Experimental Investigation of Voting over Common Pool Resources

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Experimental Investigation of Voting over Common Pool Resources"

Transcription

1 Experimental Investigation of Voting over Common Pool Resources Robert Holahan 1 Indiana University-Bloomington Department of Political Science and Workshop in Political Theory and Policy Analysis raholaha@indiana.edu Abstract. Common pool resource systems are governed by a wide variety of institutions designed to promote long run resource viability. Relatively little work has focused on the use of majority rule voting in managing resource stocks. This paper develops a theoretical and experimental framework for assessing the efficiency of majority rule voting in allocating appropriation rights to a group of resource users. By varying the distribution of individual capacities to appropriate, but keeping the aggregate level constant, we find that systems dominated by large scale appropriators collectively extract more of the resource than systems dominated by small scale appropriators, whether or not voting is used. When voting is used, the resulting policies are more extractive under systems dominated by large scale appropriators. Keywords: Common pool resources, experimental economics, majority rule voting 1 Funding for this project was provided by National Science Foundation Doctoral Dissertation Improvement Grant # The author wishes to thank the program officers at NSF for funding the project. In addition, this project would not have been possible without the guidance and suggestions of Elinor Ostrom, James Walker, Bi ll Bianco and Mike Ensley. Experiments were conducted using Z-Tree experiment software and I wish to thank the authors of that program for making it available for use (Fischbacher 2007). Any mistakes are the author s alone.

2 Holahan 2 Common pool resource systems are governed through a variety of institutional frameworks. In the United States and the European Union, for example, policies affecting common pool resources are often made in federal or state legislatures, regional councils, resource user associations, homeowner s associations, and many other organizational structures. In many of these situations, some form of simple majority or super majority rule voting is used to assign individuals appropriation rights over the resource. Despite its increasingly common usage, however, majority rule voting is perhaps one of the least studied and understood mechanisms for assigning resource extraction or appropriation rights. How efficient is majority rule voting at assigning appropriation rights? How does the distribution of individual capacities to appropriate affect vote outcomes? This paper develops an experimental framework in which we study the benefits and limitations of majority rule voting over a shared resource. In particular, we develop an appropriation game with an explicit risk function to participants that models the potential for resource exhaustion and allows us to test the efficiency of majority rule voting over a non-cooperative appropriation game in different situations of homogenous and heterogeneous user capacity. It is our contention that characteristics of common pool resources make them an ideal setting for empirically testing the implications of formal models of majority rule voting. CPRs are shared resources that must be divided among a group of resource users and thus each time a decision on use rights is made, there is political bargaining taking place. Second, these are often low-dimension policy problems. An individual has preferences over how much he individually wants to appropriate and over how much he wants everyone else to appropriate. In the latter situation, this could equally be framed as the individual has a preference over the aggregate risk of overharvesting the system, since the collective appropriation determines the implicit risk

3 Holahan 3 factor. Thus, many CPR settings can easily be identified as a simple two dimensional vote problem. Third, the resource being divided and the policy outcome are often formulated in discrete, numeric terms. For example, a policy might be over the number or weight of fish an individual can catch; or, over the cubic meters of water an individual can use to irrigate; or, over the acres of grass a herder can use to graze. Since many implications of formal theories of majority rule voting are about the range of enactable policies in low-dimensional policy spaces (i.e. Bianco and Sened 2005), CPRs are an excellent area to find real-world data that could be used to test the limitations of our formal theories. As resource systems across the world are facing continued strain of overharvest, it is increasingly important that we understand the mechanics of the majority rule voting institutions that govern a wide array of resource settings. Beyond just voting, however, this study looks at the underlying distribution of preferences or capacities of resource users to understand how these affect aggregate appropriation behavior. We begin to examine this issue by first providing an overview of the literature on CPR governance and highlight the lack of research into voting as a means of decision-making. Next we develop a theoretical model of the preferences, vote decisions, and outcomes of a group of resource users. Using this model as a guide, we then discuss the experimental environment we developed to test the predictions in a controlled environment. Finally, we discuss the results of these experiments and the implications for future research. Background Common pool resources (hereafter CPRs) are a particular class of goods that are both subtractable and only excludable at high cost (Ostrom 1999). Unlike public goods, in which the

4 Holahan 4 use of the good by one does not prevent another from its use, in a CPR the appropriation by one necessarily limits the appropriation by others. Since many CPRs are seasonal (i.e. irrigation water) or are renewable resources from one year to another (i.e. fisheries and forests), the shared nature of the resource setting also means that individual appropriation decisions in a given time period, aggregated across the entire system, produce a particular risk of overharvest or resource collapse. This observation, discussed as early as Gorden (1954), led subsequent scholars to hypothesize about the consequences of individual appropriation over a shared resource. In his influential article on the Tragedy of the Commons, Hardin (1968) argued that rationally self-interested individuals appropriating from a shared common pool resource will exploit the resource to exhaustion. Since the marginal cost to each individual s appropriation decision is shared among all resource users, but the marginal benefit of appropriation accrues solely to the individual, CPR users will always see a net benefit to appropriating one additional unit of resource. As this game is played out across the entire CPR system, Hardin argued, it will naturally lead to overharvest and eventual resource collapse, unless either an external, disinterested entity could intervene and limit individual appropriations, or unless the resource could be privatized. Hardin s theory continued to dominate the thinking on common pool resources for decades until scholars recognized a diversity of resource systems that have managed to persist for long periods of time (Ostrom 1990). Scholars have studied a variety of institutional frameworks to better understand successful CPR management settings. For example, scholars have examined the role of national government intervention (e.g. Terborgh 1999), privatization of the commons (e.g. Tietenberg 2002), religious figures (e.g. Lansing 1991), and specialized courts or consensual arrangements among resource users (Ostrom 1990) in maintaining long-run resource viability. Through these

5 Holahan 5 studies, scholars have found that resource users are not necessarily doomed to a Tragedy of the Commons, but are, at least sometimes, capable of crafting successful management schemes. Once a management scheme has emerged, scholars have found that external, non-ecological, factors like interpersonal relationships, communication, social sanctioning, or embedded cultural knowledge can all have positive effects on the ability of individuals to maintain a consensually agreed upon management scheme. Especially in small communities, the threat of social ostracizing is often sufficient to induce cooperation (Agrawal and Gibson 1999). Little work has focused, however, on the underlying individual preferences of resource users and how these preferences influence consensual agreements before they are crafted. Scholars have found a variety of mechanisms for sustaining cooperation once a system is in place and scholars have posited a variety of design principles for successful institutions (Ostrom 1990), but few have attempted to understand how underlying preferences for resource use influence arrangements before they are finalized. For example, before a group of fishermen agree on limiting catches to a certain amount per boat, does the size of the boats the fishermen use influence the limit that is set? Or, are the catch limits independent of the fishermen s capacity to catch the fish are they based on the ecology of the system? This is a fundamental distinction between systems of governance in which policy is based on the underlying ecology of the system and systems of governance in which policy is based on the underlying capacities of the resource users. It is our contention that the latter case is more often what happens, particularly in the developed world, and that we should therefore be interested in understanding how capacities affect policy outcomes. Laboratory experiments have long been a primary means to study different governance regimes in CPR settings. Ostrom, Gardner, and Walker (1994) developed a simple model of a

6 Holahan 6 generic CPR in which members of a group choose to invest tokens in one of two markets. The first, a private sector, provided a constant return, while the second market returned a nonlinear profit that was decreasing in aggregate group investment. By extending this design to situations of cheap talk, face-to-face communication and sanctioning, scholars have shown the importance of contextual variables to the long run viability of resource management institutions. In an earlier experimental work, Ostrom, Walker and Gardner (1992) had already argued that selforganization of resource users to overcome collective action dilemmas was possible given their self-interest in the resource setting. The results of these early appropriation games showed that the Tragedy of the Commons is not inevitable, but that some institutions perform better than others. Many such studies into CPR success and failures focus on case studies from the developing world or modeling local, village-based resource management schemes. In much of the developed world, however, CPRs are managed on a much larger scale and through large bureaucracies, legislatures, commissions, or resource user associations that are more complex than small scale resource system. For example, while a village of fishermen along the Colombian coast may have successful management institutions that rely on agreement among all the resource users or at least a large consensus of resource users, solely relying on interpersonal relationships to determine appropriation policy over the European Common Fisheries policy, for example, is unrealistic. Instead, many settings in the developed world rely on majority rule voting to determine CPR management policies. Examples of majority rule voting over CPR systems are plentiful. The Maine lobster fishing industry, for example, uses state sanctioned exclusive management zones that are overseen by elected boards of lobster fishing representatives. These boards set catch limits and

7 Holahan 7 technological requirements (net size, etc.) for the zones through majority rule voting at council meetings (Acheson 2003). Until recent reforms with the Common Fisheries Policy, the European Council of Ministers also used majority rule voting to determine the Total Allowable Catches of member states over specific species in defined fishing zones. In the United States, ocean fishery policy, particularly the catch limits and sizes, are decided by the eight Ocean Fishery Commissions, 17-member boards of industry, recreation and government representatives, that use majority rule voting 2. In ground water management, many states or regional governments have set up water management boards, like the West Basin Municipal Water District in which the commission uses standard majority rule voting procedures to implement regional water policy (Blomquist 1992). Despite the variety of such situations, majority rule voting as a management institution remains woefully understudied in the broader literature on CPRs. Two recent experimental studies, however, have examined the role of majority rule voting in a CPR setting. Walker, Gardner, Herr and Ostrom (2000) develop a voting game in which groups of 7 individuals vote over precise appropriations for each of the seven members. Subjects share an identical cost and benefit function. In their game, subjects receive a fixed profit for each token appropriated, but then are charged a nonlinear cost that declines with aggre gate group withdrawal. Similar to the current study, subjects first play a ten-period non-cooperative game and then play a ten-period voting game. Each subject makes a proposal for the precise appropriation each member of the seven person group will receive and then subjects vote over the proposals. They find that the introduction of voting over a non-cooperative game increases group efficiency, but that in many cases subjects resort to a strategy of minimum winning 2 The Ocean Fisheries Commission s decisions are actually just recommendations that must be approved by the Secretary of Commerce. However, the Secretary s approval is considered a formality for the most part, and thus policy is de facto determined through majority rule voting by thes e Commissions.

8 Holahan 8 coalitions. In these instances groups of 4 subjects vote to appropriate large amounts of tokens among themselves, but shut out the other 3 members from appropriating anything. Margreiter, Sutter and Dittrich (2005) expand on the original Walker et al (2000) design by incorporating heterogeneous costs into the profit function. These authors point out that most users of a CPR are not all equal in capacity; some have larger boats or some may have better appropriation technology. They find that homogenous and heterogeneous groups show no difference in aggregate appropriation when playing the uncoordinated game, but that homogenous groups more easily reach a majority rule decision over appropriation when voting is allowed. In the latter case, proposals that successfully are implemented using majority rule are closer to social optimum than when no decision is reached or when the uncoordinated game is played. Serious questions remain about the applicability of the Walker et al (2000) and Margreiter (2005) designs to real-world situations of CPR voting. While it may be the case that in small scale CPR settings individuals vote over individual appropriation rights, it s not so clear that this is how many of the institutions in developed countries operate. For example, fisheries are usually regulated through the use of Total Allowable Catch (TAC) that either specify some aggregate fishery-wide seasonal quota or that sub-divided an aggregate quota into individual rights to catch a pre-determined amount of fish. Furthermore, we know that in many real-world settings the option to shut-out some resource users is infeasible or illegal. For example, Acheson (2003) discusses how in Maine regional lobster fishery councils use majority rule voting to set boat catch limits, but these boards must allow all pre-existing fishing boats to continue using the resource. The experiments discussed in this paper more closely model the

9 Holahan 9 TAC process by excluding the possibility of shutting out some users with a dominate Minimum Winning Coalition. Beyond just fisheries, however, there are other reasons to believe a new model of CPR appropriation is necessary to understand real-world processes. For example, several scholars have pointed out that national budgets are similar in kind to common pool resources and have used the CPR model to understand bargaining over budget appropriations (e.g. Shepsle and Weingast 1985). In the Congressional legislative process that leads to omnibus appropriations, individual legislators each fight for particularized district benefits ( pork ). Because it is not the case that Minimum Winning Coalitions, in this instance the majority party, shut out benefits to minority party members, we have reason to suspect the applicability of Walker et al s original model design. In the current paper, our addition of a probabilistic destruction of the resource mimics the potential for default or over-spending on the part of the legislature and the inclusion of all group members in appropriation, even after a vote, more closely mirrors real budgetary processes. The study of common pool resources has come a long way over the past two decades toward identifying key variables that make long run resource sustainability more likely. However, most of this research has looked at small scale resource systems or assumed that policy can be decided with ecological considerations in mind. In the next section, we develop an updated model of the CPR setting in which a rational agent can favor limiting aggregate appropriation even if this comes at a personal cost to himself. We then discuss how this insight can be used to develop a new voting game over CPR appropriation in which the distribution of capacities over appropriation may influence policy outcomes.

10 Holahan 10 Theory We begin with the assumption that preferences over common pool resources are naturally multi-dimensional, but that a two-dimensional model captures a significant portion of the variance. Often scholars assume that individuals have preferences over only their own personal appropriation. For example, Hardin (1968) assumed that individuals cared only about personal benefits without considering costs because these were too diffuse throughout the system to be individually tangible. Because of this assumption, his model necessarily predicts resource system collapse. However, if we allow individuals to have a preference over both her personal appropriation and over the aggregate appropriation of the entire resource system, then Hardin s model begins to falter. Similarly, we can build a model that better explains the results of Ostrom (1990), among others, that institutional frameworks can sustain resource systems over multiple generations. In particular, if there is not a second dimension of preferences, it is unlikely that institutional emergence will occur since there are no individual incentives to work with others in the system. A rational agent should be concerned about the consequences of over-appropriation. If a system is over-appropriated, there could be resource collapse at the extreme or at the least a lower available resource stock to appropriate. It seems reasonable to assume, given this situation, that a rational agent assigns an array of probabilities of resource collapse that correspond to different system-wide levels of appropriation. A rational individual would then utilize this personal array to determine a profit maximizing collective appropriation level that balances his own personal risk attitude. The more risk-taking an individual, the more likely that individual will prefer larger collective appropriation levels, especially if the collective appropriation is divided up among the different resource users. On one level, then, his

11 Holahan 11 preference over his personal appropriation level is a function of risk attitude as well. What is clear, however, is that using this simple model of a rational agent, we can identify two dimensions of preference: personal and collective appropriation. The latter is a simple transformation of his risk attitude and the former is a combination of risk attitude and capacity. Underlying the individual preferences for a CPR is the individual capacity one has to appropriate from the resource. For example, in a fishery, boats have different hold sizes and in irrigation farmers have different acreages. Should we expect someone with a large-hold fishing boat to favor the same levels of appropriation as one with a small-hold fishing boat? Indeed, if we assume that individuals want to individually appropriate as much of a CPR as is technically feasible for himself, then we can identify his personal capacity, or capacity, as a suitable substitute for the first dimension of preferences over the resource use. Thus far we have discussed a rational agent s preference for collective withdrawal as being a substitute for his risk-preference. But are all collective withdrawals the same? If 3 appropriators in a given resource setting are capable of collectively appropriating 10 fish, does it matter how the individual capacities of the resource users are distributed? Ehrhart, Gardner, von Hagen and Keser (2007) asked a similar question about budget processes. In their experiment, the authors investigate whether it makes a difference if a budget process is top-down or bottomup i.e. if the aggregate budget amount is determined and then divided among the group, or if the aggregate budget amount is determined by individual funding requests from within the group. They find that top-down processes lead to overall smaller budgets. One area they stop short of investigating, however, is differences in final policy outcome resulting from different distribution of subject ideal points.

12 Holahan 12 Distribution of preferences matters in a voting situation. In formal theories of the voting process, outcomes are predicted through Euclidian distances between policy proposals and individual preferences. As the distribution of preferences becomes skewed, outcomes vary. In a uni-dimensional model, the distribution of preferences determines the median voter. In a multidimensional space, it determines the Core (e.g. Fiorina and Plott 1978) or the Uncovered Set (Miller 1981). Understanding how these distributions lead to different policy outcomes in a CPR setting allows us to better craft institutions to reduce the upward pressure on policy when the dominant coalition of resource users want large appropriation. In our experiments, we model a resource system in which five users have an aggregate capacity to appropriate 200 resource units. In the first treatment, Homogenous Distribution, each of the five users has an individual capacity to harvest 40 units. In the other two treatments, however, we vary the individual capacities. In the Small Boats Dominant treatment, three users can appropriate 34 units each and two users can appropriate 49 units each. Finally in the third, Large Boats Dominant treatment two users can appropriate 34 units each and three users can appropriate 44 units each. We assign a known risk factor to over-appropriating in which each unit harvested above 125 collective units. In particular, each unit appropriated above 125 leads to a 1% chance of complete over-exhaustion. Thus, if the users collectively withdraw 150 units there is a 25% chance of over-exhaustion and collapse, and so on. If the resource is overappropriated, subjects in the group all earn $0 for the round. If the resource is not overappropriated, however, subjects earn $0.05 per unit individually appropriated and are charged a $0.02 opportunity cost for each unit not appropriated short of their capacity. Subjec ts play a 10- round game with no coordination and then play a second 10-round game in which they are able to vote over a maximum cap of individual appropriation.

13 Holahan 13 In particular, subjects are asked to each make a proposal over a Maximum Individual Withdrawal that limits the appropriation of all group members. If they successfully vote for one of the proposals, it is costlessly and perfectly implemented so that each subject appropriates either his personal Capacity or the group s Maximum Individual Withdrawal, whichever is less. In this sense they are voting for an individual Total Allowable Catch. If the TAC is above the individual Capacity, it doesn t matter to the individual because he still can only catch what he is feasibly able to keep. If the TAC is below the capacity, however, he may only appropriate up to that level. A more detailed explanation of how the sessions operated is discussed in the next section. In this simple design, there are significant differences in the Nash Equilibrium and Social Optimum strategies between the voting and non-voting stages, but are not significant differences across treatments. Most of the variation between the voting and non-voting stages comes from the imposition of a symmetric policy proposal if a proposal receives a majority of support it is implemented equally on all group members. When subjects are not allowed to vote over appropriation levels, the social optimum occurs when each of the five subjects appropriates 28 units, but the Nash Equilibrium is an appropriation in which two subjects appropriate 40 units and the other three subjects each appropriate 39 units. In all three treatments with voting, however, the Social Optimum and Nash Equilibrium both coincide to a proposal of appropriating either 27 or 28 units per individual. If it is the case that collective withdrawal levels are different across treatments, then we would suspect that subjects are not just playing a Nash or Social Optimum strategy. Instead, there would be some evidence that the fundamental underlying distribution of capacities leads to different levels of collective withdrawal, which might indicate different tolerances for risk in

14 Holahan 14 different distributions. One possible strategy that subjects might play in the voting stage is a simple uni-dimensional median voter strategy. In other words, if the resource setting is fundamentally a one-dimensional choice space, we should expect that the median voter s capacity will be implemented. In this case, we would expect successful proposals of 34, 40, and 44 in the Small Boats Dominant, Homogenous Distribution, and Large Boats Dominant treatments, respectively. We hypothesize that during the voting stage the Large Boat Dominant treatment will, all else equal, have higher collective withdrawals than the Homogenous Distribution and Small Boats Dominant treatments. This is because there is greater upward pressure to withdraw larger individual quantities when the dominant coalition consists of large capacities. These three individuals can successfully pass a policy proposal that favors them at the expense of the smaller capacity appropriators. What is not so clear, however, is whether we should expect differences in collective withdrawals during the non-voting stage. Even though the same dominant coalition exists, there is no mechanism for coordination in the non-voting stage of the experiment, so individuals make a personal withdrawal decision based solely on individual preferences for earnings and risk. It is not clear why, on the whole, we would expect a difference among the treatments in the uncoordinated setting, since the aggregate capacities are the same. In the next section we describe in detail the procedures used to run the experiments and discuss the rationale for why we chose some of the characteristics. Since we are particularly interested in the collective withdrawal levels as a proxy for sustainable, long run policy outcomes, we pay particular attention to what collective withdrawals groups make.

15 Holahan 15 Procedures Experiments took place during February and March 2009 at the Interdisciplinary Experimental Laboratory at Indiana University-Bloomington. Subjects were undergraduate students at Indiana University, recruited using a pre-existing database of undergraduate students that had voluntarily signed up to receive notification of experimental opportunities. The treatments were programmed by the author using Z-Tree software, a freeware program designed to allow easy programming for a variety of experimental economics designs (Fischbacher 2006). As subjects arrived at the lab, they were asked to read an informed consent statement that explained they would be participating in a group decision-making experiment. Subjects were also informed at this point that they would receive a $10 show-up fee, to be paid with earnings at the end of the experiment. Experimental sessions were conducted with either 2 or 3 five-person groups at a time, so that individuals could not be certain which other subjects were in their group. Once 10 or 15 subjects had arrived, they were escorted into the computer room and sat at individual computer terminals separated by dividers. Instructions were read aloud and subjects were also asked to read along on their computer screen (a copy of the instructions is available in the appendix). Subjects were told that they would first play a game for 10 rounds and then would play a separate game for another 10 rounds. Instructions were then read for the non-voting stage. After the first stage was finished, new instructions were read for the voting stage. By allowing subjects to participate in a noncooperative appropriation game first, this allowed them to become somewhat familiar with the characteristics of the choice space and thus allowed for more informed voting later on. In addition, the inclusion of the baseline stage allows us to see if differences across treatments are

16 Holahan 16 solely attributable to differences in voting, or whether there are simply fundamental differences in the treatments themselves. Subjects were told that they would be making a decision over how many tokens to withdraw from a shared pool of tokens in each round. It was made clear that each round was an independent event, that the pool of available tokens reset each round, and that therefore there was no carry over from round to round. We then explained in detail how subjects would be making money. In each round, subjects could collectively withdraw up to 125 tokens without any risk of over-drawing the resource. However, for each token collectively withdrawn above 125 tokens there was a 1% chance that the resource would be over-drawn and all subjects in the group would earn $0 for the round if this happened. In order to determine if an over-draw occurs, subjects were informed that each round the computer would create a Chance of Over-Draw equal to the collective withdrawal minus 125 and then draw a random number from 0 to 100. If the random number was less than or equal to the Chance of Over-Draw, subjects will have over-drawn the pool of tokens and earn $0 for the round. Subjects were able to see the collective group withdrawal, corresponding Chance of Over-Draw and the randomly generated number each period to ensure them that the experimenter had no control over the outcome. In addition, subjects were given a copy of a table that listed each possible collective withdrawal level and the correspond Chance of Over-Draw, to ensure that everyone could easily calculate the risk of overdraw. We are particularly interested in how the distribution of preferences over a CPR affects vote outcomes. Since we cannot adequately assign preferences per se, we instead gave each subject a capacity that represented their maximum individual token withdrawal. In the first

17 Holahan 17 treatment, Homogenous Distribution, subjects are homogenous in capacity. Subjects in this treatment were each assigned an individual capacity of 40 tokens. In the second treatment, Small Boats Dominant, three members of the group had an individual capacity of 34 and two members of the group had an individual capacity of 49. Finally, in the third treatment, Large Boats Dominant, three members of the group had an individual capacity of 44 and two members of the group had an individual capacity of 34. As discussed in the previous section, we view preferences as a two-dimensional choice space in which an individual has a preference over his individual withdrawal and a preference over the aggregate withdrawal of all CPR users. To operationalize this view in the context of a CPR setting, we assign each individual a Capacity that represents the maximum number of tokens an individual may withdraw in a given round. In addition, to represent the opportunity cost of not utilizing full capacity, subjects incurred a cost of $0.02 per token not taken up to the capacity. Not only did this cost work as an opportunity cost, however, but it also was a method by which to ensure that the capacity was a tangible ideal withdrawal point for subjects. In this sense we hoped to bring our experiments into line with spatial experiments of majority rule voting in which subject payments are dependent on the distance from their ideal point to outcome (e.g. Baron and Ferejohn 1989). In each treatment, subjects were informed of the distribution of capacities in their group, but were not informed which particular individual had which capacity. At the beginning of each round in the baseline game, subjects were asked to withdraw tokens simultaneously, but without interaction from one another. Each subject would enter an amount up to their personal capacity level and then they saw a screen that listed their individual

18 Holahan 18 withdrawal decision, the collective group withdrawal level and then their profit for the round and their profit for the experiment to that point. After the first 10-rounds were completed, subjects were read a second set of instructions that described the voting stage of the experiment. They were informed that for the last 10 rounds of the experiment they had the opportunity to enact a Maximum Individual Withdrawal that would be perfectly and costlessly implemented on the entire group. In order to keep the results of the voting stage as comparable to the non-voting stage as possible, subjects were told that if a Maximum Individual Withdrawal level was successfully implemented through majority rule voting, that each individual would automatically withdraw either this amount or his personal Capacity, whichever was less. Thus, subjects do not necessarily withdraw a symmetric amount in the voting stage for example, if the Maximum Individual Withdrawal was 35 in the Large Boats Dominant treatment, the three individuals with a Capacity of 44 would withdraw 35 tokens and the two individuals with a Capacity of 34 would only withdraw 34 tokens. Similar to the first 10 rounds, they were informed that the collective withdrawal level would determine a Chance of Over-Draw and that they would also be charged $0.02 per token they failed to withdraw up to their Capacity. During the voting stage of the experiments subjects were asked to first make a proposal for the Maximum Individual Withdrawal. After everyone had submitted a proposal, each subject saw all 5 proposals for her group and was asked to vote for one of them. If two or more subjects made the same proposal, this was treated as one proposal and votes for either were consolidated together. If a majority of subjects (3 or more) voted for a particular proposal level, this was implemented in the manner discussed above. If none of the five proposals received a majority of

19 Holahan 19 support, then subjects reverted to the uncoordinated game played in the first stage of the experiment. Majority rule voting does not take place under a unitary set of procedures. Rather, there has been considerable attention paid to how different institutional procedures influence vote outcomes. The purpose of these experiments is not to determine the benefit of one set of procedures over another, nor to determine the optimal procedures to crafting sustainable outcomes, but rather to understand how voting can, at its root, mediate risky behavior in common pool resource settings. Therefore, we chose a specific set of institutions that mimic real-world common pool resource conditions and kept these institutions constant across the different treatments. Unlike many policy areas in which the timing of final passage makes little to no difference in the effect of the policy, common pool resource harvesting often occurs seasonally and the level of harvesting one season may have dramatic consequences for the amount harvested the next. If the decision making body of the resource system fails to implement a cap on fishery catch levels, forestry harvests, or cattle grazing acres, for example, then the reversion policy is followed until such a policy can be enacted. Thus, there is a natural finite time-frame in which the policy must be agreed upon, after which point regulations for that particular season are meaningless. To capture this idea, we implement a reversion policy, that is implemented in the event that no majority vote is reached, equal to the baseline uncoordinated game. This is also the procedure used in Walker et. al (2000) and Margreiter et al (2005). At the end of the 20 th round, subjects were told the experiment was over and were asked to fill out a brief questionnaire while the experimenter prepared payments.

20 Holahan 20 Results Results from the experiments are still preliminary, as we have not yet fully exploited the dataset gathered in the experiments. To date, we have run 40 subjects in the SBD treatment (8 groups), 40 subjects in the LBD treatment (8 groups) and 30 subjects in the Homogenous Distribution treatment (6 groups). The data analysis that follows in this section focuses primarily on aggregate by-period results, as we have not yet been able to investigate some individual-level hypotheses to be addressed in subsequent research. In addition, the analysis focuses on differences between the SBD and LBD treatments, as analysis on the Homogenous Distribution treatments is still preliminary. The first question to be addressed is whether or not subjects play a uni-dimensional policy game or not. If indeed subjects view the game as a simple choice space about individual withdrawal, then we should expect that successful proposals in the voting game coincide with the uni-dimensional median voter. This is not the case, however. In the SBD treatment, the median voter s capacity is 34 and in the LBD the median voter s capacity is 44. Table 1 lists the successful proposals, i.e. those proposals that were successfully enacted with majority rule voting, and frequency that these proposals occur. In the SBD treatment, the most commonly enacted proposal was 30, while in the LBD treatment the most commonly enacted proposal was 32, both far below the median voter s capacity. In both treatments the distribution of successful proposals is statistically significantly different from the predictions of the median voter model. Table 1. Incidence of Successful Proposals Small Boats Dominant Treatment Large Boats Dominant Treatment Proposal Count Proposal Count

21 Holahan So, if preferences are perfectly aligned with capacity (which is a big assumption), then we have evidence of a multi-dimensional policy space, consistent with our theory that incorporates risk preferences. Another interesting finding is that LBD treatments enact larger successful proposals than SBD treatments. In particular, the average successful proposal in the LBD treatment is 30.48, whereas it is only in the SBD treatment (significant at the.01 level). This may indicate that LBD treatments are more tolerant of large aggregate withdrawals than in SBD treatments. Further evidence for this can be seen in looking at the average collective withdrawal per period or per stage for both treatments. There is a statistically significant difference between treatments on the average collective withdrawal (p-value <.01), but there is not a significant difference within treatments between stages. Table 2 lists the average withdrawal in the SBD and LBD treatments for the non-voting stage, the voting-stage, and then disaggregates between successful votes and failed votes. One result is immediately striking: In both treatments, there is no statistical difference between the collective withdrawals in periods with a successful vote and the non-voting stages. Only when we incorporate failed vote periods do the voting-stage results increase significantly over non-voting. One explanation for this finding is that subjects vote for policies that mimic their strategies without voting. If a proposal fails, however, the subjects may be playing a punishment strategy by withdrawing larger quantities of tokens following the failed vote.

22 Holahan 22 Table 2. Average Withdrawal Levels Aggregated by Stage and Successful vs. Failed Votes, Standard Deviations in Brackets Small Boats Dominant Treatment Large Boats Dominant Treatment Homogenous Distribution Treatment All Periods (1-20) (17.09) (14.37) (13.47) Non-Voting Periods (1-10) (17.09) (14.61) (12.28) Periods with Successful Vote (16.84) (13.88) (14.26) Periods without a Successful Vote (14.17) (10.58) (11.55) Notice also that the difference between treatments increases in the voting stage relative to the non-voting stage of the treatments. Figure 1 below provides the average withdrawal rates across the two treatments by period. Notice that the LBD treatment withdraws more in aggregate than the SBD treatment in all every period. One final question to be addressed concerns the frequency of reaching a successful vote. Margreiter et al (2005) find that the frequency of successful votes is higher in homogenous groups than in groups with heterogeneous costs. Table 3 lists the frequency of reaching a successful majority proposal during voting stages.

23 Holahan 23 Table 3. Frequency of Reaching a Successful Vote LBD SBD HT Frequency # Periods Unlike Margreiter et al (2005), we find no evidence that homogeneous subjects managed to reach a successful proposal more often than heterogeneous groups. Indeed, the only statistically significant difference is between the SBD treatment and the other two. In our study it appears that small group dominant settings are more capable of reaching agreement than either a large group dominant setting or a homogenous distribution. Conclusions and Discussion In the experiments presented here, we allow resource users to vote. This is not necessarily what happens in modern democracies, but in some sense it is. For example, the lobster fishery councils in Maine are comprised of elected lobster fishermen (Acheson 2003), US Ocean Fisheries Commissions are comprised of industry and recreational interests, and many smaller scale situations use some form of explicit or implicit voting among users to set resource limits. Legitimate criticism of these experiments could be that resource users themselves are rarely the individuals actually voting over appropriation. The experiments presented here have shown preliminary evidence that differing the distribution of user capacities can have significant consequences for aggregate appropriations. However, no evidence was found that voting by itself produces significantly different aggregate appropriations within treatments than an uncoordinated game. Finally, evidence suggests that

24 Holahan 24 users are indeed playing a multiple dimension voting game when considering group withdrawal levels. Further study is needed before broad claims can be made about the results so far. In the coming weeks, additional sessions are being performed to get at least a reasonable sample of 30 individuals per treatment. Once that is completed, additional statistical analysis can be completed, including panel-level analysis of individual behavior. For example, we would like to know better how individuals with a capacity of 34 function in both the Small Boats Dominant and Large Boats Dominant treatments. If these individuals behave similarly in both treatments, but aggregate withdrawals remain significantly different across treatments, this would seem to indicate that most of the variance occurs because of the dominant coalition in the voting game.

25 Holahan 25 Works Cited Acheson, James M Capturing the Commons: Devising Institutions to Manage the Maine Lobster Industry. Hanover, NH: University Press of New England. Agrawal, Arun and Clark Gibson Enchantment and Disenchantment: The Role of Community in Natural Resource Conservation. World Development 27(4): Baron, David and John Ferejohn Bargaining in Legislatures. American Political Science Review 83(4) Bianco, William and Itai Sened Uncovering Evidence of Conditional Party Government: Reassessing Majority Party Influence in Congress and State Legislatures. American Political Science Review 99: Blomquist, Bill Dividing the Waters. ICS Press: San Francisco. Ehrhart, Karl-Martin, Roy Gardner, Jurgen von Hagen, and Claudia Keser Budget Processes: Theory and Experimental Evidence. Games and Economic Behavior 59(2): Fiorina, Morris P. and Charles R. Plott Committee Decisions under Majority Rule: An Experimental Study. The American Political Science Review 72(2): Fischbacher, Urs z-tree: Zurich Toolbox for Ready-made Economic Experiments. Experimental Economics 10(2): Gordon, H. Scott The Economic Theory of a Common-Property Resource: The Fishery. The Journal of Political Economy 62(2): Hardin, Garret The Tragedy of the Commons. Science 162: Lansing, J. Stephen Priests and Programmers: Technologies of Power in the Engineered Landscape of Bali. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Margreiter, Magdalena, Matthias Sutter and Dennis Dittrich Individual and Collective Choice and Voting in Common Pool Resource Problem with Heterogeneous Actors. Environmental and Resource Economics 32: Ostrom, Elinor Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press. Ostrom, Elinor Coping with Tragedies of the Commons. Annual Review of Political Science 2: Ostrom, Elinor, Roy Gardner, and James Walker Covenants With and Without a Sword: Self-Governance is Possible. American Political Science Review 86: Ostrom, Elinor, Roy Gardner, and James Walker Rules, Games, and Common-Pool Resources. Ann Arbor: The University of Michigan Press. Shepsle, Kenneth and Barry Weingast Legislative Politics and Budget Outcomes. In Federal Budget Policy in the 1980 s, G. Mills and J. Palmer, Eds. Washington DC: Urban Institute Press: Tietenberg, Tom The Tradable Permits Approach to Protecting the Commons: What Have We Learned? In The Drama of the Commons. National Research Council, Committee on the Human Dimensions of Global Change. Washington, D.C.: National Academy Press Walker, James, Roy Gardner, Andrew Herr, and Elinor Ostrom Collective Choice in the Commons: Experimental Results on Proposed Allocation Rules and Votes. The Economic Journal 110:

26 Holahan 26 Instructions Start. Appendix: Instructions Used Welcome! At this point you are not permitted to speak to other people in the room or to look around at other people's computers. Please turn off your cell phones and put other work away. You have already earned $10 by participating in this experiment, which will last about an hour. You may earn more money, however, depending on the choices you make individually and the choices everyone else in your group makes collectively. Please read along on screen as I read aloud. Please do not continue to the next screen until I say. You have been randomly assigned to a group of 5 people. Each member of your group will be making identical, but separate, decisions over how many tokens to withdraw from a shared pool of 250 tokens. Each of these tokens has a potential real-cash value of $0.05. When a round starts, you will be entering how many tokens you want to withdraw into the computer where prompted and then will wait for the other four members of your group to do the same. After that a screen will display with your earnings for the round. There are 20 rounds of decision making in this experiment. The directions on the following pages apply to the first 10 rounds. After each group has finished the first 10 rounds, you will be giving new instructions for the second set of 10 rounds. (Please Click ok to Continue) ///NEW SCREEN/// During each of the first 10 rounds of the experiment you will be deciding how many tokens you wish to withdraw from a pool of tokens that is shared by all 5 members of your group. You will make your decision of how many tokens to withdraw privately and at the same time as the other members of your group. At the start of each round, the pool of available tokens is reset and you will make another withdrawal decision. Each round is an independent event. If your group collectively withdraws more than 125 tokens, then there is a chance that you will over-draw and that the pool of tokens is worth $0. In this event, everyone in your group will earn $0 for that round. The likelihood that you over-draw increases with each token collectively withdrawn above 125. In particular, there is a 1% chance of over-drawing for each token withdrawn above 125. Thus, if your group withdraws 175 tokens collectively there is a 25% ( = 25) chance that you will over-draw for the round; if you withdraw 189 tokens collectively there is a 39% ( = 39) chance that you will over-harvest for the round, and so on. Please refer to the handout if you want to know what percentage chance of over-drawing there is for a corresponding collective withdrawal. Notice that if your group withdraws 125 tokens or fewer, then you are guaranteed that all of the tokens you individually withdraw are worth money. If you have any questions so far, please raise your hand. If you are satisfied with the instructions so far, please press Continue.

Common-Pool Resources: Over Extraction and Allocation Mechanisms

Common-Pool Resources: Over Extraction and Allocation Mechanisms Common-Pool Resources: Over Extraction and Allocation Mechanisms James M. Walker Department of Economics *Ostrom Workshop in Political Theory and Policy Analysis Indiana University Jim Walker Short Course

More information

Supporting Information Political Quid Pro Quo Agreements: An Experimental Study

Supporting Information Political Quid Pro Quo Agreements: An Experimental Study Supporting Information Political Quid Pro Quo Agreements: An Experimental Study Jens Großer Florida State University and IAS, Princeton Ernesto Reuben Columbia University and IZA Agnieszka Tymula New York

More information

Experimental economics and public choice

Experimental economics and public choice Experimental economics and public choice Lisa R. Anderson and Charles A. Holt June 2002 Prepared for the Encyclopedia of Public Choice, Charles Rowley, ed. There is a well-established tradition of using

More information

The Citizen Candidate Model: An Experimental Analysis

The Citizen Candidate Model: An Experimental Analysis Public Choice (2005) 123: 197 216 DOI: 10.1007/s11127-005-0262-4 C Springer 2005 The Citizen Candidate Model: An Experimental Analysis JOHN CADIGAN Department of Public Administration, American University,

More information

Solving the "Tragedy of the Commons": An Alternative to Privatization*

Solving the Tragedy of the Commons: An Alternative to Privatization* Solving the "Tragedy of the Commons": An Alternative to Privatization* Irwin F. Lipnowski Department of Economics University of Manitoba September, 1991 For presentation at the Second Annual Meeting of

More information

Foundations of the Ostrom workshop: institutional analysis, polycentricity, and self-governance of the commons

Foundations of the Ostrom workshop: institutional analysis, polycentricity, and self-governance of the commons Public Choice (2010) 143: 293 301 DOI 10.1007/s11127-010-9626-5 Foundations of the Ostrom workshop: institutional analysis, polycentricity, and self-governance of the commons Michael D. McGinnis James

More information

Coalition Formation and Selectorate Theory: An Experiment - Appendix

Coalition Formation and Selectorate Theory: An Experiment - Appendix Coalition Formation and Selectorate Theory: An Experiment - Appendix Andrew W. Bausch October 28, 2015 Appendix Experimental Setup To test the effect of domestic political structure on selection into conflict

More information

1 The Drama of the Commons

1 The Drama of the Commons 1 The Drama of the Commons Thomas Dietz, Nives Dolšak, Elinor Ostrom, and Paul C. Stern Pages contained here from the original document pag 3-36 The tragedy of the commons is a central concept in human

More information

Global Common Resources How to Manage Shared Properties

Global Common Resources How to Manage Shared Properties Global Common Resources How to Manage Shared Properties Jesper Larsson Agrarian history, Department of Urban and Rural Development, SLU The Global Economy Environment, Development and Globalization CEMUS

More information

Are Second-Best Tariffs Good Enough?

Are Second-Best Tariffs Good Enough? Are Second-Best Tariffs Good Enough? Alan V. Deardorff The University of Michigan Paper prepared for the Conference Celebrating Professor Rachel McCulloch International Business School Brandeis University

More information

Common Pool Resources

Common Pool Resources Common Pool Resources In memory of 1933-2012 Theory & Evidence on Common Pool Resource Regimes Back to the Future: Reclaiming the Commons 12 november Real World Economics Amsterdam Introduction: An example

More information

Methodology. 1 State benchmarks are from the American Community Survey Three Year averages

Methodology. 1 State benchmarks are from the American Community Survey Three Year averages The Choice is Yours Comparing Alternative Likely Voter Models within Probability and Non-Probability Samples By Robert Benford, Randall K Thomas, Jennifer Agiesta, Emily Swanson Likely voter models often

More information

A Theory of Spoils Systems. Roy Gardner. September 1985

A Theory of Spoils Systems. Roy Gardner. September 1985 A Theory of Spoils Systems Roy Gardner September 1985 Revised October 1986 A Theory of the Spoils System Roy Gardner ABSTRACT In a spoils system, it is axiomatic that "to the winners go the spoils." This

More information

Experimental Economics, Environment and Energy Lecture 3: Commons and public goods: tragedies and solutions. Paolo Crosetto

Experimental Economics, Environment and Energy Lecture 3: Commons and public goods: tragedies and solutions. Paolo Crosetto Lecture 3: Commons and public goods: tragedies and solutions A simple example Should we invest to avoid climate change? Imagine there are (just) two countries, France and the USA. they can choose to (costly)

More information

Political Economics II Spring Lectures 4-5 Part II Partisan Politics and Political Agency. Torsten Persson, IIES

Political Economics II Spring Lectures 4-5 Part II Partisan Politics and Political Agency. Torsten Persson, IIES Lectures 4-5_190213.pdf Political Economics II Spring 2019 Lectures 4-5 Part II Partisan Politics and Political Agency Torsten Persson, IIES 1 Introduction: Partisan Politics Aims continue exploring policy

More information

Social Rankings in Human-Computer Committees

Social Rankings in Human-Computer Committees Social Rankings in Human-Computer Committees Moshe Bitan 1, Ya akov (Kobi) Gal 3 and Elad Dokow 4, and Sarit Kraus 1,2 1 Computer Science Department, Bar Ilan University, Israel 2 Institute for Advanced

More information

International Environmental Agreements with Endogenous Minimum Participation and the Role of Inequality

International Environmental Agreements with Endogenous Minimum Participation and the Role of Inequality International Environmental Agreements with Endogenous Minimum Participation and the Role of Inequality David M. McEvoy Department of Economics Appalachian State University Todd L. Cherry Department of

More information

Classical papers: Osborbe and Slivinski (1996) and Besley and Coate (1997)

Classical papers: Osborbe and Slivinski (1996) and Besley and Coate (1997) The identity of politicians is endogenized Typical approach: any citizen may enter electoral competition at a cost. There is no pre-commitment on the platforms, and winner implements his or her ideal policy.

More information

Modeling Political Information Transmission as a Game of Telephone

Modeling Political Information Transmission as a Game of Telephone Modeling Political Information Transmission as a Game of Telephone Taylor N. Carlson tncarlson@ucsd.edu Department of Political Science University of California, San Diego 9500 Gilman Dr., La Jolla, CA

More information

The Integer Arithmetic of Legislative Dynamics

The Integer Arithmetic of Legislative Dynamics The Integer Arithmetic of Legislative Dynamics Kenneth Benoit Trinity College Dublin Michael Laver New York University July 8, 2005 Abstract Every legislature may be defined by a finite integer partition

More information

Multilateral Bargaining: Veto Power PS132

Multilateral Bargaining: Veto Power PS132 Multilateral Bargaining: Veto Power PS132 Introduction Some members have veto right - ability to block decisions even when a proposal has secured the necessary majority Introduction Some members have veto

More information

DISCUSSION PAPERS Department of Economics University of Copenhagen

DISCUSSION PAPERS Department of Economics University of Copenhagen DISCUSSION PAPERS Department of Economics University of Copenhagen 06-24 Pure Redistribution and the Provision of Public Goods Rupert Sausgruber Jean-Robert Tyran Studiestræde 6, DK-1455 Copenhagen K.,

More information

An Experimental Investigation of Delegation, Voting and the Provision of Public Goods

An Experimental Investigation of Delegation, Voting and the Provision of Public Goods An Experimental Investigation of Delegation, Voting and the Provision of Public Goods John Hamman Florida State University Roberto A. Weber Carnegie Mellon University Jonathan Woon University of Pittsburgh

More information

Does inequality exacerbate environmental problems? Would an equalization

Does inequality exacerbate environmental problems? Would an equalization Chapter 1 Jean-Marie Baland, Pranab Bardhan, and Samuel Bowles Does inequality exacerbate environmental problems? Would an equalization of wealth, social status, and political power contribute to environmental

More information

Supporting Information for Signaling and Counter-Signaling in the Judicial Hierarchy: An Empirical Analysis of En Banc Review

Supporting Information for Signaling and Counter-Signaling in the Judicial Hierarchy: An Empirical Analysis of En Banc Review Supporting Information for Signaling and Counter-Signaling in the Judicial Hierarchy: An Empirical Analysis of En Banc Review In this appendix, we: explain our case selection procedures; Deborah Beim Alexander

More information

Voting with hands and feet: the requirements for optimal group formation

Voting with hands and feet: the requirements for optimal group formation Exp Econ (2015) 18:522 541 DOI 10.1007/s10683-014-9418-8 ORIGINAL PAPER Voting with hands and feet: the requirements for optimal group formation Andrea Robbett Received: 13 September 2013 / Revised: 18

More information

1. The Relationship Between Party Control, Latino CVAP and the Passage of Bills Benefitting Immigrants

1. The Relationship Between Party Control, Latino CVAP and the Passage of Bills Benefitting Immigrants The Ideological and Electoral Determinants of Laws Targeting Undocumented Migrants in the U.S. States Online Appendix In this additional methodological appendix I present some alternative model specifications

More information

PLS 540 Environmental Policy and Management Mark T. Imperial. Topic: The Policy Process

PLS 540 Environmental Policy and Management Mark T. Imperial. Topic: The Policy Process PLS 540 Environmental Policy and Management Mark T. Imperial Topic: The Policy Process Some basic terms and concepts Separation of powers: federal constitution grants each branch of government specific

More information

Ideological Externalities, Social Pressures, and Political Parties

Ideological Externalities, Social Pressures, and Political Parties Ideological Externalities, Social Pressures, and Political Parties Amihai Glazer Department of Economics University of California, Irvine Irvine, California 92697 e-mail: aglazer@uci.edu Telephone: 949-824-5974

More information

Experimental Computational Philosophy: shedding new lights on (old) philosophical debates

Experimental Computational Philosophy: shedding new lights on (old) philosophical debates Experimental Computational Philosophy: shedding new lights on (old) philosophical debates Vincent Wiegel and Jan van den Berg 1 Abstract. Philosophy can benefit from experiments performed in a laboratory

More information

LOGROLLING. Nicholas R. Miller Department of Political Science University of Maryland Baltimore County Baltimore, Maryland

LOGROLLING. Nicholas R. Miller Department of Political Science University of Maryland Baltimore County Baltimore, Maryland LOGROLLING Nicholas R. Miller Department of Political Science University of Maryland Baltimore County Baltimore, Maryland 21250 May 20, 1999 An entry in The Encyclopedia of Democratic Thought (Routledge)

More information

POLITICAL EQUILIBRIUM SOCIAL SECURITY WITH MIGRATION

POLITICAL EQUILIBRIUM SOCIAL SECURITY WITH MIGRATION POLITICAL EQUILIBRIUM SOCIAL SECURITY WITH MIGRATION Laura Marsiliani University of Durham laura.marsiliani@durham.ac.uk Thomas I. Renström University of Durham and CEPR t.i.renstrom@durham.ac.uk We analyze

More information

What is The Probability Your Vote will Make a Difference?

What is The Probability Your Vote will Make a Difference? Berkeley Law From the SelectedWorks of Aaron Edlin 2009 What is The Probability Your Vote will Make a Difference? Andrew Gelman, Columbia University Nate Silver Aaron S. Edlin, University of California,

More information

INTERNATIONAL ECONOMICS, FINANCE AND TRADE Vol. II - Strategic Interaction, Trade Policy, and National Welfare - Bharati Basu

INTERNATIONAL ECONOMICS, FINANCE AND TRADE Vol. II - Strategic Interaction, Trade Policy, and National Welfare - Bharati Basu STRATEGIC INTERACTION, TRADE POLICY, AND NATIONAL WELFARE Bharati Basu Department of Economics, Central Michigan University, Mt. Pleasant, Michigan, USA Keywords: Calibration, export subsidy, export tax,

More information

Allocating Pollution Load

Allocating Pollution Load Allocating Pollution Load Reductions Between States: What's Fair, What's Efficient, and How Can we Agree to Get There? Tony Kwasnica Smeal College of Business kwasnica@psu.edu Tony Kwasnica Associate Professor

More information

Voting Power in Weighted Voting Games: A Lobbying Approach by Maria Montero, Alex Possajennikov and Martin Sefton 1 April 2011

Voting Power in Weighted Voting Games: A Lobbying Approach by Maria Montero, Alex Possajennikov and Martin Sefton 1 April 2011 [Very preliminary please do not quote without permission] Voting Power in Weighted Voting Games: A Lobbying Approach by Maria Montero, Alex Possajennikov and Martin Sefton 1 April 2011 Abstract We report

More information

Election Theory. How voters and parties behave strategically in democratic systems. Mark Crowley

Election Theory. How voters and parties behave strategically in democratic systems. Mark Crowley How voters and parties behave strategically in democratic systems Department of Computer Science University of British Columbia January 30, 2006 Sources Voting Theory Jeff Gill and Jason Gainous. "Why

More information

DATA ANALYSIS USING SETUPS AND SPSS: AMERICAN VOTING BEHAVIOR IN PRESIDENTIAL ELECTIONS

DATA ANALYSIS USING SETUPS AND SPSS: AMERICAN VOTING BEHAVIOR IN PRESIDENTIAL ELECTIONS Poli 300 Handout B N. R. Miller DATA ANALYSIS USING SETUPS AND SPSS: AMERICAN VOTING BEHAVIOR IN IDENTIAL ELECTIONS 1972-2004 The original SETUPS: AMERICAN VOTING BEHAVIOR IN IDENTIAL ELECTIONS 1972-1992

More information

Elinor Ostrom: Fighting the Tragedy of the Commons

Elinor Ostrom: Fighting the Tragedy of the Commons Elinor Ostrom: Fighting the Tragedy of the Commons Juan Camilo CARDENAS & Rajiv SETHI Among the recipients of the 2009 Nobel Memorial Prize in Economics was Elinor Ostrom, for her analysis of economic

More information

Enriqueta Aragones Harvard University and Universitat Pompeu Fabra Andrew Postlewaite University of Pennsylvania. March 9, 2000

Enriqueta Aragones Harvard University and Universitat Pompeu Fabra Andrew Postlewaite University of Pennsylvania. March 9, 2000 Campaign Rhetoric: a model of reputation Enriqueta Aragones Harvard University and Universitat Pompeu Fabra Andrew Postlewaite University of Pennsylvania March 9, 2000 Abstract We develop a model of infinitely

More information

The Provision of Public Goods Under Alternative. Electoral Incentives

The Provision of Public Goods Under Alternative. Electoral Incentives The Provision of Public Goods Under Alternative Electoral Incentives Alessandro Lizzeri and Nicola Persico March 10, 2000 American Economic Review, forthcoming ABSTRACT Politicians who care about the spoils

More information

Report for the Associated Press: Illinois and Georgia Election Studies in November 2014

Report for the Associated Press: Illinois and Georgia Election Studies in November 2014 Report for the Associated Press: Illinois and Georgia Election Studies in November 2014 Randall K. Thomas, Frances M. Barlas, Linda McPetrie, Annie Weber, Mansour Fahimi, & Robert Benford GfK Custom Research

More information

SLEEPING WITH THE ENEMY: THE ECONOMIC COST OF INTERNAL ENVIRONMENTAL CONFLICTS

SLEEPING WITH THE ENEMY: THE ECONOMIC COST OF INTERNAL ENVIRONMENTAL CONFLICTS Archived version from NCDOCKS Institutional Repository http://libres.uncg.edu/ir/asu/ Cherry, T. L. & Cotton, S. (2011). Sleeping with the enemy: The economic cost of internal environmental conflicts.

More information

1. Introduction. Michael Finus

1. Introduction. Michael Finus 1. Introduction Michael Finus Global warming is believed to be one of the most serious environmental problems for current and hture generations. This shared belief led more than 180 countries to sign the

More information

3 Electoral Competition

3 Electoral Competition 3 Electoral Competition We now turn to a discussion of two-party electoral competition in representative democracy. The underlying policy question addressed in this chapter, as well as the remaining chapters

More information

Civic Participation II: Voter Fraud

Civic Participation II: Voter Fraud Civic Participation II: Voter Fraud Sharad Goel Stanford University Department of Management Science March 5, 2018 These notes are based off a presentation by Sharad Goel (Stanford, Department of Management

More information

Mechanism design: how to implement social goals

Mechanism design: how to implement social goals Mechanism Design Mechanism design: how to implement social goals From article by Eric S. Maskin Theory of mechanism design can be thought of as engineering side of economic theory Most theoretical work

More information

Testing Political Economy Models of Reform in the Laboratory

Testing Political Economy Models of Reform in the Laboratory Testing Political Economy Models of Reform in the Laboratory By TIMOTHY N. CASON AND VAI-LAM MUI* * Department of Economics, Krannert School of Management, Purdue University, West Lafayette, IN 47907-1310,

More information

1 Electoral Competition under Certainty

1 Electoral Competition under Certainty 1 Electoral Competition under Certainty We begin with models of electoral competition. This chapter explores electoral competition when voting behavior is deterministic; the following chapter considers

More information

Rational Choice. Pba Dab. Imbalance (read Pab is greater than Pba and Dba is greater than Dab) V V

Rational Choice. Pba Dab. Imbalance (read Pab is greater than Pba and Dba is greater than Dab) V V Rational Choice George Homans Social Behavior as Exchange Exchange theory as alternative to Parsons grand theory. Base sociology on economics and behaviorist psychology (don t worry about the inside, meaning,

More information

Compulsory versus Voluntary Voting Mechanisms: An Experimental Study

Compulsory versus Voluntary Voting Mechanisms: An Experimental Study Compulsory versus Voluntary Voting Mechanisms: An Experimental Study Sourav Bhattacharya John Duffy Sun-Tak Kim January 31, 2011 Abstract This paper uses laboratory experiments to study the impact of voting

More information

Agendas and Strategic Voting

Agendas and Strategic Voting Agendas and Strategic Voting Charles A. Holt and Lisa R. Anderson * Southern Economic Journal, January 1999 Abstract: This paper describes a simple classroom experiment in which students decide which projects

More information

BEYOND MARKETS AND STATES: POLYCENTRIC GOVERNANCE OF COMPLEX ECONOMIC SYSTEMS. Elinor Ostrom

BEYOND MARKETS AND STATES: POLYCENTRIC GOVERNANCE OF COMPLEX ECONOMIC SYSTEMS. Elinor Ostrom DRAFT DO NOT QUOTE BEYOND MARKETS AND STATES: POLYCENTRIC GOVERNANCE OF COMPLEX ECONOMIC SYSTEMS by Elinor Ostrom Nobel Lecture, December 8, 2009 The Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory

More information

Research Statement. Jeffrey J. Harden. 2 Dissertation Research: The Dimensions of Representation

Research Statement. Jeffrey J. Harden. 2 Dissertation Research: The Dimensions of Representation Research Statement Jeffrey J. Harden 1 Introduction My research agenda includes work in both quantitative methodology and American politics. In methodology I am broadly interested in developing and evaluating

More information

Topics in Comparative Politics: Comparative Voting

Topics in Comparative Politics: Comparative Voting Department of Political Science Washington University Fall Semester 2011. Course No. L32 4331 Pol Sci Seigle # 103 TT 11:30 A.M.-1:00 P.M. Topics in Comparative Politics: Comparative Voting Professor Itai

More information

Wisconsin Economic Scorecard

Wisconsin Economic Scorecard RESEARCH PAPER> May 2012 Wisconsin Economic Scorecard Analysis: Determinants of Individual Opinion about the State Economy Joseph Cera Researcher Survey Center Manager The Wisconsin Economic Scorecard

More information

Lobbying in Washington DC

Lobbying in Washington DC Lobbying in Washington DC Frank R. Baumgartner Richard J. Richardson Distinguished Professor of Political Science, University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill, USA Frankb@unc.edu International Trends in

More information

International Cooperation, Parties and. Ideology - Very preliminary and incomplete

International Cooperation, Parties and. Ideology - Very preliminary and incomplete International Cooperation, Parties and Ideology - Very preliminary and incomplete Jan Klingelhöfer RWTH Aachen University February 15, 2015 Abstract I combine a model of international cooperation with

More information

Voters Interests in Campaign Finance Regulation: Formal Models

Voters Interests in Campaign Finance Regulation: Formal Models Voters Interests in Campaign Finance Regulation: Formal Models Scott Ashworth June 6, 2012 The Supreme Court s decision in Citizens United v. FEC significantly expands the scope for corporate- and union-financed

More information

Outcome Evaluation Criminal Case Management Plan. Persons. October 2010

Outcome Evaluation Criminal Case Management Plan. Persons. October 2010 Outcome Evaluation Criminal Case Management Plan Persons October 2010 Prepared by Mecklenburg County Manager s Office Executive Summary The Criminal Case Management Plan, implemented in August 2008, was

More information

Voting and Electoral Competition

Voting and Electoral Competition Voting and Electoral Competition Prof. Panu Poutvaara University of Munich and Ifo Institute On the organization of the course Lectures, exam at the end Articles to read. In more technical articles, it

More information

Introduction to Elinor Ostrom. Bob Jessop

Introduction to Elinor Ostrom. Bob Jessop Introduction to Elinor Ostrom Bob Jessop The article chosen for translation in this issue is by the recently deceased Nobel Economics Laureate, Elinor Ostrom. It presents a typical example of her heterodox

More information

policy-making. footnote We adopt a simple parametric specification which allows us to go between the two polar cases studied in this literature.

policy-making. footnote We adopt a simple parametric specification which allows us to go between the two polar cases studied in this literature. Introduction Which tier of government should be responsible for particular taxing and spending decisions? From Philadelphia to Maastricht, this question has vexed constitution designers. Yet still the

More information

COLORADO LOTTERY 2014 IMAGE STUDY

COLORADO LOTTERY 2014 IMAGE STUDY COLORADO LOTTERY 2014 IMAGE STUDY AUGUST 2014 Prepared By: 3220 S. Detroit Street Denver, Colorado 80210 303-296-8000 howellreserach@aol.com CONTENTS SUMMARY... 1 I. INTRODUCTION... 7 Research Objectives...

More information

Can Ideal Point Estimates be Used as Explanatory Variables?

Can Ideal Point Estimates be Used as Explanatory Variables? Can Ideal Point Estimates be Used as Explanatory Variables? Andrew D. Martin Washington University admartin@wustl.edu Kevin M. Quinn Harvard University kevin quinn@harvard.edu October 8, 2005 1 Introduction

More information

Democracy and cooperation in commons management: experimental evidence of representative and direct democracy from community forests in Ethiopia

Democracy and cooperation in commons management: experimental evidence of representative and direct democracy from community forests in Ethiopia Environment and Development Economics 22: 110 132 Cambridge University Press 2016 doi:10.1017/s1355770x16000322 Democracy and cooperation in commons management: experimental evidence of representative

More information

Technical Appendix for Selecting Among Acquitted Defendants Andrew F. Daughety and Jennifer F. Reinganum April 2015

Technical Appendix for Selecting Among Acquitted Defendants Andrew F. Daughety and Jennifer F. Reinganum April 2015 1 Technical Appendix for Selecting Among Acquitted Defendants Andrew F. Daughety and Jennifer F. Reinganum April 2015 Proof of Proposition 1 Suppose that one were to permit D to choose whether he will

More information

Chapter Four: Chamber Competitiveness, Political Polarization, and Political Parties

Chapter Four: Chamber Competitiveness, Political Polarization, and Political Parties Chapter Four: Chamber Competitiveness, Political Polarization, and Political Parties Building off of the previous chapter in this dissertation, this chapter investigates the involvement of political parties

More information

Problems with Group Decision Making

Problems with Group Decision Making Problems with Group Decision Making There are two ways of evaluating political systems. 1. Consequentialist ethics evaluate actions, policies, or institutions in regard to the outcomes they produce. 2.

More information

UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA, SAN DIEGO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA, SAN DIEGO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS 2000-03 UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA, SAN DIEGO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS JOHN NASH AND THE ANALYSIS OF STRATEGIC BEHAVIOR BY VINCENT P. CRAWFORD DISCUSSION PAPER 2000-03 JANUARY 2000 John Nash and the Analysis

More information

GAME THEORY. Analysis of Conflict ROGER B. MYERSON. HARVARD UNIVERSITY PRESS Cambridge, Massachusetts London, England

GAME THEORY. Analysis of Conflict ROGER B. MYERSON. HARVARD UNIVERSITY PRESS Cambridge, Massachusetts London, England GAME THEORY Analysis of Conflict ROGER B. MYERSON HARVARD UNIVERSITY PRESS Cambridge, Massachusetts London, England Contents Preface 1 Decision-Theoretic Foundations 1.1 Game Theory, Rationality, and Intelligence

More information

A Comparison of Two Different Theoretical Approaches to Commons

A Comparison of Two Different Theoretical Approaches to Commons West Virginia University From the SelectedWorks of Roger A. Lohmann Summer July 15, 2016 A Comparison of Two Different Theoretical Approaches to Commons Roger A. Lohmann This work is licensed under a Creative

More information

Household Inequality, Corporate Capital Structure and Entrepreneurial Dynamism by Fabio Braggion, Mintra Dwarkasing, and Steven Ongena

Household Inequality, Corporate Capital Structure and Entrepreneurial Dynamism by Fabio Braggion, Mintra Dwarkasing, and Steven Ongena Household Inequality, Corporate Capital Structure and Entrepreneurial Dynamism by Fabio Braggion, Mintra Dwarkasing, and Steven Ongena Johann Reindl BI Norwegian Business School Summary Very Important

More information

Figure 1. Payoff Matrix of Typical Prisoner s Dilemma This matrix represents the choices presented to the prisoners and the outcomes that come as the

Figure 1. Payoff Matrix of Typical Prisoner s Dilemma This matrix represents the choices presented to the prisoners and the outcomes that come as the Proposal and Verification of Method to Prioritize the Sites for Traffic Safety Prevention Measure Based on Fatal Accident Risk Sungwon LEE a a,b Chief Research Director, The Korea Transport Institute,

More information

THE MEDIAN VOTER THEOREM (ONE DIMENSION)

THE MEDIAN VOTER THEOREM (ONE DIMENSION) THE MEDIAN VOTER THEOREM (ONE DIMENSION) 1 2 Single Dimensional Spatial Model Alternatives are the set of points on a line Various ideologies on a spectrum Spending on different programs etc. Single-peaked

More information

3. Public Choice in a Direct Democracy

3. Public Choice in a Direct Democracy 3. Public in a Direct 4. Public in a 3. Public in a Direct I. Unanimity rule II. Optimal majority rule a) Choosing the optimal majority b) Simple majority as the optimal majority III. Majority rule a)

More information

Vote Likelihood and Institutional Trait Questions in the 1997 NES Pilot Study

Vote Likelihood and Institutional Trait Questions in the 1997 NES Pilot Study Vote Likelihood and Institutional Trait Questions in the 1997 NES Pilot Study Barry C. Burden and Janet M. Box-Steffensmeier The Ohio State University Department of Political Science 2140 Derby Hall Columbus,

More information

11th Annual Patent Law Institute

11th Annual Patent Law Institute INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY Course Handbook Series Number G-1316 11th Annual Patent Law Institute Co-Chairs Scott M. Alter Douglas R. Nemec John M. White To order this book, call (800) 260-4PLI or fax us at

More information

Problems with Group Decision Making

Problems with Group Decision Making Problems with Group Decision Making There are two ways of evaluating political systems: 1. Consequentialist ethics evaluate actions, policies, or institutions in regard to the outcomes they produce. 2.

More information

Gordon Tullock and the Demand-Revealing Process

Gordon Tullock and the Demand-Revealing Process Gordon Tullock and the Demand-Revealing Process Nicolaus Tideman In 1970 Edward Clarke, then a graduate student at the University of Chicago, submitted a manuscript titled, Introduction to Theory for Optimal

More information

Reputation and Rhetoric in Elections

Reputation and Rhetoric in Elections Reputation and Rhetoric in Elections Enriqueta Aragonès Institut d Anàlisi Econòmica, CSIC Andrew Postlewaite University of Pennsylvania April 11, 2005 Thomas R. Palfrey Princeton University Earlier versions

More information

PS 124A Midterm, Fall 2013

PS 124A Midterm, Fall 2013 PS 124A Midterm, Fall 2013 Choose the best answer and fill in the appropriate bubble. Each question is worth 4 points. 1. The dominant economic power in the first Age of Globalization was a. Rome b. Spain

More information

Designing Weighted Voting Games to Proportionality

Designing Weighted Voting Games to Proportionality Designing Weighted Voting Games to Proportionality In the analysis of weighted voting a scheme may be constructed which apportions at least one vote, per-representative units. The numbers of weighted votes

More information

1. Collective action theory

1. Collective action theory 1. Collective action theory Robert Holahan and Mark Lubell Collective action dilemmas (hereafter collective dilemmas) occur when the joint decisions of two or more individuals result in socially undesirable

More information

HANDBOOK OF SOCIAL CHOICE AND VOTING Jac C. Heckelman and Nicholas R. Miller, editors.

HANDBOOK OF SOCIAL CHOICE AND VOTING Jac C. Heckelman and Nicholas R. Miller, editors. HANDBOOK OF SOCIAL CHOICE AND VOTING Jac C. Heckelman and Nicholas R. Miller, editors. 1. Introduction: Issues in Social Choice and Voting (Jac C. Heckelman and Nicholas R. Miller) 2. Perspectives on Social

More information

Should the Democrats move to the left on economic policy?

Should the Democrats move to the left on economic policy? Should the Democrats move to the left on economic policy? Andrew Gelman Cexun Jeffrey Cai November 9, 2007 Abstract Could John Kerry have gained votes in the recent Presidential election by more clearly

More information

D. Preble, K. Ketcham, S. Parente, S. Macinko, G. Allen, J. King. RIDEM F&W Staff: T. Angell, J. McNamee. DEM Legal Counsel: G.

D. Preble, K. Ketcham, S. Parente, S. Macinko, G. Allen, J. King. RIDEM F&W Staff: T. Angell, J. McNamee. DEM Legal Counsel: G. RHODE ISLAND MARINE FISHERIES COUNCIL Minutes of Monthly Meeting October 18, 2006 URI Narragansett Bay Campus Corless Auditorium South Ferry Road Narragansett, RI RIMFC Members: Chairperson: D. Preble,

More information

Determinants of legislative success in House committees*

Determinants of legislative success in House committees* Public Choice 74: 233-243, 1992. 1992 Kluwer Academic Publishers. Printed in the Netherlands. Research note Determinants of legislative success in House committees* SCOTT J. THOMAS BERNARD GROFMAN School

More information

The National Citizen Survey

The National Citizen Survey CITY OF SARASOTA, FLORIDA 2008 3005 30th Street 777 North Capitol Street NE, Suite 500 Boulder, CO 80301 Washington, DC 20002 ww.n-r-c.com 303-444-7863 www.icma.org 202-289-ICMA P U B L I C S A F E T Y

More information

Michael Laver and Ernest Sergenti: Party Competition. An Agent-Based Model

Michael Laver and Ernest Sergenti: Party Competition. An Agent-Based Model RMM Vol. 3, 2012, 66 70 http://www.rmm-journal.de/ Book Review Michael Laver and Ernest Sergenti: Party Competition. An Agent-Based Model Princeton NJ 2012: Princeton University Press. ISBN: 9780691139043

More information

REVIEW OF FOUNDATIONS OF HUMAN SOCIALITY: ECONOMIC EXPERIMENTS AND ETHNOGRAPHIC EVIDENCE FROM FIFTEEN SMALL-SCALE SOCIETIES

REVIEW OF FOUNDATIONS OF HUMAN SOCIALITY: ECONOMIC EXPERIMENTS AND ETHNOGRAPHIC EVIDENCE FROM FIFTEEN SMALL-SCALE SOCIETIES REVIEW OF FOUNDATIONS OF HUMAN SOCIALITY: ECONOMIC EXPERIMENTS AND ETHNOGRAPHIC EVIDENCE FROM FIFTEEN SMALL-SCALE SOCIETIES ANITA JOWITT This book is not written by lawyers or written with legal policy

More information

NTNU, Trondheim Fall 2003

NTNU, Trondheim Fall 2003 INSTITUTIONS AND INSTITUTIONAL DESIGN Erling Berge Part X: Design principles I NTNU, Trondheim Fall 2003 30-10-2003 Erling Berge 2003 1 References Institutions and their design, pages 1-53 in Goodin, Robert

More information

The California Primary and Redistricting

The California Primary and Redistricting The California Primary and Redistricting This study analyzes what is the important impact of changes in the primary voting rules after a Congressional and Legislative Redistricting. Under a citizen s committee,

More information

Sincere Versus Sophisticated Voting When Legislators Vote Sequentially

Sincere Versus Sophisticated Voting When Legislators Vote Sequentially Sincere Versus Sophisticated Voting When Legislators Vote Sequentially Tim Groseclose Departments of Political Science and Economics UCLA Jeffrey Milyo Department of Economics University of Missouri September

More information

THE EFFECT OF OFFER-OF-SETTLEMENT RULES ON THE TERMS OF SETTLEMENT

THE EFFECT OF OFFER-OF-SETTLEMENT RULES ON THE TERMS OF SETTLEMENT Last revision: 12/97 THE EFFECT OF OFFER-OF-SETTLEMENT RULES ON THE TERMS OF SETTLEMENT Lucian Arye Bebchuk * and Howard F. Chang ** * Professor of Law, Economics, and Finance, Harvard Law School. ** Professor

More information

Introduction to Game Theory

Introduction to Game Theory Introduction to Game Theory ICPSR First Session, 2015 Scott Ainsworth, Instructor sainswor@uga.edu David Hughes, Assistant dhughes1@uga.edu Bryan Daves, Assistant brdaves@verizon.net Course Purpose and

More information

ISSN , Volume 13, Number 2

ISSN , Volume 13, Number 2 ISSN 1386-4157, Volume 13, Number 2 This article was published in the above mentioned Springer issue. The material, including all portions thereof, is protected by copyright; all rights are held exclusively

More information

INTERNATIONAL ECONOMICS, FINANCE AND TRADE Vol. II - Property Rights and the Environment - Lata Gangadharan, Pushkar Maitra

INTERNATIONAL ECONOMICS, FINANCE AND TRADE Vol. II - Property Rights and the Environment - Lata Gangadharan, Pushkar Maitra PROPERTY RIGHTS AND THE ENVIRONMENT Lata Gangadharan Department of Economics, University of Melbourne, Australia Department of Economics, Monash University, Clayton, Victoria, Australia Keywords: Global

More information

Content Analysis of Network TV News Coverage

Content Analysis of Network TV News Coverage Supplemental Technical Appendix for Hayes, Danny, and Matt Guardino. 2011. The Influence of Foreign Voices on U.S. Public Opinion. American Journal of Political Science. Content Analysis of Network TV

More information

Beyond Markets and States: Polycentric

Beyond Markets and States: Polycentric Beyond Markets and States: Polycentric Governance of Complex Economic Systems Prize Lecture, December 8, 2009 by Elinor Ostrom Workshop in Political Theory and Policy Analysis, Indiana University, Bloomington,

More information