Party Systems Determinants of Electoral Reform in Post-communist States

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Party Systems Determinants of Electoral Reform in Post-communist States"

Transcription

1 Draft: March 2009 Please do not cite without permission Party Systems Determinants of Electoral Reform in Post-communist States Jack Bielasiak and John W. Hulsey Department of Political Science Indiana University-Bloomington Bloomington, IN Paper prepared for the Workshop Why Electoral Reform? The Determinants, Policy and Politics of Changing Electoral Systems, European Consortium for Political Research Joint Sessions of Workshops, Lisbon, April This paper addresses the issue of how the structure of party systems affects the initiation and direction of electoral reforms in post-communist emerging democracies. The analysis examines the relationship between party systems, defined in terms of the effective number of political actors, electoral volatility, and shares of party votes and seats, and the presence of diverse reform types. The findings reveal a significant number of reforms that undermine the institutional inertia claim, although the frequency of reforms declines appreciably with successive electoral cycles. There is no unidirectional trend, as both permissive and restrictive reforms are in evidence. These findings do not support the theoretical assertions linking party system fragmentation or electoral volatility to a specific direction of electoral change.

2 The collapse of authoritarian and communist regimes during the third wave of democratization ushered in a new political era across the globe. The monopoly of power vested in single parties, military regimes, or authoritarian personalities was replaced by a legitimating principle that evolved, in most cases, towards a contested version of politics. For many, the change signaled the embrace of democratic principles associated with the politics of choice, including the design of electoral institutions to invigorate popular participation and political competition. At about the same time, several mature democracies shed long-term stability by introducing significant electoral changes, whether in Italy, Japan or New Zeeland. Both developments, the electoral reforms in the advanced industrial world and the design of electoral systems in nascent democracies, provided strong impetus for scholarly attention to questions of electoral engineering and reform (Lijphart, 1994; Farrell, 2001; Birch, 2003; Norris, 2004; Colomer, 2005; Diamond and Plattner, 2006). For some time, the issue had taken second place to the dominant approach in the study of electoral and party systems, the consequences of electoral rules on the structure of party competition (Duverger, 1954). True, the central question has always evolved around the causal linkage between the two systems, with a clear recognition of a mutual relationship (Benoit, 2001, 2002). Still the prevailing approach in the literature examined the consequences of electoral regulations on party systems, government stability, or executive-legislative relations. The assumption about electoral rules inertia was rooted in the belief that institutions are robust and require external shocks for alteration. The collapse of authoritarian and communist regimes in the third wave and the initiation of electoral law changes in established democracies ushered in a turn to politics in the study of electoral systems: what are the driving forces in the origins and change of election laws? A new orthodoxy posited that the design and reform of electoral institutions is a 1

3 politically endogenous process, whereby political actors have a profound interest in shaping institutions to their advantage. Duverger s approach that electoral formulas structure party systems was turned upside down (Benoit, 2004; Colomer, 2005). More specifically the theoretical claim, supported by empirical evidence, was that fragmented and volatile party systems culminate in preferences for proportional representation (PR), so as to assure political access to the contending parties. In contrast, politics dominated by one or two players tend toward the advocacy and selection of majoritarian rules to amplify their position and restrict access to other political actors (Shugart, 1992; Remmer, 2008). This paper addresses the issue of how the structure of party systems affects the initiation and direction of electoral reforms in the post-communist world. As such, it follows the upsidedown Durvergerian perspective that the configuration of party systems defines the rules of completion. The analysis examines the relationship between the structure of party systems, defined in terms of the effective number of political actors, electoral volatility, and shares of party votes and seats, and electoral reforms, including major and minor types, ranging from the electoral formula to legislative size. The paper consists of three main sections. The first provides an overview of the theoretical perspectives on the linkage between party system and electoral reform. The second looks at the initiation and frequency of reforms in light of the theoretical claim about institutional inertia. The third examines the direction of reform as permissive or restrictive, to evaluate theoretical propositions about party system fragmentation and electoral directionality. Conceptualizing Electoral Reform The collapse of monopolistic power and the ensuing efforts to establish contested politics is fraught with considerable challenges that affect the development of electoral and party 2

4 systems. Emerging democracies give rise to new political forces that lack experience and face an uncertain future, in an inchoate political environment. Reconfiguration of the party systems is a frequent occurrence, as new parties appear, old ones splinter, and voters shift allegiances from election to election. Party systems are fluid, and have been especially so in post-communist states, prone to high rates of electoral volatility and system fragmentation (Mainwaring, 1998; Bielasiak, 2002). In these conditions, the power holders have strong incentives to assure their status as viable political actors. Pressures for alteration in contestation rules appear, to adjust to initial uncertainties and outcomes. There is evidence from various regions of the world that newly competitive regimes turn to reforms of election rules more frequently than the changes in mature democracies (Katz, 2005; Bielasiak, 2006; Reilly, 2007; Remmer, 2008). However, in the face of political fluidity and transition complexity, the reform impulse is subject to two distinct pulls, that of representation and governance. On the one hand, as a response to the chaos of party systems, political entrepreneurs seek to assure success by revising electoral laws towards more relaxed rules that maximize representation, and enhance the prospects of survival in the political game. On the other hand, the fragmented, volatile electoral environment calls for measures that trim party systems to provide better opportunities for stable and effective governance. Political leaders must navigate between these alternatives in their consideration of electoral reform. Three theoretical perspectives are articulated concerning the dilemma of broad representation versus effective governance. Strategic Calculations The first posits a strategic, rational choice motivation for the introduction of electoral change. This view is predicated on the seat and office seeking perspective of power maximization, so that parties undertake instrumental actions to boost their benefits in the 3

5 legislative and policy arenas (Boix, 1999, Benoit, 2004). Electoral reform is a consequence of self-interested politicians responding to party system cues, such as fragmentation and volatility, to cut future losses or expand benefits. In essence, changes in the party systems shape lead to reassessment of electoral rules by politicians committed to safeguard positions of power. High fragmentation and volatility portends the entry of new political players and dispersed political support. In this case, politicians move to protect their own standing by advocating more permissive electoral rules to guarantee access to the legislative arena, i.e. they seek rule changes in the direction of PR away from plurality and majority formulas, or alter PR towards more proportional properties. The tendency towards greater proportionality is accentuated when uncertainty about fortunes in forthcoming elections is especially high (Kaminski, 2002; Pilet, 2007). Risk-aversion explains the predominant global tendency in democratic systems to move from majoritarian to PR systems (Colomer, 2005). Since in emerging competitive polities there is greater likelihood to have unwieldy, fragmented party systems, as in many former communist states, the strategic maximization perspective argues for a predominance of permissive reforms. During the initial period of contested politics, extensive multipartism and high volatility bring forth pressures for more permissive decision rules. Governance Norms An alternative perspective looks not so much to seat maximization as to policy effectiveness as the driving incentive in the initiation of reforms. In this case, parties fortunes depend also on their capacity to implement policies preferred by voters. To stay in power or retain a significant influence in the legislature requires effective policy provisions. Two variants of the policy seeking perspective are evident, the self-interest and the socio-tropic models. 4

6 The first postulates that alternative election mechanisms affect policy outcomes differentially (Benoit, 2002). In PR systems dependent on coalitions and consensus legislation, there is danger of vetoes by smaller parties that undermine the policy agenda. In such cases, policy failures reflect on governing parties, with likely losses at the ballot box. To forestall such outcomes, large parties seek remedy by altering election laws in favor of more constrained systems. In practice, this leads to attempts at more restrictive election rules, even when party systems are highly fragmented (Renwick, 2008). The second variant claims that more general interests also govern the actions of politicians in the process of electoral engineering. The collective interest rather than partisan preferences serve broader ideological perspectives or the norms of democracy, seeking to give reality to the representation of diverse social views (Katz, 1997; Birch et al, 2002). After the collapse of communism, the projection of multiple voices onto the political arena created a spirit of inclusiveness that carried forth in the building of competitive institutions, favoring the adaptation of PR rules. The extensive splintering of the political scene and major shifts in electoral support across post-communist elections presented serious obstacles to stability. High political fragmentation rendered more difficult the formation of stable coalition governments, creating substantial difficulties in agenda setting and policy implementation. Problems of managing society increased public distrust in politicians, parties, and parliaments. The overall effect included punishment at the ballot box by a disenchanted electorate. Since failures in policy lead to poor electoral performance, political entrepreneurs are motivated to gain better control of the fragmented political space through more restrictive electoral procedures. 5

7 Institutional Inertia A third image of electoral development emphasizes inertia, with few changes in election practices. The perspective holds that institutions are robust, and that it is difficult to mobilize support for alterations except in case of external shocks (Nohlen, 1984). Electoral procedures are imbedded in contextual conditions that define choices of electoral systems, whether due to historical experience, social or ethnic requisites, or colonial legacies (Horowitz, 1985; Blais and Massicotte, 1997; Elster et al, 1998). The prospects of reform are further undermined by robust institutional requirements to implement change. Emerging democracies seek to safeguard pluralist procedures of competition by embedding them in foundational documents, making the reform process more tenuous. A variety of provisions are in evidence in the post-communist setting that set a high barrier for reform; anchoring the PR electoral system in the constitution, as in Poland, or subjecting changes to referenda, as in Slovenia or Romania (Millard, 2008; Moniquet, 2008; Fink-Haffner, 2008). In these cases, political entrepreneurs shy away from undertaking tasks necessitating the expansion of political capital in the face of low probabilities of success. So even in conditions of fragmentation and volatility, high levels of uncertainty about reform are likely to produce inaction (Alesina, 2006). The emphasis on maintaining existing contestation rules is likely to be reinforced by evidence of past failures to carry out proposed changes, so the institutional inertia outlook posits a prevailing pattern of fewer reforms than party system fragmentation or electoral volatility would justify. Instead, both the frequency and direction of reforms are likely to be less visible and systematic. While the literature posits a strong relationship between party and electoral systems, it is divided on the impact of the party systems on electoral system changes. The different theoretical 6

8 claims postulate divergent outcomes in conditions of weak party systems, emphasizing power, policy or institutional conditioning that result in either permissive, restrictive, or limited reforms. We turn to an examination of these theoretical propositions through an analysis of how the structure of post-communist party systems impacts on the initiation and direction of electoral reforms. Method: Operationalizing Electoral Reform Case Selection The cases for the study are competitive elections after the founding elections in former communist states in post-1989 East Europe and the post-1991 Soviet and Yugoslav political space. To take into account the quality of democracy question as to the nature of competitive politics in many emerging democratic regimes (Zakaria, 1997; Morlino, 2004; Merkel, 2004), we control for regime type and focus on democratic systems rather than on all former communist states with elections, so as to exclude instances of electorism marred by unfair competition. The central question after all is how unconstrained competition in party systems affects the choices of electoral rules. While there are various methods of operationalizing regime type, we rely on the standard assessments by Polity IV scores. 1 A second issue concerns the time frame for the study. Given the focus on reform, the time horizon covered starts after the founding elections that bring about competitive politics. That is, the first freely contested elections are taken as a base line to gauge subsequent changes in the post-1989 or1991 period for East European and post-soviet states respectively. The result is a data set that includes 74 cases, each case defined as a legislative election for the unilateral or lower chamber, after the first postfounding election and the last election held by the end of December The index enables distinction among three types of political systems, depending on the score in the Polity data set, which classifies polities based on an additive score of authoritarian and democratic features, with -10 to -4 as authoritarian, -3 to 5 as semi-authoritarian, and 6 to 10 as democratic. 7

9 Dependent Variables Another central question concerns the definition of the dependent variable: what constitutes electoral reform? The formal definition of legal changes in the electoral code masks the dilemma of electoral reform significance. The basic question is which changes are sufficiently important to form a new rule configuration that alters the mechanisms of vote to seat conversion and the incentives for political actors (Lijphart, 1994). To assess the differential impact of diverse election rules, efforts have focused on distinguishing between major and minor changes in electoral systems (Lijphart, 1994; Katz, 2005). There is wide consensus that the electoral formula is the critical component in defining the competitive environment (Duverger, 1954; Lijphart, 1994; Katz, 2005, Colomer, 2005). For our purposes, then, we consider changes between majoritarian, mixed, and PR formulas as major reforms that significantly affect the rules of party contestation. A strong case has also been made for the major impact of district magnitude on the vote to seat calculation, postulating a close relationship between electoral and party systems through the medium of district size magnitude. Simply, the higher the number of seats available per district, the better the chance of smaller political formations to win a seat, and thus to participate in political completion (Taagepera and Shugarrt, 1989; Lijphart, 1994; Gallagher, 1991). For that reason, changes in average district magnitude are taken as major alterations that redefine the linkage between electoral and party systems. There are numerous other components to electoral codes that must be taken into account in evaluating the relationship. These minor alterations range across diverse practices (Katz, 2005). We consider the following minor reforms as sufficiently important to affect results: the vote to seats conversion method in PR systems, the number of tiers in the electoral system, assembly size, and legal threshold. More inclusive electoral procedures include two tiers as 8

10 opposed to single tier districting, larger assembly chambers, but lower legal bars for entry into the legislature, as well as shifts in conversion methods from d Hondt and LR-Imeperiali type towards St Lague and Hare calculation methods (Lijphart, 1994, 159). Lijphart s original criterion defined significant modification in magnitude, chamber size, or threshold as a 20% change. This standard is replicated here, so that alongside alteration in electoral formula, changes of 20% or more in the numerical electoral properties take on the characteristics of distinct voting systems. All the changes are then codified as to the direction of the reform as restrictive or permissive. For the purpose of the statistical analysis, the major and minor changes have been combined into a summary indicator denoting the presence of reform and whether it was permissive or restrictive. Direction of Electoral Change The primary questions of the study center first on whether the structure of party systems enhances the initiation of electoral reforms, and second, on the direction of the changes as permissive or restrictive. Different specifications follow from the theoretical claims presented above. Under the strategic self-interest perspective, a large number of political actors increase the prospects for dispersed popular support. In the face of a declining vote share, parties primary interest is to safeguard access to the political system, thereby leading to a rationale advocacy of more relaxed rules (Shugart, 1992; Remmer, 2008). The hypothesis is that high party system fragmentation leads to probability of more permissive rules, while lower fragmentation tends towards the initiation of more restrictive electoral rules. The governance model posits an alternative impulse, based on the premise that fragmentation of the political scene presents greater difficulties for building effective policy coalitions, propelling major political actors to advocate more restrictive rules to eliminate 9

11 smaller political parties. So the hypothesis here is that under high fragmentation, the primary task is to reduce the chaos in the political space by undertaking more restrictive reforms that limit future access to the party system. The institutional inertia model maintains that electoral laws do not change often, for overriding robust institutional barriers necessitates the expenditure of substantial capital in the face of risky outcomes. Moreover, prolonged duration of existing rules acquires a focal point that is difficult to overcome since it involves greater political costs (Alesina, 2006). In this case, the hypothesis holds that despite fragmentation, the prevailing pattern makes reform less likely over subsequent electoral cycles. The probability of changing the rules is also affected by electoral stability or volatility (Remmer, 2008, 10). Consistency in the outcomes across elections reinforces institutional inertia, as the winners have no motives for altering the rule of the game. The expectation is that low volatility will signify no or few changes in the election codes. Instances of high volatility, in contrast, render all political actors subject to greater uncertainty and present incentives to minimize the risks by introducing reforms. The direction of the changes is bounded by the position and preferences of political actors, so that strategic calculations of self-interest dictate preferences for permissive change, while concern with governance capability redirect preferences towards more restrictive elements in the electoral law. The hypothesis is that volatility encourages reform, while stability reinforces status quo in the electoral rules. Independent Variables The independent variables concern the structure of party systems, as the effective number of political actors, electoral volatility, and shares of party votes and seats. The configuration of party systems is determined in large part by the number of functioning political actors, for it 10

12 structures the placement of parties along the political space, and in turn forms choices for the electorate. In that sense, the number of effective parties is a good indicator of political fragmentation. We employ the standard distinction between electoral (ENPV) and parliamentary (ENPS) party systems, to determine the effect of vote and seat fragmentation on the initiation and direction of reforms. 2 Two additional indicators are employed in the analysis as evidence of power concentration in the party system, namely the percent share for largest party in terms of vote and seats, as well as the percent of seats controlled by the two largest political parties in the unicameral or lower house of parliament, as a means to gauge the capacity of dominant political players to revise the electoral systems. Finally, we use the Pederson index of electoral volatility (EVV), which concentrates on changes in the voting share for parties in consecutive elections. 3 The premise is that consistent voting results over time as opposed to significant swings in the electorate s preferences form stable or inchoate party systems that affect incentives for reform. To reflect the belief in the literature that electoral changes may be driven by economic factors or the duration of the democratic regime, we turn to two principal control variables. The first concerns an evaluation of economic performance through inclusion of GDP growth rates, lagged for years prior to the election year (World Bank Development Indicators). The second is a measure of electoral cycles, defined by the electoral sequence since the transition from communist to democratic regime. 2 The measure of effective number of parties uses the Laakso and Taagepera formula: N = 1/ Σ p i 2 where N is the effective number of parties and p i is the fractional share of votes or seats for the i-th party. 3 Electoral volatility is calculated as V = ½ v p, t v p,t-1 where v p, t stands for the percentage of the vote obtained by a party at election t, and v p,t-1 for the percentage in the previous election (Pedersen, 1979). 11

13 Party Systems and Electoral Reform: Results We begin with an assessment of electoral reforms in light of the third model s assertion that institutions are robust and difficult to revise even in conditions of extensive fragmentation and volatility. We examine the frequency and temporal pattern of the changes, the type of reforms, and the direction of alterations through bivariate descriptive statistics, as well as statistical models to take a closer look at the causes of reform. Initiation and Frequency of Reform An overview of the changes in election rules is the post-communist world is presented in Table 1 for competitive elections during Reforms were introduced in 18 countries, and applied to 33 different election cycles, out of a total of 74 elections in the sample. The only country in the region without electoral tampering was Estonia, whose unusually complex code has remained in place since its initiation for the 1992 election. Even in this case, if the founding election is moved back to 1990 when Estonia conducted a free electoral contest while still part of the Soviet Union, there is a change in formula between the 1990 STV rules and the three tiered, linked PR system employed since Table 1 about here The changes in the other post-communist states ranged across all properties of the electoral codes, from alterations in the electoral formula to alterations in legislative size and thresholds. Many of these episodes involved reforms in multiple features of the electoral code, within the same election cycle, with a total of 52 voting rule modifications clustered in 33 election cycles. While these changes are examined separately in our initial analysis, in the statistical models we treat each election cycle as a unit, avoiding duplicate counts on the dependent variable. 12

14 The majority of changes (22) apply to one specific feature of the electoral law, concentrated in reforms of electoral formula and the legal threshold. Both of these measures have the advantage of transparency, providing a clear signal as to the intent of the reform and offering inducements to political actors interested in change. In addition, there are 11 episodes of more complex reform clusters that affect several different properties at the same time, even while discounting changes due to the natural effects of alterations in formula type. When there are multiple reforms in one election cycle, they are generally unidirectional, moving to either restrictive or permissive rules. The former tend to be concentrated in the early period, after the initial burst of political actors onto the post-communist political space leads to constraint efforts (e.g. Poland in 1993), while the latter are often associated with subsequent second transition openings of the political system (e.g. Croatia in 2000). In addition, in several instances, the nature of reform is not as transparent, involving changes in the same reform package that are both permissive and restrictive; these have been coded as to the net effect of the reform for each election cycle (e.g. Slovakia 1998 and Poland 2001). We return to the directionality issue below, at this point we emphasize the relatively high frequency of reforms after the founding elections of post-communism. The prevalence of electoral innovations in the region is confirmed through comparison with changes in other parts of the world. In regard to the major reform of electoral formula, 14 such episodes have taken place in the established democracies between 1950 and 2002, in both legislative and executive arenas (Katz, 2005); 6 legislative reforms in mature democracies between 1959 and 2006 (Renwick, 2008); and 6 in the Asia-Pacific region between 1990 and 2004 (Reilley, 2007). In the post-communist countries in , there were 10 outright formula changes and three additional changes in the single member segment of mixed electoral systems. Expanding the 13

15 comparison to all types of reform, Lijphart (1994) identified 30 for in 27 established democracies, in contrast to the 33 reforms instituted in 22 post-communist states during The comparative evidence, then, demonstrates the extensive nature of reforms, and casts a shadow on the claim that institutional inertia is a dominant aspect of political development even in condition of inchoate, volatile political systems. In emerging democracies, when party systems are unsettled and governmental effectiveness is in doubt, there are powerful inducements for the provision on new electoral rules to alter political conditions. Though reform prospects were reduced by imbedding electoral provision in legal requirements of constitutional amendments, public referenda, or supermajority legislative votes, reforms have been a major feature of the post-communist landscape. There were ten reforms of the electoral formula in six states, but concentrated in three countries. Mongolia is responsible for three shifts, with two consecutive reforms in which the latter reversed the first, from single member run-off to multimember plurality, and back to SMM. The other cases of multiple formula alterations took place in Macedonia and Ukraine, but these were unidirectional, from SMD to Mixed to PR systems. In addition there were three formula adjustments within the single member component of mixed systems, but again one set involved a turnaround: Lithuania first moved from majority run-off to plurality rules, than reverted back in the following election. While this concentration may produce the impression that changes in formula were not as prevalent as initially noted, the number of affected countries is still twice that of the alterations in established democracies. If we embrace a more expansive definition of major reforms to include district magnitude, then the number of adjustments in elections law increase significantly, as there were eight such changes due to redistricting and eight additional ones due to reform in other electoral 14

16 properties, e.g. size of the legislative chamber. These important revisions in the conduct of elections were supplemented by additional alterations in other minor reforms of the electoral code. Here the most pervasive instrument is the application of the threshold, with 19 revisions, by far the most common element of electoral engineering in the post-communist environment. Again, this is tied to the transparency of the change, which is much easier to interpret than other modifications in the electoral system. For that reason, increases in the legal bar were an especially popular mechanism in East Europe and the former Soviet Union in the initial phase of democratization, when political chaos characterized the newly opened political space, and provided a catalyst to restrain the political noise through more restrictive rules. Table 2 about here The inchoate nature of the new politics in the aftermath of the 1989 breakthrough is a factor in the temporal trend of reforms. There is a high concentration of changes in the first two post-founding election cycles, with a probability of reform at 77% in the second wave of elections, 50% in the third cycle, and a drop off to slightly above 30% in the subsequent elections. The propensity to initiate election reform is skewed towards the first voting contests, with 18 out of the 33 reform clusters during the first two cycles, and the other 13 reforms spread across the subsequent electoral periods (Table 2). This trend is evident also for the major reform types, with eight alterations in electoral formula at the forefront of competitive politics, with the remaining five in the subsequent three elections; a pattern repeated for the changes in district magnitude. The chronological path of reform implementation mirrors the extent of party system fragmentation, which is higher during the years immediately following the fall of the ancient regimes and levels off during the last three election cycles, although the level of volatility remains high for much of the period. So at least in terms of comparative trends, countries that 15

17 undertook reform had higher average volatility and fragmentation in the preceding election cycle than those that did not undertake reform. However, a multivariate probit analysis for the entire post communist period does not find any meaningful effect of party system shape on the propensity to adopt reforms. Table 3 about here This holds for the lagged measure of party fragmentation by votes and seats, and for control of parliamentary majorities. In both the votes and the seats models, the estimated effect of fragmentation measured by the effective number of parties shows no substantive or statistically significant effect. Electoral prospects are more likely to influence the likelihood of reforms. The effect of electoral volatility is large in the first few election cycles and statistically significant to the.01 level. In the second election cycle, the first in which we can observe change, the predicted probability of reform for countries with average levels of volatility is.63 (with all other independent and control variables held at their mean or modal values). Those with levels of volatility one standard deviation below and above the mean showed predicted probabilities of.17 and.95 respectively. This very large substantive effect all but disappears in the fourth election cycle and beyond. In the model based on votes, the vote share of the largest party has a positive and statistically significant effect, which fades in later election cycles. Larger vote shares are associated with increased likelihoods of reform, all else being equal. In the second election cycle, again the first in which we can observe reform, the predicted probability of reform for countries with average vote shares for the largest party is.66 (with all other independent and control variables held at their mean or modal values). Increasing or decreasing the largest party s vote share by one standard deviation yields predicted probabilities of.90 and.33 16

18 respectively. The effect over time is more robust than for electoral volatility but of somewhat smaller magnitude. Voting trends rather than party system fragmentation are more likely to affect the chances of reform. Direction of Reforms Nonetheless, reforms of electoral systems have been a consistent feature of the democratizing experience in the post-communist world. The central question is whether the initiation of reform favors permissive or restrictive innovations. The empirical evidence on the direction of reform is mixed (Table 4). On the most inclusive level, for all major and minor reforms, there is no overall pattern favoring one type of reform over the other; in fact there is an equal division with 17 restrictive and 16 permissive electoral innovations. Given the absence of a unidirectional, systematic trend, we cannot attribute the implementation of reforms to either the strategic seat maximization or the governance effectiveness motivations. Rather both models seem applicable at different times, for different reforms. As a chronological trend, there is some evidence that restrictive laws were concentrated in the first two post-founding voting cycles, as a response to the inchoate nature of the political system at the start of democratization, indicating a desire to impose greater efficiency. At the same time, however, there is an evident presence of permissive reforms throughout the period, with a flurry of activity during the third cycle, indicating concern with strategic calculations of representation. Table 4 about here There is some indication from the bivariate pattern that the shape of party systems does affect the direction of change. Systems that introduce more restrictive electoral rules have higher levels of party system fragmentation in the prior election cycle in terms of votes (6.1 average) and seats (4.4), and an increase in fragmentation over time. In comparison, reforms in a 17

19 permissive direction occur in conditions with fewer effective numbers of electoral (4.4 average) and parliamentary parties (3.0 average), and are undergoing a decline in the former measure. From this evidence, we can deduce that the high fragmentation of post-communist parties tends to favor measures that seek to introduce a more manageable political environment, giving greater credence to the effective governance perspective. However, permissive reforms are associated with higher levels of electoral volatility (27.2 average) than restrictive reforms (23.6). In both trends, volatility is still quite significant, so that that strategic position that high volatility brings about more permissive rules, and the governance perspective that high volatility results in more restrictive electoral applications are possible. In order to clarify the timing and direction of electoral innovations, we turn to a multinomial logit model, which allows for a joint estimation of the likelihood of both direction of reform. We divide instances of reform into restrictive and permissive categories in order to investigate the causal factors associated with each type of reform. Table 5 shows two multinomial logit models, one based on measures derived from votes and one based on measures derived from seats. The baseline outcome is no reform, so the models for restrictive and permissive reform are in relation to no reform. Just as in the probit models, we have included a continuous variable for election cycle and interaction terms with the variables of theoretical interest. Table 5 about here The results for electoral volatility by votes (EVV) are very similar to those in the probit model. Interestingly, the effect is almost identical for both restrictive and permissive reform, meaning that volatility provides no leverage for ascertaining the likelihood of restrictive over permissive electoral changes. Rather higher levels of volatility in the previous electoral cycle are 18

20 associated with a greater probability of both types of rule changes, towards more open and more closed systems. The coefficient is statistically significant for the restrictive type, and while the coefficient for volatility under permissive reform is not significant at the.05 level, it only just falls short of that critical value. As a specific example of the relationship, Figure 1 shows the predicted probabilities for each value of volatility in the votes model for the second election cycle; all other variables are held at their mean or modal values. The higher likelihood of permissive reform reflects the greater propensity toward that type of reform in the first election cycles. 4 Most of the cases fall between 15 and 35 on volatility, and the mean is 25. Figure 1 shows the strong impact of volatility on the likelihood of both types of rule modification. Figure 1 about here These results support aspects of both the strategic perspective s contention that high volatility increases the likelihood of permissive reform and the governance perspective s claim that high volatility brings about restrictive reform. Additionally, the negative sign on the interaction term suggests increasing inertia in later election cycles. In relation to the other variables included in the model, volatility is the strongest predictor of reform, but does not provide solid information on the direction of the change as either permissive or restrictive. In the votes model, the effective number of parties produces results in opposite directions, but the standard errors are very large, throwing doubt on any substantive interpretation. However, in the seats model, there is a strong negative impact on the likelihood of alterations towards more permissive election rules. Higher numbers of parties are associated with a lower likelihood of permissive reform, although the strength of the effect decreases in 4 This may be, in part, an artifact of the modeling choices regarding election cycle discussed above. The reforms are split evenly between restrictive and permissive reform in the second election cycle, but permissive reforms predominate in the third electoral cycle. The choice of a continuous specification of electoral cycle instead of a set of dummy variables forces a more linear relationship between reform and election cycle. 19

21 later election cycles, and the effect is gone by the fourth cycle. Therefore, these results do not provide support for claims that party system fragmentation affects the likelihood of permissive or restrictive reform. In both the votes and the seats model, the effect of the largest party vote share is small and not statistically significant, however, as in the probit seats model, the multinomial logit seats model slows a statistically significant, negative relationship between the vote share of the largest two parties and the likelihood of reform. In the multinomial logit seats model, the effect is only statistically significant for permissive reforms. Greater vote shares for the two largest parties are associated with a decreased likelihood of permissive reforms, although the size of the impact decreases in later election cycles. Interpreting the impact of the election cycle variable is made difficult by the interaction terms with the volatility and fragmentation measures. Even though the coefficients for election cycle in the votes model are positive, the combined net effect of election cycle and the interaction terms including the cycle measure is negative when all variables are held at their mean. The net effect of election cycle is shown in Figure 2, which depicts the predicted probability for each type of reform by successive elections. Consistent with the inertia perspective, the probabilities of both types of reform decrease dramatically over time. Figure 2 about here Types of Reform: Frequency and Direction A more evident temporal pattern as to the introduction of permissive or restrictive criteria emerges in conjunction with specific types of reform. For the most significant reform, that of formula, the direction is markedly more towards the permissive side, with nine alterations as opposed to four in the opposite direction. On this dimension, the evidence points to more 20

22 frequent consideration of strategic calculations for assuring representation through more relaxed rules. Most of the changes in the formula mirror the long-term global path towards PR defined by Colomer (2005). A closer examination of the evidence outlined in Table 1 reveals that the trend is even more pronounced when discounting reversals in subsequent elections. In that case, the majority of formula reforms have moved towards proportional representation, whether in Bulgaria at the start of the post-communist transition or later on in the Ukraine, Macedonia or Croatia in conjunction with pressures associated with the second transition from dominant party systems. In all these instances, the reform has moved away from single member plurality or majoritarian systems to mixed or PR formulas, and then from mixed to full PR. Two countries, as noted previously, have initiated formula reforms only to reinstitute the previous method in the subsequent election. Both in Lithuania and Mongolia, the final disposition in the experimentation with formula alterations was towards a more permissive electoral system. In fact, of the eight countries applying revisions to their formula, only Albania 2005 application of plurality to its SMD segment and Romania 2008 introduction of a MMP have culminated in more restrictive election practices. These last two more recent changes reflect other attempts in the region to bring about more restrictive systems, as for example in the arguments advanced in Poland for the replacement of PR with mixed or majoritarian systems (Millard, 2008). In these instances, the justification for moving away from pure PR is to facilitate the work of the legislature, overcome weak government, strengthen the main parties and consolidate the party system. The effort, successful or not, is clearly a reflection of the dominant parties concern with streaming the unruly competitive space and facilitate more efficient government. 21

23 Similarly, the governance model s assertion that effectiveness is a critical component in the selection of electoral reforms is borne out by long-standing practices concerning the electoral threshold and the vote to seat conversion in proportional representation systems. Revisions in these two properties of election codes obviously aim at restrictive practices that signal a desire to trim the party systems. By far the most common reform in that regard is the introduction or increase in the legal bar for entry into parliament, affecting requirements for single parties and for pre-election coalitions. Once again, the practice was especially prevalent during the first two post-founding elections cycles, when the explosion of new political actors onto the democratic competitive field rendered the legislative agenda problematic. The paradigmatic case here is Poland between 1991 and 1993, when the appearance of dozen of parties in the electoral and parliamentary space made stable governance impossible, leading to the imposition of a 5% threshold for parties and 8% for coalition at the lower tier, and an increase from 5 to 7% at the upper tier of the unlinked PR system; accompanied at the same time by a shift to the more restrictive d Hondt conversion method. Similar practices took place throughout the region in the first part of the 1990s, with higher threshold requirements imposed in the Czech Republic, Hungary, Latvia, Lithuania, Romania, and Slovakia (Table 1). The only significant exception to the reductive effect of threshold reforms occur in Croatia 2000 and Georgia 2008, when the appearance of new political forces in the aftermath of the erosion of strong-man rule provides a strong impetus to open up the political process and assure representation. The greater propensity to institute more restrictive demands through the legal requirement and the vote to seat conversion rules is countered by the more permissive direction of changes in district magnitude. On this dimension, taking into account district, assembly size, and tier changes that affect the magnitude of the electoral system, there were 12 permissive 22

24 alterations in contrast to just four restrictive ones. Even when we discount the changes in magnitude due to the shifts from SMD or mixed to PR systems, there are still significant shifts in magnitude within PR, the most evident in Slovakia s adaptation of a nationwide district of 150 in 1998 and Montenegro s return to a single district of 30 in Conclusion In view of these changes, there is an obvious discrepancy, or at least a duality, in the direction of reforms in the post-1989 period. The post-communist states have embraced both permissive and restrictive strategies of electoral system transformation. On the whole, major reforms in formula and district magnitude have moved the election practices towards more permissive rules. These steps, however, are countered by other, significant restrictive innovations, most evident in threshold and conversion rules. For the democratic cases of postcommunism, then, some states have initiated reforms that are permissive and suggest predominant concerns with strategic calculations. Other countries have favored more restrictive adjustments in electoral properties, pointing to a greater concern with policy efficiency. At first glance, the trends do not produce clear evidence how the shape of the party system informs the initiation and direction of electoral reforms. In view of both permissive and restrictive electoral changes present in the post-communist states, the question as to what determines the decision to reform and in what direction remains uncertain. Still, throughout much of the region, there is a propensity towards electoral law fetishism, evident in the sequence of reforms, as well as the continuing attempts at reform. Modifications of electoral codes are embraced as remedies for the ills of the party systems, either to assure representation in an unstable political context or to provide better efficiency in governance. But the problem may well be deeper that election decision rules; associated rather 23

25 with the extent and complexity of the post-communist transition that generates an inchoate party system populated by weak political parties. The solution to the dilemma may well rest beyond the alteration of electoral systems, through the gradual emergence of winners and losers in the competitive process bound by established rules, rather than the manipulation of electoral institutions. 24

26 Table 1. Electoral Reforms in Unicameral or Lower Legislative Chamber Country Year Electoral Reforms Reform Direction Albania 1997 Decrease in threshold From majority run-off to plurality in SMD segment - Bosnia 2000 District change: decrease in average district magnitude - Introduction of threshold - Single to two tiers PR Introduction of threshold in upper tier - Bulgaria 1991 From Mixed to PR system + Reduced number of deputies - Croatia 2000 From Mixed to PR system + Increased number of deputies + Decrease in threshold + Czech R District change: increase in average district magnitude + Increased number of deputies + Introduce threshold for coalitions District change: decrease in average district magnitude - Increased threshold for coalitions - Two tiers to single tier PR - Georgia 2008 District change: increase in average district magnitude + Decrease in threshold + Reduced number of deputies - Hungary 1994 Increase in threshold - Latvia 1995 Increase in threshold - Lithuania 1996 Increase in threshold From majority run-off to plurality in SMD segment From plurality to majority run-off in SMD segment + Macedonia 1998 From SMD to Mixed system From Mixed to PR system + Moldova 2001 Increase in threshold - 25

27 Table 1. Electoral Reforms in Unicameral or Lower Legislative Chamber/continued Country Year Electoral Reforms Reform Direction Mongolia 1992 SMD to multi member plurality MMP to single member plurality SMD to multi member plurality + Poland 1993 District change: decrease in average district magnitude - Change in seat allocation formula - Increase in threshold District change: increase in average district magnitude + Change from two tiers to one tier PR - Change in seat allocation formula Change in seat allocation formula - Romania 1996 Introduce higher threshold for coalitions Increase in threshold PR to multi member proportional - Slovakia 1992 Change in lower level seat allocation formula - Increase in threshold District change: increase in average district magnitude + Change from two tiers to one tier PR - Increase in threshold for coalition Decrease in threshold for coalition + Slovenia 2000 Change in seat allocation formula - Ukraine 1998 SMD to Mixed electoral system Mixed to PR electoral system + Decrease in threshold in Mix PR to full PR - Yugoslavia Montenegro 2000 District change: increase in average district magnitude + 26

Chapter 6 Online Appendix. general these issues do not cause significant problems for our analysis in this chapter. One

Chapter 6 Online Appendix. general these issues do not cause significant problems for our analysis in this chapter. One Chapter 6 Online Appendix Potential shortcomings of SF-ratio analysis Using SF-ratios to understand strategic behavior is not without potential problems, but in general these issues do not cause significant

More information

Introduction Why Don t Electoral Rules Have the Same Effects in All Countries?

Introduction Why Don t Electoral Rules Have the Same Effects in All Countries? Introduction Why Don t Electoral Rules Have the Same Effects in All Countries? In the early 1990s, Japan and Russia each adopted a very similar version of a mixed-member electoral system. In the form used

More information

Part Three (continued): Electoral Systems & Linkage Institutions

Part Three (continued): Electoral Systems & Linkage Institutions Part Three (continued): Electoral Systems & Linkage Institutions Our political institutions work remarkably well. They are designed to clang against each other. The noise is democracy at work. -- Michael

More information

Electoral Systems and Evaluations of Democracy

Electoral Systems and Evaluations of Democracy Chapter three Electoral Systems and Evaluations of Democracy André Blais and Peter Loewen Introduction Elections are a substitute for less fair or more violent forms of decision making. Democracy is based

More information

Partisan Advantage and Competitiveness in Illinois Redistricting

Partisan Advantage and Competitiveness in Illinois Redistricting Partisan Advantage and Competitiveness in Illinois Redistricting An Updated and Expanded Look By: Cynthia Canary & Kent Redfield June 2015 Using data from the 2014 legislative elections and digging deeper

More information

Power Dispersion and Its Consequences: Three Models of Post- Communist Parliamentarism i

Power Dispersion and Its Consequences: Three Models of Post- Communist Parliamentarism i Power Dispersion and Its Consequences: Three Models of Post- Communist Parliamentarism i Csaba Nikolenyi Department of Political Science Concordia University Paper presented at the Joint Workshop Sessions

More information

Tzu-chiao Su Chinese Culture University, Taiwan

Tzu-chiao Su Chinese Culture University, Taiwan The Effect of Electoral System and Election Timing on Party System and Government Type: a Cross-Country Study of Presidential and Semi-presidential Democracies Tzu-chiao Su Chinese Culture University,

More information

Women s. Political Representation & Electoral Systems. Key Recommendations. Federal Context. September 2016

Women s. Political Representation & Electoral Systems. Key Recommendations. Federal Context. September 2016 Women s Political Representation & Electoral Systems September 2016 Federal Context Parity has been achieved in federal cabinet, but women remain under-represented in Parliament. Canada ranks 62nd Internationally

More information

THRESHOLDS. Underlying principles. What submitters on the party vote threshold said

THRESHOLDS. Underlying principles. What submitters on the party vote threshold said THRESHOLDS Underlying principles A threshold is the minimum level of support a party needs to gain representation. Thresholds are intended to provide for effective government and ensure that every party

More information

Manipulating Electoral Rules:

Manipulating Electoral Rules: Manipulating Electoral Rules: Intra-Party Conflict, Partisan Interests, and Constitutional Thickness Stanford University Dissertation (Draft) Chapter 1 Presenting and Testing a General Theory of Electoral

More information

Congruence in Political Parties

Congruence in Political Parties Descriptive Representation of Women and Ideological Congruence in Political Parties Georgia Kernell Northwestern University gkernell@northwestern.edu June 15, 2011 Abstract This paper examines the relationship

More information

Designing Weighted Voting Games to Proportionality

Designing Weighted Voting Games to Proportionality Designing Weighted Voting Games to Proportionality In the analysis of weighted voting a scheme may be constructed which apportions at least one vote, per-representative units. The numbers of weighted votes

More information

Elections and Electoral Systems

Elections and Electoral Systems Elections and Electoral Systems Democracies are sometimes classified in terms of their electoral system. An electoral system is a set of laws that regulate electoral competition between candidates or parties

More information

CAN FAIR VOTING SYSTEMS REALLY MAKE A DIFFERENCE?

CAN FAIR VOTING SYSTEMS REALLY MAKE A DIFFERENCE? CAN FAIR VOTING SYSTEMS REALLY MAKE A DIFFERENCE? Facts and figures from Arend Lijphart s landmark study: Patterns of Democracy: Government Forms and Performance in Thirty-Six Countries Prepared by: Fair

More information

The California Primary and Redistricting

The California Primary and Redistricting The California Primary and Redistricting This study analyzes what is the important impact of changes in the primary voting rules after a Congressional and Legislative Redistricting. Under a citizen s committee,

More information

Chapter 4. Party Systems

Chapter 4. Party Systems Chapter 4 Party Systems Effective parties that work well can serve multiple functions in democracies: simplifying and structuring electoral choices; organizing and mobilizing campaigns; articulating and

More information

Volatile and tripolar: The new Italian party system

Volatile and tripolar: The new Italian party system Volatile and tripolar: The new Italian party system Alessandro Chiaramonte and Vincenzo Emanuele February 27, 2013 The extraordinary success of Grillo and the electoral collapse of the PdL and the PD deeply

More information

Which electoral systems succeed at providing proportionality and concentration? An

Which electoral systems succeed at providing proportionality and concentration? An Which electoral systems succeed at providing proportionality and concentration? An investigation of promising (mixed) designs and risky tools. Johannes Raabe (Universität Kiel, Germany) Eric Linhart (Technische

More information

Benchmarking SME performance in the Eastern Partner region: discussion of an analytical paper

Benchmarking SME performance in the Eastern Partner region: discussion of an analytical paper Co-funded by the European Union POLICY SEMINAR EASTERN EUROPE AND SOUTH CAUCASUS INITIATIVE SUPPORTING SME COMPETITIVENESS IN THE EASTERN PARTNER COUNTRIES Benchmarking SME performance in the Eastern Partner

More information

Measuring Presidential Power in Post-Communist Countries: Rectification of Mistakes 1

Measuring Presidential Power in Post-Communist Countries: Rectification of Mistakes 1 Measuring Presidential Power in Post-Communist Countries: Rectification of Mistakes 1 Doi:10.5901/mjss.2015.v6n1s1p443 Abstract Oleg Zaznaev Professor and Chair of Department of Political Science, Kazan

More information

Electoral Systems and Democracy: a Comparative Analysis of Macedonia and Albania

Electoral Systems and Democracy: a Comparative Analysis of Macedonia and Albania Journal of Identity and Migration Studies Volume 7, number 1, 2013 Electoral Systems and Democracy: a Comparative Analysis of Macedonia and Albania Etem AZIRI, Oreta SALIAJ Abstract. Elections and electoral

More information

MODELING THE EFFECT OF EXECUTIVE-LEGISLATIVE RELATIONS ON DEMOCRATIC STABILITY. Terry D. Clark, Creighton University. and

MODELING THE EFFECT OF EXECUTIVE-LEGISLATIVE RELATIONS ON DEMOCRATIC STABILITY. Terry D. Clark, Creighton University. and 4/5/2004 2:58 PM MODELING THE EFFECT OF EXECUTIVE-LEGISLATIVE RELATIONS ON DEMOCRATIC STABILITY Terry D. Clark, Creighton University and Raivydas Šimėnas, Creighton University 2 MODELING THE EFFECT OF

More information

Reforming the Judiciary: Learning from the Experience of Central, Eastern, and Southeastern Europe

Reforming the Judiciary: Learning from the Experience of Central, Eastern, and Southeastern Europe E U R Reforming the Judiciary: Learning from the Experience of Central, Eastern, and Southeastern Europe Chapter 2 of Fall 2017 Regional Economic Outlook Laura Papi Assistant Director, Emerging Economies

More information

Political Economics II Spring Lectures 4-5 Part II Partisan Politics and Political Agency. Torsten Persson, IIES

Political Economics II Spring Lectures 4-5 Part II Partisan Politics and Political Agency. Torsten Persson, IIES Lectures 4-5_190213.pdf Political Economics II Spring 2019 Lectures 4-5 Part II Partisan Politics and Political Agency Torsten Persson, IIES 1 Introduction: Partisan Politics Aims continue exploring policy

More information

Supplementary information for the article:

Supplementary information for the article: Supplementary information for the article: Happy moves? Assessing the link between life satisfaction and emigration intentions Artjoms Ivlevs Contents 1. Summary statistics of variables p. 2 2. Country

More information

The Electoral Systems in SEE Countries: From Experiments to Consolidation

The Electoral Systems in SEE Countries: From Experiments to Consolidation Doi:10.5901/mjss.2014.v5n7p569 Abstract The Electoral Systems in SEE Countries: From Experiments to Consolidation PhD. Afrim Krasniqi University Aleksander Moisiu Albania E-mail: afrimkrasniqi@gmail.com

More information

Unit 1 Introduction to Comparative Politics Test Multiple Choice 2 pts each

Unit 1 Introduction to Comparative Politics Test Multiple Choice 2 pts each Unit 1 Introduction to Comparative Politics Test Multiple Choice 2 pts each 1. Which of the following is NOT considered to be an aspect of globalization? A. Increased speed and magnitude of cross-border

More information

Electoral System Change in Europe since 1945: Czech Republic

Electoral System Change in Europe since 1945: Czech Republic Electoral System Change in Europe since 1945: Czech Republic Authored by: Alan Renwick Compiled with the assistance of: Peter Spáč With thanks to: 1 Section 1: Overview of Czech Electoral System Changes

More information

Preferential votes and minority representation in open list proportional representation systems

Preferential votes and minority representation in open list proportional representation systems Soc Choice Welf (018) 50:81 303 https://doi.org/10.1007/s00355-017-1084- ORIGINAL PAPER Preferential votes and minority representation in open list proportional representation systems Margherita Negri

More information

HOW DUAL MEMBER PROPORTIONAL COULD WORK IN BRITISH COLUMBIA Sean Graham February 1, 2018

HOW DUAL MEMBER PROPORTIONAL COULD WORK IN BRITISH COLUMBIA Sean Graham February 1, 2018 HOW DUAL MEMBER PROPORTIONAL COULD WORK IN BRITISH COLUMBIA Sean Graham smg1@ualberta.ca February 1, 2018 1 1 INTRODUCTION Dual Member Proportional (DMP) is a compelling alternative to the Single Member

More information

Stuck in Transition? STUCK IN TRANSITION? TRANSITION REPORT Jeromin Zettelmeyer Deputy Chief Economist. Turkey country visit 3-6 December 2013

Stuck in Transition? STUCK IN TRANSITION? TRANSITION REPORT Jeromin Zettelmeyer Deputy Chief Economist. Turkey country visit 3-6 December 2013 TRANSITION REPORT 2013 www.tr.ebrd.com STUCK IN TRANSITION? Stuck in Transition? Turkey country visit 3-6 December 2013 Jeromin Zettelmeyer Deputy Chief Economist Piroska M. Nagy Director for Country Strategy

More information

Political Sophistication and Third-Party Voting in Recent Presidential Elections

Political Sophistication and Third-Party Voting in Recent Presidential Elections Political Sophistication and Third-Party Voting in Recent Presidential Elections Christopher N. Lawrence Department of Political Science Duke University April 3, 2006 Overview During the 1990s, minor-party

More information

Political Sophistication and Third-Party Voting in Recent Presidential Elections

Political Sophistication and Third-Party Voting in Recent Presidential Elections Political Sophistication and Third-Party Voting in Recent Presidential Elections Christopher N. Lawrence Department of Political Science Duke University April 3, 2006 Overview During the 1990s, minor-party

More information

Electoral Systems and Party Systems: Which is the Cause and Which is the Consequence? Mette Bakken August

Electoral Systems and Party Systems: Which is the Cause and Which is the Consequence? Mette Bakken August Electoral Systems and Party Systems: Which is the Cause and Which is the Consequence? Mette Bakken August 2008 1 Abstract: Electoral systems research can be divided into two main branches: the study of

More information

Gender pay gap in public services: an initial report

Gender pay gap in public services: an initial report Introduction This report 1 examines the gender pay gap, the difference between what men and women earn, in public services. Drawing on figures from both Eurostat, the statistical office of the European

More information

Parliamentary Election Turnout in Europe since 1990

Parliamentary Election Turnout in Europe since 1990 POLITICAL STUDIES: 2002 VOL 50, 916 927 Parliamentary Election Turnout in Europe since 1990 Alan Siaroff University of Lethbridge John W. A. Merer Vanderbilt University This article examines the cross-national

More information

Elections and referendums

Elections and referendums Caramani (ed.) Comparative Politics Section III: Structures and institutions Chapter 10: Elections and referendums by Michael Gallagher (1/1) Elections and referendums are the two main voting opportunities

More information

Analysis of public opinion on Macedonia s accession to Author: Ivan Damjanovski

Analysis of public opinion on Macedonia s accession to Author: Ivan Damjanovski Analysis of public opinion on Macedonia s accession to the European Union 2014-2016 Author: Ivan Damjanovski CONCLUSIONS 3 The trends regarding support for Macedonia s EU membership are stable and follow

More information

LEVELING THE PLAYING FIELD: ELECTORAL THRESHOLDS AND THE REPRESENTATION OF WOMEN TRACY QUINLAN GENERAL SITUATION OF WOMEN IN PARLIAMENTS

LEVELING THE PLAYING FIELD: ELECTORAL THRESHOLDS AND THE REPRESENTATION OF WOMEN TRACY QUINLAN GENERAL SITUATION OF WOMEN IN PARLIAMENTS LEVELING THE PLAYING FIELD: ELECTORAL THRESHOLDS AND THE REPRESENTATION OF WOMEN TRACY QUINLAN There are large cross-national differences in the percentage of women in legislatures. Institutional arrangement

More information

CU Scholar. University of Colorado, Boulder. Daniel Kotsides University of Colorado Boulder. Spring 2013

CU Scholar. University of Colorado, Boulder. Daniel Kotsides University of Colorado Boulder. Spring 2013 University of Colorado, Boulder CU Scholar Undergraduate Honors Theses Honors Program Spring 2013 Democracy, Post-Communism and Public Trust: An Examination of Levels of Democracy and Post- Communism as

More information

A PARLIAMENT THAT WORKS FOR WALES

A PARLIAMENT THAT WORKS FOR WALES A PARLIAMENT THAT WORKS FOR WALES The summary report of the Expert Panel on Assembly Electoral Reform November 2017 INTRODUCTION FROM THE CHAIR Today s Assembly is a very different institution to the one

More information

Parity democracy A far cry from reality.

Parity democracy A far cry from reality. Parity democracy A far cry from reality Comparative study on the results of the first and second rounds of monitoring of Council of Europe Recommendation Rec(2003)3 on balanced participation of women and

More information

Electoral Threshold, Representation, and Parties Incentives to Form a Bloc.

Electoral Threshold, Representation, and Parties Incentives to Form a Bloc. Electoral Threshold, Representation, and Parties Incentives to Form a Bloc. Andrei Bremzen, Georgy Egorov, Dmitry Shakin This Draft: April 2, 2007 Abstract In most countries with proportional representation

More information

European Union Expansion and the Euro: Croatia, Iceland and Turkey

European Union Expansion and the Euro: Croatia, Iceland and Turkey International Journal of Business and Social Science Vol. 5, No. 13; December 2014 European Union Expansion and the Euro: Croatia, Iceland and Turkey Cynthia Royal Tori, PhD Valdosta State University Langdale

More information

Incumbency as a Source of Spillover Effects in Mixed Electoral Systems: Evidence from a Regression-Discontinuity Design.

Incumbency as a Source of Spillover Effects in Mixed Electoral Systems: Evidence from a Regression-Discontinuity Design. Incumbency as a Source of Spillover Effects in Mixed Electoral Systems: Evidence from a Regression-Discontinuity Design Forthcoming, Electoral Studies Web Supplement Jens Hainmueller Holger Lutz Kern September

More information

Hungary. Basic facts The development of the quality of democracy in Hungary. The overall quality of democracy

Hungary. Basic facts The development of the quality of democracy in Hungary. The overall quality of democracy Hungary Basic facts 2007 Population 10 055 780 GDP p.c. (US$) 13 713 Human development rank 43 Age of democracy in years (Polity) 17 Type of democracy Electoral system Party system Parliamentary Mixed:

More information

The Case of the Disappearing Bias: A 2014 Update to the Gerrymandering or Geography Debate

The Case of the Disappearing Bias: A 2014 Update to the Gerrymandering or Geography Debate The Case of the Disappearing Bias: A 2014 Update to the Gerrymandering or Geography Debate Nicholas Goedert Lafayette College goedertn@lafayette.edu May, 2015 ABSTRACT: This note observes that the pro-republican

More information

The political economy of electricity market liberalization: a cross-country approach

The political economy of electricity market liberalization: a cross-country approach The political economy of electricity market liberalization: a cross-country approach Erkan Erdogdu PhD Candidate The 30 th USAEE/IAEE North American Conference California Room, Capital Hilton Hotel, Washington

More information

The United Kingdom in the European context top-line reflections from the European Social Survey

The United Kingdom in the European context top-line reflections from the European Social Survey The United Kingdom in the European context top-line reflections from the European Social Survey Rory Fitzgerald and Elissa Sibley 1 With the forthcoming referendum on Britain s membership of the European

More information

A comparative analysis of poverty and social inclusion indicators at European level

A comparative analysis of poverty and social inclusion indicators at European level A comparative analysis of poverty and social inclusion indicators at European level CRISTINA STE, EVA MILARU, IA COJANU, ISADORA LAZAR, CODRUTA DRAGOIU, ELIZA-OLIVIA NGU Social Indicators and Standard

More information

Which electoral procedures seem appropriate for a multi-level polity?

Which electoral procedures seem appropriate for a multi-level polity? Policy Department C Citizens' Rights and Constitutional Affairs Which electoral procedures seem appropriate for a multi-level polity? CONSTITUTIONAL AFFAIRS PE 408.297 JANUARY 2004 EN Directorate-General

More information

LOK SATTA People Power. The National Campaign for Political Reforms - Why? 6 th October 2004, Mumbai

LOK SATTA People Power. The National Campaign for Political Reforms - Why? 6 th October 2004, Mumbai LOK SATTA People Power The National Campaign for Political Reforms - Why? 6 th October 2004, Mumbai 401 Nirmal Towers, Dwarakapuri Colony, Punjagutta, Hyderabad 500 082 Tel: 91 40 2335 0778 / 23350 790;

More information

Fair Division in Theory and Practice

Fair Division in Theory and Practice Fair Division in Theory and Practice Ron Cytron (Computer Science) Maggie Penn (Political Science) Lecture 4: The List Systems of Proportional Representation 1 Saari s milk, wine, beer example Thirteen

More information

The international diffusion of electoral systems: The spread of mechanisms tempering proportional representation across Europe

The international diffusion of electoral systems: The spread of mechanisms tempering proportional representation across Europe 384 European Journal of Political Research 54: 384 410, 2015 doi: 10.1111/1475-6765.12091 The international diffusion of electoral systems: The spread of mechanisms tempering proportional representation

More information

The Financial Crises of the 21st Century

The Financial Crises of the 21st Century The Financial Crises of the 21st Century Workshop of the Austrian Research Association (Österreichische Forschungsgemeinschaft) 18. - 19. 10. 2012 Economic Attitudes in Financial Crises: The Democratic

More information

CHAPTER 7 SEMI-PRESIDENTIALISM UNDER POST-COMMUNISM OLEH PROTSYK

CHAPTER 7 SEMI-PRESIDENTIALISM UNDER POST-COMMUNISM OLEH PROTSYK CHAPTER 7 SEMI-PRESIDENTIALISM UNDER POST-COMMUNISM OLEH PROTSYK In Robert Elgie, Sophia Moestrup, Yu-Shan Wu, eds., Semi-Presidentialism and Democracy (Palgrave Macmillan, 2011) Constitutional engineering

More information

Chapter 6 Democratic Regimes. Copyright 2015 W.W. Norton, Inc.

Chapter 6 Democratic Regimes. Copyright 2015 W.W. Norton, Inc. Chapter 6 Democratic Regimes 1. Democracy Clicker question: A state with should be defined as a nondemocracy. A.a hereditary monarch B.an official, state-sanctioned religion C.a legislative body that is

More information

The psychological and mechanical effects of voting rules. Evidence from the Romanian parliamentary elections

The psychological and mechanical effects of voting rules. Evidence from the Romanian parliamentary elections The psychological and mechanical effects of voting rules. Evidence from the Romanian parliamentary elections Andra-Maria ROESCU * andra_roescu@yahoo.com National School of Political and Administrative

More information

Index for the comparison of the efficiency of 42 European judicial systems, with data taken from the World Bank and Cepej reports.

Index for the comparison of the efficiency of 42 European judicial systems, with data taken from the World Bank and Cepej reports. FB Index 2012 Index for the comparison of the efficiency of 42 European judicial systems, with data taken from the World Bank and Cepej reports. Introduction The points of reference internationally recognized

More information

Arguments for and against electoral system change in Ireland

Arguments for and against electoral system change in Ireland Prof. Gallagher Arguments for and against electoral system change in Ireland Why would we decide to change, or not to change, the current PR-STV electoral system? In this short paper we ll outline some

More information

Effect of Electoral Systems on the Quality of Political Representation

Effect of Electoral Systems on the Quality of Political Representation Martin Oost December 216 Faculty of Behavioural, Management and Social Sciences University of Twente Effect of Electoral Systems on the Quality of Political Representation Abstract: Legislatures as elected

More information

Runoff Elections and the Number of Presidential Candidates A Regression Discontinuity Design Using Brazilian Municipalities

Runoff Elections and the Number of Presidential Candidates A Regression Discontinuity Design Using Brazilian Municipalities Runoff Elections and the Number of Presidential Candidates A Regression Discontinuity Design Using Brazilian Municipalities Timothy J. Power University of Oxford Rodrigo Rodrigues-Silveira University of

More information

Former Centrally Planned Economies 25 Years after the Fall of Communism James D. Gwartney and Hugo M. Montesinos

Former Centrally Planned Economies 25 Years after the Fall of Communism James D. Gwartney and Hugo M. Montesinos Former Centrally Planned Economies 25 Years after the Fall of Communism James D. Gwartney and Hugo M. Montesinos A little more than a quarter of a century has passed since the collapse of communism, which

More information

Sex-disaggregated statistics on the participation of women and men in political and public decision-making in Council of Europe member states

Sex-disaggregated statistics on the participation of women and men in political and public decision-making in Council of Europe member states Sex-disaggregated statistics on the participation of women and men in political and public decision-making in Council of Europe member states Situation as at 1 September 2008 http://www.coe.int/equality

More information

The Electoral System and its Impact on Electoral Behaviour: Is Taiwan s Experience Unusual?

The Electoral System and its Impact on Electoral Behaviour: Is Taiwan s Experience Unusual? The Electoral System and its Impact on Electoral Behaviour: Is Taiwan s Experience Unusual? Chia-hung Tsai Election Study Center, NCCU June 21, 2014 Presented at The Ordinary and the Extraordinary in Taiwan

More information

Why are there only two major parties in US? [party attachments below]

Why are there only two major parties in US? [party attachments below] Why are there only two major parties in US? [party attachments below] A. Institutional Constraints on 3 rd Parties 1. Election System Single-member districts (SMDs) Winner-take-all first-past-the-post

More information

THE SOUTH AUSTRALIAN LEGISLATIVE COUNCIL: POSSIBLE CHANGES TO ITS ELECTORAL SYSTEM

THE SOUTH AUSTRALIAN LEGISLATIVE COUNCIL: POSSIBLE CHANGES TO ITS ELECTORAL SYSTEM PARLIAMENTARY LIBRARY OF SOUTH AUSTRALIA THE SOUTH AUSTRALIAN LEGISLATIVE COUNCIL: POSSIBLE CHANGES TO ITS ELECTORAL SYSTEM BY JENNI NEWTON-FARRELLY INFORMATION PAPER 17 2000, Parliamentary Library of

More information

NATIONAL INTEGRITY SYSTEM ASSESSMENT ROMANIA. Atlantic Ocean. North Sea. Mediterranean Sea. Baltic Sea.

NATIONAL INTEGRITY SYSTEM ASSESSMENT ROMANIA. Atlantic Ocean.   North Sea. Mediterranean Sea. Baltic Sea. Atlantic Ocean Baltic Sea North Sea Bay of Biscay NATIONAL INTEGRITY SYSTEM ASSESSMENT ROMANIA Black Sea Mediterranean Sea www.transparency.org.ro With financial support from the Prevention of and Fight

More information

NATO S ENLARGEMENT POLICY IN THE POST-COLD WAR ERA

NATO S ENLARGEMENT POLICY IN THE POST-COLD WAR ERA IN THE POST-COLD WAR ERA The purpose of this article is not to address every aspect of the change taking place in NATO but rather to focus on the enlargement and globalization policy of NATO, which is

More information

Political Science 381: The Politics of Electoral Systems. Course Description

Political Science 381: The Politics of Electoral Systems. Course Description Political Science 381: The Politics of Electoral Systems Dr. Brian F. Crisp 285 Siegle Hall crisp@wustl.edu Office Hours: Thursdays 2:30-3:30 or by appointment Course Description It is impossible to appreciate

More information

HAS DEMOCRACY MET THE STRESS TEST IN POST-COMMUNIST EUROPE? By Adrian A. Basora

HAS DEMOCRACY MET THE STRESS TEST IN POST-COMMUNIST EUROPE? By Adrian A. Basora September 2012 HAS DEMOCRACY MET THE STRESS TEST IN POST-COMMUNIST EUROPE? By Adrian A. Basora Ambassador Adrian A. Basora is Director of the FPRI Project on Democratic Transitions (PDT). As U.S. Ambassador

More information

Iowa Voting Series, Paper 4: An Examination of Iowa Turnout Statistics Since 2000 by Party and Age Group

Iowa Voting Series, Paper 4: An Examination of Iowa Turnout Statistics Since 2000 by Party and Age Group Department of Political Science Publications 3-1-2014 Iowa Voting Series, Paper 4: An Examination of Iowa Turnout Statistics Since 2000 by Party and Age Group Timothy M. Hagle University of Iowa 2014 Timothy

More information

Comparative Economic Geography

Comparative Economic Geography Comparative Economic Geography 1 WORLD POPULATION gross world product (GWP) The GWP Global GDP In 2012: GWP totalled approximately US $83.12 trillion in terms of PPP while the per capita GWP was approx.

More information

If a party s share of the overall party vote entitles it to five seats, but it wins six electorates, the sixth seat is called an overhang seat.

If a party s share of the overall party vote entitles it to five seats, but it wins six electorates, the sixth seat is called an overhang seat. OVERHANGS How an overhang occurs Under MMP, a party is entitled to a number of seats based on its shares of the total nationwide party vote. If a party is entitled to 10 seats, but wins only seven electorates,

More information

John M. Carey & Simon Hix The electoral sweet spot: low-magnitude proportional electoral systems

John M. Carey & Simon Hix The electoral sweet spot: low-magnitude proportional electoral systems John M. Carey & Simon Hix The electoral sweet spot: low-magnitude proportional electoral systems Working paper Original citation: Carey, John M. and Hix, Simon (2009) The electoral sweet spot: low-magnitude

More information

- 1 - RULES OF PROCEDURE OF THE CEI PARLIAMENTARY DIMENSION (as of April 27, 2010) Content

- 1 - RULES OF PROCEDURE OF THE CEI PARLIAMENTARY DIMENSION (as of April 27, 2010) Content - 1 - RULES OF PROCEDURE OF THE CEI PARLIAMENTARY DIMENSION (as of April 27, 2010) Content Rule 1 General Provisions 2 Rule 2 Objectives 2 Rule 3 Membership and Composition 2 Rule 4 Bodies of the Parliamentary

More information

12. NATO enlargement

12. NATO enlargement THE ENLARGEMENT OF NATO 117 12. NATO enlargement NATO s door remains open to any European country in a position to undertake the commitments and obligations of membership, and contribute to security in

More information

European Parliament Elections: Turnout trends,

European Parliament Elections: Turnout trends, European Parliament Elections: Turnout trends, 1979-2009 Standard Note: SN06865 Last updated: 03 April 2014 Author: Section Steven Ayres Social & General Statistics Section As time has passed and the EU

More information

Political Participation under Democracy

Political Participation under Democracy Political Participation under Democracy Daniel Justin Kleinschmidt Cpr. Nr.: POL-PST.XB December 19 th, 2012 Political Science, Bsc. Semester 1 International Business & Politics Question: 2 Total Number

More information

The Determinants of Electoral Reform: A Synthesis of Alternative Approaches

The Determinants of Electoral Reform: A Synthesis of Alternative Approaches DRAFT March 2009 Please Do NOT Cite Without Authors Permission The Determinants of Electoral Reform: A Synthesis of Alternative Approaches Gideon Rahat & Reuven Y. Hazan Department of Political Science

More information

Electoral Reform in the United Kingdom: Lessons From the 2011 Alternative Vote Referendum

Electoral Reform in the United Kingdom: Lessons From the 2011 Alternative Vote Referendum Electoral Reform in the United Kingdom: Lessons From the 2011 Alternative Vote Referendum Abigail L. Heller Advisor: Professor Matthew Schousen GOV490, Government Departmental Honors Thesis Defended April

More information

Institutionalization: New Concepts and New Methods. Randolph Stevenson--- Rice University. Keith E. Hamm---Rice University

Institutionalization: New Concepts and New Methods. Randolph Stevenson--- Rice University. Keith E. Hamm---Rice University Institutionalization: New Concepts and New Methods Randolph Stevenson--- Rice University Keith E. Hamm---Rice University Andrew Spiegelman--- Rice University Ronald D. Hedlund---Northeastern University

More information

Neoliberalism and the future of market economy after the world financial crisis in Eastern Europe

Neoliberalism and the future of market economy after the world financial crisis in Eastern Europe EUROPEAN ACADEMIC RESEARCH Vol. III, Issue 1/ April 2015 ISSN 2286-4822 www.euacademic.org Impact Factor: 3.4546 (UIF) DRJI Value: 5.9 (B+) Neoliberalism and the future of market economy after the world

More information

Resistance to Women s Political Leadership: Problems and Advocated Solutions

Resistance to Women s Political Leadership: Problems and Advocated Solutions By Catherine M. Watuka Executive Director Women United for Social, Economic & Total Empowerment Nairobi, Kenya. Resistance to Women s Political Leadership: Problems and Advocated Solutions Abstract The

More information

Supplementary Materials for Strategic Abstention in Proportional Representation Systems (Evidence from Multiple Countries)

Supplementary Materials for Strategic Abstention in Proportional Representation Systems (Evidence from Multiple Countries) Supplementary Materials for Strategic Abstention in Proportional Representation Systems (Evidence from Multiple Countries) Guillem Riambau July 15, 2018 1 1 Construction of variables and descriptive statistics.

More information

5.1 Assessing the Impact of Conflict on Fractionalization

5.1 Assessing the Impact of Conflict on Fractionalization 5 Chapter 8 Appendix 5.1 Assessing the Impact of Conflict on Fractionalization We now turn to our primary focus that is the link between the long-run patterns of conflict and various measures of fractionalization.

More information

Table A.2 reports the complete set of estimates of equation (1). We distinguish between personal

Table A.2 reports the complete set of estimates of equation (1). We distinguish between personal Akay, Bargain and Zimmermann Online Appendix 40 A. Online Appendix A.1. Descriptive Statistics Figure A.1 about here Table A.1 about here A.2. Detailed SWB Estimates Table A.2 reports the complete set

More information

Europe and the US: Preferences for Redistribution

Europe and the US: Preferences for Redistribution Europe and the US: Preferences for Redistribution Peter Haan J. W. Goethe Universität Summer term, 2010 Peter Haan (J. W. Goethe Universität) Europe and the US: Preferences for Redistribution Summer term,

More information

Measuring Social Inclusion

Measuring Social Inclusion Measuring Social Inclusion Measuring Social Inclusion Social inclusion is a complex and multidimensional concept that cannot be measured directly. To represent the state of social inclusion in European

More information

Classical papers: Osborbe and Slivinski (1996) and Besley and Coate (1997)

Classical papers: Osborbe and Slivinski (1996) and Besley and Coate (1997) The identity of politicians is endogenized Typical approach: any citizen may enter electoral competition at a cost. There is no pre-commitment on the platforms, and winner implements his or her ideal policy.

More information

ONTARIO SUPERIOR COURT OF JUSTICE. JOAN RUSSOW and THE GREEN PARTY OF CANADA. - and -

ONTARIO SUPERIOR COURT OF JUSTICE. JOAN RUSSOW and THE GREEN PARTY OF CANADA. - and - ONTARIO SUPERIOR COURT OF JUSTICE File No.: B E T W E E N: JOAN RUSSOW and THE GREEN PARTY OF CANADA Applicants - and - THE ATTORNEY GENERAL OF CANADA, THE CHIEF ELECTORAL OFFICER OF CANADA and HER MAJESTY

More information

European Parliament Eurobarometer (EB79.5) ONE YEAR TO GO UNTIL THE 2014 EUROPEAN ELECTIONS Institutional Part ANALYTICAL OVERVIEW

European Parliament Eurobarometer (EB79.5) ONE YEAR TO GO UNTIL THE 2014 EUROPEAN ELECTIONS Institutional Part ANALYTICAL OVERVIEW Directorate-General for Communication Public Opinion Monitoring Unit Brussels, 21 August 2013. European Parliament Eurobarometer (EB79.5) ONE YEAR TO GO UNTIL THE 2014 EUROPEAN ELECTIONS Institutional

More information

Migrants and external voting

Migrants and external voting The Migration & Development Series On the occasion of International Migrants Day New York, 18 December 2008 Panel discussion on The Human Rights of Migrants Facilitating the Participation of Migrants in

More information

Strategic Electoral Rule Choice Under Uncertainty

Strategic Electoral Rule Choice Under Uncertainty Strategic Electoral Rule Choice Under Uncertainty Konstantinos Matakos University of Rochester Dimitrios Xefteris University of Cyprus October, 01 Abstract We study electoral rule choice in a multi-party

More information

Theoretical comparisons of electoral systems

Theoretical comparisons of electoral systems European Economic Review 43 (1999) 671 697 Joseph Schumpeter Lecture Theoretical comparisons of electoral systems Roger B. Myerson Kellog Graduate School of Management, Northwestern University, 2001 Sheridan

More information

parties and party systems

parties and party systems A/449268 classics Series Editor: Alan Ware University of Oxford parties and party systems a framework for analysis Giovanni Sartori with a new preface by the author and an introduction by Peter Mair contents

More information

2010 Municipal Elections in Lebanon

2010 Municipal Elections in Lebanon INTERNATIONAL FOUNDATION FOR ELECTORAL SYSTEMS 2010 Municipal Elections in Lebanon Electoral Systems Options Municipal elections in Lebanon are scheduled for Spring/Summer 2010. The current electoral system

More information

A positive correlation between turnout and plurality does not refute the rational voter model

A positive correlation between turnout and plurality does not refute the rational voter model Quality & Quantity 26: 85-93, 1992. 85 O 1992 Kluwer Academic Publishers. Printed in the Netherlands. Note A positive correlation between turnout and plurality does not refute the rational voter model

More information

Studies in Applied Economics

Studies in Applied Economics SAE./No.95/December 2017 Studies in Applied Economics AN EXAMINATION OF THE FORMER CENTRALLY PLANNED ECONOMIES 25 YEARS AFTER THE FALL OF COMMUNISM By James D. Gwartney and Hugo Montesinos Johns Hopkins

More information

Voter turnout and the first voters

Voter turnout and the first voters ASSOCIATION OF CENTRAL AND EASTERN EUROPEAN ELECTION OFFICIALS АССОЦИАЦИЯ ОРГАНИЗАТОРОВ ВЫБОРОВ СТРАН ЦЕНТРАЛЬНОЙ И ВОСТОЧНОЙ ЕВРОПЫ Voter turnout and the first voters 1. Introduction 1.1. Importance of

More information