ELECTORAL RULES AS CONSTRAINTS ON CORRUPTION Jana Kunicova and Susan Rose-Ackerman *

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "ELECTORAL RULES AS CONSTRAINTS ON CORRUPTION Jana Kunicova and Susan Rose-Ackerman *"

Transcription

1 ELECTORAL RULES AS CONSTRAINTS ON CORRUPTION Jana Kunicova and Susan Rose-Ackerman * Department of Political Science Yale University First Draft: September 5, 2001 This Version: June 24, 2002 Abstract This paper investigates how electoral rules influence political corruption. We show that closed-list and open-list proportional representation (PR) systems are more susceptible to corruption relative to plurality systems. We argue that this effect is due to differences in the locus of rents between PR and plurality systems, and to monitoring difficulties under PR. Monitoring is limited under PR because (1) such systems produce districts with large numbers of voters producing severe collective action problems for voters, and (2) under PR opposition parties face incentive problems in monitoring corrupt incumbents. In addition, in CLPR systems the link between re-election and performance in office is weaker than in plurality or OLPR systems, making them especially susceptible to corruption. We also examine interaction effects between electoral rules and presidentialism. We empirically test our main predictions, interaction effects, and the proposed causal mechanism on a crosssection of up to 99 countries, controlling for economic, political, and social background factors. The empirical findings strongly support our theoretical hypothesis that closed-list PR systems, especially together with presidentialism, are associated with higher levels of corruption. This result is robust to different model specifications and to the deletion of influential observations. * We would like to thank José Antonio Cheibub, Rafael DiTella, Aaron Edlin, Eduardo Engel, Philip Levy, Fiona McGillivray, Jonathan Rodden, Frances Rosenbluth, Matthew Shugart, Peter Siavelis, Alastair Smith, and Georg Vanberg for helpful discussions and comments on earlier drafts, and Phil Keefer and Jessica Seddon for sharing their data. We also benefited from comments received in seminar presentations at Yale, Berkeley Law School, the Public Choice Society, the Midwest Political Science Association, and the Society for Comparative Research. All remaining errors are ours. Rose-Ackerman s contribution was partially supported by the Center for Advanced Study in the Behavioral Sciences. Contact Information: jana.kunicova@yale.edu; susan.roseackerman@yale.edu.

2 ELECTORAL RULES AS CONSTRAINTS ON CORRUPTION 1. Introduction Elections serve two functions in representative democracies. First, they select political actors who enact public policies in light of constituents preferences. Second, they permit citizens to hold their representatives accountable and to punish them if they are corrupt or self-serving. In other words, elections provide both incentives for politicians to enact certain kinds of policies and constraints on politicians malfeasance. In this paper, we focus on the second of these two functions and investigate how different electoral systems constrain political corruption, holding constant other political, economic, and social background factors. We study three stylized categories of electoral rules: plurality/majoritarian systems with single-member districts, and two kinds of proportional representation (PR) systems: closed- and open-list. Under a closed list system, party leaders rank candidates, and voters only cast votes for parties. Under an open list, voters both select a party and rank candidates given the party s selection of candidates. The control of political corruption depends both on the locus of corrupt rents and on whether any actors have both the incentive and the ability to monitor those politicians with access to rents. We argue that PLURALITY and PR systems differ in that under PLURALITY rule more rentseeking opportunities are available to individual legislators, compared to the leadership, and that under PLURALITY, the monitoring of these rent seekers is likely to be more stringent than the monitoring of rent seekers under PR. There are three reasons for this. First, PLURALITY rule produces districts with relatively small populations where voters face less severe collective action problems in monitoring the incumbents than in the large, often national, districts in PR systems. Second, the opposition has greater incentives to uncover corruption in PLURALITY systems. If the conditions of Duverger s law hold, PLURALITY rule leads to only one major party in opposition in each district. This eliminates the free-rider problems associated with exposing corrupt incumbents in systems with multiple opposition parties. Furthermore, opposition parties in PR systems may be reluctant to expose incumbents if they think that they may be asked to form a government with them in the next political round. Third, in PLURALITY systems the locus of monitoring effort at the district level is more effectively targeted toward the potentially corrupt than in PR systems where the leadership controls the rents and is difficult to monitor. As far as the difference between CLPR and OLPR is concerned, we expect CLPR systems to be more corrupt because they are more opaque. If voters cast votes for party lists, the link between re-election and performing well in office is weakened in comparison to OLPR and PLURALITY systems, where voters select individual candidates. 2

3 Although our primary focus is on the methods by which the legislature is chosen, we also recognize that a complete model should include other institutional features of a political system such as presidentialism/parliamentarism, federalism, bi-cameralism, and the strength of parties. We examine the interaction between presidentialism and electoral rules, and include other institutional variables, most notably federalism, as controls in our empirical work. Our paper stands at the intersection of two broad literatures: one examining electoral rules and their effects, and the other attempting to explain political corruption. Electoral rules have been shown to affect the incentives of political actors to organize and hence the number of political parties (Duverger 1954, Rae 1971, Riker 1982, Powell 1982, Taagepera & Shugart 1989, Lijphart 1990, 1994; ), as well as the way in which parties and politicians compete for votes, producing personalistic versus party-centered systems (Carey & Shugart 1995 Shugart 1999, Myerson 1993a, Gaviria et al. 1999, Seddon et al. 2001, Panizza 2001). Theoretical arguments conclude that, under plausible conditions, PLURALITY rule results in two major parties and PR produces several competing parties (for qualified arguments, see Taagepera & Grofman 1985, Ordeshook & Shvetsova 1994, and Neto & Cox 1997). In addition, electoral rules are believed to affect party discipline: where politicians have incentives to cultivate a personal vote, party discipline will be low ( Carey & Shugart 1995, Ames 1995, Reed 1994, Bowler et al. 1999). Our paper builds directly on these stepping stones. We argue that electoral rules affect the incentives and ability of voters, opposition politicians, and intra-party actors to organize and monitor the corruption of incumbents. The result critically depends on the process of nominating candidates, the number of parties in the opposition, and on party discipline-- factors that are, to some extent, the by-products of electoral rules. In addition to the large and developed literature on the effects of electoral rules, there exists a new and growing literature that addresses the relationship between political institutions and corruption. Our paper makes several contributions to this developing field. First, it explicitly distinguishes between criminal corruption (embezzlement of funds, bribery) and pork-barrel spending (perfectly legal activity), which tends to be conflated elsewhere (Geddes 1994, Rasmussen and Ramseyer 1994, Bicchieri 1995, Bueno de Mesquita et al. 1999). This distinction is crucial because electoral systems that constrain corruption may encourage pork-barrel spending, and vice versa. Second, on the theoretical side, our causal mechanism linking electoral rules and corruption is different from existing models (Myerson 1993, Holmstrom 1982, Persson and Tabellini 2000, ch. 9). Those models focus on district magnitude or party lists as the driving forces determining the impact of electoral rules on corruption; 1 we emphasize the effect of district size (that is, voters per district, as opposed to the number of representatives elected per district), and the number of parties in opposition. Third, there is only one other study that has attempted to assess the link between electoral rules and corruption empirically (Persson, Tabellini, and Trebbi 2001). Although we 3

4 confirm their basic finding that proportional elections are associated with higher corruption levels, we test a different causal mechanism. Most importantly, we are more attentive to other institutional details that were assumed away by Persson, Tabellini, and Trebbi (2001). In addition to differentiating between closed- and open-list PR, we control for the effects of federalism and presidentialism because they have been shown to influence corruption in two recent papers (Treisman 2000 and Kunicova 2001, respectively). We also explore the interaction effects of electoral rules and presidentialism. Finally, we use a more comprehensive and up-to-date dataset covering up to 99 democracies and test the robustness of our results to alternative measures of corruption, different specifications, and to deleting influential observations. The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. Section 2 discusses the importance of distinguishing between corruption and pork-barrel spending. Section 3 presents our basic theoretical argument about the link between electoral rules and corruption. Section 4 adds presidentialism to this framework. Section 5 states our hypotheses, and Section 6 describes the data and methods used to test them. Section 7 presents the results of the regression analysis. Section 8 concludes. 2. Corruption versus Pork-Barrel Spending A standard definition of corruption is misuse of public office for private gain (cf. Bardhan 1997; Rose-Ackerman 1999; Treisman 2000; Sandholtz and Koetzle 2000; Lambsdorff 1998). Yet, some authors broaden this definition to include rent extraction by public officials, which tends to subsume other activities of politicians, from direct embezzlement of funds for private gain through paying off political supporters to maximize their chances of re-election. An example of such work is Bueno de Mesquita et al. (1999). The authors formulate and empirically test a formal model in which politicians stay in office by offering public goods that benefit everyone and private goods that benefit only their core supporters. The latter is considered corruption and is influenced by institutions in both autocracies and democracies. For other arguments conflating corruption and targeted public spending, see Geddes (1994), Rasmussen & Ramseyer (1994), and Bicchieri (1995). We believe that it is analytically wrong to conflate corruption, an illegal activity, and politically targeted public spending, a legal activity. This is especially ill-advised when analyzing the impact of electoral rules on corruption. Some electoral systems, although enabling voters to monitor legislators behavior, also give incentives to politicians to use a legitimate means of political competition provision of narrowly targeted public services, or so-called pork-barrel projects. These are the dual issues of incentives and constraints that we discuss in this and the following section. First, electoral rules differ in the incentives they give to politicians to offer broad-based public goods or narrowly focused pork-barrel spending. An electoral system based on geographic 4

5 representation will encourage spending targeted to particular districts at the expense of more inclusive public goods. In contrast, when the competition for votes is more broad-based, candidates and political parties will find it more electorally beneficial to run on national public goods platforms. This is consistent with the existing theoretical models of public finance and electoral systems. Persson & Tabellini (1999) argue that in plurality systems, politicians only need to please swing voters in marginal districts, not the population as a whole. Hence, there will be disproportionately more geographically targeted pork-barrel and fewer universal public goods in plurality systems as compared to PR. The same theoretical result comes from a different model developed by Lizzeri & Persico (2001). To see the logic of this argument, consider our three stylized electoral systems: majoritarian/plurality with single member districts (PLURALITY); nationwide, closed-list proportional representation (CLPR) where party leaders rank candidates and voters only select political parties; and open-list proportional representation (OLPR) where voters can cast their votes for a particular candidate on a party list. Electoral competition in PLURALITY systems has a local, geographic basis. National issues such as war and peace or moral issues such as abortion may, of course, sway voters, but incumbents will also want to claim that they have brought home the bacon to their constituents. Unless national political parties are very strong, incumbents are likely to make a nonpartisan appeal for reelection arguing that they have been able to obtain targeted benefits. In contrast, under CLPR, politicians have an incentive to provide broad-based public goods so long as the parties constituencies are widely dispersed so that it is difficult to target narrow benefits to one s supporters. In OLPR systems, there are no ready-made geographical constituencies as in PLURALITY systems, but a candidate may try to appeal to particular group of voters by becoming their advocate within the party and later bragging about his or her success. Thus, there will be more targeting in OLPR than CLPR, but less than in PLURALITY. Furthermore, the type of targeting is likely to single out different groups. If pork-barrel spending is conflated with corruption, one would conclude that PLURALITY systems are more susceptible to corruption because they give incentives for pork-barrel spending. However, having made an explicit distinction between the two, we arrive at a different prediction. As we argue in the following section, the same features of electoral systems that create incentives for pork-barrel spending also constrain political corruption. 3. Monitoring Corruption Consider a conceptual framework with four types of actors. The first are the incumbent party leaders; the second are the individual rank-and-file legislators who are not in the leadership; the 5

6 third are political opponents, either individuals or parties; and the fourth are the voters themselves. The incumbents party leaders and/or individual legislators have opportunities to extract corrupt rents. However, they may also have incentives to monitor each other. In addition, they are monitored by the political opposition and by voters. We specify the objective functions of these four political actors as follows. First, incumbent politicians, both leaders and rank-and-file, care about individual wealth and re-election. They would like to maximize rents without being detected, since detection is associated with costs, both monetary (such as legal fees or even a prison term) and political (decrease in probability of re-election). Different electoral systems shape the incumbents opportunities to extract rents as well as their chances of re-election. Second, opposition candidates care about winning office. Their chances of winning increase as the chance of incumbents re-election decreases, so the opposition benefits from revelations of corruption involving incumbents. However, challengers incentives to work to uncover corruption depend on the electoral system. Finally, voters prefer honest to corrupt elected officials since their utility decreases when public resources are diverted for private gain. This is, of course, the reason why we assume that a corruption scandal lowers the incumbent s chance of reelection. Again, we claim that the voters ability and incentives to monitor corrupt politicians vary with the design of the electoral system. Corruption in our formulation is illegal self-regarding activity. If detected, a corrupt politician usually pays considerable costs, both legal and political. Hence, we assume that the probability of detection constrains political corruption, and, all else equal, the stronger the constraint, the lower we expect the equilibrium level of political corruption to be. We argue that electoral rules affect the probability of detection, and hence the anti-corruption constraints, by shaping the incentives and ability of political actors to monitor political corruption. Figure 1 depicts the oversight relations that are shaped by the electoral rules. 2 We explore them in detail below. Figure 1 about here To understand how electoral rules affect the monitoring of corruption, we need to explore three interrelated issues. First, how do the opportunities for private gain differ in different electoral systems? Second, who has the incentive to monitor potentially corrupt groups or individuals? Third, who has the ability to do so? The first salient difference between voting systems is the locus of control over corrupt rents, that is, the opportunities for private gain. Under CLPR the party leaders are very powerful vis à vis the rank and file because they determine a candidate s ranking on the list. 3 Thus the leadership faces most of the opportunities for private gain and can determine how the spoils are divided. The rankand-file party members in the legislature face few individualized corrupt opportunities. The situation is similar under OLPR, except that the leadership itself may be more divided and unstable. Individual 6

7 members can challenge the leadership by threatening to campaign against them through direct appeals to voters. 4 Compare the situation under PLURALITY rule. Here, individual incumbents may gain power within the party because of the strength of their local power base. Even where the party has the nominal power to assign candidates to districts, an incumbent who wins by a large margin has some independent bargaining power vis à vis the party. This means that such incumbents can demand a share of the rents of political power in the form of corrupt payoffs or in pork-barrel projects for their districts. Their own preference for payoffs or pork will be a function of the oversight by voters, the media, and citizens groups, on the one hand, and challengers, on the other. This discussion suggests that in terms of uncovering corruption, monitoring the leadership is relatively more important under PR, and monitoring the rank-and-file is relatively more important under PLURALITY rule. Of course, leaders may be able to garner corrupt rents under PLURALIY rule as well. Our claim is only that individual legislators have more opportunities for rent extraction under PLURALITY than under CLPR. Thus, in PR systems, especially closed-list ones, the opportunities for rent extraction are vested mainly in party leaders, and in PLURALITY they are divided between the party leaders and individual representatives. Now consider the incentives and ability of political actors to engage in monitoring. As Figure 1 shows, the oversight relations that interest us are mainly voters and political opponents monitoring of both party leaders and individual politicians. We also consider the possibility of intra-party monitoring, i.e., rank-and-file members monitoring of the party leadership and the leadership s monitoring of the rank-and-file. We are interested not in the overall level of oversight, but in the way the electoral system affects monitoring on the margin. In addition, we assume both that monitoring is costly, and that hiding one s malfeasance is a costly and imperfect process. 5 We consider each of the three monitoring relationships in turn. Monitoring by Voters As a normative matter, the rank-and-file need to be more closely monitored by voters under PLURALITY rule than under CLPR because the rank-and-file incumbents have more control over rents under PLURALITY rule than under PR. As a positive matter, we argue that this is what we would expect to happen. Voters do not have the ability to monitor the relevant actors equally in all electoral systems. We discuss two ways in which electoral systems may influence the voters ability to monitor corrupt politicians.the first involves the voters ability to observe malfeasance if it occurs. The second concerns the incentives of voters to organize for oversight. We consider these arguments in turn, although they are not independent of each other. Thus, voters may be more likely to overcome collective action problems if the benefits of engaging in oversight are relatively large. 7

8 The first argument is derived from the career-concern model of Holmstrom (1982) and its extension to rents and corruption by Persson and Tabellini (2000, ch. 9). Voters prefer honest politicians to corrupt ones because of the costs that corruption imposes on citizens in terms of inflated budgets, low value public projects, etc. Hence, if voters can identify corrupt politicians, they will punish them by voting against them in the next election. Persson and Tabelliini argue that voting over individual candidates, as in a PLURALITY rule system, creates a direct link between individual performance and re-election. This, in turn, gives incentives to incumbents to avoid corruption (Persson, Tabellini, and Trebbi 2001). However, so far, this argument does not distinguish well between voting systems. In CLPR systems, the leadership is also known to the voters. Because it is precisely the leadership that needs to be monitored in CLPR, voters can identify those politicians most subject to corrupt incentives in both systems. However, it is not sufficient to identify those who might be corrupt. In addition, voters must be able to assess whether the politicians actually are engaging in malfeasance. They need to monitor the rank and file under PLURALITY and the leadership under CLPR. We argue that such monitoring is easier in the smaller districts produced by PLURALITY rule than in the larger districts characteristic of PR. Voters in a district with a small population are more likely to have direct contact with their representative and hence more information about the candidates they elect. Holding the freedom of press constant, we would expect that information about individual kick-backs to politicians would be less readily available to voters in CLPR systems than in PLURALITY systems. In short, we claim that voters are more likely to become aware of corruption under PLURALITY rule than under PR and that one reason for this is the smaller population of districts under PLURALITY rule. The second argument concerns the incentives of voters to organize to provide oversight. Free-rider problems are ubiquitous in political life, and the monitoring of corruption is no exception. In this case, only a small sub-set of the voters needs to organize to engage in monitoring. If they do, all voters benefit. In general, collective action problems among voters should be less severe in small groups than they are in large groups (Olson 1982). This suggests that citizens in smaller districts, measured by number of voters, ought to find it easier to overcome free-rider problems than those in larger districts. Holding other factors constant, PLURALITY rule produces districts with smaller numbers of voters than PR. Thus, overcoming free rider problems should be easier in such systems. In addition, it may be easier to organize groups willing to engage in monitoring simply because it is less difficult to observe corruption and its results in a PLURALITY system. Our discussion of monitoring by voters has so far left out OLPR systems. There, similar to CLPR, the leadership controls the rents. Yet OLPR shares one feature with PLURALITY systems: voters can cast their votes for particular candidates, albeit within a party. This strengthens the link between performing well in office and getting re-elected in comparison to CLPR systems and gives 8

9 the rank-and-file some power vis-à-vis the party leaders. However, the first feature of PLURALITY systems relatively small single-member districts is absent in OLPR systems. This disables grassroot monitoring by voters who, in addition, are likely to face considerable collective action problems. Furthermore, individual candidates are likely to have little say over their party s rent-extraction activities. On balance, then, OLPR systems fall in between CLPR and PLURALITY systems the link between performing well in office and being re-elected is stronger than in CLPR, but the voters cannot monitor their representatives as closely as in PLURALITY. Even if they did so, the integrity of the system would benefit little because rent-seeking opportunities are centered in the party leadership. Monitoring by Political Opponents The second piece of the puzzle is the competitiveness of the political system and its impact on the monitoring of incumbents by their political opponents. As we noted above, challengers have a direct incentive to uncover the malfeasance of incumbents because they increase their probability of winning office once the incumbent is discredited. They can do this under PR systems by investigating the integrity of party leaders, and under PLURALITY rule at the district level as well. Either might be a feasible strategy, but we suggest that there are features of PLURALITY rule that tip the balance in its favor. We offer two arguments why under PR it is more difficult for the opposition to monitor the incumbents: the first one is based on a free-rider problem among multiple parties, while the second one concerns the adverse effects of coalition politics on monitoring. We consider these two arguments in turn. First, we claim that the net benefits for an opponent of uncovering a scandal tend to be higher under PLURALITY rule than under PR. To see this, consider first the opposite argument, namely that competitive pressures are higher under PR and will lead to lower corruption (Myerson 1993; Persson, Rolland, & Tabellini 2000). Under PR, entry barriers are low so that multiple parties are common; under PLURALITY rule, when Duverger s law holds, only two major parties will compete in each district. The high cost of establishing a new party contributes to the lack of political competition in these models. Assuming that politics is multidimensional, voters find it more difficult to vote out corrupt politicians if honest candidates, whom the voters might like on other issues as well, find it difficult to enter into the competition for public office. Conversely, the less expensive it is for a challenger to take on the incumbent, the more likely one is to appear in response to voter dissatisfaction. This is an important argument, but it ignores the incentives that opponents have to uncover corruption independent of the party s ideology. The barriers-to-entry theory is an application of economic arguments from industrial organization to the realm of politics. The basic point that a competitive political system limits 9

10 corruption seems a valid one (Rose-Ackerman 1978). It is not obvious, however, that multi-member districts produce benefits similar to those of markets with many competing firms. What we question is the claim, implied by the empirical work, that competition is greater the larger is the district magnitude. True, a PLURALITY system with single-member districts will often produce only two parties. However, one opposition party with a credible chance of winning the election ought to be sufficient to give the incumbent an incentive to limit self-dealing, and the marginal cost of fielding a candidate is likely to be low for such an established party. Furthermore, multi-member districts selecting legislators by PR may indeed produce many more viable parties, but no party may have much incentive to monitor the corruption of incumbents because a scandal is a public good for all opposition parties. In short, the argument that corruption monitoring will increase with the number of political opponents does not seem convincing. 6 To the contrary, the incentive to free ride off the scandal-mongering of others could mean that the impact of competitive politics on corruption monitoring actually falls as the number of parties increases. 7 The second argument for PLURALITY being conducive to better monitoring by opposition focuses on inter-party relationships under PR and PLURALITY rule. With PLURALITY, coalition governments are possible but unlikely unless many regional parties exist. Under PR, they are common and in many countries parties do not sort themselves into two stable blocs. Instead, a party currently in opposition may expect to form a coalition with one or more of the incumbent parties sometime in the future. If this is so, opposition politicians will have little incentive to expose the corruption of those politicians that they might collaborate with in the future. The lack of a clear alternation between fixed groups of parties deters inter-party monitoring. 8 In sum, we argue that the number of parties is a poor proxy for the intensity of competition at least with respect to the control of corruption. The analogy to private market competition is misplaced. Although the party or candidate that uncovers the malfeasance gets some credit for diligence, the main benefit is an overall decline in support for the incumbent that benefits all opponents. Thus, a challenger has a larger incentive to bear this cost, the fewer the number of opposition parties. The challenger s incentive to uncover corruption is higher under PLURALITY rule than under PR so long as the number of effective parties is, in fact, lower and most districts are competitive. Comparison of Electoral Systems Table 1 summarizes our arguments about the oversight relations under the three electoral systems that we consider. The table presents our claims about the relative incentives and ability of political actors to monitor rent-extraction by politicians. They have no cardinal meaning. Table 1 about here 10

11 PLURALITY rule scores the highest of the three stylized electoral systems on both the incentives and the ability of political actors to monitor rent-extraction. Districts with small numbers of voters mitigate the collective-action problems of voters and make it easier for them to observe the behavior of individual legislators likely participants in most corrupt deals in such systems. At the opposite extreme, under CLPR, collective action problems are more serious, and voters find it difficult to observe the behavior of party leaders the primary locus of corrupt deals in CLPR. Furthermore, PLURALITY rule will produce opposition parties with higher incentives to unveil the corruption of incumbents than in multiple party regimes. The opposition will reap more of the electoral benefits from such revelations and is not likely to want to form a coalition with the incumbents in the future. Because OLPR systems share features of both CLPR and PLURALITY systems, they occupy an intermediate category in monitoring corruption. In particular, voters are better able to monitor incumbents in OLPR than in CLPR because individual identifiability and accountability are greater, but transparency in the large OLPR districts is lower than in the smaller PLURALITY districts. Finally, OLPR is no different from CLPR in that political opponents have few incentives to expose corrupt incumbents due to the collective action problem among multiple challengers. Before deriving hypotheses from our analysis, we allow for the possibility of intra-party monitoring and check whether it changes our predictions. Intra-party Monitoring Intra-party monitoring is unlikely to be a sufficient constraint on corruption under any electoral system. The basic problem is collusion. If there is little outside monitoring by voters, opponents, or other aspects of civil society, leaders can collude with the rank-and-file to share corrupt rents. Internal party whistle-blowers can arise, but this is likely to be a risky role to play even under PLURALITY rule where individual members have more independent influence than under PR. First, consider the incentives of the rank-and-file legislators to monitor the leadership. Recall that the objective of the incumbent legislators is to maximize a function that includes both private rents and the probability of re-election. They may differ in their underlying commitment to honesty, however, with some opposed to all payoffs and others willing to balance the benefits and costs. Whether they will monitor the leadership depends on their own relative preference for payoffs, on whether they have access to rents themselves, and on whether they can increase their probability of re-election by exposing a corrupt party leadership. Under CLPR, individual members of the party have little access to rents, so the key variable for them is the probability of re-election. Individual members have little incentive to expose corrupt 11

12 leaders because their future careers depend directly on the leadership s decision to rank them on the party list or to give them other patronage positions in government or the party apparatus. 9 Hence, incentives for political entrepreneurship are low. Nevertheless, if a rank-and-file member does happen to observe corruption by the leadership, he or she may have the leverage to demand a share of the rents in return for silence. Alternatively, the potential whistle-blower could insist on a high place on the list. This blackmail potential gives the rank-and-file some bargaining power, but it seems likely that the result will be some kind of deal rather than a scandal because the cost to the whistle-blower of going forward is high. Unless he or she is planning on leaving politics in any case or is powerful enough to challenge the leadership for party control, a scandal will undermine the career of the whistle-blower along with all who are associated with the party. Under OLPR, individual legislators have more incentives to appeal to voters over the heads of party bosses, but accusing the leadership of corruption also risks destroying rather than reforming the party. Thus effective rank and file monitoring seems unlikely, although some gain sharing may occur. In a PLURALITY rule system, although risk is also present, it is somewhat weaker because the party is less centralized. Honest politicians have some incentive to blow the whistle on a corrupt leadership because the leadership does not entirely control their fate. Even those with no personal commitment to honesty may reveal the corruption of others if they believe that their constituents will reward them. Of course, even here, whistle-blowing is a risky strategy because it may lead to the fall of the government in a parliamentary system. However, on balance, if the rank-and-file members are honest, they are better equipped to constrain the rent-seeking behavior of the leadership in a PLURALITY rule system. In contrast, if they are corrupt, they can more easily flout attempts by the leadership to control their behavior and as in the PR cases, can demand a share of the leaders spoils. Relying on the leadership s incentives and ability to monitor rank-and-file appears similarly problematic. Regardless of the electoral rule, the leadership may have an incentive to monitor individual members because their potential corrupt practices, if exposed, may harm the name of the party and worsen its overall electoral prospects. In PLURALITY systems the leadership has the most incentives to monitor individual members because they have relatively more opportunities to extract rents, but unfortunately the leadership has relatively little ability to control individual members in comparison to PR systems. In sum, the incentives for intra-party monitoring do not seem very powerful under any electoral system. Therefore, we believe that monitoring by outside actors -- voters and political opponents is what truly differentiates electoral systems with regard to limiting corruption. However, where the intra-party monitoring does operate, it does not change our basic prediction about electoral systems influence on corruption. PLURALITY is superior to both PR systems on all counts except one the ability of the party leaders to monitor individual representatives. Although 12

13 top-down intra-party monitoring appears to be problematic in PLURALITY systems, we believe that this deficiency is more than offset by the ability and incentives of both voters and political opponents to monitor individual representatives. At the same time, party leaders, who share the locus of rents with the individual representatives in PLURALITY, are relatively well monitored both inside the party and by outside actors. On balance, we predict that PLURALITY rule voting will do a better job at controlling corruption than PR, especially CLPR. The cost of PLURALITY rule may be a more particularized political system that focuses on providing benefits to narrow ranges of constituents in key districts, but that is simply the consequence of the more individualized nature of politics. Under PLURALITY rule, (1) corrupt opportunities will be concentrated in just those political actors who are best able to be monitored by voters, (2) the two-party system that frequently results will give opponents an incentive to uncover scandals at any level, and (3) the greater power of the rank-and-file means that, if the rank and file is honest, the leadership will be discouraged from corruption by credible rankand-file threats to reveal its malfeasance. 4. Presidential and Parliamentary Systems Other elements of constitutional design may be important for corruption control besides the differences in voting rules. The most interesting are those that are not merely controls but that interact with the voting rule to affect the opportunities for corruption and the incentives and opportunities for its control. We focus on one such feature: the distinction between presidential and parliamentary systems. Opportunities for corruption are enhanced by centralized control over government. Then those with power can, if they wish, create rent-seeking opportunities with little oversight inside government. A president who controls the executive branch has rent-creating possibilities that can be used for personal gain. In a presidential system, the leaders of the legislative parties are less powerful than under a parliamentary system (Shugart 1998, Mainwaring 1995). They must negotiate with the president to pass legislation and do not control the rents that arise within the executive. 10 Consider the framework that we introduced in the previous section with the addition of one more incumbent: the president. Figure 2 about here Among the incumbents, the president has access to the rents generated within the executive although some of these rents may be shared strategically with the legislature. The president s undivided power over many of these rents implies that diverting them for personal gain is likely to be easier than in a more collegial system of cabinet government. 11 He also has an interest in creating 13

14 additional rents through executive action. In spite of the legislature s incentive to monitor the President, his fixed term in office gives him considerable leeway subject only to the threat of impeachment. The legislature has no instrument similar to the vote of no confidence in parliamentary systems, where the legislature can remove the executive from power at any time between elections. Of course, legislatures do try to restrict presidential freedom, but their control is less direct than that exercised by a parliament over the Cabinet in a parliamentary system. In addition, in most presidential systems, US-style checks and balances are absent and presidents tend to have extensive legislative and non-legislative powers. This is not inherent in the nature of presidential systems but is an empirical reality. Using a large cross-section of countries, Kunicova (2001) shows not only that presidentialism per se is associated with higher corruption, but also that the more extensive the president s powers, the more corruption. Thus, monitoring of the executive by the legislature is in principle and in practice more difficult in presidential systems than in parliamentary ones where the vote of no confidence gives the legislature oversight powers over the executive. Presidents frequently need to cooperate with the legislature to get policy initiatives passed (Cox and Morgenstern 2001, Shugart 1998). A corrupt president may seek to enact statutes that incorporate rent-generating opportunities that can be exploited for personal gain. To pass such laws, however, the president needs to bargain with the legislature. 12 In such cases, electoral rules affect the strength of legislative parties and their bargaining power in dealings with the President. Theoretical claims about electoral rules and party strength have two prongs. First, as discussed above, parties are stronger under CLPR than under PLURALITY rule. Second, parties are weaker in presidential systems than in parliamentary systems because in the former they do not need to organize themselves to form a government (Mainwaring 1995; Shugart 1998, 1999) Taken together, these arguments imply that parties will be weakest in presidential systems with PLURALITY-rule legislatures and strongest in parliamentary systems operating under CLPR. However, the other two possibilities cannot be clearly ranked except to note that they fall between the extremes. One cannot say a priori if parties are stronger under a parliamentary system with PLURALITY voting or under a presidential system with the legislature chosen by CLPR. The relation to the expected level of corruption is complex. On the one hand, we expect that presidential systems will be more corrupt than parliamentary systems that use similar voting rules for the legislature. On the other hand, we expect that CLPR systems will be more corrupt than PLURALITY systems. The combination of CLPR and presidentialism is likely to create unfortunate synergies. This happens, we argue, because several factors converge. In line with our previous discussion consider, first, the bargaining relationship between the President and the legislature and the scope for intra-party monitoring. If he wishes, the President has the power to generate high levels of corrupt rents through his control of the executive. Under 14

15 CLPR, he can form an alliance with the party leaders to share rents at relatively low transaction costs because the rank and file does not have to be included. Even if the parties are somewhat weaker than under a parliamentary system, they still control their members. The rank and file, as we argued above, can often be kept in the dark and even if they learn of a corrupt deal, they have little incentive to blow the whistle on party leaders. Aspects of this corruption-prone scenario do not carry over into other combinations. If a president faces a PLURALITY-rule legislature whose parties are weak, he may have to bargain with a multitude of individual members in order to form an alliance. Any alliance will be difficult to form in the first place because of the number of legislators involved; it is not enough just to include the party leaders. Furthermore, it may be difficult to sustain if marginal members threaten to defect. The greater number of individuals involved increases the risk that one of them will report the scandal. In addition, even rank-and-file members of a party that is nominally allied with the president have an incentive to be integrity entrepreneurs to enhance their own reputation. The very difficulty of forming an alliance with the legislature should deter corruption. This discussion suggests that the greater corrupt opportunities created by presidentialism should be especially evident in CLPR systems. OLPR ought to be an intermediate case. The parties are less powerful bargaining units than under CLPR, but individual members have little to bring to the table. To complete the argument we need to consider the possibility of monitoring by voters and opposition politicians. These groups have an incentive to monitor the president, but their ability is limited. For voters, the situation is similar to that of their monitoring of party leaders the collective action problems are large in nation-wide districts and evidence of corruption is hidden in public contracts and individualized decisions that are hard to monitor. This is part of the basic argument for expecting more corruption in presidential systems. In contrast, legislators from parties different from the president s do have an incentive to monitor, and if they control the legislature, they may have the power to enact laws that constrain the president. The issue is then whether the role of opposition parties ought to differ between PR and PLURALITY systems. We propose the following way of thinking about this issue: Suppose that the corrupt president tries to preempt future oversight by giving many potential opponents a share of the spoils, thus neutralizing them as monitors. This is a more feasible option if only party leaders have any real power and in presidential systems this is most likely to be true under CLPR (Carey&Shugart 1995, Seddon et al. 2001). In contrast, consider PLURALITY rule in a case where only two major parties are likely to exist, one of which is likely to be the president s own party. 13 As we argued above, PLURALITY rule lessens the power of party leaders, including the president s party, and gives individual politicians incentives to be integrity entrepreneurs, on the one hand, or free-lance rent seekers, on the other. The problem is not simply to get a majority 15

16 behind the corrupt initiative, but also to assure that minority legislators do not blow the whistle to enhance their own political standing with the voters. Members can gain political capital by presenting themselves to their own constituents as defenders of honest politics. It appears that what matters in presidential bargaining with the legislature is not the number of parties that the president needs to work with, but the extent to which these parties are capable of voting as unified blocs. In this sense, CLPR seems to be most conducive to corrupt deals Hypotheses From our discussion in the previous three sections, we derive the following three hypotheses: H1 Existence of a relationship between electoral rules and corruption. Ceteris paribus, we expect CLPR systems to be more corrupt than OLPR and PLURALITY systems. This should hold controlling for other institutional factors, as well as for background factors such as level of economic and political development. H2 Interaction effects. Ceteris paribus, presidential PR systems are expected to be more corrupt than their parliamentary counterparts. We predict that CLPR presidential systems will be especially corrupt relative to other types of government structures. H3 Causal mechanism. Ceteris paribus, the population size of districts and the number of parties in the opposition should be negatively associated with corruption control. 6. Data, Measurement, and Econometric Methods We use cross-country data sets that characterize countries in terms of the level of corruption and that record the way in which their legislatures are selected. To this basic data we add information on whether a separately elected president exists and include other background political and economic variables. We use average perceptions of corruption in each country, based on a measure that captures high-level political and bureaucratic corruption as perceived by outsiders, mostly business people. Although these perceptions combine two kinds of corruption, the indices are mostly a measure of corruption at the top of government where politicians are likely to be involved. High-level bureaucratic corruption in, say, the award of contract or other favors, almost always has a strongly partisan cast. 15 On the other side of the ledger, we have summary measures of the voting rules in 16

17 each country. We cannot distinguish empirically between opportunities for corruption and the ability and incentives to monitor it. However, we claim that the convergence of these three factors ought to mean that PLURALITY systems are less corrupt on balance. We also provide a first cut at testing some of the causal mechanisms that we proposed in the theoretical section. 6.1 Corruption Data Corruption is difficult to define, systematically observe, and measure. The most comprehensive cross-country data on corruption are based on perceptions, not concrete measures of payoffs. This raises the possibility that corruption may be perceived to be high because people take the trouble to uncover it. In the extreme, there could be an inverse relationship between the underlying amount of corruption and perceptions of its prevalence. For example, the underlying level of corruption may have been higher in Italy before the Clean Hands investigations than after it, but public perceptions of its level could have increased as a result of the investigations. However, although this can occur in an individual country as policy changes over time, we doubt that it would represent a stable result. We assume that politicians act strategically. If they predict that their corruption is likely to be uncovered, they will engage in less of it. Then perceptions and reality would converge. Political systems that encourage corruption would be more corrupt, and those who deal with the state at high levels would also perceive corruption to be high. The surveys that we use are mostly based on the perceptions of such well-placed observers. In recent years, several indices have been developed that attempt to capture the abuse of political and bureaucratic power across countries. We rely on two indices that both measure perceptions of corruption, but use different aggregation methodologies: the Corruption Perception Index (CPI), compiled by Transparency International (Lambsdorff 1998), and the Control of Corruption Index (CORRWB), also known as GRAFT, compiled by the World Bank (Kaufamann, Kraay, and Zoido- Lobaton 1999). We prefer the CORRWB measure, but to check the robustness of our results, we run all our models on CPI as well. Transparency International (TI) has published its annual CPI ranking of countries since TI aggregates surveys of perceived corruption across countries based on the views of business people, risk analysts, investigative journalists, and the general public. Notice that many of the respondents are likely to have first hand knowledge of state operations not available to ordinary voters. The index aggregates corruption scores from up to 17 different polls for every country, including Wall Street Journal, Gallup International, Economist Intelligence Unit, World Bank, World Economic Forum, and others. These polls ask questions based on the concept of corruption as the misuse of public power for private benefit; specifically, the focus is on kickbacks in public procurement, the embezzlement of public funds, and the bribery of public officials. 17

Theoretical comparisons of electoral systems

Theoretical comparisons of electoral systems European Economic Review 43 (1999) 671 697 Joseph Schumpeter Lecture Theoretical comparisons of electoral systems Roger B. Myerson Kellog Graduate School of Management, Northwestern University, 2001 Sheridan

More information

Political Economics II Spring Lectures 4-5 Part II Partisan Politics and Political Agency. Torsten Persson, IIES

Political Economics II Spring Lectures 4-5 Part II Partisan Politics and Political Agency. Torsten Persson, IIES Lectures 4-5_190213.pdf Political Economics II Spring 2019 Lectures 4-5 Part II Partisan Politics and Political Agency Torsten Persson, IIES 1 Introduction: Partisan Politics Aims continue exploring policy

More information

Handcuffs for the Grabbing Hand? Media Capture and Government Accountability by Timothy Besley and Andrea Prat (2006)

Handcuffs for the Grabbing Hand? Media Capture and Government Accountability by Timothy Besley and Andrea Prat (2006) Handcuffs for the Grabbing Hand? Media Capture and Government Accountability by Timothy Besley and Andrea Prat (2006) Group Hicks: Dena, Marjorie, Sabina, Shehryar To the press alone, checkered as it is

More information

LOGROLLING. Nicholas R. Miller Department of Political Science University of Maryland Baltimore County Baltimore, Maryland

LOGROLLING. Nicholas R. Miller Department of Political Science University of Maryland Baltimore County Baltimore, Maryland LOGROLLING Nicholas R. Miller Department of Political Science University of Maryland Baltimore County Baltimore, Maryland 21250 May 20, 1999 An entry in The Encyclopedia of Democratic Thought (Routledge)

More information

This manuscript has been accepted for publication at Electoral Studies

This manuscript has been accepted for publication at Electoral Studies Party Systems, Electoral Systems and Constraints on Corruption Abstract: This article explores the relationship between the party system, electoral formula and corruption. Previous research has focused

More information

Econ 554: Political Economy, Institutions and Business: Solution to Final Exam

Econ 554: Political Economy, Institutions and Business: Solution to Final Exam Econ 554: Political Economy, Institutions and Business: Solution to Final Exam April 22, 2015 Question 1 (Persson and Tabellini) a) A winning candidate with income y i will implement a policy solving:

More information

Introduction. Political Institutions and the Determinants of Public Policy. STEPHAN HAGGARD and MATHEW D. MCCUBBINS

Introduction. Political Institutions and the Determinants of Public Policy. STEPHAN HAGGARD and MATHEW D. MCCUBBINS Introduction Political Institutions and the Determinants of Public Policy STEPHAN HAGGARD and MATHEW D. MCCUBBINS INTRODUCTION This volume is devoted to exploring the effects of political institutions

More information

Torsten Persson is Professor of Economics and Director of the Institute for International Economic

Torsten Persson is Professor of Economics and Director of the Institute for International Economic Constitutions and Economic Policy Torsten Persson and Guido Tabellini Torsten Persson is Professor of Economics and Director of the Institute for International Economic Studies, Stockholm University, Stockholm,

More information

political budget cycles

political budget cycles P000346 Theoretical and empirical research on is surveyed and discussed. Significant are seen to be primarily a phenomenon of the first elections after the transition to a democratic electoral system.

More information

Chapter 7 Institutions and economics growth

Chapter 7 Institutions and economics growth Chapter 7 Institutions and economics growth 7.1 Institutions: Promoting productive activity and growth Institutions are the laws, social norms, traditions, religious beliefs, and other established rules

More information

Women s. Political Representation & Electoral Systems. Key Recommendations. Federal Context. September 2016

Women s. Political Representation & Electoral Systems. Key Recommendations. Federal Context. September 2016 Women s Political Representation & Electoral Systems September 2016 Federal Context Parity has been achieved in federal cabinet, but women remain under-represented in Parliament. Canada ranks 62nd Internationally

More information

Hungary. Basic facts The development of the quality of democracy in Hungary. The overall quality of democracy

Hungary. Basic facts The development of the quality of democracy in Hungary. The overall quality of democracy Hungary Basic facts 2007 Population 10 055 780 GDP p.c. (US$) 13 713 Human development rank 43 Age of democracy in years (Polity) 17 Type of democracy Electoral system Party system Parliamentary Mixed:

More information

brazilianpoliticalsciencereview ARTICLE Career Choice and Legislative Reelection Evidence from Brazil and Colombia 1

brazilianpoliticalsciencereview ARTICLE Career Choice and Legislative Reelection Evidence from Brazil and Colombia 1 brazilianpoliticalsciencereview ARTICLE Career Choice and Legislative Reelection Evidence from Brazil and Colombia 1 Felipe Botero Andes University, Colombia e Lucio R. Rennó University of Brasília, Brazil

More information

Coalition Governments and Political Rents

Coalition Governments and Political Rents Coalition Governments and Political Rents Dr. Refik Emre Aytimur Georg-August-Universität Göttingen January 01 Abstract We analyze the impact of coalition governments on the ability of political competition

More information

Does Political Competition Reduce Ethnic Discrimination?

Does Political Competition Reduce Ethnic Discrimination? Does Political Competition Reduce Ethnic Discrimination? Evidence from the Samurdhi Food Stamp Program in Sri Lanka Iffath Sharif Senior Economist South Asia Social Protection February 14, 2011 Presentation

More information

CORRUPTION AND GOVERNMENT. Lessons for Portugal Susan Rose-Ackerman

CORRUPTION AND GOVERNMENT. Lessons for Portugal Susan Rose-Ackerman 1 CORRUPTION AND GOVERNMENT Lessons for Portugal Susan Rose-Ackerman PORTUGAL IN THE TRANSPARENCY INTERNATIONAL INDEX In Portugal corruption is a serious problem. TI ranks Portugal 29 th of 180 countries

More information

Corruption and Political Competition

Corruption and Political Competition Corruption and Political Competition Richard Damania Adelaide University Erkan Yalçin Yeditepe University October 24, 2005 Abstract There is a growing evidence that political corruption is often closely

More information

CORRUPTION VOTING AND POLITICAL CONTEXT:

CORRUPTION VOTING AND POLITICAL CONTEXT: CORRUPTION VOTING AND POLITICAL CONTEXT: Testing the Micro Mechanisms GEORGIOS XEZONAKIS WORKING PAPER SERIES 2012:15 QOG THE QUALITY OF GOVERNMENT INSTITUTE Department of Political Science University

More information

Political Participation under Democracy

Political Participation under Democracy Political Participation under Democracy Daniel Justin Kleinschmidt Cpr. Nr.: POL-PST.XB December 19 th, 2012 Political Science, Bsc. Semester 1 International Business & Politics Question: 2 Total Number

More information

CARLETON ECONOMIC PAPERS

CARLETON ECONOMIC PAPERS CEP 17-06 In Defense of Majoritarianism Stanley L. Winer March 2017 CARLETON ECONOMIC PAPERS Department of Economics 1125 Colonel By Drive Ottawa, Ontario, Canada K1S 5B6 In Defense of Majoritarianism

More information

Introduction Why Don t Electoral Rules Have the Same Effects in All Countries?

Introduction Why Don t Electoral Rules Have the Same Effects in All Countries? Introduction Why Don t Electoral Rules Have the Same Effects in All Countries? In the early 1990s, Japan and Russia each adopted a very similar version of a mixed-member electoral system. In the form used

More information

At the rare moments in history when a nation debates constitutional reform,

At the rare moments in history when a nation debates constitutional reform, Journal of Economic Perspectives Volume 18, Number 1 Winter 2004 Pages 75 98 Constitutions and Economic Policy Torsten Persson and Guido Tabellini At the rare moments in history when a nation debates constitutional

More information

Particularism around the World

Particularism around the World Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized the world bank economic review, vol. 17, no. 1 133 143 Particularism around the World

More information

Chapter 1. Introduction

Chapter 1. Introduction Chapter 1 Introduction 1 2 CHAPTER 1. INTRODUCTION This dissertation provides an analysis of some important consequences of multilevel governance. The concept of multilevel governance refers to the dispersion

More information

Manipulating Electoral Rules:

Manipulating Electoral Rules: Manipulating Electoral Rules: Intra-Party Conflict, Partisan Interests, and Constitutional Thickness Stanford University Dissertation (Draft) Chapter 1 Presenting and Testing a General Theory of Electoral

More information

In Defense of Majoritarianism

In Defense of Majoritarianism Carleton University, Ottawa March 2-4, 2017 In Defense of Majoritarianism Stanley L. Winer, Carleton University Conference Sponsor(s): Faculty of Public Affairs Partners: Presenting sponsor: Version /

More information

The Provision of Public Goods Under Alternative. Electoral Incentives

The Provision of Public Goods Under Alternative. Electoral Incentives The Provision of Public Goods Under Alternative Electoral Incentives Alessandro Lizzeri and Nicola Persico March 10, 2000 American Economic Review, forthcoming ABSTRACT Politicians who care about the spoils

More information

Answer THREE questions, ONE from each section. Each section has equal weighting.

Answer THREE questions, ONE from each section. Each section has equal weighting. UNIVERSITY OF EAST ANGLIA School of Economics Main Series UG Examination 2016-17 GOVERNMENT, WELFARE AND POLICY ECO-6006Y Time allowed: 2 hours Answer THREE questions, ONE from each section. Each section

More information

PROBLEMS OF CREDIBLE STRATEGIC CONDITIONALITY IN DETERRENCE by Roger B. Myerson July 26, 2018

PROBLEMS OF CREDIBLE STRATEGIC CONDITIONALITY IN DETERRENCE by Roger B. Myerson July 26, 2018 PROBLEMS OF CREDIBLE STRATEGIC CONDITIONALITY IN DETERRENCE by Roger B. Myerson July 26, 2018 We can influence others' behavior by threatening to punish them if they behave badly and by promising to reward

More information

Maintaining Control. Putin s Strategy for Holding Power Past 2008

Maintaining Control. Putin s Strategy for Holding Power Past 2008 Maintaining Control Putin s Strategy for Holding Power Past 2008 PONARS Policy Memo No. 397 Regina Smyth Pennsylvania State University December 2005 There is little question that Vladimir Putin s Kremlin

More information

Politics and Public Policy

Politics and Public Policy American Government: Brief Version 6/e 12 Politics and Public Policy I. Reviewing the Chapter Chapter Focus Study Outline The purpose of this chapter is to explain how the American constitutional system

More information

Party Systems, the Selection and Control of Politicians and Corruption

Party Systems, the Selection and Control of Politicians and Corruption Party Systems, the Selection and Control of Politicians and Corruption Petra Schleiter St Hilda s College University of Oxford petra.schleiter@st-hildas.ox.ac.uk Alisa M. Voznaya St Antony s College University

More information

The Political Economy of Policy Implementation. David K. Levine and Andrea Mattozzi 13/02/18

The Political Economy of Policy Implementation. David K. Levine and Andrea Mattozzi 13/02/18 The Political Economy of Policy Implementation David K. Levine and Andrea Mattozzi 13/02/18 Overview: As we have seen, for example, during the Greek crisis, the European Monetary Union is heavily influenced

More information

Electoral Systems and Trade

Electoral Systems and Trade Chapter 15 Electoral Systems and Trade Stephanie J. Rickard In democracies, politicians compete to win votes, and subsequently office, in free and fair elections. Elected representatives should therefore

More information

An Overview Across the New Political Economy Literature. Abstract

An Overview Across the New Political Economy Literature. Abstract An Overview Across the New Political Economy Literature Luca Murrau Ministry of Economy and Finance - Rome Abstract This work presents a review of the literature on political process formation and the

More information

Executive summary 2013:2

Executive summary 2013:2 Executive summary Why study corruption in Sweden? The fact that Sweden does well in international corruption surveys cannot be taken to imply that corruption does not exist or that corruption is not a

More information

Unit 1 Introduction to Comparative Politics Test Multiple Choice 2 pts each

Unit 1 Introduction to Comparative Politics Test Multiple Choice 2 pts each Unit 1 Introduction to Comparative Politics Test Multiple Choice 2 pts each 1. Which of the following is NOT considered to be an aspect of globalization? A. Increased speed and magnitude of cross-border

More information

The Impact of an Open-party List System on Incumbency Turnover and Political Representativeness in Indonesia

The Impact of an Open-party List System on Incumbency Turnover and Political Representativeness in Indonesia The Impact of an Open-party List System on Incumbency Turnover and Political Representativeness in Indonesia An Open Forum with Dr. Michael Buehler and Dr. Philips J. Vermonte Introduction June 26, 2012

More information

Market failures. If markets "work perfectly well", governments should just play their minimal role, which is to:

Market failures. If markets work perfectly well, governments should just play their minimal role, which is to: Market failures If markets "work perfectly well", governments should just play their minimal role, which is to: (a) protect property rights, and (b) enforce contracts. But usually markets fail. This happens

More information

FRED S. MCCHESNEY, Northwestern University, Chicago, IL 60611, U.S.A.

FRED S. MCCHESNEY, Northwestern University, Chicago, IL 60611, U.S.A. 185 thinking of the family in terms of covenant relationships will suggest ways for laws to strengthen ties among existing family members. To the extent that modern American law has become centered on

More information

Amy Tenhouse. Incumbency Surge: Examining the 1996 Margin of Victory for U.S. House Incumbents

Amy Tenhouse. Incumbency Surge: Examining the 1996 Margin of Victory for U.S. House Incumbents Amy Tenhouse Incumbency Surge: Examining the 1996 Margin of Victory for U.S. House Incumbents In 1996, the American public reelected 357 members to the United States House of Representatives; of those

More information

The Integer Arithmetic of Legislative Dynamics

The Integer Arithmetic of Legislative Dynamics The Integer Arithmetic of Legislative Dynamics Kenneth Benoit Trinity College Dublin Michael Laver New York University July 8, 2005 Abstract Every legislature may be defined by a finite integer partition

More information

1 Introduction. Cambridge University Press International Institutions and National Policies Xinyuan Dai Excerpt More information

1 Introduction. Cambridge University Press International Institutions and National Policies Xinyuan Dai Excerpt More information 1 Introduction Why do countries comply with international agreements? How do international institutions influence states compliance? These are central questions in international relations (IR) and arise

More information

1. One of the various ways in which parties contribute to democratic governance is by.

1. One of the various ways in which parties contribute to democratic governance is by. 11 Political Parties Multiple-Choice Questions 1. One of the various ways in which parties contribute to democratic governance is by. a. dividing the electorate b. narrowing voter choice c. running candidates

More information

Political Science 381: The Politics of Electoral Systems. Course Description

Political Science 381: The Politics of Electoral Systems. Course Description Political Science 381: The Politics of Electoral Systems Dr. Brian F. Crisp 285 Siegle Hall crisp@wustl.edu Office Hours: Thursdays 2:30-3:30 or by appointment Course Description It is impossible to appreciate

More information

kicking the tyres Choosing a voting system for New Zealand

kicking the tyres Choosing a voting system for New Zealand kicking the tyres Choosing a voting system for New Zealand by steve thomas contents Kicking the Tyres. Choosing a voting system for New Zealand 1 Evaluating Voting Systems 2 Mixed Member Proportional (MMP)

More information

Runoff Elections and the Number of Presidential Candidates A Regression Discontinuity Design Using Brazilian Municipalities

Runoff Elections and the Number of Presidential Candidates A Regression Discontinuity Design Using Brazilian Municipalities Runoff Elections and the Number of Presidential Candidates A Regression Discontinuity Design Using Brazilian Municipalities Timothy J. Power University of Oxford Rodrigo Rodrigues-Silveira University of

More information

AP US GOVERNMENT: CHAPER 7: POLITICAL PARTIES: ESSENTIAL TO DEMOCRACY

AP US GOVERNMENT: CHAPER 7: POLITICAL PARTIES: ESSENTIAL TO DEMOCRACY AP US GOVERNMENT: CHAPER 7: POLITICAL PARTIES: ESSENTIAL TO DEMOCRACY Before political parties, candidates were listed alphabetically, and those whose names began with the letters A to F did better than

More information

The Formation of National Party Systems Does it happen with age? Brandon Amash

The Formation of National Party Systems Does it happen with age? Brandon Amash The Formation of National Party Systems Does it happen with age? Brandon Amash A Senior Honors Thesis Submitted to The Department of Political Science University of California, San Diego March 31, 214

More information

Where Have All the Zoku Gone? LDP DM Policy Specialization and Expertise. Robert Pekkanen University of Washington

Where Have All the Zoku Gone? LDP DM Policy Specialization and Expertise. Robert Pekkanen University of Washington Where Have All the Zoku Gone? LDP DM Policy Specialization and Expertise Robert Pekkanen University of Washington pekkanen@u.washington.edu Benjamin Nyblade University of British Columbia bnyblade@politics.ubc.ca

More information

POL-GA Comparative Government and Institutions New York University Spring 2017

POL-GA Comparative Government and Institutions New York University Spring 2017 POL-GA.3501.004 Comparative Government and Institutions New York University Spring 2017 Professor: Hande Mutlu-Eren Class Time: Tuesday 2:00-3:50 PM Office: 303 Class Location: 435 Office hours: Tuesday

More information

Social Rankings in Human-Computer Committees

Social Rankings in Human-Computer Committees Social Rankings in Human-Computer Committees Moshe Bitan 1, Ya akov (Kobi) Gal 3 and Elad Dokow 4, and Sarit Kraus 1,2 1 Computer Science Department, Bar Ilan University, Israel 2 Institute for Advanced

More information

Capture and Governance at Local and National Levels

Capture and Governance at Local and National Levels Capture and Governance at Local and National Levels By PRANAB BARDHAN AND DILIP MOOKHERJEE* The literature on public choice and political economy is characterized by numerous theoretical analyses of capture

More information

Lobbying and Bribery

Lobbying and Bribery Lobbying and Bribery Vivekananda Mukherjee* Amrita Kamalini Bhattacharyya Department of Economics, Jadavpur University, Kolkata 700032, India June, 2016 *Corresponding author. E-mail: mukherjeevivek@hotmail.com

More information

Political Sophistication and Third-Party Voting in Recent Presidential Elections

Political Sophistication and Third-Party Voting in Recent Presidential Elections Political Sophistication and Third-Party Voting in Recent Presidential Elections Christopher N. Lawrence Department of Political Science Duke University April 3, 2006 Overview During the 1990s, minor-party

More information

Political Sophistication and Third-Party Voting in Recent Presidential Elections

Political Sophistication and Third-Party Voting in Recent Presidential Elections Political Sophistication and Third-Party Voting in Recent Presidential Elections Christopher N. Lawrence Department of Political Science Duke University April 3, 2006 Overview During the 1990s, minor-party

More information

The California Primary and Redistricting

The California Primary and Redistricting The California Primary and Redistricting This study analyzes what is the important impact of changes in the primary voting rules after a Congressional and Legislative Redistricting. Under a citizen s committee,

More information

The Provision of Public Goods, and the Matter of the Revelation of True Preferences: Two Views

The Provision of Public Goods, and the Matter of the Revelation of True Preferences: Two Views The Provision of Public Goods, and the Matter of the Revelation of True Preferences: Two Views Larry Levine Department of Economics, University of New Brunswick Introduction The two views which are agenda

More information

Political Parties. The drama and pageantry of national political conventions are important elements of presidential election

Political Parties. The drama and pageantry of national political conventions are important elements of presidential election Political Parties I INTRODUCTION Political Convention Speech The drama and pageantry of national political conventions are important elements of presidential election campaigns in the United States. In

More information

Vote Buying and Clientelism

Vote Buying and Clientelism Vote Buying and Clientelism Dilip Mookherjee Boston University Lecture 18 DM (BU) Clientelism 2018 1 / 1 Clientelism and Vote-Buying: Introduction Pervasiveness of vote-buying and clientelistic machine

More information

Problems with Group Decision Making

Problems with Group Decision Making Problems with Group Decision Making There are two ways of evaluating political systems: 1. Consequentialist ethics evaluate actions, policies, or institutions in regard to the outcomes they produce. 2.

More information

Vote-Buying and Selling

Vote-Buying and Selling The Political Economy of Elections in Uganda: Vote-Buying and Selling Presented during The National Conference on Religion Rights and Peace convened by Human Rights and Peace Centre (HURIPEC) School of

More information

To what extent do the institutions of presidentialism allow voters to hold governments accountable?

To what extent do the institutions of presidentialism allow voters to hold governments accountable? American Political Science Review Vol. 98, No. 3 August 2004 Presidentialism and Accountability for the Economy in Comparative Perspective DAVID SAMUELS University of Minnesota To what extent do the institutions

More information

Congressional Incentives & The Textbook Congress : Representation & Getting Re-Elected

Congressional Incentives & The Textbook Congress : Representation & Getting Re-Elected Congressional Incentives & The Textbook Congress : Representation & Getting Re-Elected Carlos Algara calgara@ucdavis.edu November 13, 2017 Agenda 1 Recapping Party Theory in Government 2 District vs. Party

More information

Corruption and Good Governance

Corruption and Good Governance Corruption and Good Governance Discussion paper 3 Management Development and Governance Division Bureau for Policy and Programme Support United Nations Development Programme New York July 1997 Copyright

More information

Coalition Parties versus Coalitions of Parties: How Electoral Agency Shapes the Political Logic of Costs and Benefits

Coalition Parties versus Coalitions of Parties: How Electoral Agency Shapes the Political Logic of Costs and Benefits Coalition Parties versus Coalitions of Parties: How Electoral Agency Shapes the Political Logic of Costs and Benefits by Kathleen Bawn Department of Political Science UCLA and Frances Rosenbluth Department

More information

Lobbying successfully: Interest groups, lobbying coalitions and policy change in the European Union

Lobbying successfully: Interest groups, lobbying coalitions and policy change in the European Union Lobbying successfully: Interest groups, lobbying coalitions and policy change in the European Union Heike Klüver Postdoctoral Research Fellow Nuffield College, University of Oxford Heike Klüver (University

More information

Minority rights advocacy in the EU: a guide for the NGOs in Eastern partnership countries

Minority rights advocacy in the EU: a guide for the NGOs in Eastern partnership countries Minority rights advocacy in the EU: a guide for the NGOs in Eastern partnership countries «Minority rights advocacy in the EU» 1. 1. What is advocacy? A working definition of minority rights advocacy The

More information

Tzu-chiao Su Chinese Culture University, Taiwan

Tzu-chiao Su Chinese Culture University, Taiwan The Effect of Electoral System and Election Timing on Party System and Government Type: a Cross-Country Study of Presidential and Semi-presidential Democracies Tzu-chiao Su Chinese Culture University,

More information

Electoral Reform Proposal

Electoral Reform Proposal Electoral Reform Proposal By Daniel Grice, JD, U of Manitoba 2013. Co-Author of Establishing a Legal Framework for E-voting 1, with Dr. Bryan Schwartz of the University of Manitoba and published by Elections

More information

THRESHOLDS. Underlying principles. What submitters on the party vote threshold said

THRESHOLDS. Underlying principles. What submitters on the party vote threshold said THRESHOLDS Underlying principles A threshold is the minimum level of support a party needs to gain representation. Thresholds are intended to provide for effective government and ensure that every party

More information

Judicial Elections and Their Implications in North Carolina. By Samantha Hovaniec

Judicial Elections and Their Implications in North Carolina. By Samantha Hovaniec Judicial Elections and Their Implications in North Carolina By Samantha Hovaniec A Thesis submitted to the faculty of the University of North Carolina in partial fulfillment of the requirements of a degree

More information

Coalition Parties versus Coalitions of Parties: How Electoral Agency Shapes the Political Logic of Costs and Benefits

Coalition Parties versus Coalitions of Parties: How Electoral Agency Shapes the Political Logic of Costs and Benefits Coalition Parties versus Coalitions of Parties: How Electoral Agency Shapes the Political Logic of Costs and Benefits by Kathleen Bawn Department of Political Science UCLA and Frances Rosenbluth Department

More information

CAN FAIR VOTING SYSTEMS REALLY MAKE A DIFFERENCE?

CAN FAIR VOTING SYSTEMS REALLY MAKE A DIFFERENCE? CAN FAIR VOTING SYSTEMS REALLY MAKE A DIFFERENCE? Facts and figures from Arend Lijphart s landmark study: Patterns of Democracy: Government Forms and Performance in Thirty-Six Countries Prepared by: Fair

More information

Bachelorproject 2 The Complexity of Compliance: Why do member states fail to comply with EU directives?

Bachelorproject 2 The Complexity of Compliance: Why do member states fail to comply with EU directives? Bachelorproject 2 The Complexity of Compliance: Why do member states fail to comply with EU directives? Authors: Garth Vissers & Simone Zwiers University of Utrecht, 2009 Introduction The European Union

More information

LEARNING OBJECTIVES After studying Chapter 12, you should be able to: 1. Describe the characteristics of our senators and representatives, and the nature of their jobs. 2. Explain what factors have the

More information

The Duma Districts Key to Putin s Power

The Duma Districts Key to Putin s Power The Duma Districts Key to Putin s Power PONARS Policy Memo 290 Henry E. Hale Indiana University and Robert Orttung American University September 2003 When politicians hit the campaign trail and Russians

More information

Chapter 14. The Causes and Effects of Rational Abstention

Chapter 14. The Causes and Effects of Rational Abstention Excerpts from Anthony Downs, An Economic Theory of Democracy. New York: Harper and Row, 1957. (pp. 260-274) Introduction Chapter 14. The Causes and Effects of Rational Abstention Citizens who are eligible

More information

Electoral Threshold, Representation, and Parties Incentives to Form a Bloc.

Electoral Threshold, Representation, and Parties Incentives to Form a Bloc. Electoral Threshold, Representation, and Parties Incentives to Form a Bloc. Andrei Bremzen, Georgy Egorov, Dmitry Shakin This Draft: April 2, 2007 Abstract In most countries with proportional representation

More information

Testing Political Economy Models of Reform in the Laboratory

Testing Political Economy Models of Reform in the Laboratory Testing Political Economy Models of Reform in the Laboratory By TIMOTHY N. CASON AND VAI-LAM MUI* * Department of Economics, Krannert School of Management, Purdue University, West Lafayette, IN 47907-1310,

More information

CHAPTER 9: Political Parties

CHAPTER 9: Political Parties CHAPTER 9: Political Parties Reading Questions 1. The Founders and George Washington in particular thought of political parties as a. the primary means of communication between voters and representatives.

More information

Post-Election Survey Findings: Americans Want the New Congress to Provide a Check on the White House, Follow Facts in Investigations

Post-Election Survey Findings: Americans Want the New Congress to Provide a Check on the White House, Follow Facts in Investigations To: Interested Parties From: Global Strategy Group, on behalf of Navigator Research Re: POST-ELECTION Navigator Research Survey Date: November 19th, 2018 Post-Election Survey Findings: Americans Want the

More information

Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation

Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation S. Roy*, Department of Economics, High Point University, High Point, NC - 27262, USA. Email: sroy@highpoint.edu Abstract We implement OLS,

More information

Political Science 10: Introduction to American Politics Week 10

Political Science 10: Introduction to American Politics Week 10 Political Science 10: Introduction to American Politics Week 10 Taylor Carlson tfeenstr@ucsd.edu March 17, 2017 Carlson POLI 10-Week 10 March 17, 2017 1 / 22 Plan for the Day Go over learning outcomes

More information

Publicizing malfeasance:

Publicizing malfeasance: Publicizing malfeasance: When media facilitates electoral accountability in Mexico Horacio Larreguy, John Marshall and James Snyder Harvard University May 1, 2015 Introduction Elections are key for political

More information

Electoral systems, corruption and satisfaction with democracy

Electoral systems, corruption and satisfaction with democracy Electoral systems, corruption and satisfaction with democracy Vincenzo Memoli Department of Political and Social Sciences University of Catania (Italy) memoli@unict.it Alessandro Pellegata Department of

More information

Research Statement. Jeffrey J. Harden. 2 Dissertation Research: The Dimensions of Representation

Research Statement. Jeffrey J. Harden. 2 Dissertation Research: The Dimensions of Representation Research Statement Jeffrey J. Harden 1 Introduction My research agenda includes work in both quantitative methodology and American politics. In methodology I am broadly interested in developing and evaluating

More information

What to Do about Turnout Bias in American Elections? A Response to Wink and Weber

What to Do about Turnout Bias in American Elections? A Response to Wink and Weber What to Do about Turnout Bias in American Elections? A Response to Wink and Weber Thomas L. Brunell At the end of the 2006 term, the U.S. Supreme Court handed down its decision with respect to the Texas

More information

What criteria should guide electoral system choice?

What criteria should guide electoral system choice? What criteria should guide electoral system choice? Reasoning from principles What do we mean by principles? choices determined by principles -- not vice versa Criteria from New Zealand, Ontario and IDEA

More information

DPA/EAD input to OHCHR draft guidelines on effective implementation of the right to participation in public affairs May 2017

DPA/EAD input to OHCHR draft guidelines on effective implementation of the right to participation in public affairs May 2017 UN Department of Political Affairs (UN system focal point for electoral assistance): Input for the OHCHR draft guidelines on the effective implementation of the right to participate in public affairs 1.

More information

Public Justice in Representation. A CPJ Position Paper on Electoral Reform and Representation

Public Justice in Representation. A CPJ Position Paper on Electoral Reform and Representation Public Justice in Representation A CPJ Position Paper on Electoral Reform and Representation Approved by the Board of Directors: April 16, 2009 Our Vision CPJ is committed to seek human flourishing and

More information

Statement of the Council of Presidents and Prime Ministers of the Americas

Statement of the Council of Presidents and Prime Ministers of the Americas Statement of the Council of Presidents and Prime Ministers of the Americas Financing Democracy: Political Parties, Campaigns, and Elections The Carter Center, Atlanta Georgia March 19, 2003 The Carter

More information

Migrants and external voting

Migrants and external voting The Migration & Development Series On the occasion of International Migrants Day New York, 18 December 2008 Panel discussion on The Human Rights of Migrants Facilitating the Participation of Migrants in

More information

Primary Election Systems. An LWVO Study

Primary Election Systems. An LWVO Study Primary Election Systems An LWVO Study CONSENSUS QUESTIONS with pros and cons Question #1. What do you believe is the MORE important purpose of primary elections? a. A way for political party members alone

More information

EPRDF: The Change in Leadership

EPRDF: The Change in Leadership 1 An Article from the Amharic Publication of the Ethiopian Peoples Revolutionary Democratic Front (EPRDF) ADDIS RAYE (NEW VISION) Hamle/Nehase 2001 (August 2009) edition EPRDF: The Change in Leadership

More information

policy-making. footnote We adopt a simple parametric specification which allows us to go between the two polar cases studied in this literature.

policy-making. footnote We adopt a simple parametric specification which allows us to go between the two polar cases studied in this literature. Introduction Which tier of government should be responsible for particular taxing and spending decisions? From Philadelphia to Maastricht, this question has vexed constitution designers. Yet still the

More information

The Puzzle.. Bureaucratic Reform. Consequently, Answer: Lets make the following simplifying assumptions about politicians and the way the polity works

The Puzzle.. Bureaucratic Reform. Consequently, Answer: Lets make the following simplifying assumptions about politicians and the way the polity works The Puzzle.. Bureaucratic Rem 1. In a modern polity, government agencies ence laws, administer programs Health, education, welfare, immigration, environmental encement, economic management, management

More information

Developing Political Preferences: Citizen Self-Interest

Developing Political Preferences: Citizen Self-Interest Developing Political Preferences: Citizen Self-Interest Carlos Algara calgara@ucdavis.edu October 12, 2017 Agenda 1 Revising the Paradox 2 Abstention Incentive: Opinion Instability 3 Heuristics as Short-Cuts:

More information

SHOULD THE UNITED STATES WORRY ABOUT LARGE, FAST-GROWING ECONOMIES?

SHOULD THE UNITED STATES WORRY ABOUT LARGE, FAST-GROWING ECONOMIES? Chapter Six SHOULD THE UNITED STATES WORRY ABOUT LARGE, FAST-GROWING ECONOMIES? This report represents an initial investigation into the relationship between economic growth and military expenditures for

More information

Partisan Advantage and Competitiveness in Illinois Redistricting

Partisan Advantage and Competitiveness in Illinois Redistricting Partisan Advantage and Competitiveness in Illinois Redistricting An Updated and Expanded Look By: Cynthia Canary & Kent Redfield June 2015 Using data from the 2014 legislative elections and digging deeper

More information