater amounts of overall information. Both of these hypotheses are rejected here. Only hypothesis H3 is 19

21 confirmed, finding that in the realistic distribution of information, subjects viewed fewer attributes overall. These results suggest that subjects and, via them, voters, may indeed have a set upper limit for information search during a campaign. When more offices and candidates appear, voters respond by dividing their search to a greater extent between the various campaigns, but not searching for more information, overall. 4 <<<<<<Insert Figure 3 about here>>>>>> Looking at how subjects searched for information about each office is also instructive, and points to some clear differences in the level of information subjects seek out each type of office. Figure 3 clearly shows a difference in the number of attributes viewed for congressional candidates depending upon which conditions subjects faced. Those subjects in the equal information distribution condition viewed significantly more attributes than did those in the realistic-distribution condition. By reducing the availability of information about congressional candidates, subjects do lose the ability to become aware of what those candidates stand for. Similarly, candidates who are unable to put sufficient advertising into the campaign environment must similarly suffer, with voters unable to learn what they stand for, and forced to either guess or draw inferences from other information. The inclusion of a Senate contest also significantly decreases the depth of congressional search, again suggesting that when additional offices appear on the ballot, overall information search for each is divided up between the offices, lowering the depth of information search about each one. 4 This could also be a result of subjects hitting a time limit in the experiment, where they viewed as many items as possible, but simply ran out of time to view more. This is highly unlikely, because subjects on average only viewed about 25% of all the boxes that scrolled before them, spending little more than half of the available time doing so. Most subjects had a great deal of extra time left to open more information, but simply chose not to. 20

22 <<<<<< Insert Figure 4 about here >>>>>> In contrast, none of the manipulations altered the search for information about Senate candidates. Though only half the sample viewed a Senate contest, making it more difficult to achieve statistical significance, the line graph in figure 4 demonstrates that there was also no substantive effect of the manipulations, and subjects tended to view the same amount of information about Senate candidates regardless of the election environment they were in. This is not very surprising, because the Senate race was not subject to the manipulations per se. When it appeared on the ballot, there were always two other contests, so it should have received a constant depth of search, which it did. When appearing, the senatorial contests also produced a constant availability of information, so the only effects that can be expected there are in response to changes in congressional or presidential information differences. Nothing is found in these results, which indicates that the depth of Senate information search was largely immune to outside campaign spending in this experiment. <<<<<< Insert Figure 5 about here >>>>>> The final office to examine, the Executive, is affected by two manipulations, but in this case it is the presence of the Senate contest and which executive appears that make a significant difference. Both of those manipulations are statistically significant, while the distribution of information manipulation is just below the standard threshold for significance. Figure 5, below, shows that the presence of a Senate contest drastically decreases the depth of information search for presidential candidates. While the difference in the level of search based upon which executive office appears is difficult to determine in this set of charts, there is a clear difference in the effect that the distribution 21

23 of information had upon the executive when they were a governor compared to a president. For the gubernatorial candidates, the two lines overlap, indicating that the information search for gubernatorial candidates was unresponsive to the information availability condition. For the presidential candidates however, the lines are separate and parallel, indicating that the increased availability of information about the presidential candidates did encourage subjects to view more information about them, though not significantly so. The three-way ANOVA for the executive answers hypothesis 4, which proposed that, controlling for everything else, subjects would search for more information about the president than the governor. This statistical test in the analysis of variance shows that there is a statistically significant difference in the depth of search for information about these two offices, and the descriptive statistics indicate that it is in favor of the presidency. This hypothesis is thus confirmed. While the addition of another contest, the Senate, decreased the depth of information searches for both congressional and executive candidates, the campaign spending manipulation did not produce strong results. The distribution of information creates variance both in how offices were able to campaign, with the realistic condition increasing campaigning by the presidential candidates, while decreasing campaigning by the congressional candidates. Conclusions This analysis presents a first rough look into how voters learn about multiple candidates campaigning for different offices all at once. In it, I demonstrate that voters do appear to have an upper limit on their total search for political information during 22

24 campaigns. This limit results in voters learning a rather stable amount of information about politics, regardless of how many offices are contested at once. As a consequence, when more offices are contested at once, voters learn less about each set of candidates on the ballot. Voters are also responsive to the information environment around them, choosing to seek out more information about campaigns that have more active campaigns, while being unable to learn a great deal about less active campaigns. Additionally, voters search out different levels of information about different offices on the ballot, prioritizing information search about executives over legislative offices, and Senate candidates over House candidates. Subjects have two options when presented with additional contests during a campaign cycle. First, they could increase the level of information they view in relation to the number of offices being contested, adding on to the number of views in an additive fashion with no indentified limits. This would imply that voters always attempt to learn a certain level of information about each contest they encounter, altering their attention to politics proportionally to the number of offices being contested, and increasing their information search to allow them to learn a constant level of information about each office on the ballot. The other alternative is less ambitious, suggesting instead that subjects generally operate under an identifiable upper boundary of information search. This boundary prevents voters from searching for a constant set of information about all of the candidates, but allows them to distribute their information search equivalently (or according to some set ratio) between the offices. If voters have a set maximum attention level that they are willing and able to expend when monitoring campaigns, they must 23

25 shift their allocation of search somehow among the available offices, decreasing the actual information they learn about the individual candidates, whether that means implementing equal decreases in search across the board, or systematically choosing which candidates get more attention than others. The consequence of the first style of information search is that, while voters may be able to make well informed decisions, they would require a great deal of effort to do so. The consequence of the second is that, while maintaining a comfortable level of information search, voters faced with many contests may not be able to learn enough about all of the office-candidates Between these two options, the latter receives greater support at this stage. Simply looking at the line graphs of the changes in the total information search along with the related significance levels suggest that subjects did not respond to the offices on the ballot when searching for information overall. There is no evidence that the addition of 54 new unique information items for the senate caused subjects to view more information boxes in a sufficient quantity to support the first option. The only manipulation that affected total information search was that for the distribution of information between candidates. Subjects exposed themselves to greater levels of information when all of the offices campaigned to an equal degree, presenting each piece of information about the candidates twice, rather than when the presidential candidates (when appearing) presented their attributes four times to the House s single appearance. Subjects may have simply recognized the overwhelming presence of repeat information, and had a limit to what they were interested in learning about each candidate. In response, they chose to forego the opportunity to seek out additional information about the president, because they have already learned enough, while being 24

26 unable to open more boxes about the House because of their unavailability. This would lead subjects to open boxes for the president at roughly the same rate between conditions, while being able to open fewer for the House, leading to a significant difference overall (the Senate and governor did not change between conditions, so no difference would be expected). That is what the results point to. In real world elections, a scenario in which only two or three offices is contested is exceedingly rare. States currently attempt to minimize the costs of running an election by placing as many offices as possible on the ballot at once. If the results found here generalize further down the ballot, this poses great challenges to our current understanding of democracy and voting. If voters respond to concurrent elections by learning less and less about the offices they face, and particularly less about those offices with the least prestige, power and ability to raise campaign finances, at some point they will pass below a minimum threshold of information necessary to use even the most basic heuristic. Unable to identify any information about a candidate, voters must cast votes based upon the information they view on the ballot typically the name, incumbency and party of the candidates. Without any other information about the candidates, voters must guess, using heuristics that are better tailored for higher-level offices. This guesswork makes voting at lower levels of the political process into a blunt tool, basing state and local decisions upon the understanding that voters develop of national level politics. Local political matters become susceptible to national level forces that have little relevance to the powers and responsibilities of state and local government. In a world where dozens of states face structural deficits developed over years of poor governmental decision- 25

27 making, and millions of voters wonder who was responsible, this may provide a clue as to the source of current troubles. When elections are clustered together, voters pay little attention to the bottom of the ballot, learning very little about the actions and proposals of state and local officials. This leaves these offices largely unmonitored, and puts the occupants of those offices in a peculiar position. If they do little to attract attention, they are likely to win reelection and keep a position they enjoy. If they do make bold moves however perhaps attempting to resolve societal problems through tough choices, such as tax increases or spending cuts those actions will be noticed by the public. As the only bits of information that voters receive, because their attention remains largely at the top of the ballot, such bold actions result in negative consequences on Election Day, turning lower-ballot elected officials out of office when they make bold moves. The only rational strategy that remains is to do little to attract negative attention, even when the consequences for society are dire. Concurrent elections, by exceeding the ability of the average voter to gather enough information about all the offices and candidates, make lower office-holders less likely to act in ways that may necessary for the public good. Ironically, under the design of the constitution, these are the very offices that are supposed to be most responsive to public will. 26

28 References Andersen, David J The Electoral Environment and House Races: Political Knowledge, Political Interest and Government Evaluations as a Function of Electoral Density. Paper presented at the 2009 annual meeting of the Midwest Political Science Association. Campbell, Angus, Philip E. Converse, Warren E. Miller, and Donald E. Stokes The American Voter. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Conover, Pamela Johnston and Stanley Feldman. Candidate Perception in an Ambiguous World: Campaigns, Cues, and Inference Processes. American Journal of Political Science, Vol. 33, No. 4 (Nov., 1989), pp Delli Carpini, Michael X. and Scott Keeter What Americans Know About Politics and Why it Matters. Yale University Press, New Haven, CT. Downs, Anthony An Economic Theory of Democracy. New York: Harper & Row. Fiorina, Morris P Retrospective Voting in American national Elections. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press. Funk, Carolyn L. Bringing the Candidate into Models of Candidate Evaluation. The Journal of Politics, Vol. 61, No. 3. (Aug., 1999), pp Green, Donald P., Bradley Palmquist, and Eric Schickler Macropartisanship: A Replication and Critique. American Political Science Review, 92(December): Key, V.O The Responsible Electorate. Cambridge, MA. Harvard University Press. Lau, Richard R. and David P. Redlawsk "Voting Correctly." American Political Science Review, 91(September): Lau, Richard R. and David P. Redlawsk "Advantages and Disadvantages of Cognitive Heuristics in Political Decision Making." American Journal of Political Science, 45(October): Lau, Richard R. and David P. Redlawsk How Voters Decide: Information Processing During Election Campaigns. New York: Cambridge University Press. Lodge, Milton, Kathleen M. McGraw, and Patrick Stroh An Impression Driven Model of Candidate Evaluation. American Political Science Review 83(June):

29 Arthur Lupia Shortcuts versus Encyclopedias: Information and Voting Behavior in California Insurance Reform Elections. American Political Science Review 88: Lupia, Arthur, Mathew D. McCubbins, and Samuel L. Popkin Beyond Rationality: Reason and the Study of Politics. In Arthur Lupia, Mathew D. McCubbins, and Samuel L. Popkin (eds.), Elements of Reason: Cognition, Choice, and the Bounds of Rationality. New York: Cambridge University Press. MacKuen, Michael B., Robert S. Erikson, and James A. Stimson Macropartisanship. American Political Science Review, 83(December): Popkin, Samuel The Reasoning Voter: Communication and Persuasion in Presidential Campaigns. Chicago, IL. University of Chicago Press. Rahn, Wendy Affect as information: The Role of Public Mood in Poltitical Reasoning. In Arthur Lupia, Mathew D. McCubbins, and Samuel L. Popkin (eds.), Elements of Reason: Cognition, Choice, and the Bounds of Rationality. New York: Cambridge University Press Redlawsk, David P What Voters Do: Information Search during Election Campaigns. Political Psychology 25(August): Riker, William H. and Peter C. Ordeshook A Theory of the Calculus of Voting. American Political Science Review 62(1): Rudolph, T. J Who's Responsible for the Economy? The Formation and Consequences of Responsibility Attributions. American Journal of Political Science, 47: Sears, D. O College sophomores in the laboratory: Influences of a narrow database on social psychology's view of human nature. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, (51) Sniderman, Paul M., Richard A. Brody, and Philip E. Tetlock Reasoning and Choice: Explorations in Political Psychology. New York: Cambridge University Press Wolak, Jennifer The Consequences of Concurrent Campaigns for Citizen Knowledge of Congressional Candidates. Political Behavior, 31(2),

30 Table 1. List of Hypotheses Tables and Figures Hypotheses about total information search H1 When the Senate contest appears, subjects will search for a greater total level of information. H2 When the presidential contest appears, subjects will search for a greater total level of information. H3 When the realistic distribution of information appears, subjects will search for a lesser level of overall information. Hypotheses about information search for each office H4 When the President appears on the ballot, subjects will seek out more information about the executive office. H5 When the Senate appears on the ballot, subjects will seek out less information about each office on the ballot. H6 When there is a realistic distribution of information, subjects will seek out more information about the executive. H6a When there is a realistic distribution of information and the President is on the ballot, subjects will seek out more information about the executive. H6b When there is a realistic distribution of information, subjects will seek out less information about the House. Table 2. Three-way ANOVA descriptive statistics for total number of attributes viewed by subjects Equal Distribution of Information Realistic Distribution of Information Pres and House Only Gov and House Only Pres, Senate and House Gov, Senate and House Pres and House Only Gov and House Only Pres, Senate and House Gov Senate and House Executive (11.59) (10.87) (8.89) (7.51) (10.87) (13.98) (8.59) (11.70) Senate (8.00) (8.70) (9.83) (11.97) House (11.15) (11.68) (8.52) (8.06) (8.94) (12.31) (7.02) (9.11) Current Events (11.67) (11.37) (11.75) (9.65) (10.07) (10.11) 5.14 (5.02) (10.33) Total Items (22.66) (24.13) (26.11) (20.97) (19.36) (24.85) (20.53) (26.63) 29

31 Table 3. Three-way ANOVA of number of attributes viewed, by office Corrected Model Intercept Presidential Race Senate Race Realistic Pres*Sen Pres*Real Sen*Real Pres* Sen* Real Adjusted R Squared *** - >.001 ** - >.010 * - >.050 Total House Senate Executive Current Events *** *** 0.000*** 0.000*** 0.000*** 0.000*** 0.000*** 0.000*** * 0.003** *** 0.000*** 0.003** 0.015* 0.000*** *

32 Figure 1. Total information search, by manipulation 31

33 Figure 2. Three-way ANOVA of total attributes viewed 32

34 Figure 3. Three-way ANOVA of House attributes viewed 33

35 Figure 4. Three-way ANOVA of Senate attributes viewed 34

36 Figure 5. Three-way ANOVA of Executive attributes viewed 35

Modeling Political Information Transmission as a Game of Telephone

Modeling Political Information Transmission as a Game of Telephone Modeling Political Information Transmission as a Game of Telephone Taylor N. Carlson tncarlson@ucsd.edu Department of Political Science University of California, San Diego 9500 Gilman Dr., La Jolla, CA

More information

Asymmetric Partisan Biases in Perceptions of Political Parties

Asymmetric Partisan Biases in Perceptions of Political Parties Asymmetric Partisan Biases in Perceptions of Political Parties Jonathan Woon Carnegie Mellon University April 6, 2007 Abstract This paper investigates whether there is partisan bias in the way that individuals

More information

Turnout and Strength of Habits

Turnout and Strength of Habits Turnout and Strength of Habits John H. Aldrich Wendy Wood Jacob M. Montgomery Duke University I) Introduction Social scientists are much better at explaining for whom people vote than whether people vote

More information

This journal is published by the American Political Science Association. All rights reserved.

This journal is published by the American Political Science Association. All rights reserved. Article: National Conditions, Strategic Politicians, and U.S. Congressional Elections: Using the Generic Vote to Forecast the 2006 House and Senate Elections Author: Alan I. Abramowitz Issue: October 2006

More information

The Electoral Process. Learning Objectives Students will be able to: STEP BY STEP. reading pages (double-sided ok) to the students.

The Electoral Process. Learning Objectives Students will be able to: STEP BY STEP. reading pages (double-sided ok) to the students. Teacher s Guide Time Needed: One Class Period The Electoral Process Learning Objectives Students will be able to: Materials Needed: Student worksheets Copy Instructions: All student pages can be copied

More information

Ai, C. and E. Norton Interaction Terms in Logit and Probit Models. Economic Letters

Ai, C. and E. Norton Interaction Terms in Logit and Probit Models. Economic Letters References Ai, C. and E. Norton. 2003. Interaction Terms in Logit and Probit Models. Economic Letters 80(1):123 129. Alesina, Alberto and Edward L. Glaeser. 2004. Fighting Poverty in the US and Europe:

More information

Issue Importance and Performance Voting. *** Soumis à Political Behavior ***

Issue Importance and Performance Voting. *** Soumis à Political Behavior *** Issue Importance and Performance Voting Patrick Fournier, André Blais, Richard Nadeau, Elisabeth Gidengil, and Neil Nevitte *** Soumis à Political Behavior *** Issue importance mediates the impact of public

More information

Case Study: Get out the Vote

Case Study: Get out the Vote Case Study: Get out the Vote Do Phone Calls to Encourage Voting Work? Why Randomize? This case study is based on Comparing Experimental and Matching Methods Using a Large-Scale Field Experiment on Voter

More information

Voters Ready to Act against Big Money in Politics

Voters Ready to Act against Big Money in Politics Date: November 10, 2014 To: Friends of and Every Voice From: Stan Greenberg and James Carville, David Donnelly, Every Voice Ben Winston, GQRR Voters Ready to Act against Big Money in Politics Lessons from

More information

SIERRA LEONE 2012 ELECTIONS PROJECT PRE-ANALYSIS PLAN: INDIVIDUAL LEVEL INTERVENTIONS

SIERRA LEONE 2012 ELECTIONS PROJECT PRE-ANALYSIS PLAN: INDIVIDUAL LEVEL INTERVENTIONS SIERRA LEONE 2012 ELECTIONS PROJECT PRE-ANALYSIS PLAN: INDIVIDUAL LEVEL INTERVENTIONS PIs: Kelly Bidwell (IPA), Katherine Casey (Stanford GSB) and Rachel Glennerster (JPAL MIT) THIS DRAFT: 15 August 2013

More information

Social Rankings in Human-Computer Committees

Social Rankings in Human-Computer Committees Social Rankings in Human-Computer Committees Moshe Bitan 1, Ya akov (Kobi) Gal 3 and Elad Dokow 4, and Sarit Kraus 1,2 1 Computer Science Department, Bar Ilan University, Israel 2 Institute for Advanced

More information

Amy Tenhouse. Incumbency Surge: Examining the 1996 Margin of Victory for U.S. House Incumbents

Amy Tenhouse. Incumbency Surge: Examining the 1996 Margin of Victory for U.S. House Incumbents Amy Tenhouse Incumbency Surge: Examining the 1996 Margin of Victory for U.S. House Incumbents In 1996, the American public reelected 357 members to the United States House of Representatives; of those

More information

Author(s) Title Date Dataset(s) Abstract

Author(s) Title Date Dataset(s) Abstract Author(s): Traugott, Michael Title: Memo to Pilot Study Committee: Understanding Campaign Effects on Candidate Recall and Recognition Date: February 22, 1990 Dataset(s): 1988 National Election Study, 1989

More information

Political Science 333: Elections, American Style Spring 2006

Political Science 333: Elections, American Style Spring 2006 Course Summary: Political Science 333: Elections, American Style Spring 2006 Professor Paul Gronke 434 Eliot Hall 503-517-7393 Office Hours: Thursday, 9-11 am or by appointment Readings and other resources:

More information

Searching for Meaning in Presidential Elections

Searching for Meaning in Presidential Elections Searching for Meaning in Presidential Elections Larry M. Bartels Vanderbilt University THE ELUSIVE MANDATE Obama won but he s got no mandate. Charles Krauthammer A divided nation did not hand President

More information

Poli 123 Political Psychology

Poli 123 Political Psychology Poli 123 Political Psychology Professor Matthew Hibbing 210B SSM mhibbing@ucmerced.edu Course Description and Goals This course provides an introduction and overview to the field of political psychology.

More information

Julie Lenggenhager. The "Ideal" Female Candidate

Julie Lenggenhager. The Ideal Female Candidate Julie Lenggenhager The "Ideal" Female Candidate Why are there so few women elected to positions in both gubernatorial and senatorial contests? Since the ratification of the nineteenth amendment in 1920

More information

EDW Chapter 9 Campaigns and Voting Behavior: Nominations, Caucuses

EDW Chapter 9 Campaigns and Voting Behavior: Nominations, Caucuses EDW Chapter 9 Campaigns and Voting Behavior: Nominations, Caucuses 1. Which of the following statements most accurately compares elections in the United States with those in most other Western democracies?

More information

A Tool for All People, but Not All Occasions: How Voting Heuristics Interact with Political Knowledge and Environment

A Tool for All People, but Not All Occasions: How Voting Heuristics Interact with Political Knowledge and Environment A Tool for All People, but Not All Occasions: How Voting Heuristics Interact with Political Knowledge and Environment Jacob S. Bower-Bir Workshop in Political Theory and Policy Analysis Indiana University

More information

Illinois Redistricting Collaborative Talking Points Feb. Update

Illinois Redistricting Collaborative Talking Points Feb. Update Goals: Illinois Redistricting Collaborative Talking Points Feb. Update Raise public awareness of gerrymandering as a key electionyear issue Create press opportunities on gerrymandering to engage the public

More information

Iowa Voting Series, Paper 6: An Examination of Iowa Absentee Voting Since 2000

Iowa Voting Series, Paper 6: An Examination of Iowa Absentee Voting Since 2000 Department of Political Science Publications 5-1-2014 Iowa Voting Series, Paper 6: An Examination of Iowa Absentee Voting Since 2000 Timothy M. Hagle University of Iowa 2014 Timothy M. Hagle Comments This

More information

Iowa Voting Series, Paper 4: An Examination of Iowa Turnout Statistics Since 2000 by Party and Age Group

Iowa Voting Series, Paper 4: An Examination of Iowa Turnout Statistics Since 2000 by Party and Age Group Department of Political Science Publications 3-1-2014 Iowa Voting Series, Paper 4: An Examination of Iowa Turnout Statistics Since 2000 by Party and Age Group Timothy M. Hagle University of Iowa 2014 Timothy

More information

Partisan Nation: The Rise of Affective Partisan Polarization in the American Electorate

Partisan Nation: The Rise of Affective Partisan Polarization in the American Electorate Partisan Nation: The Rise of Affective Partisan Polarization in the American Electorate Alan I. Abramowitz Department of Political Science Emory University Abstract Partisan conflict has reached new heights

More information

Voting Criteria April

Voting Criteria April Voting Criteria 21-301 2018 30 April 1 Evaluating voting methods In the last session, we learned about different voting methods. In this session, we will focus on the criteria we use to evaluate whether

More information

Federal Primary Election Runoffs and Voter Turnout Decline,

Federal Primary Election Runoffs and Voter Turnout Decline, Federal Primary Election Runoffs and Voter Turnout Decline, 1994-2010 July 2011 By: Katherine Sicienski, William Hix, and Rob Richie Summary of Facts and Findings Near-Universal Decline in Turnout: Of

More information

Publicizing malfeasance:

Publicizing malfeasance: Publicizing malfeasance: When media facilitates electoral accountability in Mexico Horacio Larreguy, John Marshall and James Snyder Harvard University May 1, 2015 Introduction Elections are key for political

More information

The Impact of Minor Parties on Electoral Competition: An Examination of US House and State Legislative Races

The Impact of Minor Parties on Electoral Competition: An Examination of US House and State Legislative Races The Impact of Minor Parties on Electoral Competition: An Examination of US House and State Legislative Races William M. Salka Professor of Political Science Eastern Connecticut State University Willimantic,

More information

POLI 300 Fall 2010 PROBLEM SET #5B: ANSWERS AND DISCUSSION

POLI 300 Fall 2010 PROBLEM SET #5B: ANSWERS AND DISCUSSION POLI 300 Fall 2010 General Comments PROBLEM SET #5B: ANSWERS AND DISCUSSION Evidently most students were able to produce SPSS frequency tables (and sometimes bar charts as well) without particular difficulty.

More information

Public Opinion and American Politics

Public Opinion and American Politics Public Opinion and American Politics Political Science 4204: CRN 87367 Fall 2013 (T TR : 2:00-3:20pm at GS 111) Instructor: Dukhong Kim Office Hours: T R:1:00-2:00, and by appointment Contact Information

More information

Partisan Advantage and Competitiveness in Illinois Redistricting

Partisan Advantage and Competitiveness in Illinois Redistricting Partisan Advantage and Competitiveness in Illinois Redistricting An Updated and Expanded Look By: Cynthia Canary & Kent Redfield June 2015 Using data from the 2014 legislative elections and digging deeper

More information

The Electoral Process STEP BY STEP. the worksheet activity to the class. the answers with the class. (The PowerPoint works well for this.

The Electoral Process STEP BY STEP. the worksheet activity to the class. the answers with the class. (The PowerPoint works well for this. Teacher s Guide Time Needed: One class period Materials Needed: Student worksheets Projector Copy Instructions: Reading (2 pages; class set) Activity (3 pages; class set) The Electoral Process Learning

More information

PLSC 2415: Campaigns and Elections Course Syllabus

PLSC 2415: Campaigns and Elections Course Syllabus PLSC 2415: Campaigns and Elections Course Syllabus Instructor: Dr. Jeffrey Lyons Email: Jeffrey.Lyons51@du.edu Office: Sturm Hall, Room 473 Office Hours: Wednesday 10:00-12:00, and by appointment Time:

More information

Friends of Democracy Corps and Greenberg Quinlan Rosner Research. Stan Greenberg and James Carville, Democracy Corps

Friends of Democracy Corps and Greenberg Quinlan Rosner Research. Stan Greenberg and James Carville, Democracy Corps Date: January 13, 2009 To: From: Friends of Democracy Corps and Greenberg Quinlan Rosner Research Stan Greenberg and James Carville, Democracy Corps Anna Greenberg and John Brach, Greenberg Quinlan Rosner

More information

American Voters and Elections

American Voters and Elections American Voters and Elections Instructor Information: Taeyong Park Department of Political Science, Washington University in St. Louis Email: t.park@wustl.edu 1. COURSE DESCRIPTION This course will provide

More information

Political Science 10: Introduction to American Politics Week 10

Political Science 10: Introduction to American Politics Week 10 Political Science 10: Introduction to American Politics Week 10 Taylor Carlson tfeenstr@ucsd.edu March 17, 2017 Carlson POLI 10-Week 10 March 17, 2017 1 / 22 Plan for the Day Go over learning outcomes

More information

Campaigns & Elections. US Government POS 2041

Campaigns & Elections. US Government POS 2041 Campaigns & Elections US Government POS 2041 Votes for Women, inspired by Katja Von Garner. http://www.youtube.com/watch?v=lvqnjwk W7gA For Discussion Do you think that democracy is endangered by the

More information

Latinos and the Mid- term Election

Latinos and the Mid- term Election Fact Sheet Novem ber 27, 2006 Latinos and the 2 0 0 6 Mid- term Election Widely cited findings in the national exit polls suggest Latinos tilted heavily in favor of the Democrats in the 2006 election,

More information

Online Appendix: Robustness Tests and Migration. Means

Online Appendix: Robustness Tests and Migration. Means VOL. VOL NO. ISSUE EMPLOYMENT, WAGES AND VOTER TURNOUT Online Appendix: Robustness Tests and Migration Means Online Appendix Table 1 presents the summary statistics of turnout for the five types of elections

More information

Patterns of Poll Movement *

Patterns of Poll Movement * Patterns of Poll Movement * Public Perspective, forthcoming Christopher Wlezien is Reader in Comparative Government and Fellow of Nuffield College, University of Oxford Robert S. Erikson is a Professor

More information

THE WORKMEN S CIRCLE SURVEY OF AMERICAN JEWS. Jews, Economic Justice & the Vote in Steven M. Cohen and Samuel Abrams

THE WORKMEN S CIRCLE SURVEY OF AMERICAN JEWS. Jews, Economic Justice & the Vote in Steven M. Cohen and Samuel Abrams THE WORKMEN S CIRCLE SURVEY OF AMERICAN JEWS Jews, Economic Justice & the Vote in 2012 Steven M. Cohen and Samuel Abrams 1/4/2013 2 Overview Economic justice concerns were the critical consideration dividing

More information

A positive correlation between turnout and plurality does not refute the rational voter model

A positive correlation between turnout and plurality does not refute the rational voter model Quality & Quantity 26: 85-93, 1992. 85 O 1992 Kluwer Academic Publishers. Printed in the Netherlands. Note A positive correlation between turnout and plurality does not refute the rational voter model

More information

Chapter Four: Chamber Competitiveness, Political Polarization, and Political Parties

Chapter Four: Chamber Competitiveness, Political Polarization, and Political Parties Chapter Four: Chamber Competitiveness, Political Polarization, and Political Parties Building off of the previous chapter in this dissertation, this chapter investigates the involvement of political parties

More information

Chapter 14. The Causes and Effects of Rational Abstention

Chapter 14. The Causes and Effects of Rational Abstention Excerpts from Anthony Downs, An Economic Theory of Democracy. New York: Harper and Row, 1957. (pp. 260-274) Introduction Chapter 14. The Causes and Effects of Rational Abstention Citizens who are eligible

More information

Battleground 59: A (Potentially) Wasted Opportunity for the Republican Party Republican Analysis by: Ed Goeas and Brian Nienaber

Battleground 59: A (Potentially) Wasted Opportunity for the Republican Party Republican Analysis by: Ed Goeas and Brian Nienaber Battleground 59: A (Potentially) Wasted Opportunity for the Republican Party Republican Analysis by: Ed Goeas and Brian Nienaber In what seems like so long ago, the 2016 Presidential Election cycle began

More information

CHOICE VOTING: ONE YEAR LATER

CHOICE VOTING: ONE YEAR LATER CHOICE VOTING: ONE YEAR LATER CHRISTOPHER JERDONEK SONNY MOHAMMADZADEH CONTENTS 1. Introduction 1 2. Choice Voting Background 2 3. Part 1 of Analysis: Slate Representation 3 4. Part 2 of Analysis: Candidate

More information

Follow this and additional works at: Part of the American Politics Commons

Follow this and additional works at:  Part of the American Politics Commons Marquette University e-publications@marquette Ronald E. McNair Scholars Program 2013 Ronald E. McNair Scholars Program 7-1-2013 Rafael Torres, Jr. - Does the United States Supreme Court decision in the

More information

WHAT IS PUBLIC OPINION? PUBLIC OPINION IS THOSE ATTITUDES HELD BY A SIGNIFICANT NUMBER OF PEOPLE ON MATTERS OF GOVERNMENT AND POLITICS

WHAT IS PUBLIC OPINION? PUBLIC OPINION IS THOSE ATTITUDES HELD BY A SIGNIFICANT NUMBER OF PEOPLE ON MATTERS OF GOVERNMENT AND POLITICS WHAT IS PUBLIC OPINION? PUBLIC OPINION IS THOSE ATTITUDES HELD BY A SIGNIFICANT NUMBER OF PEOPLE ON MATTERS OF GOVERNMENT AND POLITICS The family is our first contact with ideas toward authority, property

More information

Rock the Vote September Democratic Strategic Analysis by Celinda Lake, Joshua E. Ulibarri, and Karen M. Emmerson

Rock the Vote September Democratic Strategic Analysis by Celinda Lake, Joshua E. Ulibarri, and Karen M. Emmerson Rock the Vote September 2008 Democratic Strategic Analysis by Celinda Lake, Joshua E. Ulibarri, and Karen M. Emmerson Rock the Vote s second Battleground poll shows that young people want change and believe

More information

Supplementary Materials A: Figures for All 7 Surveys Figure S1-A: Distribution of Predicted Probabilities of Voting in Primary Elections

Supplementary Materials A: Figures for All 7 Surveys Figure S1-A: Distribution of Predicted Probabilities of Voting in Primary Elections Supplementary Materials (Online), Supplementary Materials A: Figures for All 7 Surveys Figure S-A: Distribution of Predicted Probabilities of Voting in Primary Elections (continued on next page) UT Republican

More information

The Electoral Process

The Electoral Process Barack Obama speaks at the Democratic National Convention in 2012. Narrowing the Field It s Election Time! Candidates for the larger political parties are chosen at party meetings called conventions. The

More information

Introduction to the declination function for gerrymanders

Introduction to the declination function for gerrymanders Introduction to the declination function for gerrymanders Gregory S. Warrington Department of Mathematics & Statistics, University of Vermont, 16 Colchester Ave., Burlington, VT 05401, USA November 4,

More information

Who Votes for the Future? Information, Expectations, and Endogeneity in Economic Voting

Who Votes for the Future? Information, Expectations, and Endogeneity in Economic Voting DOI 10.1007/s11109-016-9359-3 ORIGINAL PAPER Who Votes for the Future? Information, Expectations, and Endogeneity in Economic Voting Dean Lacy 1 Dino P. Christenson 2 Springer Science+Business Media New

More information

It s Not Easy Being Green: Minor Party Labels as Heuristic Aids

It s Not Easy Being Green: Minor Party Labels as Heuristic Aids Political Psychology, Vol. 29, No. 3, 2008 It s Not Easy Being Green: Minor Party Labels as Heuristic Aids Travis G. Coan Claremont Graduate University Jennifer L. Merolla Claremont Graduate University

More information

DATA ANALYSIS USING SETUPS AND SPSS: AMERICAN VOTING BEHAVIOR IN PRESIDENTIAL ELECTIONS

DATA ANALYSIS USING SETUPS AND SPSS: AMERICAN VOTING BEHAVIOR IN PRESIDENTIAL ELECTIONS Poli 300 Handout B N. R. Miller DATA ANALYSIS USING SETUPS AND SPSS: AMERICAN VOTING BEHAVIOR IN IDENTIAL ELECTIONS 1972-2004 The original SETUPS: AMERICAN VOTING BEHAVIOR IN IDENTIAL ELECTIONS 1972-1992

More information

Executive Summary. 1 Page

Executive Summary. 1 Page ANALYSIS FOR THE ORGANIZATION OF AMERICAN STATES (OAS) by Dr Irfan Nooruddin, Professor, Walsh School of Foreign Service, Georgetown University 17 December 2017 Executive Summary The dramatic vote swing

More information

ELECTIONS AND VOTING BEHAVIOR CHAPTER 10, Government in America

ELECTIONS AND VOTING BEHAVIOR CHAPTER 10, Government in America ELECTIONS AND VOTING BEHAVIOR CHAPTER 10, Government in America Page 1 of 6 I. HOW AMERICAN ELECTIONS WORK A. Elections serve many important functions in American society, including legitimizing the actions

More information

PS 5030: Seminar in American Government & Politics Fall 2008 Thursdays 6:15pm-9:00pm Room 1132, Old Library Classroom

PS 5030: Seminar in American Government & Politics Fall 2008 Thursdays 6:15pm-9:00pm Room 1132, Old Library Classroom PS 5030: Seminar in American Government & Politics Fall 2008 Thursdays 6:15pm-9:00pm Room 1132, Old Library Classroom Professor: Todd Hartman Phone: (828) 262-6827 Office: 2059 Old Belk Library Classroom

More information

Research Note: U.S. Senate Elections and Newspaper Competition

Research Note: U.S. Senate Elections and Newspaper Competition Research Note: U.S. Senate Elections and Newspaper Competition Jan Vermeer, Nebraska Wesleyan University The contextual factors that structure electoral contests affect election outcomes. This research

More information

THE ACCURACY OF MEDIA COVERAGE OF FOREIGN POLICY RHETORIC AND EVENTS

THE ACCURACY OF MEDIA COVERAGE OF FOREIGN POLICY RHETORIC AND EVENTS THE ACCURACY OF MEDIA COVERAGE OF FOREIGN POLICY RHETORIC AND EVENTS MADALINA-STELIANA DEACONU ms_deaconu@yahoo.com Titu Maiorescu University Abstract: The current study has extended past research by elucidating

More information

Making Progress: The Latest on Women and Running for Office

Making Progress: The Latest on Women and Running for Office Making Progress: The Latest on Women and Running for Office ANNIE S LIST THE ANNIE S LIST AGENDA FELLOWS INTRO Ashley Thomas Ari HollandBaldwin QUESTIONS 1. What is the current state of women s political

More information

Pitch Perfect: Winning Strategies for Women Candidates

Pitch Perfect: Winning Strategies for Women Candidates Pitch Perfect: Winning Strategies for Women Candidates November 8, 2012 Executive Summary We ve all heard it: this perception that I would vote for a qualified woman, especially when a woman runs for major

More information

Cognitive Heterogeneity and Economic Voting: Does Political Sophistication Condition Economic Voting?

Cognitive Heterogeneity and Economic Voting: Does Political Sophistication Condition Economic Voting? 연구논문 Cognitive Heterogeneity and Economic Voting: Does Political Sophistication Condition Economic Voting? Han Soo Lee (Seoul National University) Does political sophistication matter for economic voting?

More information

LEARNING OBJECTIVES After studying Chapter 10, you should be able to: 1. Explain the functions and unique features of American elections. 2. Describe how American elections have evolved using the presidential

More information

Part I: Univariate Spatial Model (20%)

Part I: Univariate Spatial Model (20%) 17.251 Fall 2012 Midterm Exam answers Directions: Do the following problem. Part I: Univariate Spatial Model (20%) The nation is faced with a situation in which, if legislation isn t passed, the level

More information

Retrospective Voting

Retrospective Voting Retrospective Voting Who Are Retrospective Voters and Does it Matter if the Incumbent President is Running Kaitlin Franks Senior Thesis In Economics Adviser: Richard Ball 4/30/2009 Abstract Prior literature

More information

Political Sophistication and Third-Party Voting in Recent Presidential Elections

Political Sophistication and Third-Party Voting in Recent Presidential Elections Political Sophistication and Third-Party Voting in Recent Presidential Elections Christopher N. Lawrence Department of Political Science Duke University April 3, 2006 Overview During the 1990s, minor-party

More information

CREST CENTRE FOR RESEARCH INTO ELECTIONS AND SOCIAL TRENDS

CREST CENTRE FOR RESEARCH INTO ELECTIONS AND SOCIAL TRENDS CREST CENTRE FOR RESEARCH INTO ELECTIONS AND SOCIAL TRENDS Working Paper Number 87 September 2001 Political Knowledge and Electoral Choices By Robert Andersen, Anthony Heath and Richard Sinnott The Centre

More information

Federal Elections, Union Publications. and. Union Websites

Federal Elections, Union Publications. and. Union Websites Federal Elections, Union Publications and Union Websites (Produced by the APWU National Postal Press Association) Dear Brother or Sister: Election Day is Tuesday, November 8, 2008. Working families have

More information

Vote Likelihood and Institutional Trait Questions in the 1997 NES Pilot Study

Vote Likelihood and Institutional Trait Questions in the 1997 NES Pilot Study Vote Likelihood and Institutional Trait Questions in the 1997 NES Pilot Study Barry C. Burden and Janet M. Box-Steffensmeier The Ohio State University Department of Political Science 2140 Derby Hall Columbus,

More information

British Election Leaflet Project - Data overview

British Election Leaflet Project - Data overview British Election Leaflet Project - Data overview Gathering data on electoral leaflets from a large number of constituencies would be prohibitively difficult at least, without major outside funding without

More information

Texas Elections Part I

Texas Elections Part I Texas Elections Part I In a society governed passively by free markets and free elections, organized greed always defeats disorganized democracy. Matt Taibbi Elections...a formal decision-making process

More information

c 2011 Parina Patel ALL RIGHTS RESERVED

c 2011 Parina Patel ALL RIGHTS RESERVED c 2011 Parina Patel ALL RIGHTS RESERVED THE EFFECTS OF INSTITUTIONS ON CORRECT VOTING by PARINA PATEL A Dissertation submitted to the Graduate School New Brunswick Rutgers, The State University of New

More information

Lecture Outline: Chapter 7

Lecture Outline: Chapter 7 Lecture Outline: Chapter 7 Campaigns and Elections I. An examination of the campaign tactics used in the presidential race of 1896 suggests that the process of running for political office in the twenty-first

More information

Party Cue Inference Experiment. January 10, Research Question and Objective

Party Cue Inference Experiment. January 10, Research Question and Objective Party Cue Inference Experiment January 10, 2017 Research Question and Objective Our overarching goal for the project is to answer the question: when and how do political parties influence public opinion?

More information

The Center for Voting and Democracy

The Center for Voting and Democracy The Center for Voting and Democracy 6930 Carroll Ave., Suite 610 Takoma Park, MD 20912 - (301) 270-4616 (301) 270 4133 (fax) info@fairvote.org www.fairvote.org To: Commission to Ensure Integrity and Public

More information

Each election cycle, candidates, political parties,

Each election cycle, candidates, political parties, Informing the Electorate? How Party Cues and Policy Information Affect Public Opinion about Initiatives Cheryl Boudreau Scott A. MacKenzie University of California, Davis University of California, Davis

More information

Political Sophistication and Third-Party Voting in Recent Presidential Elections

Political Sophistication and Third-Party Voting in Recent Presidential Elections Political Sophistication and Third-Party Voting in Recent Presidential Elections Christopher N. Lawrence Department of Political Science Duke University April 3, 2006 Overview During the 1990s, minor-party

More information

Key Considerations for Implementing Bodies and Oversight Actors

Key Considerations for Implementing Bodies and Oversight Actors Implementing and Overseeing Electronic Voting and Counting Technologies Key Considerations for Implementing Bodies and Oversight Actors Lead Authors Ben Goldsmith Holly Ruthrauff This publication is made

More information

'Wave riding' or 'Owning the issue': How do candidates determine campaign agendas?

'Wave riding' or 'Owning the issue': How do candidates determine campaign agendas? 'Wave riding' or 'Owning the issue': How do candidates determine campaign agendas? Mariya Burdina University of Colorado, Boulder Department of Economics October 5th, 008 Abstract In this paper I adress

More information

The California Primary and Redistricting

The California Primary and Redistricting The California Primary and Redistricting This study analyzes what is the important impact of changes in the primary voting rules after a Congressional and Legislative Redistricting. Under a citizen s committee,

More information

CALTECH/MIT VOTING TECHNOLOGY PROJECT A

CALTECH/MIT VOTING TECHNOLOGY PROJECT A CALTECH/MIT VOTING TECHNOLOGY PROJECT A multi-disciplinary, collaborative project of the California Institute of Technology Pasadena, California 91125 and the Massachusetts Institute of Technology Cambridge,

More information

Young Voters in the 2010 Elections

Young Voters in the 2010 Elections Young Voters in the 2010 Elections By CIRCLE Staff November 9, 2010 This CIRCLE fact sheet summarizes important findings from the 2010 National House Exit Polls conducted by Edison Research. The respondents

More information

14 Managing Split Precincts

14 Managing Split Precincts 14 Managing Split Precincts Contents 14 Managing Split Precincts... 1 14.1 Overview... 1 14.2 Defining Split Precincts... 1 14.3 How Split Precincts are Created... 2 14.4 Managing Split Precincts In General...

More information

Revolt against Congress: Game On Survey of the Battleground House Districts

Revolt against Congress: Game On Survey of the Battleground House Districts Date: December 13, 2013 To: Friends of and Women s Voices Women Vote Action Fund From: Stan Greenberg, James Carville, and Erica Seifert Revolt against Congress: Game On Survey of the Battleground House

More information

AP GOPO CHAPTER 9 READING GUIDE

AP GOPO CHAPTER 9 READING GUIDE AP GOPO CHAPTER 9 READING GUIDE 1. Have levels of political participation increased in recent years? 2. Remember what grassroots is. It s come up once or twice before in class. 3. What is a primary? Are

More information

Running head: PARTY DIFFERENCES IN POLITICAL PARTY KNOWLEDGE

Running head: PARTY DIFFERENCES IN POLITICAL PARTY KNOWLEDGE Political Party Knowledge 1 Running head: PARTY DIFFERENCES IN POLITICAL PARTY KNOWLEDGE Party Differences in Political Party Knowledge Emily Fox, Sarah Smith, Griffin Liford Hanover College PSY 220: Research

More information

The Initiative Industry: Its Impact on the Future of the Initiative Process By M. Dane Waters 1

The Initiative Industry: Its Impact on the Future of the Initiative Process By M. Dane Waters 1 By M. Dane Waters 1 Introduction The decade of the 90s was the most prolific in regard to the number of statewide initiatives making the ballot in the United States. 2 This tremendous growth in the number

More information

Developing Political Preferences: Citizen Self-Interest

Developing Political Preferences: Citizen Self-Interest Developing Political Preferences: Citizen Self-Interest Carlos Algara calgara@ucdavis.edu October 12, 2017 Agenda 1 Revising the Paradox 2 Abstention Incentive: Opinion Instability 3 Heuristics as Short-Cuts:

More information

Campaign Skills Handbook. Module 4 Voter Contact Communicating Directly with Voters

Campaign Skills Handbook. Module 4 Voter Contact Communicating Directly with Voters Campaign Skills Handbook Module 4 Voter Contact Communicating Directly with Voters Introduction One of the most important things that candidates, political parties and party activists do is communicate

More information

Chapter 9 Campaigns and Voting Behavior (Elections) AP Government

Chapter 9 Campaigns and Voting Behavior (Elections) AP Government Chapter 9 Campaigns and Voting Behavior (Elections) AP Government The Nomination Game 9.1 Competing for Delegates 9.1 National party convention State delegates meet and vote on nominee Nomination process

More information

WORKING PAPERS ON POLITICAL SCIENCE

WORKING PAPERS ON POLITICAL SCIENCE Documentos de Trabajo en Ciencia Política WORKING PAPERS ON POLITICAL SCIENCE Judging the Economy in Hard-times: Myopia, Approval Ratings and the Mexican Economy, 1995-2000. By Beatriz Magaloni, ITAM WPPS

More information

Voting as a Right or a Duty: A social Psychological Analysis. Meredith Sprengel. Georgetown University

Voting as a Right or a Duty: A social Psychological Analysis. Meredith Sprengel. Georgetown University Voting as a Right or a Duty 1 Running Header: VOTING AS A RIGHT OR A DUTY Voting as a Right or a Duty: A social Psychological Analysis Meredith Sprengel Georgetown University Voting as a Right or a Duty

More information

Political Parties and Soft Money

Political Parties and Soft Money 7 chapter Political Parties and Soft Money The role of the players in political advertising candidates, parties, and groups has been analyzed in prior chapters. However, the newly changing role of political

More information

An Increased Incumbency Effect: Reconsidering Evidence

An Increased Incumbency Effect: Reconsidering Evidence part i An Increased Incumbency Effect: Reconsidering Evidence chapter 1 An Increased Incumbency Effect and American Politics Incumbents have always fared well against challengers. Indeed, it would be surprising

More information

THE SECRETS OF VOTER TURNOUT 2018

THE SECRETS OF VOTER TURNOUT 2018 Dish THE SECRETS OF VOTER TURNOUT 2018 AN ANALYSIS OF INDIVIDUALLEVEL VOTE HISTORY IN THE VIRGINIA GOVERNOR S RACE Comcast May 2018 Netflix!X!1 Overview VIRGINIA 17: WHAT HAPPENED Despite polls suggesting

More information

Supplementary Materials for Strategic Abstention in Proportional Representation Systems (Evidence from Multiple Countries)

Supplementary Materials for Strategic Abstention in Proportional Representation Systems (Evidence from Multiple Countries) Supplementary Materials for Strategic Abstention in Proportional Representation Systems (Evidence from Multiple Countries) Guillem Riambau July 15, 2018 1 1 Construction of variables and descriptive statistics.

More information

Colorado 2014: Comparisons of Predicted and Actual Turnout

Colorado 2014: Comparisons of Predicted and Actual Turnout Colorado 2014: Comparisons of Predicted and Actual Turnout Date 2017-08-28 Project name Colorado 2014 Voter File Analysis Prepared for Washington Monthly and Project Partners Prepared by Pantheon Analytics

More information

An in-depth examination of North Carolina voter attitudes in important current issues. Registered Voters in North Carolina

An in-depth examination of North Carolina voter attitudes in important current issues. Registered Voters in North Carolina An in-depth examination of North Carolina voter attitudes in important current issues Registered Voters in North Carolina January 21-25, 2018 Table of Contents Key Survey Insights... 3 Satisfaction with

More information

Tax Cut Welcomed in BC, But No Bounce for Campbell Before Exit

Tax Cut Welcomed in BC, But No Bounce for Campbell Before Exit Page 1 of 10 PROVINCIAL POLITICAL SCENE Tax Cut Welcomed in BC, But No Bounce for Campbell Before Exit The provincial NDP maintains a high level of voter support, and two-thirds of British Columbians would

More information

%: Will grow the economy vs. 39%: Will grow the economy.

%: Will grow the economy vs. 39%: Will grow the economy. Villains and Heroes on the Economy and Government Key Lessons from Opinion Research At Our Story The Hub for American Narratives we take the narrative part literally. Including that villains and heroes

More information