Disambiguation of social polarization concepts and measures

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Disambiguation of social polarization concepts and measures"

Transcription

1 The Journal of Mathematical Sociology ISSN: X (Print) (Online) Journal homepage: Disambiguation of social polarization concepts and measures Aaron Bramson, Patrick Grim, Daniel J. Singer, Steven Fisher, William Berger, Graham Sack & Carissa Flocken To cite this article: Aaron Bramson, Patrick Grim, Daniel J. Singer, Steven Fisher, William Berger, Graham Sack & Carissa Flocken (2016) Disambiguation of social polarization concepts and measures, The Journal of Mathematical Sociology, 40:2, , DOI: / X To link to this article: Published online: 13 Apr Submit your article to this journal Article views: 212 View related articles View Crossmark data Full Terms & Conditions of access and use can be found at Download by: [University of Michigan] Date: 02 October 2017, At: 11:52

2 THE JOURNAL OF MATHEMATICAL SOCIOLOGY 2016, VOL. 40, NO. 2, Disambiguation of social polarization concepts and measures Aaron Bramson a,b, Patrick Grim c, Daniel J. Singer d, Steven Fisher e,f, William Berger e,f, Graham Sack g, and Carissa Flocken h a Riken Brain Science Institute, Laboratory for Symbolic Cognitive Development, Wakoshi, Japan; b Department of General Economics, Ghent University, Ghent, Belgium; c Department of Philosophy, Group for Logic & Formal Semantics, Stony Brook University, Stony Brook, New York, USA; d Philosophy Department, University of Pennsylvania, Philadelphia, Pennsylvania, USA; e Center for the Study of Complex Systems, University of Michigan, Ann Arbor, Michigan, USA; f Department of Political Science, University of Michigan, Ann Arbor, Michigan, USA; g Department of English & Comparative Literature, Columbia University, New York, New York, USA; h Honors Program, University of Michigan, Ann Arbor, Michigan, USA ABSTRACT This article distinguishes nine senses of polarization and provides formal measures for each one to refine the methodology used to describe polarization in distributions of attitudes. Each distinct concept is explained through a definition, formal measures, examples, and references. We then apply these measures to GSS data regarding political views, opinions on abortion, and religiosity topics described as revealing social polarization. Previous breakdowns of polarization include domain-specific assumptions and focus on a subset of the distribution s features. This has conflated multiple, independent features of attitude distributions. The current work aims to extract the distinct senses of polarization and demonstrate that by becoming clearer on these distinctions we can better focus our efforts on substantive issues in social phenomena. 1. Introduction ARTICLE HISTORY Received 25 January 2015 Revised 16 January 2016 Accepted 22 January 2016 KEYWORDS Belief aggregation; formal epistemology; measurement; polarization; social epistemology Though the term polarization is frequently invoked to describe patterns in distributions (e.g., in opinion polls), it is not the single concept it is often taken to be. Occurrences of polarization frequently appear in the sociology and political science literature (Baldassarri & Gelman, 2008; Bartels, 2000; Brownstein, 2007; DiMaggio, Evans, & Bryson, 1996; Fiorina, Abrams, & Pope, 2010; Hetherington & Weiler, 2009; Hunter, 1991; McCarty, Poole, & Rosenthal, 2008), but the specific ways in which polarization is realized are not systematically distinguished. Often entire articles appear on the topic of polarization, but with little attempt to make it clear what precisely is meant by the term. In those cases in which a formal measure is provided (see Christen, Ott, & Schwarz, 2013; DiMaggio et al., 1996; Fiorina et al., 2010; Estaban & Ray 2012), it may be specific to the analyzed dataset or topic of interest, not fully formalized, not evaluated compared to other measures and/or presented as a measure that is a composite of the measures presented here. Because a genuine understanding of the phenomena at issue demands making definitions unambiguous, here we tease out nine distinct concepts of polarization and demonstrate how each one can be made precise with an example formal measure. In this effort we make no claims of completeness; to the contrary, we acknowledge that alternative measures are possible within each concept and point toward further concepts beyond the nine included here. Specifically, we are elsewhere pursuing measures that incorporate spatial and social network configurations, but our focus here is on polarization phenomena within a distribution of CONTACT Aaron Bramson bramson@brain.riken.jp Laboratory for Symbolic Cognitive Development, RIKEN Brain Science Institute, BSI West Building 2F, 2-1 Hirosawa, Wako City, Saitama Japan Color versions of one or more of the figures in the article can be found online at Taylor & Francis

3 THE JOURNAL OF MATHEMATICAL SOCIOLOGY 81 cardinal property values. One common example of appropriate data in the social sciences is the Likert scale responses of one s degree of agreement in a survey statement. These properties are variably referred to as attitudes, beliefs, opinions, views, tastes, ideas, attributes, and properties, etc., in the literature, but we refer to all these as attitudes throughout except when matching the terminology from the literature. Furthermore, nonattitudinal properties such as wealth, educational attainment, and commuting distance are also viable targets of the polarization measures presented here. All the measures provided in this article are presented for one-dimensional applications, though they often have obvious equivalents for high-dimensional data. 1 Examples of data appropriate for the analysis presented here include opinions toward abortion (see Figure 1), people s political views, opinions toward women s rights, degree of support for a particular policy, online product reviews, and the level of funding appropriate for a budget s line item. The abortion figure is illustrative of the ambiguity in polarization phenomena. There are two clear clumps of attitudes at 1 and 5 which indicates some sort of polarization. The groups are largely steady in size and position, so whatever polarization there is, it appears to be constant. If the groups moved further apart, then intuitively the polarization has increased that is an easy case. What about a scenario in which the liberal group shrinks and the moderate group increases in size? Or how would the level of polarization change if both groups shrank and a sizable third group formed at 8? A full characterization of polarization needs to have clear and justifiable answers to these questions. Our first purpose is to emphasize that polarization refers to a concept cluster rather than single concept. In some senses polarization depends only on the distribution of attitudes across the whole population, while in other senses polarization depends upon how groups within the population are distributed. When groups are appropriate/necessary, we provide clear formal measures in terms of both distributions of attitudes across an unstructured population with endogenously identified Figure 1. Attitudes toward abortion, distribution by year, from the full sample General Social Survey (DiMaggio et al., 1996). 1 Furthermore, increasing the number of dimensions also expands polarization into additional distinct senses; i.e., there are types of polarization (such as the correlation of attitudes across multiple issue dimensions (Baldassarri & Gelman, 2008; Fiorina et al., 2010)) that are only sensible for higher-dimensional data.

4 82 A. BRAMSON ET AL. groupings and distributions of attitudes across exogenously defined groups of individuals. Before moving on to applications we also briefly consider compound concepts that require combining multiple senses; a consideration that is especially important when addressing a literature that commonly combines or switches the meaning of these terms. In the final section we analyze data regarding people s political views and views toward abortion from the General Social Survey (GSS). These datasets are analyzed by themselves and through the lens of religiosity. Religiosity is categorized by using individuals response to a question regarding the origin of the Bible. We investigate each sense of polarization for these data by applying our example formal measures and providing a detailed report of the results. We also compare the polarization level of political views and abortion opinions to demonstrate the use of our distinctions for both analyzing trends and differences across issues. 2. What is polarization? This project has three arms: conceptual analysis, formal methodology, and applied social science. The analytical aspect comes into play as we try to better understand the concept(s) of polarization. The scenario in Figure 1 has been identified as a clear case of polarization by DiMaggio et al. (1996) and others. We must ask: if this distribution is polarized, what makes it polarized? What does it mean for the distribution to be polarized? What feature(s) of the distribution is the property of polarization picking out? Even if we can all agree and consistently pick out the cases of polarized distributions based on our intuitions, if we cannot explain what makes it polarized (or what it means to be polarized) then we do not have a strong understanding of the phenomena. Furthermore, even for cases as clear as the abortion data, we do not all agree and most cases are not nearly so clear. The term polarization is sometimes used to refer to a static property and sometimes a process (DiMaggio et al., 1996). The measures we provide here are properties of a distribution that can be captured at any time-slice of the system. The numbers produced by our measures are not intended to be informative in isolation; rather, they gain their meaning as relative values through comparisons (i.e., being more or less polarized). They can therefore be used to compare two different questions at a given time (e.g., are attitudes about education more or less polarized than attitudes about abortion) or they can be made into measures of a polarizing process through the standard approach of measuring the change in value across time (polarization in trends). The comparative approach allows us to apply our concepts and measures across issues or time without requiring new concepts or measures (Dandekar, Goel, & Lee, 2013). Because the individual measures are themselves not comparative, calculations can be done independently and then later compared across data, researchers, topics, or domains. A further corollary of our quantitative measurement approach is that when authors say of a system that it has become polarized this simply means that the value for some measure(s) has gone from a low to a comparatively high value. That is, it is a quantitative increase rather than being a qualitative shift implying that it possesses a new property. 3. Formal measures for polarization This article focuses on properties distributed on a normalized spectrum along one dimension. These properties can be anything that admits cardinal values because our formalism only depends on features of the distribution and not on what that distribution represents. As stated above, we have chosen to refer to the properties with the catch-all term attitudes, but they are also commonly referred to as beliefs, opinions, views, attributes, and various other terms in the literature. We adopt the simplest method for representing the distribution of attitudes: creating a histogram of the number of individuals holding a specific attitude value along the spectrum. This representation naturally captures the Likert scale data recovered from surveys and opinion polls. It can also be used to capture more open-ended questions (e.g., what percentage of the federal budget should be spent on education? ) and household income values through binning or density functions.

5 THE JOURNAL OF MATHEMATICAL SOCIOLOGY 83 The definitions for each of the nine senses below are provided along with example measures. The definitions are conceptual distinctions that stand on their own, while the measures are mathematical means to identify those conceptual distinctions in histograms of attitude distributions along a spectrum. 2 Although some of the particular measures provided here will not work in capturing the distinct senses of polarization in every type of data (e.g., categorical or overly coarse-grained data), they should provide clarity on the conceptual distinctions and are applicable to two key forms of data: histograms of attitude distributions from surveys and simulation outputs of models with epistemic agents. For concreteness, the measures provided here assume the following characteristics. There are N agents, participants, or respondents: a 1, a 2,...aN. Each agent a i has an attitude value x i on a range normalized to between 0 and 1; this is the location of that agent s attitude along the spectrum. The full distribution of all agents attitudes is written X. The set of bins used for discrete characterizations is R. For r P R, the expression y(x r ) is the count of agents occupying the bin containing the value x r ; that is, the number of agents holding attitude x r Spread The simplest concept of polarization is the width of the field of attitudes actually represented in the system. Without taking account of the shape of the distribution, or even whether there is continuity between the extremes, the further out the furthest individuals are the more varied their attitudes. The wider the difference in the most extreme views held, the more polarized the population s ideas are (in this sense). In a modeled range of attitudes, polarization in the sense of spread could be measured as the attitude level of the agent with the highest attitude value minus the attitude level of the agent with the lowest attitude value. This measure is also commonly called the range of the data spread ¼ max X min X (1) x i x i For multidimensional data, the diameter of the system (the greatest pairwise distance among all the points) is the general measure of spread, of which this is a special case. Polarization in the sense of spread is illustrated in Figure 2 with two groups (red and blue), although the measure is clearly not group-dependent. To the contrary, the measure just described is purposefully inclusive of the whole population; however, seeing a comparison between the situations (a) and (b) in which the groups are largely similar but differ in their spread should aid in grasping this as an isolated sense of polarization. Also, although the diagram represents the height of the distributions, that is also irrelevant for the measure of spread. An example application would consider the responses to questions such as What percentage of the federal budget should be spent on education? and What percentage of the federal budget Figure 2. Distribution (b) shows greater polarization in the sense of spread than does distribution (a). 2 Specifically, we provide measures that operate on a metric space so that there is a clear ordering from one end to the other and that distance measures are well-defined everywhere.

6 84 A. BRAMSON ET AL. should be spent on infrastructure? For example, spread could be used to compare the results across years, between political affiliations, or among nations. Comparing the widths of the band of held attitudes provides a relative measure, even if a simple one, of polarization on that question. For cases in which data are sparse or incomplete, this may be the only reliable quantitative measure available. The spread measure will often be correlated with the later measures such as the dispersion, coverage, and the distance between group means because many distributions shapes constrain how these values can change. However, for each of the other measures here an example can be generated that demonstrates its independence (see Section 4 for more information about measure independence) Dispersion Another simple, and common, measure of the variation in attitudes is statistical dispersion (or statistical variation). Unlike spread, which considers only the extremes of the population, dispersion considers the shape of the whole distribution. Dispersion can increase when groups move apart, or when the distribution flattens, or when the agents within the distribution move away from the middle toward opposite ends of the distribution. Just as in spread, greater dispersion (ceteris paribus) implies higher levels of polarization. There are many measures of statistical dispersion that are appropriate for our demonstration application, including mean difference, average absolute deviation, standard deviation, coefficient of variation, and entropy are all candidates. For simplicity we select average absolute deviation from the mean as our example here because this can be calculated from aggregate survey data. In our agent-based modeling research, we also find that the mean pairwise value differences are useful. For a population with N individuals the absolute deviation measure (normalized to be between zero and one) becomes dispersion ¼ 2 N X N x i jx i X j; (2) in which X is the mean value of distribution X. Changes in dispersion for different shape changes are presented in Figure 3. Note that the diagrams in the figure show dispersion increasing as spread is held constant. Like spread, dispersion does not include any notion of groups or subpopulations because it operates on the entire distribution X. We address dispersion within groups in Section 3.8 on group consensus. Figure 3. Distribution (c) shows greater polarization in the sense of dispersion than does distribution (b), which is greater than distribution (a). Various measures of dispersion have already been invoked in both the polarization and statistical literature. DiMaggio et al. (1996) refer to dispersion as the event that opinions are diverse, far apart in content. Just being far apart is not as precise as it could be because although spread is also a measure of statistical dispersion, spread and dispersion as defined here are clearly distinct polarization concepts Coverage Polarization in the sense of coverage captures the level of variation in the values held. One can think of it as the number of distinct attitudes held or the variety of attitudes that at least one person in the

7 THE JOURNAL OF MATHEMATICAL SOCIOLOGY 85 population holds. Although this sense is not sensitive to the shape of the distribution or even the number of agents who hold each position, it does capture a basic feature of variation. For this sense it does not matter how different the values are, or whether they are clumped together or at extremes; polarization as coverage captures only the variety of distinct attributes in the population. Because more coverage implies more different ideas, and this variety is at odds with converging ideas, polarization is higher. It is important to keep in mind that this interpretation of polarization as increasing with increasing coverage is in isolation of any other features of the distribution. It is possible to imagine a scenario with two sharp spikes separated by a wide gap. Covering some of the gap with new ideas would make convergence easier via some particular mechanisms. However, this measure is independent of where the coverage occurs, and more coverage could also be created by adding more extreme ideas. So, it is only in isolation that greater coverage tends to imply greater polarization. A more nuanced understanding of a particular case s overall polarization will require multiple measures and further specifics. A simple way to measure coverage in a discrete (binned data) spectrum is to simply calculate the proportion of bins that are occupied by at least one agent. Note that this discrete measure does not rely on any distance measure or ordering of the values, and therefore is also appropriate for categorical data. coverage d ¼ 1 X jrj r2r 1 yðx r Þ > 0 0 yðx r Þ¼0 That discrete measure, though simple, depends on the choice of bins when applied to nondiscrete data: varying the width and/or location of bins can alter the measure for the same underlying continuous (or fine-grained) data. We also present a continuous measure that does not rely on binning the data. This is done by setting halos of radius ρ around each agent for one-dimensional data this makes an agent-centered bin of width 2ρ. Any portion of the attitude space within ρ of an agent is considered covered, with the rest considered uncovered. Continuous coverage is measured by calculating the proportion of the space covered by those halos as 8 X < x j x i x j <x i þ ρ 2ρ þ r þ x j x i x i þ r x j x i þ 2ρ (4) : x i <x j 2ρ x j >x i þ 2ρ In some applications a further condition should be added for attitude values within ρ of the attitude space boundaries. Figure 4 illustrates a case in which coverage changes while spread remains constant. Although the height of the distribution (the number of individuals possessing that value) as well as three separate groups (red, blue, and green) are shown in the figure, those details are for reference and irrelevant for measuring coverage. Coverage is actually a crude measure of diversity, and there is a linkage between a diversity of attitudes and those attitudes being polarized (explored in other work). Though crude, coverage is valuable for categorical data, especially when data are sparse (i.e., the number of observations is small (3) Figure 4. Distribution (b) is more polarized than (a) in the sense of coverage because more of the space is non-empty.

8 86 A. BRAMSON ET AL. relative to the number of bins/categories). The continuous version is more valuable when using large datasets for which fine resolution is appropriate and for which the selection of bins biases the results. When applying to higher dimensions, both the continuous and discrete versions can be applied (although some normalization scheme should be implemented for the discrete version to ensure comparability across the number of dimensions). Coverage does not capture the clustering of the data points, which is a separate polarization concept likely crucial for many broader polarization applications. However, when comparing single- to multidimensional data, coverage is a convenient way to determine the degree to which pairs of attitudes line up. In the simulation literature, the influential paper of Hegselmann and Krause use consensus (conformity) to refer to minimal coverage, polarization(polarity) to refer to a scenario in which exactly two attitudes are held, and fragmentation(plurality) to indicate that multiple attitudes are held within the population (Hegselmann & Krause, 2002). Coverage converts this categorical breakdown into a measure. Discrete coverage as measured by Eq. (3) is also an accurate measure of polarization for Axelrod s Dissemination of Culture model precisely because it is categorical, even though he invokes some of the other concepts below when defining the term (Axelrod 1997) Regionalization In addition to the amount of space covered by attitudes, patterns in the empty attitude space are also relevant for capturing polarization. The number of uncovered ideas is the same concept as coverage (and its measure is the additive inverse). However, the number of uncovered intervals (ignoring their size) is a distinct sense of variety and hence a different way that distributions can be polarized. The more empty regions of the attitude space, the greater the polarization is in the sense of regionalization. Essentially this is reporting a simple version of clustering in the data in which gaps in the attributes indicate separate clusters. In order to measure the regionalization on a discrete spectrum, it is sufficient to count the regions of contiguous empty bins (including the initial space and trailing space if appropriate). For a discrete spectrum with ordered bins R we can calculate the regionalization with the following formalism: 8 X < 1 yðr 0 Þ¼0 1 yðr i Þ > 0 and yðr iþ1 Þ¼0 (5) : r i 2R 0 otherwise One can also define a continuous version of this measure using halos, just as we did for coverage, which better accounts for gaps in dense datasets but depends on the choice of radius. Figure 5 shows a scenario in which regionalization is greater despite the same coverage and spread. The figure has three color-coded subdistributions, and there is a clear connection between empty regions and identifying distinct groups, but that is not the current sense of polarization (both group identification and distinctness are discussed below as separate senses). What this diagram makes clear is that in (a) the subdistributions on the left are clustered together and as a result the distribution is less polarized than in (b) when they are not. Figure 5. Distributions with equal coverage and spread, but in which (b) shows a larger number of empty spaces between occupied areas, indicating greater polarization in the sense of regionalization.

9 THE JOURNAL OF MATHEMATICAL SOCIOLOGY 87 Although coverage, spread, and regionalization have appropriate and useful applications, they may be the weakest senses of polarization for many practical reasons: 1. Many surveys report at least one response for each value; 2. They fail to capture the locations of the attitudes; 3. They fail to capture the frequency of attitudes along the spectrum; and 4. Multiple, vastly different distributions will be produce identical measurements. Although a combination of all three does provide a rough picture, the location and frequency of attitudes matters a great deal in capturing our intuitive notion of polarization. While the refinements below add these features, the simple measures above are distinct features of distributions that should be distinguished in analyses of polarization phenomena. They are most useful for sparse data because they can still achieve exact, high-confidence results in such circumstances Community fragmentation The core of community fragmentation is the degree to which the population can be broken into subpopulations. As a conceptually independent sense of polarization, the more groups there are, the greater the polarization. The number of groups, in and of itself, does not reflect the distribution of attitudes; that is, holding all descriptions of the size and shape of the distribution constant, more separate groups imply more polarization in this sense. Note that in some previous definitions of polarization, a large number of groups indicated a lack of polarization (e.g., Esteban & Ray, 1994), but their reasoning for such a relationship invoked senses of polarization we have separated from just the consideration of the number of groups alone. The implications this has on a situation depends on what is meant by group in that context. Here we consider four different ways of understanding groups. The first way to think about groups is for when there is no information about the social structure underlying an attitude distribution. Groups can be identified directly from the distribution (histogram) as collections of individuals included within the basin of attraction around peaks as in Figures 6 (a) and (b). In this way the groups are identified endogenously by the patterns in attitude values. This approach identifies and counts the modes in the distribution to determine if it is unimodal, bimodal, trimodal, and so forth (Downey & Huffman, 2001). 3 For example, in DiMaggio s figure depicting the attitudes toward abortion (Figure 1 in the introduction) we can visibly discern a group on the far liberal (left) side, and another group in the central position; Figure 6. Polarization increases from (a) to (b) for endogenously defined groups. For exogenously defined groups the histogram for the entire population may be broken in to varying numbers of overlapping sub-populations, as in case (c). 3 Our approach here is a naive approach that simply calculates the number of modes as one plus the number of local minima. In the data analysis presented in Section 6 we find cases in which the peak and valley differ only by a few responses, but this is sufficient to reveal an additional group. Such cases may be better captured with a measure that puts minimal variation restrictions on the distribution and/or counts partial groups based on the variation (see Section 5 for more ideas on combined and hybrid measures). Another alternative is to find endogenous groups according to halo-like technique that connects bins together into groups as long as they are sufficiently similar (Mas, Flache, & Helbing, 2010).

10 88 A. BRAMSON ET AL. furthermore, in most years there is a third group created by an upturn on the far conservative (right) side. So in this strict sense that data is trimodal and would result in a measure of three groups for most years. We revisit this data in detail in Section 6.3. Identifying groups in this way precludes the subpopulations from overlapping because group boundaries are defined by the local minima in the distributions. There are several techniques to identify the local minima in discrete data sets; though considerations such as smoothing roughness, bin locations and sizes, and boundary effects complicate these techniques beyond the scope of this article. For our application of this technique to GSS and other survey data in Section 6, we find the local minima bins as those in which both neighboring bins have greater values (or there are multiple bins of equal value forming a flat valley). Half of the contents of minima bins are distributed to each of the groups of which it is a border (for calculating group sizes). 4 The level of community fracturing is one plus the number of minima, that is, the number of endogenously defined groups. The second way to define groups is by exogenous variables. In many cases the data are organized by ethnicity, nationality, sex, or other categories, for example, attitudes on education spending grouped by education attainment level. Such an application can create overlapping subpopulations such as in Figure 6 (c). In our data analysis section, we demonstrate both endogenous groups and groups defined exogenously by religiosity. A third way that appears in the literature is when the data themselves reflect an implicit group membership. For example, for the abortion opinion data in Figure 1 (and much more like it), authors divide the population at the center line into liberal (left of center) and conservative (right of center) responses. The center line may cut the distribution at a valley or peak or anyplace else, and so these user-defined groups will not generally correspond to the endogenously defined groups. Furthermore, because this ad hoc way of distinguishing groups is data-specific and userdefined, it always picks out the same number of groups (so it is not a measure of the fragmentation). This is an approach to define groups exogenously without requiring data beyond the single distribution of responses by making context-based assumptions about the structure of the underlying population. A fourth way to identify groups comes from agents on networks, grids, or spatial arrangements. Social, physical, and property relationships can all be the basis for grouping individuals together. Furthermore, many of these scenarios allow for degrees of group membership resulting in noninteger numbers of groups and partial group membership. Measures for polarization on spatial and network data require different formalisms even for the same senses presented here. 5 This topic is left for future work. Exogenously defined groups provide a way to include categorical data into our analysis framework as long as it is paired with at least one property that holds ordered values along a spectrum. Each category specifies a group, and the subpopulations are plotted together on the spectrum according to the variable with a distribution of cardinal values. For example, in the GSS data presented in Figure 1 we can identify groups endogenously by the shape of the distribution as previously described, or we could group the responses into party self-identification (e.g., Democrat, Republican, other; see Christen et al., 2013). Or we could do both and compare the results (as we do in Section 6). It is important for this sense as a measure of polarization that the number of groups is not known a priori because that is the feature being measured. It is therefore clear that although there are changes in the number of exogenous groups across time and locations, it is the endogenous sense that is more useful as a measure. 4 In applications to higher-dimensional data, endogenously defining the groups requires finding the manifolds of the distribution a well-defined, but much more complicated, similar procedure. 5 Even in the case of measuring the number of groups, the task is more complicated for network and spatial data. Take, for example, the various algorithms for detecting community structure (and hence the number of communities) in networks. Those network connections only reflect part of the story, and a measure of polarization on networks must combine the community structure of the agents with their attitude values into a single polarization measure.

11 THE JOURNAL OF MATHEMATICAL SOCIOLOGY Role of groups in some senses of polarization There are other ways to identify groups (such as hierarchical clustering), and some other feature of the population besides what we have called groups could operate as a measure of community fragmentation. Even when the groups are defined in the way presented above, our current project aims at analyzing the polarization in the distributions of attitudes rather than the groups themselves. While the number of groups acts as a distinct sense of polarization, the group identification methods described above also play a role in the measures that follow. Because the measures below require comparisons among subpopulations or sub-distributions, different group identification methods yield variants of the interpretations and polarizations measures to come. When appropriate, one could use different techniques for measuring community fracturing versus the identification of groups for the other senses Distinctness After we have identified or defined groups, we can ask how different these subpopulations or subdistributions are. What matters for polarization in the sense of distinctness is how well we can distinguish the groups. The more clearly the groups can be seen as separate, the more polarized the total population is, regardless of the distance between groups, their size, and the levels of internal consensus (other senses described below). Another way to think about this sense is how unlikely it would be to confuse a person belonging to one group as belonging to another one; the less likely that confusion, the more distinct (and hence polarized) the groups. This sense of polarization can be captured in at least a few ways. One way is to rank the groups in order of their mean attitude values and then perform pair-wise comparisons of the distributions using the Kolgomorov-Smirnov (KS) two-sample test (Kaner, Mohanty, & Lyons, 1980; Wilcox, 1997). The KS test is a nonparametric way to examine two sets of data and determines the probability that they were drawn from the same distribution, without making any assumptions about what those distributions might be. The resulting p-values for their being separate distributions act as measures of the distinctness of the groups. A related N-sample test or Bayesian method could potentially extend that approach for any number of groups instead of aggregating pairwise results. In many applications a simpler measure may suffice to capture the level of distinctness. If the groups are exogenously defined then the overlap between groups (the number of individuals in group A that match attitude values with individuals in group B) works as a pairwise comparison. The Jaccard distance measure captures this as 1 ja \ Bj= ja [ Bj. The Bhattacharyya distance measures the dissimilarity between two probability distributions and could also be adapted to our current purposes: ln P pffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi r2r yaðrþybðrþ: A less elegant measure of the exogenous distinctness of two groups (but one that is useful for our intended data from surveys and agent-based models) is provided by: 1 jajþ jbj 1 X r2r minfy A ðrþ; y B ðrþg : (6) This formula determines the proportion of the overlap of two distributions by normalizing the sum of the values at each bin of whichever distribution has a lower value in that bin. 6 When there are more than two groups in the analysis, some aggregation of the pairwise comparisons must be made that also keeps the measure insensitive to the number of groups and the group size disparities. In our applications in Section 6 we add all the pairwise scores and then divide by the number of pairwise comparisons: (G 2 G)/2. 6 To visualize how this works, look at Figure 7 (a) and trace along the minimum of the two distributions from left to right. The sum of those heights will be the area of the gray region, which is then normalized by the total population (the size of A plus the size of B).

12 90 A. BRAMSON ET AL. Figure 7. Distinctness scenarios of exogenously defined groups (a) and endogenously identified groups (b). In both cases the distribution in (c) exhibits greater polarization in the sense of distinctness. As defined in Section 3.5, borders for endogenously identified groups occur at the local minima in the distribution. The greater proportion of individuals that exist at this boundary the ones that are between the two neighboring groups the less distinct the groups are. That is, a high frequency of inbetween agents (a mountain pass) is less distinguishing than a low frequency (deep valley). Endogenous distinctness among any number of revealed groups can be calculated via the following formula: 1 X yðrþ yðrþ < yðr 1Þ & yðrþ < yðr þ 1Þ : (7) 0 otherwise r2r For endogenously defined groups, the number of group boundaries is G 1, so we normalize by dividing by this number to take out the effect of a greater number of groups. In application one must also account for the complication that there may be wide valleys (i.e., several contiguous empty bins) such that multiple bins need to be included in the in-between zone. Since some flat areas may be plateaus or outcroppings from a slope, accounting for this detail in identifying only ranges of minima in a simple formula is not possible. Programing a check for these caveats is, however, not at all problematic. Both exogenous and endogenous distinctness are illustrated in Figure 7. What DiMaggio et al. call bimodality is similar to this concept of polarization: people are polarized in this sense insofar as people with different positions on an issue cluster into separate camps, with locations between the two modal positions sparsely occupied (DiMaggio et al., 1996). They note that No issue represents contemporary social conflict as vividly as does abortion, the struggle over which has become symbolic of the so-called culture wars Americans have become more divided in their attitudes towards abortion... Although we will later see that the trend is not strong, it is the case that attitudes toward abortion between 1970 and 1990 (shown in Figure 1) reflect high levels of polarization in the sense of distinctness because few individuals hold positions between the two large groups. Bartels analysis of voting behavior and party identification from 1952 to 1996 reveals that the strength and importance of party identification for voting behavior dropped in the 1960s and 1970s and has rebounded through the 1980s and 1990s. Since their lowest point in 1976, the proportion of strong identifiers has increased while the proportion of weak identifiers decreased (although these trends are not monotonic). Furthermore, the proportion of voters that identify as pure independents has reduced while the independent leaners have increased (Bartels, 2000). If we assume, as most do, that the two major U.S. political parties represent positions toward the left and right sides of a spectrum, and that (at least some of) the independents are between these parties, then we can interpret the described change as increased polarization in the sense of distinctness. The frequency of individuals at the locations of the parties has increased while the frequency of individuals between them has decreased. Bartels information about strong and weak identifiers and pure and leaning independents suffices for this conclusion based on the conceptual breakdown being offered, but because he does not provide numbers for which party they identify with it is insufficient to precisely measure this dispersion Group divergence While group distinctness captures how different groups are with respect to being separated (regardless of how far away those groups are in their attitudes), group divergence captures the

13 THE JOURNAL OF MATHEMATICAL SOCIOLOGY 91 reverse: how distant the groups attitudes are without accounting for their shapes. The more the groups attributes diverge the greater the polarization. For our current purposes it is sufficient to use the normalized distances among the group means (or the area of the convex hull of the means for more than two groups in more than two dimensions). This measure is applicable whether the groups are defined endogenously or exogenously. When there are more than two groups we normalize by the maximum sum of distances possible for G groups on the interval (0,1) (i.e., when all the groups are located at the extremes near 0 and 1). For a set of G attitude subdistributions or subpopulations {g 1...g G }, the normalized pairwise differences in group means is: divergence ¼ 2 X G G 2 G i<j g i g j : (8) Increasing divergence can be easily imagined as two groups moving away from each other. However, any change that increases the distance of the means will increase divergence, which can also be accomplished while holding spread, coverage, distinctness, etc. constant (as depicted in Figure 8). Thus divergence captures yet another distinct and independent, though common, notion of polarization. Diverging means is an obvious and therefore a common way to measure polarization. The examples above from both DiMaggio et al. and Bartels for distinctness also slide into divergence. That is, because these measures were not as finely defined in their work, their analysis fails to separate the distinct senses. Our measure tracks the aggregate distances among group means at each time slice, which can then be compared across variables or time. Other researches have examined the interaction terms of the group means and the year (Page &, Shapiro 1992). That and other versions are explicitly temporal measures with more restrictions, but they are conceptually the same. Figure 8. Attitude distribution (b) shows greater polarization than (a) in the sense of group divergence Group consensus Polarization sometimes describes features of a whole population and/or differences among the groups within that population; instead of these, polarization in the sense of group consensus reflects the make-up of the groups themselves. Groups that are more unified in their positions are internally less polarized for the same reasons described in Section 3.2 on dispersion. However, when there are multiple groups, and each group is unified in its attitude, then the society is more polarized. Separate groups that are individually more diffuse already admit to a variety of attitudes, so the less consensus held by each group the lower the polarization. Group consensus for polarization can be measured via any of the previously considered measures of population dispersion: aggregated in-group absolute deviations, variances, pairwise distances, or even aggregated group spreads. For a set of G attitude sub-distributions (groups) {g 1...g G } with population values {n 1... n G }, our example aggregated group consensus measure is averaged deviations from the group means: group consensus ¼ 1 1 G X G i¼1 2 n i X ni j¼1 x j X i : (9)

14 92 A. BRAMSON ET AL. As the population of each group becomes more focused on a few attitudes, the closer the average distance to the mean is within each group, and the more polarized the population (as illustrated in Figure 9). This holds whether it is the same set of attitudes for both groups or for other areas along the spectrum. Again recall that this sense is independent of the other senses, so group consensus may increase even as the coverage, population dispersion, distinctness, fragmentation, etc. are all held constant. Figure 9. Distribution (b) shows greater polarization than (a) in the sense of group consensus. We have already noted in Section 3.6 that based on Bartels s analysis distinctness increased in the U.S. voting population from the 1970s to the late 1990s. That is also the case with Congressional votes in the US. In the early 1970s, both Senators and Congressmen voted along party lines about 65% of the time; in the early 2000s, that had increased to over 85% (McCarty et al., 2008). That fact itself does not imply that the two parties overlap less on the issue space, or that they are moving further apart, but it does imply that individuals within the groups are moving closer to the center of their respective groups. So these data support a claim that it is in the sense of group consensus, rather than other senses, that polarization is increasing. Finding that the mean positions of the parties has not significantly changed does not countervail this claim of polarization because they are picking up different features of the distribution. Baldassarri and Gelman further note increased consensus among voters in terms of particular issue domains. Looking separately at trends among Republican and Democratic voters we find clear evidence of increasing constraint within issue domains, especially among Republicans. In fact, Republicans have become more consistent on economic and civil rights issues, while Democrats have lost constraint on these issues and become a bit more coherent in their moral views. In both groups of voters, the constraint is growing faster than in the populace as a whole (Baldassarri & Gelman, 2008). Clearly these require a multidimensional issue space and a measure of consensus that aggregates for each each party how they have changed across all the issues. We do not provide that here, but it underlines the need for extending these concepts to measures for higher dimensions because it is clear that this feature will not be picked out and distinguishable from other forms of polarization by approaches using correlation and mean squared errors across time and issues Size parity So far none of our senses is directly affected by the sizes of the groups in a population. Our formal measures up to this point either ignore groups completely or focus on in-group aggregates and Figure 10. Groups with comparable sizes are more polarized than a large group with smaller outlier groups; therefore in the sense of size parity, attitude distribution (a) shows a more polarized population than (b).

15 THE JOURNAL OF MATHEMATICAL SOCIOLOGY 93 comparisons of group means. However, it is clear that subpopulation sizes should play a role in the full collection of polarization concepts. Holding the number of groups constant, a society that has one dominant attitude group with a few small minority outliers is less polarized than one with all similarly sized groups (see Figure 10). Although this sense is independent of the particular attitude distributions of the groups, the reasoning here is that (ceteris paribus) a society is more polarized when differing attitudes are held by large segments of the population rather than just small fringe groups. To measure size parity independently of the other senses requires a formalism that is sensitive to the sizes of the groups while being simultaneously insensitive to the number of groups. A normalized entropy measure fits this description exactly, although for endogenously defined groups this measure may be erratic when the groups change and/or shift boundary bins. For a set of G groups with population proportions {p 1...p G }, size parity entropy ¼ 1 X G p i ln p i : (10) ln G i¼1 As a revealing application of this measure, consider Americans opinions regarding the role of women (Bolzendahl & Meyers, 2004). We ran our polarization analysis on data from the American National Election Studies from 1972 to 2008 reporting individuals responses (scored from 1 to 7) to the following question: Some people feel that women should have an equal role with men in running business, industry and government. Others feel that women s place is in the home. Where would you place yourself on this scale or haven t you thought much about this? (ANES, 2010). Many of our measures reveal little change in polarization on this topic even while the mean attitude has moved steadily from 3.92 in 1972 to 1.98 in The size parity measure, however, decreased from 0.96 to 0.67 as the population moved from three distinct and substantial clumps toward a distribution that spikes on a score of 1 (equal roles) and falls off quickly as scores increase. In this sense (and in the sense of population dispersion) the polarization regarding women s rights has significantly decreased society has both moved to greater equality and become more unified (less polarized) on this position. 4. Measure independence The distinct senses above are demonstrably pairwise independent within the constraints of certain boundary conditions: for any two senses one can construct an example from two distributions showing that an increase in one sense of polarization does not require or imply an increase (and could be matched with a decrease) in the other sense. Throughout the exposition we have pointed out this sort of independence and constructed our figures to demonstrate a change in only the specific measure being described. The concepts (and their measures) are not, however, completely orthogonal. If one sets and holds constant the value of a third measure it may force the first two to become positively or negatively related (depending on the particular measures involved). For clarity we now provide an example of such a case. Recall that a suggested measure for spread is simply the distance between the maximum and minimum observed value. Coverage is the proportion of bins in which at least one person holds that bin s value. And dispersion is the average distance of data points to the mean. Assume that the distribution is not completely filling the bounded (between 0 and 1) attitude space. 7 To increase spread without varying coverage, one can (for example) move those data points located at positions greater than the median value to larger valued bins. To increase spread without varying dispersion, one can take occupants from near the edge and move one inward and another outward by the same distance. 8 However, if one fixes the spread of the distribution, then moving points to increase 7 This is one of the boundary condition caveats: If both spread and coverage were 100% of a bounded region, then decreasing spread would imply a decrease in coverage, although the reverse is not true. 8 This is a second boundary condition caveat: If each bin initially only has one occupant then moving occupants to increase spread without changing dispersion may be impossible.

16 94 A. BRAMSON ET AL. coverage (by filling in intermediate bins) will generate a change in dispersion as well. Similarly, keeping coverage constant while accommodating increasing spread requires increasing dispersion. Other relationships among multiple measures exist as well. For example, if the number of groups equals the regionalization plus one, then the distinctness is already maximal because the groups have no neighboring or overlapping regions. We do not intend to catalog all these potential relationships because they can be identified and explored (if useful) when they come up in specific applications. We have included this section because we believe that it is scenarios such as these that obfuscate the varied senses of polarization, thus creating confusion in analyzing polarization patterns. Also keep in mind that despite their mathematical linkages the polarization senses detailed here remain conceptually distinct. The fact that they are pairwise measure independent is mostly important for demonstrating them to be separate building blocks rather than for practical considerations. 5. Measure combinations and comparisons Capturing the senses independently is vital for understanding the core conceptual basis of how systems might be polarized. Further noting the connections among the measures in applications is necessary to pierce through the confusion that can occur when applying these senses to data. We can get an even deeper understanding of this family of concepts by developing measures that capture multiple senses at once while still keeping the contributions separated. We do not claim that any one of the above senses fully captures any particular widely used notion of polarization, but rather that these senses constitute minimal building blocks of all such notions. These building blocks can be combined in various ways to capture differing, richer notions of polarization while remaining unambiguous about the features of the distribution being described. As an example, consider the most common measure of polarization in the political literature: bimodality. The use of bimodality implies that the population can be most usefully broken down into exactly two subpopulations, and that a balanced deviation from a moderate position is whatitmeanstobepolarized. Fiorina and Abrams use such a measure for American political opinion by tracing the drop in percent of respondents labeled moderate combined with balanced redistribution to both sides of the moderate position (accumulation to only one side did not count as a polarizing trend to them) (Fiorina et al., 2010). Increases in the bimodality of a distribution can be broken down into increases in several senses of polarization identified here; that is, it is a combination measure of our building block senses. Community fragmentation clearly plays a role because it is important that there are two distinguishable groups. The distinctness of those groups is also important; Fiorina and Abrams are invoking distinctness when they measure the drop in moderate view holders. Group divergence and spread are also included because these increase when equal numbers of responses move to both sides (but less so when they move disproportionately to one side). Neither group consensus nor size parity are explicitly invoked with bimodality, although if there is too little consensus or size parity then the groups may not be visibly discernible as such. Bimodality aggregates at least three (and up to six) distinct senses of polarization, but the problem with this combination is that, while looking at the same data series, one author can claim that bimodality is increasing while another claims it is decreasing. For example, the two groups could become more divergent (increasing average distance to the mean) while the distinctness (lack of individuals at moderate positions) is decreasing. By separating our measures more finely, we can identify both of these changes and focus our discussion on the substantive importance of both trends rather than a semantic disagreement over whether there is polarization and its appropriate measurement. Bimodality is not the only extant polarization measure that can be easily broken down. In Axelrod s well-known model of the dissemination of culture, polarization is characterized by the appearance of regions which are internally homogeneous and have no attributes in common with the other internally homogeneous regions (Axelrod, 1997). In this case the groups are endogenously defined, and the more groups the greater the polarization. But it also requires group consensus and distinctness of the agents traits. Axelrod s meaning of polarization nicely breaks down into the

17 THE JOURNAL OF MATHEMATICAL SOCIOLOGY 95 concepts offered in this paper even though the traits of the agents are not cardinal values and therefore other measures would be required to quantify some aspects of the polarization. As it turns out, due to the specifics of Axelrod s model, coverage as defined above succeeds in capturing almost exactly the quantity that he identifies even though his description evokes the other concepts. 9 Another example of a combined measure is the notion of polarization used by Estaban and Ray: Suppose that the population is grouped into significantly sized clusters, such that each cluster is very similar in terms of the attributes of its members, but different clusters have members with very dissimilar attributes. In that case we would say that the society is polarized (Esteban & Ray, 1994). This version of polarization combines (at least) three senses in our breakdown: (1) there needs to be at least two discernible groups that are both (2) widely divergent and (3) have a strong group consensus. For Estaban and Ray s purpose, of teasing out conditions ripe for social unrest, this combination may be the most appropriate, and seeing it as a combination of features facilitates a more refined analysis and a deeper comparison to other polarization phenomena. Flache and Macy s definition is similar: By polarization we mean that a population divides into a small number of factions with high internal consensus and sharp disagreement between them (Flache & Macy, 2011). For Flache and Macy, sharp disagreement seems to imply distinctness either in place of, or in addition to, divergence combined with the existence of multiple groups with high consensus. These examples further highlight that polarization is a cluster concept; neither divergence nor distinctness is necessary for polarization no single feature of the nine presented here is necessary, but the features can be combined to form broader definitions as appropriate for the application at hand. Seeing them as different combinations, rather than distinct and incommensurate definitions/measures, ties the the disparate versions of polarization together without prioritizing them. 5.1 Confidence measures A further consideration that is left out of the current analysis is the incorporation of confidence into the polarization measures. As you will see, the analysis below uses the percentage of respondents in each category (answer) as the frequency of that response. In some years the number of respondents is fewer than 700 (in weighted terms), while in other years it is greater than 2,000. We do not take account of this response rate variance in our measures. In calculating the number of endogenously defined groups, for example, a valley with a value of 1.0 between two bins with value 10.0 counts just as much as a valley with a value of 9.9 (although that difference in valley height is picked up with the distinctness measure). A more refined measure of polarization of this type might combine both the number of groups, the size parity, the distinctness, and a frequency-based confidence measure. For our current purposes of demonstrating the value of these conceptual distinctions in measuring polarization, these technical considerations are too far afield. Our example measures here are intended to be indicative of these distinctions rather than recommended best practices for teasing these distinctions out of empirical data. 6. Data analysis Our purpose in this article is to help refine and clarify empirical research on polarization so that the discussion can focus on the interpretive questions and substantive issues. As Hirschl et al. point out in their analysis of religious-political polarization, this task is both empirical and interpretive because an empirical trend is unimportant in the absence of substantive interpretation (Hirschl, Booth, Glenna, & Green, 2012). They also make the case that the research literature is divided on this question with several investigators finding a positive trend in religious-political polarization since 1980, and others finding no polarization (Hirschl et al., 2012). Although it is not our aim to support one side or the other on this 9 The discrepancy occurs when multiple islands of agents coincidently possess all the same traits values.

18 96 A. BRAMSON ET AL. debate (or any other debate), we will reevaluate the presence of religious-political polarization through our collection of measures and use these results to reassess the support for their substantial claims. Although debates that cross over multiple data sets tend to burn hotter, and suffer more from incongruous analysis approaches, we will restrict ourselves in this article to analyses that pull their data from the General Social Survey (GSS) dataset. The GSS contains responses to questions on a broad spectrum of topics, including many that are critical for understanding trends in political and social attitudes. The breadth (> 5,500 variables) and continuity ( ) of the GSS makes it an excellent data source for social scientists. However, few of the questions have responses keyed on a 1 6 (or higher) Likert scale. Instead they are limited to 5 values or less or have categorical answers; many are true/false or agree/disagree questions. Although the frequencies of responses in binary or categorical data can reveal trends in attitudes with respect to a specific question, addressing polarization in a broader topic (such as women s rights, religiosity, or intellectualism) typically requires inferences from examining patterns in multiple questions. To measure polarization on the GSS data using the example measures presented above requires us to limit our application to those topics with appropriate ranked-order scoring systems Political polarization As a demonstration of our technique to social-political data, we first address the question of whether there has been polarization in the American populace s general political views. We take the normalized frequencies of the responses to the POLVIEWS question of GSS and apply the above measures to the responses for each year the question was reported. Because we are using a single variable here, the groups are endogenously defined and the group-dependent measures are calculated on the revealed subdistributions. The Hirschl et al. analysis reveals (among other things) that among some Americans (nonsouthern Christian white males) there exists a greater degree of religious belief correlating with a greater likelihood of voting for Republican candidates and a lesser degree of religiosity correlating with a decreasing likelihood of voting Republican. The effect is amplified among the wealthiest quarter of the population. Their analysis includes details that are not important for our discussion here; our goal is not model validation. Instead, we wish to determine to what degree the kind of politico-religious polarization detected by Hirschl et al. can be picked out and measured by our technique. Rather than looking at specific voting behavior, we investigate the presence of polarization in the more general political views captured by the POLVIEWS question of the GSS. The question is: We hear a lot of talk these days about liberals and conservatives. I m going to show you a seven-point scale on which the political views that people might hold are arranged from extremely liberal point 1 to extremely conservative point 7. Where would you place yourself on this scale? First we apply our measures to the political views data by itself, and then we apply our measures to the political views data using the BIBLE question (described below) to define exogenous groups. The POLVIEWS data for the first analysis are filtered by those respondents who also answered the BIBLE question so that our analysis of political views here will match up in years and sample size with our analysis below (see Figure 11). Some measures (such as spread, coverage, and regionalization) are not relevant for this analysis because, as is typical for survey data with a limited number of possible responses, nearly all the bins 10 Specifically, our technique requires ordered response values rather than categorical responses and excludes responses of no response, don t know, can t choose, and the like. Some questions (like POLVIEWS described below) ask participants to rank themselves on a 1-7 scale. These variables can be analyzed without analytical gymnastics across multiple variables. The ABORTION variable we use is, however, a composite of multiple true/false questions that are added together to produce a 0-8 scale.

19 THE JOURNAL OF MATHEMATICAL SOCIOLOGY 97 Figure 11. The POLVIEWS data by religiosity category and combined. Contour plots at the top of each pair show the data with interpolation order 2, the heat maps on the bottoms are color codings of the raw GSS data presented in the Appendix. have at least one entry. 11 Figure 12 shows the results of the relevant polarization measures to the political views. The two most striking results in this plot are: 1. The population dispersion climbs slightly, but not monotonically, from 1984 to 2012; and 2. The number of endogenously defined groups, as well as the measures across those groups, undergo a striking and lasting shift in 1996 (see Table 4 in Appendix for the actual measure values). None of the group-based senses of polarization can be measured when there is only one group, and when groups are being defined endogenously the existence of a single group indicates a single-peaked distribution. In order for there to be an increase in the number of endogenously defined groups, it must be that the distribution has shifted to produce more peaks and valleys. What happened in this case is that in 1996 the proportion of respondents who described themselves as strictly conservative increased from 16.3% to 18.4%, which put that bin above the proportion who described themselves as 11 For the political views data taken together, no bins are empty. When broken down by BIBLE, in 1984 there are no respondents who chose extremely conservative and answered that the bible is a book of fables and that is the only empty bin. For the abortion analysis below, there are a few scattered empty bins for the book of fables group, likely the result of low sample size in some years. They are left out of the analysis because they do not indicate coherent patterns in the data.

20 98 A. BRAMSON ET AL MeasureValue MeasureValue PopulationMean Dispersion CommunityFragmentation Distinctness Divergence GroupConsensus SizeParity Years 0.0 Figure 12. The relevant measures of polarization by year for the POLVIEWS variable filtered by BIBLE. slightly conservative (which went from 16.6% to 16.7%) creating a new peak at the conservative bin. This increased the number of groups, a measure of the community fracturing sense of polarization, but half the bump in conservative can be attributed to an influx from the extremely conservative bin (from 3.9% to 2.8%). The increase in polarization in this case, therefore, is not an overall move to the right, but rather a pull in from the right that increased focus on the pure conservative bin. In 2000 the same thing happens on the liberal side: the pure liberals outnumber the slightly liberals to generate a third mode in the population distribution. That doesn t last, and the liberal side is strictly decreasing again until At that point the trend first creates another group divide at slightly liberal and then the number of groups goes down to two in 2012 because the 14-year conservative peak dissolves. By itself the community fragmentation measure doesn t distinguish where on the spectrum the groups are occurring, only the number of groups. Although there is sometimes two and sometimes three groups after 1996, there is no clear increasing or decreasing pattern. 12 The other group-based measures are normalized by the number of groups to isolate the individual senses; however, the group composition clearly plays a role in determining these measures. From 1996 to 2010 there is a group divide at slightly conservative, and the size parity jumps when a third group also forms (in 2000, 2008, and 2010). In 2012 the single group divide is at the bin representing slightly liberal, and the conservative and moderates are all in a group together. As one can tell from the higher than 50% population mean value, the total population leans right, so the size parity plummets when the distribution shifts in this way. Although the direct effect of the number of groups has been distilled from that measure, cutting the population up in different ways can produce sudden, drastic changes in other measures. More important than any of these specific results is (1) the differences in the polarization for the different measures and (2) the difference between this collection of measures and other approaches. The population dispersion experiences a slow and steady increase despite the abrupt changes in the shape of the distribution picked up by other measures. The suite of measures provided here capture each aspect of that change separately to provide a thorough description of the attitude dynamics. They do not reveal a consistent polarizing trend in Americans political views. Within the timespan for which groups are observed ( ) group divergence, distinctness, consensus, and size parity do not consistently change, so we have just one sense in which the population polarized: community fragmentation. This one sense in which we do see polarization is connected to Fiorina and Abrams notion of bimodality, although more subtle because it is not the case that moderates decrease and the extremes increase. The extreme positions vary, but not in a consistent way. The movement is from nearly moderate positions to slightly less moderate positions on both sides. That sounds similar to what was intended by bimodality, but it would not be picked up by a direct bimodality detector because the percent of moderate responses actually increase through the 1994 to 2000 period in which the 12 A regression analysis between the community fragmentation measure and the year naturally reveals a positive relation with high confidence, but with so few samples (18 years) and a single variable this is not an appropriate characterization of coherent patterns in the data.

21 THE JOURNAL OF MATHEMATICAL SOCIOLOGY 99 number of discernible groups increases. Our measure of community fragmentation (essentially the number of modes) picks up lopsided changes, and it is agnostic with regard to the global distribution of attitudes (e.g. generally normal, inverse normal, or fat tailed). It only does one thing, and it does it precisely. Because the overall population is not appreciably drifting apart (as measured by population dispersion and group divergence) one may be inclined to deny the presence of polarization. But those are different senses of polarization than fragmentation, and in the sense of community fragmentation there is an increase in polarization from the pre-1995 period that persists throughout the post-1995 period Political polarization by religiosity Although some authors have pointed to religion as being a strong driver of social polarization (e.g., Evans, 2002; Hunter, 1991), ideas differ regarding how to categorize religiosity. Following Hirschl et al. we adopt responses to the BIBLE question from the GSS as a reasonable proxy, or indicator, of respondent religiosity. This question asks participants Which of these statements comes closest to describing your feelings about the Bible? Respondents must choose one of the following answers (or opt out): (a) The Bible is the actual word of God and is to be taken literally, word for word. (b) The Bible is the inspired word of God but not everything in it should be taken literally, word for word. (c) The Bible is an ancient book of fables, legends, history, and moral precepts recorded by men. Because there are only three responses available for this question it is not recommended that one apply our measures to this attitude distribution directly. Instead, we use these three responses to define exogenous groups, and use these groups to run our polarization analysis on the same political views spectrum above. For the BIBLE question, there are no empty bins for any years, so the community fragmentation measure is entirely determined by the number of possible responses to that question in this case three. 13 It is not surprising to find that the mean political views of the Word of God group is consistently more conservative than the Book of Fables group. Furthermore, except in 1997 when the Word of God groups scored slightly less conservative than the Inspired Word group, the more religious groups were also increasingly conservative from 1984 to It is clear from Figure 13 that the population dispersion and the average in-group dispersion values captured by group consensus are nearly identical. Group consensus is higher because the largest group, Inspired Word, has a lower dispersion than the other two (which are nearly identical), and the group consensus measure averages the three groups without adjusting for their sizes. None of the measures show high degrees of fluctuation or dramatic trends, so any claim to polarization of political views by religiosity must be weak. The clearest sign of increased polarization is from group divergence (the average distance among the group means). The value in 1984 is , and the value in 2012 is ; although the rise is not monotonic, it is the case that only two years prior to 1996 reached above 0.12, while every year after 1996 scored above Hence there is some indication that the average political views of the highly religious and secular groups are crawling away from each other. Size parity also shows a slight trend of increasing polarization: it rose from the lowest value (in 2002) of to in This reflects a sharp increase in the percentage of respondents who gave the Book of Fables answer from 14% to 22%, most of which came from the largest group 13 There are cases, for other questions, in which some response values are not given by anybody for some years. If these questions are used to exogenously define groups, then the number of groups will change across time. As mentioned earlier, this is rare for survey data, but when analyzing simulation models it is common for predefined types of agents to enter and leave the population.

22 100 A. BRAMSON ET AL MeasureValue MeasureValue PopulationMean Dispersion Distinctness Divergence GroupConsensus SizeParity Years Figure 13. The relevant measures of polarization by year for the POLVIEWS variable grouped by BIBLE. Inspired Words went from 56% to 46%. These religiosity group size changes do produce changes in the political view distributions, so the do not show up in the other measures. That is, changes in size parity are measures of the polarization of political views through changes in religiosity rather than changes in political views. 14 However, since the lowest value of size parity occurs in 2002 we cannot make the claim that there is an overall increasing trend, only that the sizes of the religiosity groups have been equalizing over the last 10 years of data. 15 The measures of distinctness and group consensus have negative trends, but only barely. For distinctness there is a negligible increase from 1984 until the high point in 2002, after which it declines noticeably. Distinctness went from a high of in 2002 down to in 2012, meaning that there was an 8.68% increase in the average amount of overlapping responses among the groups. The religiously separate groups are becoming politically less polarized with respect to their distinctness. Group consensus reveals a more consistently downward trend, but the difference in values is too small to make any conclusions. All together our measures indicate that the political polarization of the populace (1) is minor, (2) is confined to specific aspects of the distribution, and (3) is increasing or decreasing depending on the aspect examined. Furthermore, although the supposed religious divide certainly exists and is reflected in the groups political views, it is only slowly widening. That widening may be offset by the flattening of political attitudes within the religious groups, and perhaps a disconnecting of religious and political views Abortion rights polarization We now turn our attention to an issue that, while not directly political, is politically heated and tied to religiosity: abortion rights. The abortion rights issue has drawn a lot of attention because it is a hot media item and because the data so clearly reveal different modes of thought on the issue (recall Figure 1). Previous analyses have remarked that the attitude distribution on this topic is divided but stable (Bolzendahl & Meyers, 2004; DiMaggio et al., 1996). We already referenced abortion opinion data in the introduction and to demonstrate endogenous group distinctions in Section 3.5; now we present a full polarization analysis of the GSS abortion data (see Figure 14). The role of religiosity in explaining the split in opinions has been addressed by Evans (2002) and others, but their methodologies are not directly comparable. 14 Because the GSS data used here are not from longitudinal studies, we are not detecting individuals changing their religiosity, but just a reflection of changes in the cross section of social attitudes. 15 One must resist the inclination of assigning a negative connotation to polarization in the interpretation of these results. Here polarization is a purely descriptive term. It may very well be beneficial to have equal numbers of people in each group in some cases, and everybody in one group for other cases. The context determines whether high or low polarization values are desirable.

23 THE JOURNAL OF MATHEMATICAL SOCIOLOGY 101 Figure 14. The ABORTION data itself and broken down by by religiosity category. Contour plots at the top of each pair show the data with interpolation order 2, the heat maps on the bottoms are color codings of the proportions in the raw GSS data presented in the appendix. The GSS has included a variety of questions regarding opinions about abortion issues that varied by year. Overall opinions about abortion are determined by aggregating the responses to these questions to produce a fuller time series dataset (with respect to numbers and years of responses). 16 The results of applying our measures to the abortion opinions data are presented in Figure 15. Just as before, the values for spread, regionalization, and coverage are left out because, as is typical with Likert scale survey data, all bins are occupied yielding values of one, zero, and one respectively. With eight possible responses, it is still the case that the maximum number of endogenously defined groups is four. The actual number of mode-defined groups is consistently three (except in 1990 when there are four and in 2008 when there are two), but the locations of the minima that separate these groups constantly change locations. First note that when strictly measured, the number of modes in the data is only equal to two in a single year: strictly, speaking, the data are not bimodal. There are two dominant peaks, but the distribution is typically trimodal. 16 Specifically, the ABORTION variable used here is aggregated by COMPUTE from the study /html/d3/gss12 and reported by the SDA tool (Thomas, 2013) as the sum of ABDEFECT, ABNOMORE, ABHLTH, ABPOOR, ABRAPE, ABSINGLE, and ABANY (Smith, Marsden, Hout, & Kim, 2013). First we analyze the ABORTION variable by year filtered by BIBLE, and then grouped exogenously by BIBLE (paralleling our analysis of POLVIEWS above). The composite ABORTION variable has response positions ordered from more liberal to more restrictive, whereas the POLVIEWS had seven.

Chapter 1 Introduction and Goals

Chapter 1 Introduction and Goals Chapter 1 Introduction and Goals The literature on residential segregation is one of the oldest empirical research traditions in sociology and has long been a core topic in the study of social stratification

More information

Philosophical Analysis in Modeling Polarization: Notes from a Work in Progress

Philosophical Analysis in Modeling Polarization: Notes from a Work in Progress 1 Philosophical Analysis in Modeling Polarization: Notes from a Work in Progress Patrick Grim, Aaron Bramson, Daniel J. Singer, Steven Fisher, Carissa Flocken and William Berger Introduction Computational

More information

Do two parties represent the US? Clustering analysis of US public ideology survey

Do two parties represent the US? Clustering analysis of US public ideology survey Do two parties represent the US? Clustering analysis of US public ideology survey Louisa Lee 1 and Siyu Zhang 2, 3 Advised by: Vicky Chuqiao Yang 1 1 Department of Engineering Sciences and Applied Mathematics,

More information

Partisan Nation: The Rise of Affective Partisan Polarization in the American Electorate

Partisan Nation: The Rise of Affective Partisan Polarization in the American Electorate Partisan Nation: The Rise of Affective Partisan Polarization in the American Electorate Alan I. Abramowitz Department of Political Science Emory University Abstract Partisan conflict has reached new heights

More information

What is The Probability Your Vote will Make a Difference?

What is The Probability Your Vote will Make a Difference? Berkeley Law From the SelectedWorks of Aaron Edlin 2009 What is The Probability Your Vote will Make a Difference? Andrew Gelman, Columbia University Nate Silver Aaron S. Edlin, University of California,

More information

The 2017 TRACE Matrix Bribery Risk Matrix

The 2017 TRACE Matrix Bribery Risk Matrix The 2017 TRACE Matrix Bribery Risk Matrix Methodology Report Corruption is notoriously difficult to measure. Even defining it can be a challenge, beyond the standard formula of using public position for

More information

All s Well That Ends Well: A Reply to Oneal, Barbieri & Peters*

All s Well That Ends Well: A Reply to Oneal, Barbieri & Peters* 2003 Journal of Peace Research, vol. 40, no. 6, 2003, pp. 727 732 Sage Publications (London, Thousand Oaks, CA and New Delhi) www.sagepublications.com [0022-3433(200311)40:6; 727 732; 038292] All s Well

More information

No Adults Allowed! Unsupervised Learning Applied to Gerrymandered School Districts

No Adults Allowed! Unsupervised Learning Applied to Gerrymandered School Districts No Adults Allowed! Unsupervised Learning Applied to Gerrymandered School Districts Divya Siddarth, Amber Thomas 1. INTRODUCTION With more than 80% of public school students attending the school assigned

More information

Analyzing and Representing Two-Mode Network Data Week 8: Reading Notes

Analyzing and Representing Two-Mode Network Data Week 8: Reading Notes Analyzing and Representing Two-Mode Network Data Week 8: Reading Notes Wasserman and Faust Chapter 8: Affiliations and Overlapping Subgroups Affiliation Network (Hypernetwork/Membership Network): Two mode

More information

A positive correlation between turnout and plurality does not refute the rational voter model

A positive correlation between turnout and plurality does not refute the rational voter model Quality & Quantity 26: 85-93, 1992. 85 O 1992 Kluwer Academic Publishers. Printed in the Netherlands. Note A positive correlation between turnout and plurality does not refute the rational voter model

More information

THE WORKMEN S CIRCLE SURVEY OF AMERICAN JEWS. Jews, Economic Justice & the Vote in Steven M. Cohen and Samuel Abrams

THE WORKMEN S CIRCLE SURVEY OF AMERICAN JEWS. Jews, Economic Justice & the Vote in Steven M. Cohen and Samuel Abrams THE WORKMEN S CIRCLE SURVEY OF AMERICAN JEWS Jews, Economic Justice & the Vote in 2012 Steven M. Cohen and Samuel Abrams 1/4/2013 2 Overview Economic justice concerns were the critical consideration dividing

More information

Author(s) Title Date Dataset(s) Abstract

Author(s) Title Date Dataset(s) Abstract Author(s): Traugott, Michael Title: Memo to Pilot Study Committee: Understanding Campaign Effects on Candidate Recall and Recognition Date: February 22, 1990 Dataset(s): 1988 National Election Study, 1989

More information

The Polarization of Public Opinion about Competence

The Polarization of Public Opinion about Competence The Polarization of Public Opinion about Competence Jane Green University of Manchester Will Jennings University of Southampton First draft: please do not cite Paper prepared for the American Political

More information

Was the Late 19th Century a Golden Age of Racial Integration?

Was the Late 19th Century a Golden Age of Racial Integration? Was the Late 19th Century a Golden Age of Racial Integration? David M. Frankel (Iowa State University) January 23, 24 Abstract Cutler, Glaeser, and Vigdor (JPE 1999) find evidence that the late 19th century

More information

Strategic Partisanship: Party Priorities, Agenda Control and the Decline of Bipartisan Cooperation in the House

Strategic Partisanship: Party Priorities, Agenda Control and the Decline of Bipartisan Cooperation in the House Strategic Partisanship: Party Priorities, Agenda Control and the Decline of Bipartisan Cooperation in the House Laurel Harbridge Assistant Professor, Department of Political Science Faculty Fellow, Institute

More information

Political Economics II Spring Lectures 4-5 Part II Partisan Politics and Political Agency. Torsten Persson, IIES

Political Economics II Spring Lectures 4-5 Part II Partisan Politics and Political Agency. Torsten Persson, IIES Lectures 4-5_190213.pdf Political Economics II Spring 2019 Lectures 4-5 Part II Partisan Politics and Political Agency Torsten Persson, IIES 1 Introduction: Partisan Politics Aims continue exploring policy

More information

Telephone Survey. Contents *

Telephone Survey. Contents * Telephone Survey Contents * Tables... 2 Figures... 2 Introduction... 4 Survey Questionnaire... 4 Sampling Methods... 5 Study Population... 5 Sample Size... 6 Survey Procedures... 6 Data Analysis Method...

More information

Iowa Voting Series, Paper 4: An Examination of Iowa Turnout Statistics Since 2000 by Party and Age Group

Iowa Voting Series, Paper 4: An Examination of Iowa Turnout Statistics Since 2000 by Party and Age Group Department of Political Science Publications 3-1-2014 Iowa Voting Series, Paper 4: An Examination of Iowa Turnout Statistics Since 2000 by Party and Age Group Timothy M. Hagle University of Iowa 2014 Timothy

More information

Iowa Voting Series, Paper 6: An Examination of Iowa Absentee Voting Since 2000

Iowa Voting Series, Paper 6: An Examination of Iowa Absentee Voting Since 2000 Department of Political Science Publications 5-1-2014 Iowa Voting Series, Paper 6: An Examination of Iowa Absentee Voting Since 2000 Timothy M. Hagle University of Iowa 2014 Timothy M. Hagle Comments This

More information

Analysis of public opinion on Macedonia s accession to Author: Ivan Damjanovski

Analysis of public opinion on Macedonia s accession to Author: Ivan Damjanovski Analysis of public opinion on Macedonia s accession to the European Union 2014-2016 Author: Ivan Damjanovski CONCLUSIONS 3 The trends regarding support for Macedonia s EU membership are stable and follow

More information

LONG RUN GROWTH, CONVERGENCE AND FACTOR PRICES

LONG RUN GROWTH, CONVERGENCE AND FACTOR PRICES LONG RUN GROWTH, CONVERGENCE AND FACTOR PRICES By Bart Verspagen* Second draft, July 1998 * Eindhoven University of Technology, Faculty of Technology Management, and MERIT, University of Maastricht. Email:

More information

Introduction to the declination function for gerrymanders

Introduction to the declination function for gerrymanders Introduction to the declination function for gerrymanders Gregory S. Warrington Department of Mathematics & Statistics, University of Vermont, 16 Colchester Ave., Burlington, VT 05401, USA November 4,

More information

Learning from Small Subsamples without Cherry Picking: The Case of Non-Citizen Registration and Voting

Learning from Small Subsamples without Cherry Picking: The Case of Non-Citizen Registration and Voting Learning from Small Subsamples without Cherry Picking: The Case of Non-Citizen Registration and Voting Jesse Richman Old Dominion University jrichman@odu.edu David C. Earnest Old Dominion University, and

More information

Should the Democrats move to the left on economic policy?

Should the Democrats move to the left on economic policy? Should the Democrats move to the left on economic policy? Andrew Gelman Cexun Jeffrey Cai November 9, 2007 Abstract Could John Kerry have gained votes in the recent Presidential election by more clearly

More information

1 Electoral Competition under Certainty

1 Electoral Competition under Certainty 1 Electoral Competition under Certainty We begin with models of electoral competition. This chapter explores electoral competition when voting behavior is deterministic; the following chapter considers

More information

STATISTICAL GRAPHICS FOR VISUALIZING DATA

STATISTICAL GRAPHICS FOR VISUALIZING DATA STATISTICAL GRAPHICS FOR VISUALIZING DATA Tables and Figures, I William G. Jacoby Michigan State University and ICPSR University of Illinois at Chicago October 14-15, 21 http://polisci.msu.edu/jacoby/uic/graphics

More information

National Corrections Reporting Program (NCRP) White Paper Series

National Corrections Reporting Program (NCRP) White Paper Series National Corrections Reporting Program (NCRP) White Paper Series White Paper #3: A Description of Computing Code Used to Identify Correctional Terms and Histories Revised, September 15, 2014 Prepared by:

More information

The Integer Arithmetic of Legislative Dynamics

The Integer Arithmetic of Legislative Dynamics The Integer Arithmetic of Legislative Dynamics Kenneth Benoit Trinity College Dublin Michael Laver New York University July 8, 2005 Abstract Every legislature may be defined by a finite integer partition

More information

Cluster Analysis. (see also: Segmentation)

Cluster Analysis. (see also: Segmentation) Cluster Analysis (see also: Segmentation) Cluster Analysis Ø Unsupervised: no target variable for training Ø Partition the data into groups (clusters) so that: Ø Observations within a cluster are similar

More information

Wisconsin Economic Scorecard

Wisconsin Economic Scorecard RESEARCH PAPER> May 2012 Wisconsin Economic Scorecard Analysis: Determinants of Individual Opinion about the State Economy Joseph Cera Researcher Survey Center Manager The Wisconsin Economic Scorecard

More information

Learning and Visualizing Political Issues from Voting Records Erik Goldman, Evan Cox, Mikhail Kerzhner. Abstract

Learning and Visualizing Political Issues from Voting Records Erik Goldman, Evan Cox, Mikhail Kerzhner. Abstract Learning and Visualizing Political Issues from Voting Records Erik Goldman, Evan Cox, Mikhail Kerzhner Abstract For our project, we analyze data from US Congress voting records, a dataset that consists

More information

Dimension Reduction. Why and How

Dimension Reduction. Why and How Dimension Reduction Why and How The Curse of Dimensionality As the dimensionality (i.e. number of variables) of a space grows, data points become so spread out that the ideas of distance and density become

More information

Essential Questions Content Skills Assessments Standards/PIs. Identify prime and composite numbers, GCF, and prime factorization.

Essential Questions Content Skills Assessments Standards/PIs. Identify prime and composite numbers, GCF, and prime factorization. Map: MVMS Math 7 Type: Consensus Grade Level: 7 School Year: 2007-2008 Author: Paula Barnes District/Building: Minisink Valley CSD/Middle School Created: 10/19/2007 Last Updated: 11/06/2007 How does the

More information

Lab 3: Logistic regression models

Lab 3: Logistic regression models Lab 3: Logistic regression models In this lab, we will apply logistic regression models to United States (US) presidential election data sets. The main purpose is to predict the outcomes of presidential

More information

Mathematics and Social Choice Theory. Topic 4 Voting methods with more than 2 alternatives. 4.1 Social choice procedures

Mathematics and Social Choice Theory. Topic 4 Voting methods with more than 2 alternatives. 4.1 Social choice procedures Mathematics and Social Choice Theory Topic 4 Voting methods with more than 2 alternatives 4.1 Social choice procedures 4.2 Analysis of voting methods 4.3 Arrow s Impossibility Theorem 4.4 Cumulative voting

More information

DU PhD in Home Science

DU PhD in Home Science DU PhD in Home Science Topic:- DU_J18_PHD_HS 1) Electronic journal usually have the following features: i. HTML/ PDF formats ii. Part of bibliographic databases iii. Can be accessed by payment only iv.

More information

Expected Modes of Policy Change in Comparative Institutional Settings * Christopher K. Butler and Thomas H. Hammond

Expected Modes of Policy Change in Comparative Institutional Settings * Christopher K. Butler and Thomas H. Hammond Expected Modes of Policy Change in Comparative Institutional Settings * Christopher K. Butler and Thomas H. Hammond Presented at the Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, Washington,

More information

Remaking the Apartheid City* Presentation of Data: Durban, Draft, May 2007

Remaking the Apartheid City* Presentation of Data: Durban, Draft, May 2007 Remaking the Apartheid City* Presentation of Data: Durban, 1996-2001 Draft, May 2007 Daniel Schensul, Lead Investigator Ph.D. Candidate Department of Sociology Daniel_Schensul@Brown.edu Patrick Heller,

More information

A Global Perspective on Socioeconomic Differences in Learning Outcomes

A Global Perspective on Socioeconomic Differences in Learning Outcomes 2009/ED/EFA/MRT/PI/19 Background paper prepared for the Education for All Global Monitoring Report 2009 Overcoming Inequality: why governance matters A Global Perspective on Socioeconomic Differences in

More information

Evidence-Based Policy Planning for the Leon County Detention Center: Population Trends and Forecasts

Evidence-Based Policy Planning for the Leon County Detention Center: Population Trends and Forecasts Evidence-Based Policy Planning for the Leon County Detention Center: Population Trends and Forecasts Prepared for the Leon County Sheriff s Office January 2018 Authors J.W. Andrew Ranson William D. Bales

More information

Chapter 1. Introduction

Chapter 1. Introduction Chapter 1 Introduction 1 2 CHAPTER 1. INTRODUCTION This dissertation provides an analysis of some important consequences of multilevel governance. The concept of multilevel governance refers to the dispersion

More information

The Effectiveness of Receipt-Based Attacks on ThreeBallot

The Effectiveness of Receipt-Based Attacks on ThreeBallot The Effectiveness of Receipt-Based Attacks on ThreeBallot Kevin Henry, Douglas R. Stinson, Jiayuan Sui David R. Cheriton School of Computer Science University of Waterloo Waterloo, N, N2L 3G1, Canada {k2henry,

More information

Elite Polarization and Mass Political Engagement: Information, Alienation, and Mobilization

Elite Polarization and Mass Political Engagement: Information, Alienation, and Mobilization JOURNAL OF INTERNATIONAL AND AREA STUDIES Volume 20, Number 1, 2013, pp.89-109 89 Elite Polarization and Mass Political Engagement: Information, Alienation, and Mobilization Jae Mook Lee Using the cumulative

More information

Parties, Candidates, Issues: electoral competition revisited

Parties, Candidates, Issues: electoral competition revisited Parties, Candidates, Issues: electoral competition revisited Introduction The partisan competition is part of the operation of political parties, ranging from ideology to issues of public policy choices.

More information

Wasserman & Faust, chapter 5

Wasserman & Faust, chapter 5 Wasserman & Faust, chapter 5 Centrality and Prestige - Primary goal is identification of the most important actors in a social network. - Prestigious actors are those with large indegrees, or choices received.

More information

Colorado 2014: Comparisons of Predicted and Actual Turnout

Colorado 2014: Comparisons of Predicted and Actual Turnout Colorado 2014: Comparisons of Predicted and Actual Turnout Date 2017-08-28 Project name Colorado 2014 Voter File Analysis Prepared for Washington Monthly and Project Partners Prepared by Pantheon Analytics

More information

1. The Relationship Between Party Control, Latino CVAP and the Passage of Bills Benefitting Immigrants

1. The Relationship Between Party Control, Latino CVAP and the Passage of Bills Benefitting Immigrants The Ideological and Electoral Determinants of Laws Targeting Undocumented Migrants in the U.S. States Online Appendix In this additional methodological appendix I present some alternative model specifications

More information

Evaluating the Connection Between Internet Coverage and Polling Accuracy

Evaluating the Connection Between Internet Coverage and Polling Accuracy Evaluating the Connection Between Internet Coverage and Polling Accuracy California Propositions 2005-2010 Erika Oblea December 12, 2011 Statistics 157 Professor Aldous Oblea 1 Introduction: Polls are

More information

'Wave riding' or 'Owning the issue': How do candidates determine campaign agendas?

'Wave riding' or 'Owning the issue': How do candidates determine campaign agendas? 'Wave riding' or 'Owning the issue': How do candidates determine campaign agendas? Mariya Burdina University of Colorado, Boulder Department of Economics October 5th, 008 Abstract In this paper I adress

More information

Patterns of Housing Voucher Use Revisited: Segregation and Section 8 Using Updated Data and More Precise Comparison Groups, 2013

Patterns of Housing Voucher Use Revisited: Segregation and Section 8 Using Updated Data and More Precise Comparison Groups, 2013 Patterns of Housing Voucher Use Revisited: Segregation and Section 8 Using Updated Data and More Precise Comparison Groups, 2013 Molly W. Metzger, Assistant Professor, Washington University in St. Louis

More information

Employment Outlook 2017

Employment Outlook 2017 Annexes Chapter 3. How technology and globalisation are transforming the labour market Employment Outlook 2017 TABLE OF CONTENTS ANNEX 3.A3 ADDITIONAL EVIDENCE ON POLARISATION BY REGION... 1 ANNEX 3.A4

More information

The Borda count in n-dimensional issue space*

The Borda count in n-dimensional issue space* Public Choice 59:167-176 (1988) Kluwer Academic Publishers The Borda count in n-dimensional issue space* SCOTT L. FELD Department of Sociology, State University of ew York, at Stony Brook BERARD GROFMA

More information

Part 1: Focus on Income. Inequality. EMBARGOED until 5/28/14. indicator definitions and Rankings

Part 1: Focus on Income. Inequality. EMBARGOED until 5/28/14. indicator definitions and Rankings Part 1: Focus on Income indicator definitions and Rankings Inequality STATE OF NEW YORK CITY S HOUSING & NEIGHBORHOODS IN 2013 7 Focus on Income Inequality New York City has seen rising levels of income

More information

Online Appendix: Robustness Tests and Migration. Means

Online Appendix: Robustness Tests and Migration. Means VOL. VOL NO. ISSUE EMPLOYMENT, WAGES AND VOTER TURNOUT Online Appendix: Robustness Tests and Migration Means Online Appendix Table 1 presents the summary statistics of turnout for the five types of elections

More information

LABOUR-MARKET INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS IN OECD-COUNTRIES: WHAT EXPLANATIONS FIT THE DATA?

LABOUR-MARKET INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS IN OECD-COUNTRIES: WHAT EXPLANATIONS FIT THE DATA? LABOUR-MARKET INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS IN OECD-COUNTRIES: WHAT EXPLANATIONS FIT THE DATA? By Andreas Bergh (PhD) Associate Professor in Economics at Lund University and the Research Institute of Industrial

More information

Matthew A. Cole and Eric Neumayer. The pitfalls of convergence analysis : is the income gap really widening?

Matthew A. Cole and Eric Neumayer. The pitfalls of convergence analysis : is the income gap really widening? LSE Research Online Article (refereed) Matthew A. Cole and Eric Neumayer The pitfalls of convergence analysis : is the income gap really widening? Originally published in Applied economics letters, 10

More information

5A. Wage Structures in the Electronics Industry. Benjamin A. Campbell and Vincent M. Valvano

5A. Wage Structures in the Electronics Industry. Benjamin A. Campbell and Vincent M. Valvano 5A.1 Introduction 5A. Wage Structures in the Electronics Industry Benjamin A. Campbell and Vincent M. Valvano Over the past 2 years, wage inequality in the U.S. economy has increased rapidly. In this chapter,

More information

AP PHOTO/MATT VOLZ. Voter Trends in A Final Examination. By Rob Griffin, Ruy Teixeira, and John Halpin November 2017

AP PHOTO/MATT VOLZ. Voter Trends in A Final Examination. By Rob Griffin, Ruy Teixeira, and John Halpin November 2017 AP PHOTO/MATT VOLZ Voter Trends in 2016 A Final Examination By Rob Griffin, Ruy Teixeira, and John Halpin November 2017 WWW.AMERICANPROGRESS.ORG Voter Trends in 2016 A Final Examination By Rob Griffin,

More information

Introduction to Path Analysis: Multivariate Regression

Introduction to Path Analysis: Multivariate Regression Introduction to Path Analysis: Multivariate Regression EPSY 905: Multivariate Analysis Spring 2016 Lecture #7 March 9, 2016 EPSY 905: Multivariate Regression via Path Analysis Today s Lecture Multivariate

More information

Chapter. Estimating the Value of a Parameter Using Confidence Intervals Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved

Chapter. Estimating the Value of a Parameter Using Confidence Intervals Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved Chapter 9 Estimating the Value of a Parameter Using Confidence Intervals 2010 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved Section 9.1 The Logic in Constructing Confidence Intervals for a Population Mean

More information

THE HUNT FOR PARTY DISCIPLINE IN CONGRESS #

THE HUNT FOR PARTY DISCIPLINE IN CONGRESS # THE HUNT FOR PARTY DISCIPLINE IN CONGRESS # Nolan McCarty*, Keith T. Poole**, and Howard Rosenthal*** 2 October 2000 ABSTRACT This paper analyzes party discipline in the House of Representatives between

More information

Social Rankings in Human-Computer Committees

Social Rankings in Human-Computer Committees Social Rankings in Human-Computer Committees Moshe Bitan 1, Ya akov (Kobi) Gal 3 and Elad Dokow 4, and Sarit Kraus 1,2 1 Computer Science Department, Bar Ilan University, Israel 2 Institute for Advanced

More information

Non-Voted Ballots and Discrimination in Florida

Non-Voted Ballots and Discrimination in Florida Non-Voted Ballots and Discrimination in Florida John R. Lott, Jr. School of Law Yale University 127 Wall Street New Haven, CT 06511 (203) 432-2366 john.lott@yale.edu revised July 15, 2001 * This paper

More information

FOURIER ANALYSIS OF THE NUMBER OF PUBLIC LAWS David L. Farnsworth, Eisenhower College Michael G. Stratton, GTE Sylvania

FOURIER ANALYSIS OF THE NUMBER OF PUBLIC LAWS David L. Farnsworth, Eisenhower College Michael G. Stratton, GTE Sylvania FOURIER ANALYSIS OF THE NUMBER OF PUBLIC LAWS 1789-1976 David L. Farnsworth, Eisenhower College Michael G. Stratton, GTE Sylvania 1. Introduction. In an earlier study (reference hereafter referred to as

More information

No. 1. THE ROLE OF INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION IN MAINTAINING HUNGARY S POPULATION SIZE BETWEEN WORKING PAPERS ON POPULATION, FAMILY AND WELFARE

No. 1. THE ROLE OF INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION IN MAINTAINING HUNGARY S POPULATION SIZE BETWEEN WORKING PAPERS ON POPULATION, FAMILY AND WELFARE NKI Central Statistical Office Demographic Research Institute H 1119 Budapest Andor utca 47 49. Telefon: (36 1) 229 8413 Fax: (36 1) 229 8552 www.demografia.hu WORKING PAPERS ON POPULATION, FAMILY AND

More information

Civil Society Organizations in Montenegro

Civil Society Organizations in Montenegro Civil Society Organizations in Montenegro This project is funded by the European Union. This project is funded by the European Union. 1 TABLE OF CONTENTS EVALUATION OF LEGAL REGULATIONS AND CIRCUMSTANCES

More information

Can Ideal Point Estimates be Used as Explanatory Variables?

Can Ideal Point Estimates be Used as Explanatory Variables? Can Ideal Point Estimates be Used as Explanatory Variables? Andrew D. Martin Washington University admartin@wustl.edu Kevin M. Quinn Harvard University kevin quinn@harvard.edu October 8, 2005 1 Introduction

More information

Unequal Recovery, Labor Market Polarization, Race, and 2016 U.S. Presidential Election. Maoyong Fan and Anita Alves Pena 1

Unequal Recovery, Labor Market Polarization, Race, and 2016 U.S. Presidential Election. Maoyong Fan and Anita Alves Pena 1 Unequal Recovery, Labor Market Polarization, Race, and 2016 U.S. Presidential Election Maoyong Fan and Anita Alves Pena 1 Abstract: Growing income inequality and labor market polarization and increasing

More information

Approval Voting Theory with Multiple Levels of Approval

Approval Voting Theory with Multiple Levels of Approval Claremont Colleges Scholarship @ Claremont HMC Senior Theses HMC Student Scholarship 2012 Approval Voting Theory with Multiple Levels of Approval Craig Burkhart Harvey Mudd College Recommended Citation

More information

SHOULD THE DEMOCRATS MOVE TO THE LEFT ON ECONOMIC POLICY? By Andrew Gelman and Cexun Jeffrey Cai Columbia University

SHOULD THE DEMOCRATS MOVE TO THE LEFT ON ECONOMIC POLICY? By Andrew Gelman and Cexun Jeffrey Cai Columbia University Submitted to the Annals of Applied Statistics SHOULD THE DEMOCRATS MOVE TO THE LEFT ON ECONOMIC POLICY? By Andrew Gelman and Cexun Jeffrey Cai Columbia University Could John Kerry have gained votes in

More information

The California Primary and Redistricting

The California Primary and Redistricting The California Primary and Redistricting This study analyzes what is the important impact of changes in the primary voting rules after a Congressional and Legislative Redistricting. Under a citizen s committee,

More information

Online Appendix for The Contribution of National Income Inequality to Regional Economic Divergence

Online Appendix for The Contribution of National Income Inequality to Regional Economic Divergence Online Appendix for The Contribution of National Income Inequality to Regional Economic Divergence APPENDIX 1: Trends in Regional Divergence Measured Using BEA Data on Commuting Zone Per Capita Personal

More information

MATH4999 Capstone Projects in Mathematics and Economics Topic 3 Voting methods and social choice theory

MATH4999 Capstone Projects in Mathematics and Economics Topic 3 Voting methods and social choice theory MATH4999 Capstone Projects in Mathematics and Economics Topic 3 Voting methods and social choice theory 3.1 Social choice procedures Plurality voting Borda count Elimination procedures Sequential pairwise

More information

The League of Women Voters of Pennsylvania et al v. The Commonwealth of Pennsylvania et al. Nolan McCarty

The League of Women Voters of Pennsylvania et al v. The Commonwealth of Pennsylvania et al. Nolan McCarty The League of Women Voters of Pennsylvania et al v. The Commonwealth of Pennsylvania et al. I. Introduction Nolan McCarty Susan Dod Brown Professor of Politics and Public Affairs Chair, Department of Politics

More information

Inflation and relative price variability in Mexico: the role of remittances

Inflation and relative price variability in Mexico: the role of remittances Applied Economics Letters, 2008, 15, 181 185 Inflation and relative price variability in Mexico: the role of remittances J. Ulyses Balderas and Hiranya K. Nath* Department of Economics and International

More information

Statistical Yearbook. for Asia and the Pacific

Statistical Yearbook. for Asia and the Pacific Statistical Yearbook for Asia and the Pacific 2015 Statistical Yearbook for Asia and the Pacific 2015 Sustainable Development Goal 1 End poverty in all its forms everywhere 1.1 Poverty trends...1 1.2 Data

More information

Distorting Democracy: How Gerrymandering Skews the Composition of the House of Representatives

Distorting Democracy: How Gerrymandering Skews the Composition of the House of Representatives 1 Celia Heudebourg Minju Kim Corey McGinnis MATH 155: Final Project Distorting Democracy: How Gerrymandering Skews the Composition of the House of Representatives Introduction Do you think your vote mattered

More information

Universality of election statistics and a way to use it to detect election fraud.

Universality of election statistics and a way to use it to detect election fraud. Universality of election statistics and a way to use it to detect election fraud. Peter Klimek http://www.complex-systems.meduniwien.ac.at P. Klimek (COSY @ CeMSIIS) Election statistics 26. 2. 2013 1 /

More information

Preliminary Effects of Oversampling on the National Crime Victimization Survey

Preliminary Effects of Oversampling on the National Crime Victimization Survey Preliminary Effects of Oversampling on the National Crime Victimization Survey Katrina Washington, Barbara Blass and Karen King U.S. Census Bureau, Washington D.C. 20233 Note: This report is released to

More information

Benchmarks for text analysis: A response to Budge and Pennings

Benchmarks for text analysis: A response to Budge and Pennings Electoral Studies 26 (2007) 130e135 www.elsevier.com/locate/electstud Benchmarks for text analysis: A response to Budge and Pennings Kenneth Benoit a,, Michael Laver b a Department of Political Science,

More information

PROJECTION OF NET MIGRATION USING A GRAVITY MODEL 1. Laboratory of Populations 2

PROJECTION OF NET MIGRATION USING A GRAVITY MODEL 1. Laboratory of Populations 2 UN/POP/MIG-10CM/2012/11 3 February 2012 TENTH COORDINATION MEETING ON INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION Population Division Department of Economic and Social Affairs United Nations Secretariat New York, 9-10 February

More information

Congressional samples Juho Lamminmäki

Congressional samples Juho Lamminmäki Congressional samples Based on Congressional Samples for Approximate Answering of Group-By Queries (2000) by Swarup Acharyua et al. Data Sampling Trying to obtain a maximally representative subset of the

More information

Online Appendix for Redistricting and the Causal Impact of Race on Voter Turnout

Online Appendix for Redistricting and the Causal Impact of Race on Voter Turnout Online Appendix for Redistricting and the Causal Impact of Race on Voter Turnout Bernard L. Fraga Contents Appendix A Details of Estimation Strategy 1 A.1 Hypotheses.....................................

More information

A NOTE ON THE THEORY OF SOCIAL CHOICE

A NOTE ON THE THEORY OF SOCIAL CHOICE A NOTE ON THE THEORY OF SOCIAL CHOICE Professor Arrow brings to his treatment of the theory of social welfare (I) a fine unity of mathematical rigour and insight into fundamental issues of social philosophy.

More information

Compare Your Area User Guide

Compare Your Area User Guide Compare Your Area User Guide October 2016 Contents 1. Introduction 2. Data - Police recorded crime data - Population data 3. How to interpret the charts - Similar Local Area Bar Chart - Within Force Bar

More information

The Case of the Disappearing Bias: A 2014 Update to the Gerrymandering or Geography Debate

The Case of the Disappearing Bias: A 2014 Update to the Gerrymandering or Geography Debate The Case of the Disappearing Bias: A 2014 Update to the Gerrymandering or Geography Debate Nicholas Goedert Lafayette College goedertn@lafayette.edu May, 2015 ABSTRACT: This note observes that the pro-republican

More information

NEW PERSPECTIVES ON THE LAW & ECONOMICS OF ELECTIONS

NEW PERSPECTIVES ON THE LAW & ECONOMICS OF ELECTIONS NEW PERSPECTIVES ON THE LAW & ECONOMICS OF ELECTIONS! ASSA EARLY CAREER RESEARCH AWARD: PANEL B Richard Holden School of Economics UNSW Business School BACKDROP Long history of political actors seeking

More information

A COMPARISON OF ARIZONA TO NATIONS OF COMPARABLE SIZE

A COMPARISON OF ARIZONA TO NATIONS OF COMPARABLE SIZE A COMPARISON OF ARIZONA TO NATIONS OF COMPARABLE SIZE A Report from the Office of the University Economist July 2009 Dennis Hoffman, Ph.D. Professor of Economics, University Economist, and Director, L.

More information

Evaluating the Role of Immigration in U.S. Population Projections

Evaluating the Role of Immigration in U.S. Population Projections Evaluating the Role of Immigration in U.S. Population Projections Stephen Tordella, Decision Demographics Steven Camarota, Center for Immigration Studies Tom Godfrey, Decision Demographics Nancy Wemmerus

More information

British Election Leaflet Project - Data overview

British Election Leaflet Project - Data overview British Election Leaflet Project - Data overview Gathering data on electoral leaflets from a large number of constituencies would be prohibitively difficult at least, without major outside funding without

More information

Hoboken Public Schools. AP Statistics Curriculum

Hoboken Public Schools. AP Statistics Curriculum Hoboken Public Schools AP Statistics Curriculum AP Statistics HOBOKEN PUBLIC SCHOOLS Course Description AP Statistics is the high school equivalent of a one semester, introductory college statistics course.

More information

THE ROLE OF INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION IN MAINTAINING THE POPULATION SIZE OF HUNGARY BETWEEN LÁSZLÓ HABLICSEK and PÁL PÉTER TÓTH

THE ROLE OF INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION IN MAINTAINING THE POPULATION SIZE OF HUNGARY BETWEEN LÁSZLÓ HABLICSEK and PÁL PÉTER TÓTH THE ROLE OF INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION IN MAINTAINING THE POPULATION SIZE OF HUNGARY BETWEEN 2000 2050 LÁSZLÓ HABLICSEK and PÁL PÉTER TÓTH INTRODUCTION 1 Fertility plays an outstanding role among the phenomena

More information

Party Polarization: A Longitudinal Analysis of the Gender Gap in Candidate Preference

Party Polarization: A Longitudinal Analysis of the Gender Gap in Candidate Preference Party Polarization: A Longitudinal Analysis of the Gender Gap in Candidate Preference Tiffany Fameree Faculty Sponsor: Dr. Ray Block, Jr., Department of Political Science/Public Administration ABSTRACT

More information

IN THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE EASTERN DISTRICT OF PENNSYLVANIA

IN THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE EASTERN DISTRICT OF PENNSYLVANIA IN THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE EASTERN DISTRICT OF PENNSYLVANIA Mahari Bailey, et al., : Plaintiffs : C.A. No. 10-5952 : v. : : City of Philadelphia, et al., : Defendants : PLAINTIFFS EIGHTH

More information

A Report on the Social Network Battery in the 1998 American National Election Study Pilot Study. Robert Huckfeldt Ronald Lake Indiana University

A Report on the Social Network Battery in the 1998 American National Election Study Pilot Study. Robert Huckfeldt Ronald Lake Indiana University A Report on the Social Network Battery in the 1998 American National Election Study Pilot Study Robert Huckfeldt Ronald Lake Indiana University January 2000 The 1998 Pilot Study of the American National

More information

Estimating the Margin of Victory for Instant-Runoff Voting

Estimating the Margin of Victory for Instant-Runoff Voting Estimating the Margin of Victory for Instant-Runoff Voting David Cary Abstract A general definition is proposed for the margin of victory of an election contest. That definition is applied to Instant Runoff

More information

Party Polarization, Ideological Sorting and the Emergence of the US Partisan Gender Gap

Party Polarization, Ideological Sorting and the Emergence of the US Partisan Gender Gap British Journal of Political Science (2018), page 1 of 27 doi:10.1017/s0007123418000285 ARTICLE Party Polarization, Ideological Sorting and the Emergence of the US Partisan Gender Gap Daniel Q. Gillion

More information

Patterns of Housing Voucher Use Revisited: Segregation and Section 8 Using Updated Data and More Precise Comparison Groups, 2013

Patterns of Housing Voucher Use Revisited: Segregation and Section 8 Using Updated Data and More Precise Comparison Groups, 2013 Patterns of Housing Voucher Use Revisited: Segregation and Section 8 Using Updated Data and More Precise Comparison Groups, 2013 Molly W. Metzger Center for Social Development Danilo Pelletiere U.S. Department

More information

PROJECTING THE LABOUR SUPPLY TO 2024

PROJECTING THE LABOUR SUPPLY TO 2024 PROJECTING THE LABOUR SUPPLY TO 2024 Charles Simkins Helen Suzman Professor of Political Economy School of Economic and Business Sciences University of the Witwatersrand May 2008 centre for poverty employment

More information

Report for the Associated Press: Illinois and Georgia Election Studies in November 2014

Report for the Associated Press: Illinois and Georgia Election Studies in November 2014 Report for the Associated Press: Illinois and Georgia Election Studies in November 2014 Randall K. Thomas, Frances M. Barlas, Linda McPetrie, Annie Weber, Mansour Fahimi, & Robert Benford GfK Custom Research

More information