Attitudes Towards Highly Skilled and Low Skilled Immigration in Europe A Survey Experiment in 15 European Countries

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Attitudes Towards Highly Skilled and Low Skilled Immigration in Europe A Survey Experiment in 15 European Countries"

Transcription

1 Attitudes Towards Highly Skilled and Low Skilled Immigration in Europe A Survey Experiment in 15 European Countries Elias Naumann 1, Lukas Stoetzer 2, Giuseppe Pietrantuono 3 1 University of Mannheim, Germany 2 Massachusetts Institute of Technology, Department of Political Science 3 University of Mannheim, Germany & University of Zurich, Switzerland Introduction Migration policy is at the top of the political agenda not only since the refugee crisis. One hope among policy makers is that migration might help overcome (mainly skilled) labour shortages due to the demographic change (United Nations, 2000; European Parliament, 2007). At the same time fears prevail that (unskilled) migrant workers will displace natives from the labour market and will put downward pressure on natives wages (e.g. Borjas 2003). These concerns fuel opposition against migration and gave rise to several right-wing parties in Europe (Ivarsflaten, 2008). Public opinion is a crucial factor in understanding (migration) politics (Stimson 2004, Burstein 2006, Brooks and Manza 2006, Erikson et al. 2002) and public attitudes towards high-skilled and low-skilled migration restricts politicians room for manoeuvre. It is thus of high importance to understand how people s attitudes toward migration are shaped. Why do people oppose or favor immigration? The extant literature has proposed two basic motivations that shape public attitudes towards immigration, cultural values and economic self-interest (see Hainmueller and Hiscox 1

2 2014 for a review). The first approach emphasizes the importance of cultural factors in shaping views on immigration. According to this perspective, individuals oppose immigration because foreigners are perceived as a threat to their, i.e. the national identity (e.g., Citrin et al. 1997; Fetzer 2000; McLaren and Johnson 2007, Card et al. 2011). The latter perspective relies mainly on material self-interest to explain attitudes towards immigration. Two strands have emerged within this political economy literature. Most prominently, the labour market competition model predicts that low- skilled migration will increase competition for low-skill jobs, lowering wages and employment in low-skilled sectors while increasing wages for high-skilled natives (Scheve and Slaughter 2001). Consequently, low-skilled natives are assumed to oppose lowskilled migration and rather support high-skilled migration. The opposite holds for high-skilled natives that should support low-skilled migration but oppose high-skilled migration (see also Mayda 2006). A second strand focuses on the fiscal impacts of migration. Assuming that lowskilled migration creates a net fiscal burden as low skilled migrants will possibly be net beneficiaries of welfare and of a redistributive tax system, high-income natives as the net payers of the system should be more strongly opposed to low-skilled migration compared to their low-income native counterparts. The opposite should apply for high-skilled migration (Hanson et al. 2007, Facchini and Mayda 2009, Hainmueller and Hiscox 2010, Tingley 2013). While scholars have consistently shown cultural concerns to be strong predictors of opposition, findings regarding the self-interest hypotheses are highly contested. Therefore, our article focuses on the self-interest explanation of attitudes towards migration. There is only very slowly emerging a consensus in that irrespective of skill-level or income people prefer high-skilled migration over low-skilled migration (Hainmueller and Hiscox 2010, 2

3 Helbling and Kriesi 2014, but see also Facchini and Mayda 2009). In how far the welfare state and/or fiscal pressures moderate such a relationship is still an open question as the two major experimental studies in the field (Hainmueller and Hiscox 2010, Helbling and Kriesi 2014) rely on single-country studies i.e. the US and Switzerland and use the intra-country variation to explain attitudes towards high-skilled and low-skilled migrants. The advantage of single country studies (and the use of intra-national variation) is the internal validity of its findings as most of the institutional context is held constant. Nevertheless this comes at a cost of external validity and uncertainty in how far these findings also hold in other institutional settings. The major concerns in this respect refer to American exceptionalism (Lipset 1996) and that findings from the US might not apply to European countries that differ largely in their migration history but also in how their welfare states developed (Larsen, 2008). Moreover, the US and Switzerland are very particular cases in that both have very low shares of public social spending (19,2% of GDP in the US, 19,4% of GDP in Switzerland compared to the OECD average of 21,6%, and 28% of GDP and more in Sweden, Italy and France). Against this background it might not be surprising that the fiscal and welfare context in these studies had only limited impact on the relationship between income, skill-level and attitudes towards migration. To test the implications of the labour competition and the fiscal burden models, we use a survey experiment (used in Hainmueller & Hiscox 2010) that was conducted in 15 European countries. Respondents from a variety of institutional settings thus were randomly assigned to give their attitudes towards either high-skilled or low-skilled migration. As one of the (very) few studies in the field of experimental political science we rely on cross-country comparisons and random probability samples of the respective populations. This comparison, how it varies with 3

4 respondents characteristics and whether it holds across a variety of institutional settings, allows us to reliably test the theoretical self-interest arguments. In addition to the spatial variation, how people form their attitudes towards migration should also vary over time and is particularly affected by salient events (for example see Legewie (2013) on how terrorist attacks have affected attitudes). Therefore, we replicated our experiment in 4 European countries after the onset of the refugee crisis in Europe (Germany, Sweden, Denmark and the UK). We use the refugee crisis as an external shock to the fiscal exposure to migration and examine how increased fiscal exposure affects the patterns of attitudes towards migration. Such a within country comparison nicely complements our crosssectional analysis providing leverage in terms of internal validity and inferring causality from correlations. For the labour market competition model in general we find that both high-skilled and low skilled natives prefer high-skilled over low-skilled migration, which is in line with previous findings stating that the labour market competition model holds only for less skilled natives. However, our robustness checks offer some support (even if not significant at conventional levels) by adopting more fine-grained competition measures for the theoretical predictions also concerning better skilled natives. As for the fiscal burden model, our results show a much clearer picture: the premium attached to high-skilled migration increases with income. Highincome respondents prefer high-skilled over low-skilled migration more than low income respondents since they are mainly concerned about tax increases due to the increased migration. Our results are thus in line with recent findings from Switzerland (Helbing and Kriesi, 4

5 2014) but contradicts evidence from the US (Hainmueller and Hiscox, 2010) where the premium attached to high skilled migration decreases with income. Moreover, by exploiting the refugee crisis as an exogenous shock we find a stronger relationship between income and support for high-skilled over low-skilled migration if fiscal exposure is high. Economic concerns and immigration attitudes National economies may be impacted by immigrant worker inflows in several ways. Prominently, the literature in the field has put forward and emphasized that anti-immigrant sentiments among natives may arise from two economic concerns: On the one hand, concerns about labor market competition and, on the other hand, fears about the fiscal burden on public services. Theoretically, both channels operate based on economic self-interest even though they rely on different assumptions on how natives react to immigrant worker inflows in relation to their skill-level, and thus, predict different attitudinal and preference based outcomes. Empirically, tests of these two approaches mainly have relied on survey data and have been mixed at best and plagued by methodological concerns (see for example Hainmueller and Hiscox 2010, 2015). Promisingly, survey experiments in the field (Hainmueller and Hiscox 2010, Helbling and Kriesi 2014) address these shortcomings by explicitly test and control for the natives as swell as the immigrants skill-level. Nevertheless, the argument whether antiimmigrant sentiments are contingent upon contextual factors still remains inconclusive. The labor market competition model 5

6 According to the labor market competition model, attitudes towards immigration are based on heterophyllic preferences in regard to the immigrants skill-level: Low-skilled natives prefer high-skilled immigrants, and high-skilled natives prefer immigrants with lower skills. Income effects are mainly hypostatized based on the fact that immigrant worker inflows shift the distribution of relative supplies of factors of production (these models are often referred to as factor-proportion analysis, see Hainmueller and Hicox 2010, 2015 for more details and Borjas 1999; Borjas, Freeman, and Katz 1996, 1997). This shift threatens natives earning capacities and employment opportunities. An inflow of low-skilled immigrants raises respectively the supply for low-skilled workers leading to a decrease of wages for native low-skilled worker and eventually to a higher unemployment rate and at the same time to an increase in earnings for higher skilled natives. In the same way, an influx of high skilled immigrant workers leads to lower wages for high skilled natives and real wages for low-skilled natives will rise. Empirical tests failed to unambiguously answer the question whether concerns about labor market competition motivate anti-immigrant sentiments: Whereas there is an (established) consensus that low-skilled natives in general oppose migration to a higher level than better educated natives (Hagendoorn and Nekuee 1999; Hjerm 2001; Scheve and Slaughter 2001; Heyder 2003; Mayda 2006), and in particular prefer high-skilled immigrants to low skilled, there is still uncertainty on the preferences of high-skilled natives. The uncertainty arises from the controversial discussion whether education level is linked to xenophobic sentiments, or whether the individual perception of economic threat drives opposition towards immigrants. Generally, several studies show a correlation between education level and anti-immigrant sentiments showing that better educated people are more willing to accept foreign workers. 6

7 According to these studies natives regardless of their skill-level always prefer high-skilled immigrants. Thus, the labor market competition model offers no explications for attitudes towards immigrants for high-skilled natives (Sniderman et al. 2004; Hainmueller and Hiscox 2010). In contrast, other scholars have suggested that this fact is not due to the higher education level, but is highly mediated through the individual perception of economic threat, which is lower among higher educated. O Connell (2011) argues that even if economic concerns are also relevant for people with high skills the higher specialization they gained protects them from direct competition with immigrants. Once exposed to a higher competition and thus to a higher level of economic threat high-skilled natives are more likely to oppose immigrants with highskills (Hello et al. 2006, Helperin et al. 2007, Facchini and Mayda 2012). However, evidence from experimental studies (Hainmueller and Hiscox 2010, Helbling and Kriesi 2014) suggests that better educated individuals are more in favor of immigrants in general and that the perceived economic threat is lower among highly educated even if exposed to a higher competition. In sum we test the classical prediction from the labor market model that natives oppose same-skilled immigrants. This is low-skilled natives prefer high skilled immigrants (Hypothesis 1a) and that high skilled natives prefer low-skilled immigrants (Hypothesis 1b). Fiscal burden of public services In general the welfare state model assumes that low-skilled immigrants impose a substantial net burden on public finance and challenges the welfare state, whereas highly 7

8 skilled immigrants are net contributors in terms of taxes. These may lead to a readjustment of the welfare system by either rising taxes or by reducing economic transfers such as welfare state services and benefits (Hanson 2005; Hanson et al. 2008; Facchini and Mayda 2009). Depending on the means chosen by the government to face the increased burden of public services, predictions about the acceptance of immigrant workers vary as high-income natives fear an increase in tax rates and low-income natives lower welfare benefits. In the first scenario, where tax rates are adjusted to face the increased burden on welfare state services high-income natives prefer high-skilled over low-skilled immigrants (more the low-income natives). Progressivity in taxes leads to a relatively higher increase in taxes for wealthier natives that might be required if the demand for welfare state benefits increases (Facchini and Mayda 2009). The second scenario foresees to keep tax rates fixed and rather adjust transfer rates of welfare state services. An increased demand for such services would lead to lower transfer rates. The fear for a reduction in welfare state benefits leads lower income natives to prefer high skilled to lower skilled immigrants (more than high-income natives). Empirically, research shows that these fears are contingent upon the states tax regimes: Hainmueller and Hiscox (2010), Hanson et al. (2007), and Facchini and Mayda (2009) exploit intra-state variation in the US and Helbling and Kriesi (2014) inter-cantonal variation in Switzerland. The observational studies by Hanson et al. (2007) and Fachchini and Meyda (2009) come to the same conclusion interpreting their results as evidence that fears about higher taxes among rich natives, linked to an increased use of welfare services by low-skilled immigrants, 8

9 lead to anti-immigrant sentiments. Nevertheless, this conclusion has to be drawn with caution as the surveys these analyses rely upon do not distinguish between immigrants skill level and implicitly assume that respondents have low-skilled migrants in mind when stating their attitudes towards migration in general. Two recent survey experiments address this shortcoming and test the welfare state model explicitly by experimentally varying immigrants skill-level. Hainmueller and Hiscox (2010) contrast the predictions of the standard fiscal burden model in which rich natives oppose low-skilled immigration more than poor natives do, and this difference grows larger in states with greater fiscal exposure in terms of immigrant access to public services. They find that rich and poor natives are consistently opposed to low-skilled immigration in general, and that rich natives are less opposed to low-skilled immigration in high-exposure states than in low-exposure states. Moreover, poorer natives are more opposed to low-skilled immigration in states with high fiscal exposure than in states with low fiscal exposure. This leads the authors to conclude that concerns about access to public services may contribute to anti-immigrant attitudes among poorer respondents. Helbing and Kriesi (2014) in contrast conclude from their results that the welfare state model only holds for wealthy natives in regions with low taxes and that poor natives hardly differentiate between low- and high-skilled immigrants. In a high exposure context, they do not find evidence for an income-dependent effect. They conclude that to the extent that context makes a difference in the Swiss case, it is the rich who are particularly context-sensitive (ibid: 605). The authors argue that this is because wealthier citizen tend to choose their residence with tax and spending considerations in mind. 9

10 We will test in general whether wealthier natives prefer high-skilled immigrants, as they reduce tax burdens (Hypothesis 2a) or whether poor natives prefer high-skilled immigrants, as they fear lower per capita welfare benefits (Hypothesis 2b). Moreover, we will put the theoretical argument to a comparative test assuming that wealthier natives have a preference for high over low-skilled immigrants in national-states with low fiscal exposure as they fear increasing taxes (Hypothesis 3a). Further, we assume that poorer natives are particularly opposed to low- in comparison with high-skilled immigrants in states with a high fiscal exposure, as they fear an erosion of the welfare state (Hypothesis 3b). In sum, previous evidence from observational studies clearly has some fault back in testing the proposed theoretical approaches; particularly by empirically neglecting the central economic mechanism that opposition to immigrants is linked to migrants skill-level. Survey experiments have addressed these concerns, but still remain inconclusive in regard to the impact of crucial contextual factors. Our approach allows us to test whether previous results are idiosyncratic to the single countries that were under scrutiny or whether the results are generalizable across different welfare state and tax regimes. Moreover, we put the welfare state model to a further test by exploiting an external shock in low-skilled migration inflows. Due to the refugee crisis we can validate our results for the welfare state model. The influx of refugees challenges the welfare state as by law refugees will not be net contributors in terms of taxes (i.e. they are not allowed to work), but rather impose a substantial net burden on public finances. In line with the welfare state model we expect both high as well as low-skilled natives will shift their preferences to high skilled immigrants. 10

11 Survey Experiment We use data from the seventh round of the European Social Survey (ESS) fielded in 21 European countries between August 2014 and December The ESS is a large-scale, crossnational project that conducts biennial face-to-face interviews in European countries. Individuals are selected by strict random probability methods at every stage of the sampling process so that each country sample is representative of all persons aged 15 and over resident within private households in each country. Response rates vary between 50% and 65% (with the exception of Germany that has a response rate of 31%). The country samples consisted of at least 1,400 and at most 3,000 respondents each. In the following analysis we use data for the following 15 countries: Austria, Belgium, Czech Republic, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Ireland, Netherlands, Norway, Slovenia, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland and the United Kingdom. 12 We restrict our analysis to those respondents that were born in the respective country. Our pooled data-set contains 24,951 cases. To account for different sampling strategies affecting individuals probability to be included in the survey and varying sample sizes we use the design weights provided by the ESS. 1 We exclude Hungary, Israel, Lithuania, Portugal and Poland from our analysis since data collection in these countries took place between April and December 2015 and thus overlaps with the beginning of the European refugee crisis. It is of course difficult to say when exactly the European refugee crisis began. One event that gained high media attention across all countries was when a migrant vessel with around 850 refugees capsized in the Mediterranean on April 19. On the next day (April 20, 2015) the European Commission proposed a 10-point plan to tackle the crisis. Three days later, on 23 April 2015, an emergency summit was held and EU heads of state agreed to triple the budget of Operation Triton to 120 million for Therefore we restricted our analysis to those interviews that took place before April The majority of interviews used in our analysis (75%) took place in 2014 well before the onset of the refugee crisis. 2 We also excluded Estonia from our analysis for two reasons: first, the Estonian dataset does not provide the income variable in brackets that allow to code income qunitiles. Second, the administration of the survey experiment seems not to have worked well in Estonia as the experimental groups differ quite substantially in size (see Appendix). 11

12 The experimental design of our study resembles the one used in previous research (Hainmueller and Hiscox 2010; Helbling and Kriesi 2014). Respondents were randomly assigned to two groups. 3 Respondents in the one group were asked about their attitude towards high skill migration (version 1), the other half of respondents about low skill migration (version 2): Version 1: Please tell me to what extent you think [country] should allow professionals from [other country] 4 to come to live in [country]? Version 2: Please tell me to what extent you think [country] should allow unskilled labourers from [other country] to come to live in [country]? Answer options for both versions include Allow many to come and live here, Allow some, Allow a few and Allow none. We recode answers so that high values mean support for immigration. In line with previous research we use educational attainment as a measure for respondents skill level (Hainmueller and Hiscox 2010, Helbling and Kriesi 2014, Hanson et al. 2007, Facchini and Mayda 2009; but see also Malhotra et al and Polavieja 2016 for a critique of this 3 Balance checks between the two groups provide evidence whether randomization has worked. As expected there are no significant differences between treatment and control group for 9 of the 10 covariates we are using. Only married or widowed respondents are slightly underrepresented in the treatment group. We cannot say whether these differences are systematically related to the administration of the treatment or whether they occurred by chance. In any case, treatment and control group are not completely balanced and we therefore include marital status as an additional control in our analyses (in addition to the standard socio-demographic variables age, gender and political ideology). 4 The ESS combined this experiment with a second experiment in which the origin countries of the migrants were also varied. The stock and the inflow of migrants but also the Human Development Index of origin countries were used to identify the most significant migrant origin countries inside Europe and outside of Europe. A list of the specific countries is found in the ESS7 Appendix A10. As our interest is mainly focused on the self-interest explanation and less on the impact of cultural distance, we do not make use of this experimental variation but rather include the information as a control. 12

13 approach). We use the European Social Survey version of ISCED that provides an indicator for the highest level of education a respondent has successfully completed that is comparable across countries. We distinguish between respondents with less than lower secondary education, lower secondary education, upper secondary and advanced vocational education, and tertiary education. Although education is widely used as a measure for skill level, concerns have been raised that it does not capture respondents specific skill levels that are key on the labour market to determine labour market competition (Polavieja 2016). As a consequence, respondents exposure to labour market competition with migrants might differ substantially within the same educational group and might depend more on the specific occupation or the industry someone is working in. As an indirect measure for labour market competition, education might only very roughly capture actual labor market threat (Malhotra et al. 2013). Moreover, education is correlated with many noneconomic attitudes that also motivate attitude towards migrants such as cultural tolerance, social trust and also social desirability bias in survey responses (Hello et al. 2006, Malhotra et al. 2013). We address these concerns with a series of robustness tests using (1) an alternative measure of skill level, (2) a direct measure of labor market competition (see also Malhotra et al. 2013, Hainmueller et al. 2015), and (3) two indirect measures of labor market competition (Polavieja 2016). First, we determined respondents skill level based on their occupation (10 major occupational groups of ISCO 08) and distinguish 4 different skill levels (see Appendix). These skill levels are not only based on the formal education but also take into account the 13

14 nature of the work performed in an occupation, the amount of informal on-the-job training and skill specialization (ILO 2012). Second, we rely on a direct measure of labor market competition with migrants. The ideal approach would be to move beyond indirect measures, such as education, and assess labor market competition more directly (Malhotra et al. 2013: 394). Even within the same skill-level group, exposure to labor market competition with migrants possibly varies substantially depending on the composition of migrants and their occupations. Moreover, the skill-set of migrants possibly varies between European countries. Therefore, we re-run our analysis with a direct measure of labour market competition. Based on the EU Labour Force Survey from 2013 (with approximately 2.4 million respondents) we calculate the share of foreign-born in each occupation (at an ISCO 3-digit level) for each of our 15 countries separately (LMC1). We code a respondent as being exposed to labor market competition with migrants if the share of foreignborn in the native s occupation is above the country s average number of foreign-born (LMC1 high). Moreover, we will examine a most likely case to find the LMC hypothesis confirmed by further targeting our analysis to respondents working in occupations where the share of foreign-born is 25 percentage points higher than the national average (LMC1 very high). Thirdly, we rely on two occupational characteristics that restrict or limit outside competition: skill specialization and monitoring costs (Polavieja 2016, Ortega and Polavieja 2012). Based on data from previous rounds of the ESS we calculate a measure of skill specialization and monitoring costs for each occupation (at the ISCO 3-digit level) in each country and match these indicators to the respondents in our dataset (see Polavieja 2016). Higher values on these 14

15 indicators for skill specialization (LMC2) and monitoring costs (LMC3) are related to more outside competition. For a test of the fiscal burden/welfare state model, previous research mainly relied on indirect measures of the fiscal impact of migrants. Countries with public social spending per capita above the mean and a high share of foreign-born are assumed to have a high fiscal burden (Hainmueller and Hiscox 2010, Helbling and Kriesi 2014). Such broad measures neglect that migrants access to social benefits and also their take-up rates of social services differ from country to country (Hanson et al. 2007). Moreover, migrants contribution to the financing of these services via taxes and/or social insurance contributions also depend on the institutional context and migrants labour market access. The ideal indicator for fiscal burden would directly measure migrants contributions via taxes and social security contributions in comparison to the benefits they actually receive. The International Migration Outlook 2013 (OECD 2013) provides a first-time comparative analysis of the fiscal impact of immigration in OECD countries, using high-quality data from the EU-SILC and the Swiss Household Panel Study. The net contribution (in EUR, PPP adjusted) is defined as the difference between contributions paid and the benefits natives and foreign-born receive respectively. Benefits are all government-funded transfers received by households, including family- and children-related allowances, social assistance payments, housing allowances, unemployment benefits, old-age benefits, survivors benefits, and pensions, sickness benefits, disability benefit, and education-related allowances and scholarships. Contributions are all transfers from households to the government, including taxes, applicable tax credits, and social security contributions. We use three different measures of fiscal exposure. Fiscal Exposure 1 only relies on the net contribution of foreign-born. 15

16 Countries in which foreign-born on average receive more benefits than they contribute in taxes and social security contributions are affected by high fiscal exposure to migration. These countries are the Czech Republic, Ireland, France, and Germany. Focusing only on the net contribution of foreign-born neglects that also the number of foreign-born affects the degree of fiscal exposure. Therefore we multiply the net contribution and the number of foreign-born to calculate our second measure for fiscal exposure (Fiscal Exposure 2). Countries with Fiscal Exposure 2 above the median are classified as having a high fiscal exposure. These countries are Czech Republic, Finland, France, Germany, Ireland and Sweden. Some authors (e.g., Rho and Tomz 2016) argue that the main reason why many studies fail to find self-interested economic preferences is because of respondents economic ignorance and their misperception of economic threats. To address these concerns we rely on subjective perceptions as a third measure of fiscal exposure (Fiscal Exposure 3). Respondents were asked whether they think that people who come to their country take out more than they put in or put in more than they take out. 5 We use these subjective perceptions of fiscal exposure to migration in order to calculate a subjective indicator of fiscal exposure for each country (i.e. the country specific mean). Again we use the median to split our sample of countries in high and low fiscal exposure countries. According to Fiscal Exposure 3, respondents in Austria, Belgium, the Czech Republic, Ireland, France, Spain and in the UK feel a high fiscal exposure to migration. 5 The exact question wording is: Most people who come to live here work and pay taxes. They also use health and welfare services. On balance, do you think people who come here take out more than they put in or put in more than they take out? The Answer scale ranges from 0 Generally take out more to 10 Generally put in more. 16

17 In order to get a measure for the position of each respondent in the income distribution, we use household s total net income and assign respondents to the respective country specific income quintiles. 6 In the analysis, we further control for respondents sex, age, employment status, political ideology and whether they are married. The controls are mainly included to make the results comparable to previous studies but also to capture the non-random assignment of the moderators (education and income) in our analysis. Attitudes towards highly skilled and low skilled migration in 15 European countries - results from European Social Survey Figure 1 depicts the distribution of preferences for high-skilled and low-skilled migrants. Respondents are more positively disposed towards highly skilled migrants, compared to lowskilled migrants. While around 70% would allow some or many high-skilled migrants, only 40% percent are in favor of allowing some or many low-skilled migrants. The strong opposition towards low-skilled migrants gets especially apparent when comparing the extreme categories. Only 10 % would allow many low-skilled migrants and 26% none. The numbers are practically reversed for high skilled migrants: 8% would allow none and 23% allow many. The disparity of those two unconditional distributions is much in line with the results from previous studies (Helbling and Kriesi 2014, Hainmueller and Hiscox 2010). Moreover, these patterns are found in every single country in our study (see Figure A1 in the Appendix). In the following we will test if 6 The reported household net income has a large number of non-reported and missing values. About 13 % of the total data is missing. 17

18 those distributions are conditioned as the labor market competition model or the fiscal burden perspective would suggest. [Figure 1 about here] Labour market competition [Figure 3 about here] 18

19 The central hypothesis that natives should oppose immigrants with similar skill levels but favour immigrants with different skill levels is not reflected in the empirical patterns. Figure 3 plots the percentage of respondents who would allow many migrants for different educational attainments. Two main patterns emerge and contrast the expectations. First, both low and high skilled respondents prefer high-skilled migration over low skilled migration. 37 % of the respondents with tertiary education would allow many high skilled migrants, but only 18 % would allow low-skilled workers. For respondent with lower secondary education the increase is from 4 % to above 12 %. Second, the support for both types of migration increases with respondents own skill level. Educated respondents are generally more open to migration independent of the skill level of migrants. While this can be explained with a variety of other economic and non-economic reasons, the unmet expectation of the labour market competition here is that highly educated should actually reduce their support for potentially high skilled labour competitors (Hypothesis 1b). The same disapproving patterns are observed in Hainmueller and Hiscox (2010) and Helbling and Kriesi s (2014) analysis. 19

20 Table 1 Support for highly Skilled and Low-Skilled Immigration - Test of the Labor Market Competition Model (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) In Favor of High Skilled Migration In Favor of Low Skilled Migration In Favor Migration In Favor Migration In Favor Migration labor force: in labor force: out Education ** (0.014) ** (0.014) ** (0.014) HS-Frame ** ** ** (0.017) (0.052) (0.029) HS-Frame X Education (0.018) < lower secondary ** (0.054) HS-Frame X < lower secondary (0.067) Lower Secondary ** (0.030) HS-Frame X lower secondary * (0.040) Tertiary ** ** (0.020) ** (0.078) ** (0.025) ** (0.021) ** (0.071) (0.027) (0.033) HS-Frame X tertiary (0.043) Controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Country FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes N Ordered Probit Coefficients shown with standard errors in parentheses. All models include a set of covariates (age, gender, marital status, political ideology and income) and country dummies. The reference category for the education dummies is 'upper secondary or vocational education'. * p < 0.05, ** p <

21 The significance of the effect can be analyzed more thoroughly relying on ordered probit models. This model specification takes the uneven spacing between answering categories into account and further allows controlling for other covariates, including the different levels between countries. Table 1 reports the estimates from seven model specifications. The full specification includes a direct effect of the frame (HS-frame is coded to be one for attitudes towards high-skilled migrants and zero if the respective question refers to low-skilled migrants), a direct effect of educational attainments and an interaction between the two. All models moreover include country dummies and additional controls. The results echo the patterns from the descriptive analysis. Model 1 and 2 in Table 1 show the effect of education for the subset of respondents who are asked to express their support for high and low skilled migration. Both reveal a similar positive effect size, implying that respondents with higher education are more positive disposed towards migrants of either type. Model 3 estimates the effect of the HS-frame on the attitude. The result underscores the more positive evaluation of high skilled migrant inflow. Model 4 includes the interaction effect between education and the HS-frame. Our results confirm previous research and show that higher educated people in general hold more positive attitudes towards migration and that support for high skilled migration is stronger than support for low-skilled migration. Most importantly, the expectation that the effect of the HS-Frame should change its sign the higher educated respondents are, is not confirmed. Instead, the effect is overall positive and appears not to be moderated by education: i.e. independent of the respondents skill level, all respondents prefer high-skilled over low skilled migration. When relaxing the linearity assumption of education and using the education dummies in Model 5, one of the interactions 21

22 is significant (a negative sign of the lower secondary education HS-Frame). That is, the support enhancing effect of the high skill frame is a bit smaller for those respondents with lower secondary education compared to the baseline, those with upper secondary or vocational training. One reason for why we do not find supportive evidence for the labour market competition model might be that some of the respondents in our analysis are not (directly) affected by labour market competition any more. Restricting the sample to those respondents in the labour force should thus provide a more likely case to find evidence supporting the labor competition model (see also Hainmueller and Hiscox 2007 or Mayda 2006 for a similar approach). In a final step of our analysis we thus split our sample and compare those in the laborforce (the employed, self-employed and unemployed respondents looking for a job) with respondents out of the laborforce (i.e. retired, homemaker, disabled and unemployed not looking for work). We would assume that the reaction to the HS-Frame depends on respondents skill-level for those in the labor force (Model 6) but not for those out of the labor force (Model 7). And indeed we find differences between the two models: the interaction effect of HS-frame and education is significant for those in the labour force (and not for those out of labour force). Nevertheless, against the prediction of the labour competition model, high-skilled natives in the work-force increase their support for inflows of high skilled labour more compared to low skilled natives. Natives do not oppose immigration of workers with similar skill levels. Instead, highly-educated workers seem to attach a stronger value to likewise skilled labour. [Figure 4 about here] 22

23 The results from the models can further be investigated using the predicted probabilities to allow many migrants from model specification 5. Figure 4 highlights again that independent of a respondent s skill-level, high skilled migrants are preferred over low-skilled migrants. For both the groups of migrants, the probability increases with a respondent s education. The increase is slightly stronger for highly educated respondents. The highest support for immigration is thus observed for highly educated respondents towards highly-skilled immigrants. A finding that clearly contradicts expectations derived from the labour market competition model. Robustness checks: Alternative measures of skill-level and increasing salience of labour market competition As already outlined, the educational level may not fully capture respondents specific skill level and thus, fails to unambiguously test the labour market competition model. Concerns have been raised that first, education as an indirect measure for labour market competition may only very roughly capture actual labor market threat (Malhotra et al. 2013); and that the specific occupation or the industry someone is working in are more determinant to 23

24 conceptionalize exposure to labour market competition with immigrants. Second, the concerns point to the fact that education is highly correlated with other (noneconomic) attitudes also driving sentiments toward immigration and immigrants (Hello et al. 2006, Malhotra et al. 2013). Taking these critiques into account, we propose a series of robustness checks. The results are reported in Table 2. Model 1 is included as the reference model from the analysis including education as measure for skill level and is identical with model 6 in table 1. Model 2 conceptionalizes respondents skill level based on the ISCO scheme into 4 groups (see table A2 in the Appendix). The results in model two are consistent with the findings we showed in model 1. If anything the coefficient for the interaction term loses leverage and is not significant at conventional levels. Again, against the theoretical assumptions of the labour competition model, high-skilled natives increase their support for inflows of high skilled labour more compared to low skilled natives. Thus, also with this alternative measure of skill-level we do not find (clear) evidence for the labour competition model. In the following we restrict our analysis to (theoretically) more likely cases to find support for the labour market competition model; or in other words, we test the model for settings where competition might be more salient as the occupation specific share of immigrants coworkers are higher (see Hainmueller Hiscox Margalit 2015, Malhotra et al. 2013). For model 3 and model 4 we include a direct measure of labour market competition based on the EU Labour Force Survey from We restricted our analysis to occupations that are characterized by high competition. We relied hereby on the share of foreign-born in each occupation to construct our LCM1 indicator: LCM1 high indicates whether the share of foreign-born exceeds 24

25 the country average in the respondents occupation and LCM1 very high if the share of foreignborn is 25 percentage points higher than the national average. Examples of these highcompetition occupations include, for instance, science and engineering professionals, teaching professionals, nursing and midwifery professionals, but also shop salespersons, domestic, hotel and office cleaners, or farmers. By restricting our analysis to these high-competition occupations substantially we find again a more positive evaluation of high skilled migrant inflow. Interestingly, even if not significant at conventional levels, we find as theoretically expected that the effect of the HS-Frame changes its sign the higher educated respondents are. A very similar pattern is revealed by model 5 and 6: Following Polavieja (2016) and Ortega and Polavieja (2012) we include two indirect measures of labor market competition taking two occupational characteristics into account that limit outside competition: skill specialization and monitoring costs. We calculated occupation specific levels of skill specialization and monitoring costs. Higher values for skill specialization (LMC2) and monitoring costs (LMC3) are related to more outside competition. To sum up, we can confirm previous research in stating that the predictions of the labour market competition model clearly are not homogenously applicable to the entire society. We find supportive evidence only for the most likely cases and only when including more sophisticated measures for respondents skill levels. [Table 2 about here] 25

26 Table 2 Support for Highly Skilled and Low-Skilled Immigration Test of the Labor Market Competition Model with different skill measures in in high risk segments of the labor market (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) Full sample (active) HS-Frame ** (0.078) Education ** (0.020) HS-Frame X Education ** Skill Level ** (0.067) (0.025) HS-Frame X Skill-Level (0.023) LMC1: high ** (0.096) LMC1: very high ** (0.220) LMC2: high ** (0.228) LMC3: high ** (0.147) (0.036) (0.077) (0.131) (0.052) Skill-Level ** (0.018) ** (0.028) ** (0.058) ** (0.101) ** (0.039) Controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Country FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes N Ordered Probit Coefficients shown with standard errors in parentheses. All models include a set of covariates (age, gender, marital status, political ideology and income) and country dummies. The reference catgeory for the education dummies is 'upper secondary or vocational education' * p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01 The Fiscal Burden of Public Services The fiscal burden model argument leads to two competing expectations how people with different incomes react to the HS-Frame. On the one hand, the standard model (with fixed welfare benefits) suggests that high income respondents should have a stronger preference for high-skilled over low-skilled migration than low income respondents because they fear the increased fiscal burden (see Helbing & Kriesi 2014 for empirical support). On the other hand, an alternative prediction (assuming taxes to be fixed) suggests that low income respondents should be more supportive of high-skilled migration as low income respondents fear cuts in their welfare benefits (see Hainmueller and Hiscox 2010 for empirical support). Moreover, 26

27 whereas Hainmueller & Hiscox (2010) show that the latter relationship mainly holds in a context of high fiscal exposure, Helbing & Kriesi (2014) find strongest support for a positive interaction effect in a context of low fiscal exposure. [Figure 5 about here] Our data rather supports the standard argument of the fiscal exposure perspective that tax concerns are the dominant driver of the income gradient in attitudes towards migrants. Consequently, high income respondents preference of highly over low skilled migration is stronger compared to the premium that low income respondents attach to high skilled migration. When plotting the share of respondents that support allowing many migrants, over the different frames, different income quintiles and for high and low fiscal burden context seperately, two major patterns emerge (Figure 5). With increasing income respondents take more positive stances towards immigration. Moreover, the distributions of attitudes towards highly skilled migration and low-skilled migration are similar in the low and high fiscal exposure 27

28 condition. Except for the outlier of high fiscal exposure and the fifth income quintile, the support across income groups and the reaction to the treatment seem to be rather unchanged for the two different sets of countries. It is exactly this observation; however, that offers support for the perspective that the tax concern of high income earners is even stronger in a context of high fiscal exposure: In a context of high fiscal exposure, 14% of respondents among the highest income quintile would allow many low skilled migrants to come and live in the country. The HS-Frame leads to a drastic increase of support to 43% among the highest income quintile (+ 29 percentage points). In a context of low fiscal exposure, the increase in support among high-income earners due to the high-skill frame is 18 percentage points (from 15% in the low skill frame to 33% in the high skill frame). Based on this observation, it is cumbersome to infer in how far the fiscal burden perspective applies here. The following therefore turns to the analysis of ordered probit models to validate the expected patterns. [Table 3 about here] Table 3 Support for Highly Skilled and Low-Skilled Immigration - test of the Fiscal Burden Model (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) Both Fiscal Exposure: High Fiscal Exposure: Low Both Fiscal Exposure: High Fiscal Exposure: Low HS-Frame ** (0.041) ** (0.077) ** (0.049) ** (0.034) ** (0.062) ** (0.041) income ** (0.010) (0.018) ** (0.011) HS-Frame X Income ** (0.012) * (0.023) (0.014) Q (0.040) (0.073) (0.047) HS-Frame X Q (0.053) (0.098) (0.063) Q

29 (0.037) (0.067) (0.044) HS-Frame X Q (0.050) (0.091) (0.059) Q (0.036) (0.064) (0.043) HS-Frame X Q (0.048) (0.087) * (0.057) Q (0.038) (0.071) ** (0.045) HS-Frame X Q * (0.051) ** (0.098) (0.060) Controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Country FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes N Standard errors in parentheses Ordered Probit Coefficients shown with standard errors in parentheses. All models include a set of covariates (age, gender, marital status, political ideology and education) and country dummies. The reference catgeory for the income dummies is 'Q3' * p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01 Table 3 reports the results of six different model specifications that include interaction effects between the HS-frame and the income of a respondent. All models again include additional controls, country dummies and respondents educational attainments. The first model, estimated on the full sample, shows a positive interaction effect between the HS-frame and the income. This implies that high income people prefer highly skilled migration over low skilled migration more than low income respondents. This finding stands in sharp contrast to the findings in Hainmueller and Hiscox (2010) but rather supports the finding of Helbing & Kriesi (2014). As the subsample analysis in model 2 and 3 reveals, this significant interaction is mostly driven by countries with high fiscal exposure where foreign-born net contribution is negative (i.e. where they actually receive on average more benefits than they pay in taxes). Relaxing the linearity assumption of income and including the income quintiles as dummies, shows further that this is mainly because of the highest income quintile (Model 4). Whereas the premium attached to high skilled migration does not vary over the lowest four income quintiles, the 29

Educated Preferences: Explaining Attitudes Toward Immigration In Europe. Jens Hainmueller and Michael J. Hiscox. Last revised: December 2005

Educated Preferences: Explaining Attitudes Toward Immigration In Europe. Jens Hainmueller and Michael J. Hiscox. Last revised: December 2005 Educated Preferences: Explaining Attitudes Toward Immigration In Jens Hainmueller and Michael J. Hiscox Last revised: December 2005 Supplement III: Detailed Results for Different Cutoff points of the Dependent

More information

Appendix to Sectoral Economies

Appendix to Sectoral Economies Appendix to Sectoral Economies Rafaela Dancygier and Michael Donnelly June 18, 2012 1. Details About the Sectoral Data used in this Article Table A1: Availability of NACE classifications by country of

More information

LABOUR-MARKET INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS IN OECD-COUNTRIES: WHAT EXPLANATIONS FIT THE DATA?

LABOUR-MARKET INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS IN OECD-COUNTRIES: WHAT EXPLANATIONS FIT THE DATA? LABOUR-MARKET INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS IN OECD-COUNTRIES: WHAT EXPLANATIONS FIT THE DATA? By Andreas Bergh (PhD) Associate Professor in Economics at Lund University and the Research Institute of Industrial

More information

Why Citizens Prefer High- Over Low-Skilled Immigrants. Labor Market Competition, Welfare State, and Deservingness

Why Citizens Prefer High- Over Low-Skilled Immigrants. Labor Market Competition, Welfare State, and Deservingness European Sociological Review VOLUME 30 NUMBER 5 2014 595 614 595 DOI:10.1093/esr/jcu061, available online at www.esr.oxfordjournals.org Online publication 10 June 2014 Why Citizens Prefer High- Over Low-Skilled

More information

Migration and the European Job Market Rapporto Europa 2016

Migration and the European Job Market Rapporto Europa 2016 Migration and the European Job Market Rapporto Europa 2016 1 Table of content Table of Content Output 11 Employment 11 Europena migration and the job market 63 Box 1. Estimates of VAR system for Labor

More information

Educated Ideology. Ankush Asri 1 June Presented in session: Personal circumstances and attitudes to immigration

Educated Ideology. Ankush Asri 1 June Presented in session: Personal circumstances and attitudes to immigration Educated Ideology Ankush Asri 1 June 2016 Presented in session: Personal circumstances and attitudes to immigration at the 3rd International ESS Conference, 13-15th July 2016, Lausanne, Switzerland Prepared

More information

Immigration Policy In The OECD: Why So Different?

Immigration Policy In The OECD: Why So Different? Immigration Policy In The OECD: Why So Different? Zachary Mahone and Filippo Rebessi August 25, 2013 Abstract Using cross country data from the OECD, we document that variation in immigration variables

More information

Supplementary Materials for

Supplementary Materials for www.sciencemag.org/cgi/content/full/science.aag2147/dc1 Supplementary Materials for How economic, humanitarian, and religious concerns shape European attitudes toward asylum seekers This PDF file includes

More information

Exposure to Immigrants and Voting on Immigration Policy: Evidence from Switzerland

Exposure to Immigrants and Voting on Immigration Policy: Evidence from Switzerland Exposure to Immigrants and Voting on Immigration Policy: Evidence from Switzerland Tobias Müller, Tuan Nguyen, Veronica Preotu University of Geneva The Swiss Experience with EU Market Access: Lessons for

More information

The United Kingdom in the European context top-line reflections from the European Social Survey

The United Kingdom in the European context top-line reflections from the European Social Survey The United Kingdom in the European context top-line reflections from the European Social Survey Rory Fitzgerald and Elissa Sibley 1 With the forthcoming referendum on Britain s membership of the European

More information

Table A.2 reports the complete set of estimates of equation (1). We distinguish between personal

Table A.2 reports the complete set of estimates of equation (1). We distinguish between personal Akay, Bargain and Zimmermann Online Appendix 40 A. Online Appendix A.1. Descriptive Statistics Figure A.1 about here Table A.1 about here A.2. Detailed SWB Estimates Table A.2 reports the complete set

More information

Public Attitudes toward Asylum Seekers across Europe

Public Attitudes toward Asylum Seekers across Europe Public Attitudes toward Asylum Seekers across Europe Dominik Hangartner ETH Zurich & London School of Economics with Kirk Bansak (Stanford) and Jens Hainmueller (Stanford) Dominik Hangartner (ETH Zurich

More information

Employment convergence of immigrants in the European Union

Employment convergence of immigrants in the European Union Employment convergence of immigrants in the European Union Szilvia Hamori HWWI Research Paper 3-20 by the HWWI Research Programme Migration Research Group Hamburg Institute of International Economics (HWWI)

More information

Data on gender pay gap by education level collected by UNECE

Data on gender pay gap by education level collected by UNECE United Nations Working paper 18 4 March 2014 Original: English Economic Commission for Europe Conference of European Statisticians Group of Experts on Gender Statistics Work Session on Gender Statistics

More information

The Foreign-born Population in the EU and its contribution to National Tax and Benefit Systems. Andrew Dabalen World Bank

The Foreign-born Population in the EU and its contribution to National Tax and Benefit Systems. Andrew Dabalen World Bank The Foreign-born Population in the EU and its contribution to National Tax and Benefit Systems Andrew Dabalen World Bank Motivation Disagreements on the benefits of immigrants Welfarist view migrants are

More information

Discussion comments on Immigration: trends and macroeconomic implications

Discussion comments on Immigration: trends and macroeconomic implications Discussion comments on Immigration: trends and macroeconomic implications William Wascher I would like to begin by thanking Bill White and his colleagues at the BIS for organising this conference in honour

More information

Russian Federation. OECD average. Portugal. United States. Estonia. New Zealand. Slovak Republic. Latvia. Poland

Russian Federation. OECD average. Portugal. United States. Estonia. New Zealand. Slovak Republic. Latvia. Poland INDICATOR TRANSITION FROM EDUCATION TO WORK: WHERE ARE TODAY S YOUTH? On average across OECD countries, 6 of -19 year-olds are neither employed nor in education or training (NEET), and this percentage

More information

Inclusion and Gender Equality in China

Inclusion and Gender Equality in China Inclusion and Gender Equality in China 12 June 2017 Disclaimer: The views expressed in this publication are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views and policies of the Asian Development

More information

CO3.6: Percentage of immigrant children and their educational outcomes

CO3.6: Percentage of immigrant children and their educational outcomes CO3.6: Percentage of immigrant children and their educational outcomes Definitions and methodology This indicator presents estimates of the proportion of children with immigrant background as well as their

More information

Employment Outlook 2017

Employment Outlook 2017 Annexes Chapter 3. How technology and globalisation are transforming the labour market Employment Outlook 2017 TABLE OF CONTENTS ANNEX 3.A3 ADDITIONAL EVIDENCE ON POLARISATION BY REGION... 1 ANNEX 3.A4

More information

Widening of Inequality in Japan: Its Implications

Widening of Inequality in Japan: Its Implications Widening of Inequality in Japan: Its Implications Jun Saito, Senior Research Fellow Japan Center for Economic Research December 11, 2017 Is inequality widening in Japan? Since the publication of Thomas

More information

Income inequality the overall (EU) perspective and the case of Swedish agriculture. Martin Nordin

Income inequality the overall (EU) perspective and the case of Swedish agriculture. Martin Nordin Income inequality the overall (EU) perspective and the case of Swedish agriculture Martin Nordin Background Fact: i) Income inequality has increased largely since the 1970s ii) High-skilled sectors and

More information

OECD/EU INDICATORS OF IMMIGRANT INTEGRATION: Findings and reflections

OECD/EU INDICATORS OF IMMIGRANT INTEGRATION: Findings and reflections OECD/EU INDICATORS OF IMMIGRANT INTEGRATION: Findings and reflections Meiji University, Tokyo 26 May 2016 Thomas Liebig International Migration Division Overview on the integration indicators Joint work

More information

People on the move: impact and integration of migrants in the European Union

People on the move: impact and integration of migrants in the European Union People on the move: impact and integration of migrants in the European Union Uuriintuya Batsaikhan, Zsolt Darvas and Inês Gonçalves Raposo Bruegel workshop: Better policies for people on the move 13 th

More information

Labour mobility within the EU - The impact of enlargement and the functioning. of the transitional arrangements

Labour mobility within the EU - The impact of enlargement and the functioning. of the transitional arrangements Labour mobility within the EU - The impact of enlargement and the functioning of the transitional arrangements Tatiana Fic, Dawn Holland and Paweł Paluchowski National Institute of Economic and Social

More information

REFUGEES AND ASYLUM SEEKERS, THE CRISIS IN EUROPE AND THE FUTURE OF POLICY

REFUGEES AND ASYLUM SEEKERS, THE CRISIS IN EUROPE AND THE FUTURE OF POLICY REFUGEES AND ASYLUM SEEKERS, THE CRISIS IN EUROPE AND THE FUTURE OF POLICY Tim Hatton University of Essex (UK) and Australian National University International Migration Institute 13 January 2016 Forced

More information

Between brain drain and brain gain post-2004 Polish migration experience

Between brain drain and brain gain post-2004 Polish migration experience Between brain drain and brain gain post-2004 Polish migration experience Paweł Kaczmarczyk Centre of Migration Research University of Warsaw Conference Fachkräftebedarf und Zuwanderung IAB, Nuernberg May

More information

Economics Of Migration

Economics Of Migration Department of Economics and Centre for Macroeconomics public lecture Economics Of Migration Professor Alan Manning Professor of Economics and Director of the Centre for Economic Performance s research

More information

How does education affect the economy?

How does education affect the economy? 2. THE ECONOMIC AND SOCIAL BENEFITS OF EDUCATION How does education affect the economy? More than half of the GDP growth in OECD countries over the past decade is related to labour income growth among

More information

ATTITUDES TOWARDS IMMIGRATION: ECONOMIC VERSUS CULTURAL DETERMINANTS. EVIDENCE FROM THE 2011 TRANSATLANTIC TRENDS IMMIGRATION DATA

ATTITUDES TOWARDS IMMIGRATION: ECONOMIC VERSUS CULTURAL DETERMINANTS. EVIDENCE FROM THE 2011 TRANSATLANTIC TRENDS IMMIGRATION DATA ATTITUDES TOWARDS IMMIGRATION: ECONOMIC VERSUS CULTURAL DETERMINANTS. EVIDENCE FROM THE 2011 TRANSATLANTIC TRENDS IMMIGRATION DATA A Thesis submitted to the Faculty of the Graduate School of Arts and Sciences

More information

Article (Accepted version) (Refereed)

Article (Accepted version) (Refereed) Alan S. Gerber, Gregory A. Huber, Daniel R. Biggers and David J. Hendry Self-interest, beliefs, and policy opinions: understanding how economic beliefs affect immigration policy preferences Article (Accepted

More information

CHANGES IN WORKING LIFE AND THE APPEAL OF RIGHT-WING POPULISM IN EUROPE

CHANGES IN WORKING LIFE AND THE APPEAL OF RIGHT-WING POPULISM IN EUROPE International Conference CHANGES IN WORKING LIFE AND THE APPEAL OF RIGHT-WING POPULISM IN EUROPE 17-18 June 2004, Vienna, Austria Xenophobe attitudes towards migrants and refugees in the enlarged European

More information

Explaining Cross-Country Differences in Attitudes Towards Immigration in the EU-15

Explaining Cross-Country Differences in Attitudes Towards Immigration in the EU-15 Soc Indic Res (2009) 91:371 390 DOI 10.1007/s11205-008-9341-5 Explaining Cross-Country Differences in Attitudes Towards Immigration in the EU-15 Nikolaj Malchow-Møller Æ Jakob Roland Munch Æ Sanne Schroll

More information

Settling In 2018 Main Indicators of Immigrant Integration

Settling In 2018 Main Indicators of Immigrant Integration Settling In 2018 Main Indicators of Immigrant Integration Settling In 2018 Main Indicators of Immigrant Integration Notes on Cyprus 1. Note by Turkey: The information in this document with reference to

More information

IMF research links declining labour share to weakened worker bargaining power. ACTU Economic Briefing Note, August 2018

IMF research links declining labour share to weakened worker bargaining power. ACTU Economic Briefing Note, August 2018 IMF research links declining labour share to weakened worker bargaining power ACTU Economic Briefing Note, August 2018 Authorised by S. McManus, ACTU, 365 Queen St, Melbourne 3000. ACTU D No. 172/2018

More information

Migration Challenge or Opportunity? - Introduction. 15th Munich Economic Summit

Migration Challenge or Opportunity? - Introduction. 15th Munich Economic Summit Migration Challenge or Opportunity? - Introduction 15th Munich Economic Summit Clemens Fuest 30 June 2016 What do you think are the two most important issues facing the EU at the moment? 40 35 2014 2015

More information

Special Eurobarometer 469. Report

Special Eurobarometer 469. Report Integration of immigrants in the European Union Survey requested by the European Commission, Directorate-General for Migration and Home Affairs and co-ordinated by the Directorate-General for Communication

More information

Migration and Labor Market Outcomes in Sending and Southern Receiving Countries

Migration and Labor Market Outcomes in Sending and Southern Receiving Countries Migration and Labor Market Outcomes in Sending and Southern Receiving Countries Giovanni Peri (UC Davis) Frederic Docquier (Universite Catholique de Louvain) Christian Dustmann (University College London)

More information

Volume 35, Issue 1. An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach

Volume 35, Issue 1. An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach Volume 35, Issue 1 An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach Brian Hibbs Indiana University South Bend Gihoon Hong Indiana University South Bend Abstract This

More information

The Rights of the Child. Analytical report

The Rights of the Child. Analytical report Flash Eurobarometer 273 The Gallup Organisation Analytical Report Flash EB N o 251 Public attitudes and perceptions in the euro area Flash Eurobarometer European Commission The Rights of the Child Analytical

More information

OECD ECONOMIC SURVEY OF LITHUANIA 2018 Promoting inclusive growth

OECD ECONOMIC SURVEY OF LITHUANIA 2018 Promoting inclusive growth OECD ECONOMIC SURVEY OF LITHUANIA 218 Promoting inclusive growth Vilnius, 5 July 218 http://www.oecd.org/eco/surveys/economic-survey-lithuania.htm @OECDeconomy @OECD 2 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 21 211

More information

Regional inequality and the impact of EU integration processes. Martin Heidenreich

Regional inequality and the impact of EU integration processes. Martin Heidenreich Regional inequality and the impact of EU integration processes Martin Heidenreich Table of Contents 1. Income inequality in the EU between and within nations 2. Patterns of regional inequality and its

More information

European Parliament Eurobarometer (EB79.5) ONE YEAR TO GO UNTIL THE 2014 EUROPEAN ELECTIONS Institutional Part ANALYTICAL OVERVIEW

European Parliament Eurobarometer (EB79.5) ONE YEAR TO GO UNTIL THE 2014 EUROPEAN ELECTIONS Institutional Part ANALYTICAL OVERVIEW Directorate-General for Communication Public Opinion Monitoring Unit Brussels, 21 August 2013. European Parliament Eurobarometer (EB79.5) ONE YEAR TO GO UNTIL THE 2014 EUROPEAN ELECTIONS Institutional

More information

Determinants of the Trade Balance in Industrialized Countries

Determinants of the Trade Balance in Industrialized Countries Determinants of the Trade Balance in Industrialized Countries Martin Falk FIW workshop foreign direct investment Wien, 16 Oktober 2008 Motivation large and persistent trade deficits USA, Greece, Portugal,

More information

Gender effects of the crisis on labor market in six European countries

Gender effects of the crisis on labor market in six European countries Gender effects of the crisis on labor market in six European countries Hélène Périvier Marion Cochard et Gérard Cornilleau OECD meeting, 06-20-2011 helene.perivier@ofce.sciences-po.fr marion.cochard@ofce.sciences-po.fr

More information

3-The effect of immigrants on the welfare state

3-The effect of immigrants on the welfare state 3-The effect of immigrants on the welfare state Political issues: Even if in the long run migrants finance the pay as you go pension system, migrants may be very costly for the destination economy because

More information

Majorities attitudes towards minorities in European Union Member States

Majorities attitudes towards minorities in European Union Member States Majorities attitudes towards minorities in European Union Member States Results from the Standard Eurobarometers 1997-2000-2003 Report 2 for the European Monitoring Centre on Racism and Xenophobia Ref.

More information

USING, DEVELOPING, AND ACTIVATING THE SKILLS OF IMMIGRANTS AND THEIR CHILDREN

USING, DEVELOPING, AND ACTIVATING THE SKILLS OF IMMIGRANTS AND THEIR CHILDREN USING, DEVELOPING, AND ACTIVATING THE SKILLS OF IMMIGRANTS AND THEIR CHILDREN 29 October 2015 Thomas Liebig International Migration Division Directorate for Employment, Labour and Social Affairs, OECD

More information

The effect of migration in the destination country:

The effect of migration in the destination country: The effect of migration in the destination country: This topic can be broken down into several issues: 1-the effect of immigrants on the aggregate economy 2-the effect of immigrants on the destination

More information

Special Eurobarometer 461. Report. Designing Europe s future:

Special Eurobarometer 461. Report. Designing Europe s future: Designing Europe s future: Trust in institutions Globalisation Support for the euro, opinions about free trade and solidarity Fieldwork Survey requested by the European Commission, Directorate-General

More information

Main findings of the joint EC/OECD seminar on Naturalisation and the Socio-economic Integration of Immigrants and their Children

Main findings of the joint EC/OECD seminar on Naturalisation and the Socio-economic Integration of Immigrants and their Children MAIN FINDINGS 15 Main findings of the joint EC/OECD seminar on Naturalisation and the Socio-economic Integration of Immigrants and their Children Introduction Thomas Liebig, OECD Main findings of the joint

More information

Estimating the foreign-born population on a current basis. Georges Lemaitre and Cécile Thoreau

Estimating the foreign-born population on a current basis. Georges Lemaitre and Cécile Thoreau Estimating the foreign-born population on a current basis Georges Lemaitre and Cécile Thoreau Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development December 26 1 Introduction For many OECD countries,

More information

SPANISH NATIONAL YOUTH GUARANTEE IMPLEMENTATION PLAN ANNEX. CONTEXT

SPANISH NATIONAL YOUTH GUARANTEE IMPLEMENTATION PLAN ANNEX. CONTEXT 2013 SPANISH NATIONAL YOUTH 2013 GUARANTEE IMPLEMENTATION PLAN ANNEX. CONTEXT 2 Annex. Context Contents I. Introduction 3 II. The labour context for young people 4 III. Main causes of the labour situation

More information

The Pull Factors of Female Immigration

The Pull Factors of Female Immigration Martin 1 The Pull Factors of Female Immigration Julie Martin Abstract What are the pull factors of immigration into OECD countries? Does it differ by gender? I argue that different types of social spending

More information

Supplementary information for the article:

Supplementary information for the article: Supplementary information for the article: Happy moves? Assessing the link between life satisfaction and emigration intentions Artjoms Ivlevs Contents 1. Summary statistics of variables p. 2 2. Country

More information

Second EU Immigrants and Minorities, Integration and Discrimination Survey: Main results

Second EU Immigrants and Minorities, Integration and Discrimination Survey: Main results Second EU Immigrants and Minorities, Integration and Discrimination Survey: Main results Questions & Answers on the survey methodology This is a brief overview of how the Agency s Second European Union

More information

Migration in employment, social and equal opportunities policies

Migration in employment, social and equal opportunities policies Health and Migration Advisory Group Luxembourg, February 25-26, 2008 Migration in employment, social and equal opportunities policies Constantinos Fotakis DG Employment. Social Affairs and Equal Opportunities

More information

INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS INTO THE LABOUR MARKET IN EU AND OECD COUNTRIES

INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS INTO THE LABOUR MARKET IN EU AND OECD COUNTRIES INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS INTO THE LABOUR MARKET IN EU AND OECD COUNTRIES AN OVERVIEW Brussels, 25 June 2015 Thomas Liebig International Migration Division Directorate for Employment, Labour and Social

More information

Benefit levels and US immigrants welfare receipts

Benefit levels and US immigrants welfare receipts 1 Benefit levels and US immigrants welfare receipts 1970 1990 by Joakim Ruist Department of Economics University of Gothenburg Box 640 40530 Gothenburg, Sweden joakim.ruist@economics.gu.se telephone: +46

More information

IPES 2012 RAISE OR RESIST? Explaining Barriers to Temporary Migration during the Global Recession DAVID T. HSU

IPES 2012 RAISE OR RESIST? Explaining Barriers to Temporary Migration during the Global Recession DAVID T. HSU IPES 2012 RAISE OR RESIST? Explaining Barriers to Temporary Migration during the Global Recession DAVID T. HSU Browne Center for International Politics University of Pennsylvania QUESTION What explains

More information

ISBN International Migration Outlook Sopemi 2007 Edition OECD Introduction

ISBN International Migration Outlook Sopemi 2007 Edition OECD Introduction ISBN 978-92-64-03285-9 International Migration Outlook Sopemi 2007 Edition OECD 2007 Introduction 21 2007 Edition of International Migration Outlook shows an increase in migration flows to the OECD International

More information

Europe and the US: Preferences for Redistribution

Europe and the US: Preferences for Redistribution Europe and the US: Preferences for Redistribution Peter Haan J. W. Goethe Universität Summer term, 2010 Peter Haan (J. W. Goethe Universität) Europe and the US: Preferences for Redistribution Summer term,

More information

INTERNAL SECURITY. Publication: November 2011

INTERNAL SECURITY. Publication: November 2011 Special Eurobarometer 371 European Commission INTERNAL SECURITY REPORT Special Eurobarometer 371 / Wave TNS opinion & social Fieldwork: June 2011 Publication: November 2011 This survey has been requested

More information

ISSUE BRIEF: U.S. Immigration Priorities in a Global Context

ISSUE BRIEF: U.S. Immigration Priorities in a Global Context Immigration Task Force ISSUE BRIEF: U.S. Immigration Priorities in a Global Context JUNE 2013 As a share of total immigrants in 2011, the United States led a 24-nation sample in familybased immigration

More information

Europeans support a proportional allocation of asylum seekers

Europeans support a proportional allocation of asylum seekers In the format provided by the authors and unedited. SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION VOLUME: 1 ARTICLE NUMBER: 0133 Europeans support a proportional allocation of asylum seekers Kirk Bansak, 1,2 Jens Hainmueller,

More information

NERO INTEGRATION OF REFUGEES (NORDIC COUNTRIES) Emily Farchy, ELS/IMD

NERO INTEGRATION OF REFUGEES (NORDIC COUNTRIES) Emily Farchy, ELS/IMD NERO INTEGRATION OF REFUGEES (NORDIC COUNTRIES) Emily Farchy, ELS/IMD Sweden Netherlands Denmark United Kingdom Belgium France Austria Ireland Canada Norway Germany Spain Switzerland Portugal Luxembourg

More information

Work and income SLFS 2016 in brief. The Swiss Labour Force Survey. Neuchâtel 2017

Work and income SLFS 2016 in brief. The Swiss Labour Force Survey. Neuchâtel 2017 03 Work and income 363-1600 SLFS 2016 in brief The Swiss Labour Force Survey Neuchâtel 2017 Published by: Information: Editors: Series: Topic : Original text: Translation: Layout: Graphics: Front page:

More information

Do immigrants take or create residents jobs? Quasi-experimental evidence from Switzerland

Do immigrants take or create residents jobs? Quasi-experimental evidence from Switzerland Do immigrants take or create residents jobs? Quasi-experimental evidence from Switzerland Michael Siegenthaler and Christoph Basten KOF, ETH Zurich January 2014 January 2014 1 Introduction Introduction:

More information

Differences in National IQs behind the Eurozone Debt Crisis?

Differences in National IQs behind the Eurozone Debt Crisis? 3 Differences in National IQs behind the Eurozone Debt Crisis? Tatu Vanhanen * Department of Political Science, University of Helsinki The purpose of this article is to explore the causes of the European

More information

Special Eurobarometer 464b. Report

Special Eurobarometer 464b. Report Europeans attitudes towards security Survey requested by the European Commission, Directorate-General for Migration and Home Affairs and co-ordinated by the Directorate-General for Communication This document

More information

Labour market integration of low skilled migrants in Europe: Economic impact. Gudrun Biffl

Labour market integration of low skilled migrants in Europe: Economic impact. Gudrun Biffl Labour market integration of low skilled migrants in Europe: Economic impact Gudrun Biffl Contribution to the Conference on Managing Migration and Integration: Europe & the US University of California-Berkeley,

More information

Standard Note: SN/SG/6077 Last updated: 25 April 2014 Author: Oliver Hawkins Section Social and General Statistics

Standard Note: SN/SG/6077 Last updated: 25 April 2014 Author: Oliver Hawkins Section Social and General Statistics Migration Statistics Standard Note: SN/SG/6077 Last updated: 25 April 2014 Author: Oliver Hawkins Section Social and General Statistics The number of people migrating to the UK has been greater than the

More information

REFUGEES AND ASYLUM SEEKERS, THE CRISIS IN EUROPE AND THE FUTURE OF POLICY

REFUGEES AND ASYLUM SEEKERS, THE CRISIS IN EUROPE AND THE FUTURE OF POLICY REFUGEES AND ASYLUM SEEKERS, THE CRISIS IN EUROPE AND THE FUTURE OF POLICY Tim Hatton University of Essex (UK) and Australian National University Noise from America Firenze 11-12 June 2016 Introduction

More information

BRAND. Cross-national evidence on the relationship between education and attitudes towards immigrants: Past initiatives and.

BRAND. Cross-national evidence on the relationship between education and attitudes towards immigrants: Past initiatives and. Cross-national evidence on the relationship between education and attitudes towards immigrants: Past initiatives and future OECD directions EMPLOYER BRAND Playbook Promoting Tolerance: Can education do

More information

The Application of Quotas in EU Member States as a measure for managing labour migration from third countries

The Application of Quotas in EU Member States as a measure for managing labour migration from third countries The Application of Quotas in EU Member States as a measure for managing labour migration from third countries 1. INTRODUCTION This short EMN Inform 1 provides information on the use of quotas 2 by Member

More information

Economic Growth, Foreign Investments and Economic Freedom: A Case of Transition Economy Kaja Lutsoja

Economic Growth, Foreign Investments and Economic Freedom: A Case of Transition Economy Kaja Lutsoja Economic Growth, Foreign Investments and Economic Freedom: A Case of Transition Economy Kaja Lutsoja Tallinn School of Economics and Business Administration of Tallinn University of Technology The main

More information

International Migration and the Welfare State. Prof. Panu Poutvaara Ifo Institute and University of Munich

International Migration and the Welfare State. Prof. Panu Poutvaara Ifo Institute and University of Munich International Migration and the Welfare State Prof. Panu Poutvaara Ifo Institute and University of Munich 1. Introduction During the second half of 20 th century, Europe changed from being primarily origin

More information

Special Eurobarometer 471. Summary

Special Eurobarometer 471. Summary Fairness, inequality and intergenerational mobility Survey requested by the European Commission, Joint Research Centre and co-ordinated by the Directorate-General for Communication This document does not

More information

From Individual Attitudes towards Migrants to Migration Policy Outcomes: Theory and Evidence

From Individual Attitudes towards Migrants to Migration Policy Outcomes: Theory and Evidence DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 3512 From Individual Attitudes towards Migrants to Migration Policy Outcomes: Theory and Evidence Giovanni Facchini Anna Maria Mayda May 2008 Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft

More information

Fafo-Conference One year after Oslo, 26 th of May, Migration, Co-ordination Failures and Eastern Enlargement

Fafo-Conference One year after Oslo, 26 th of May, Migration, Co-ordination Failures and Eastern Enlargement Fafo-Conference One year after Oslo, 26 th of May, 2005 Migration, Co-ordination Failures and Eastern Enlargement Herbert Brücker DIW Berlin und IZA, Bonn Economic theory: large potential benefits associated

More information

The European emergency number 112

The European emergency number 112 Flash Eurobarometer The European emergency number 112 REPORT Fieldwork: December 2011 Publication: February 2012 Flash Eurobarometer TNS political & social This survey has been requested by the Directorate-General

More information

Migrant population of the UK

Migrant population of the UK BRIEFING PAPER Number CBP8070, 3 August 2017 Migrant population of the UK By Vyara Apostolova & Oliver Hawkins Contents: 1. Who counts as a migrant? 2. Migrant population in the UK 3. Migrant population

More information

RESEARCH NOTE The effect of public opinion on social policy generosity

RESEARCH NOTE The effect of public opinion on social policy generosity Socio-Economic Review (2009) 7, 727 740 Advance Access publication June 28, 2009 doi:10.1093/ser/mwp014 RESEARCH NOTE The effect of public opinion on social policy generosity Lane Kenworthy * Department

More information

The Myths and Veracities of the European Migration Challenge

The Myths and Veracities of the European Migration Challenge The Myths and Veracities of the European Migration Challenge Martin Kahanec Central European University (CEU); EU BA; CELSI and IZA Graz, 4-5/4/2016 Migrants/refugees as potential workers Many perspectives

More information

The Changing Relationship between Fertility and Economic Development: Evidence from 256 Sub-National European Regions Between 1996 to 2010

The Changing Relationship between Fertility and Economic Development: Evidence from 256 Sub-National European Regions Between 1996 to 2010 The Changing Relationship between Fertility and Economic Development: Evidence from 256 Sub-National European Regions Between 996 to 2 Authors: Jonathan Fox, Freie Universitaet; Sebastian Klüsener MPIDR;

More information

Improving the measurement of the regional and urban dimension of well-being

Improving the measurement of the regional and urban dimension of well-being Improving the measurement of the regional and urban dimension of well-being 4 th OECD World Forum, lunchtime seminar 19 October 2012 Walter Radermacher, Chief Statistician of the EU Walter Radermacher

More information

3.3 DETERMINANTS OF THE CULTURAL INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS

3.3 DETERMINANTS OF THE CULTURAL INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS 1 Duleep (2015) gives a general overview of economic assimilation. Two classic articles in the United States are Chiswick (1978) and Borjas (1987). Eckstein Weiss (2004) studies the integration of immigrants

More information

Migration, Mobility and Integration in the European Labour Market. Lorenzo Corsini

Migration, Mobility and Integration in the European Labour Market. Lorenzo Corsini Migration, Mobility and Integration in the European Labour Market Lorenzo Corsini Content of the lecture We provide some insight on -The degree of differentials on some key labourmarket variables across

More information

Georg Lutz, Nicolas Pekari, Marina Shkapina. CSES Module 5 pre-test report, Switzerland

Georg Lutz, Nicolas Pekari, Marina Shkapina. CSES Module 5 pre-test report, Switzerland Georg Lutz, Nicolas Pekari, Marina Shkapina CSES Module 5 pre-test report, Switzerland Lausanne, 8.31.2016 1 Table of Contents 1 Introduction 3 1.1 Methodology 3 2 Distribution of key variables 7 2.1 Attitudes

More information

DEGREE PLUS DO WE NEED MIGRATION?

DEGREE PLUS DO WE NEED MIGRATION? DEGREE PLUS DO WE NEED MIGRATION? ROBERT SUBAN ROBERT SUBAN Department of Banking & Finance University of Malta Lecture Outline What is migration? Different forms of migration? How do we measure migration?

More information

EARLY SCHOOL LEAVERS

EARLY SCHOOL LEAVERS EUROPEAN SEMESTER THEMATIC FACTSHEET EARLY SCHOOL LEAVERS 1. INTRODUCTION Early school leaving 1 is an obstacle to economic growth and employment. It hampers productivity and competitiveness, and fuels

More information

Does social comparison affect immigrants subjective well-being?

Does social comparison affect immigrants subjective well-being? Does social comparison affect immigrants subjective well-being? Manuela Stranges, Alessandra Venturini, Daniele Vignoli Abstract Despite the growing number of papers which concentrate on economic and social

More information

Special Eurobarometer 467. Report. Future of Europe. Social issues

Special Eurobarometer 467. Report. Future of Europe. Social issues Future of Europe Social issues Fieldwork Publication November 2017 Survey requested by the European Commission, Directorate-General for Communication and co-ordinated by the Directorate- General for Communication

More information

MODELLING EXISTING SURVEY DATA FULL TECHNICAL REPORT OF PIDOP WORK PACKAGE 5

MODELLING EXISTING SURVEY DATA FULL TECHNICAL REPORT OF PIDOP WORK PACKAGE 5 MODELLING EXISTING SURVEY DATA FULL TECHNICAL REPORT OF PIDOP WORK PACKAGE 5 Ian Brunton-Smith Department of Sociology, University of Surrey, UK 2011 The research reported in this document was supported

More information

The application of quotas in EU Member States as a measure for managing labour migration from third countries

The application of quotas in EU Member States as a measure for managing labour migration from third countries The application of quotas in EU Member States as a measure for managing labour migration from third countries 1. INTRODUCTION This EMN Inform 1 provides information on the use of quotas 2 by Member States

More information

OECD SKILLS STRATEGY FLANDERS DIAGNOSTIC WORKSHOP

OECD SKILLS STRATEGY FLANDERS DIAGNOSTIC WORKSHOP OECD SKILLS STRATEGY FLANDERS DIAGNOSTIC WORKSHOP Dirk Van Damme Head of Division OECD Centre for Skills Education and Skills Directorate 15 May 218 Use Pigeonhole for your questions 1 WHY DO SKILLS MATTER?

More information

Special Eurobarometer 470. Summary. Corruption

Special Eurobarometer 470. Summary. Corruption Corruption Survey requested by the European Commission, Directorate-General for Migration and Home Affairs and co-ordinated by the Directorate-General for Communication This document does not represent

More information

Migration Policy and Welfare State in Europe

Migration Policy and Welfare State in Europe Migration Policy and Welfare State in Europe Assaf Razin 1 and Jackline Wahba 2 Immigration and the Welfare State Debate Public debate on immigration has increasingly focused on the welfare state amid

More information

European Parliament Elections: Turnout trends,

European Parliament Elections: Turnout trends, European Parliament Elections: Turnout trends, 1979-2009 Standard Note: SN06865 Last updated: 03 April 2014 Author: Section Steven Ayres Social & General Statistics Section As time has passed and the EU

More information

Labour market resilience in Europe

Labour market resilience in Europe Labour market resilience in Europe INSPIRES Benchmark Report Version : 1 6 214 Erasmus University Rotterdam Bigos, M., Qaran, W., Fenger, M., Koster, F., & Veen, R. van der Table of contents 1. List of

More information