The Individual Level Dynamics of Bounded Partisanship 1

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "The Individual Level Dynamics of Bounded Partisanship 1"

Transcription

1 The Individual Level Dynamics of Bounded Partisanship 1 Anja Neundorf 2 Daniel Stegmueller 3 Thomas J. Scotto 4 Forthcoming in Public Opinion Quarterly Abstract Over the past half century, scholars utilized a variety of theoretical and methodological approaches to study the attachment or identification voters have with political parties. However, models on partisan (in)stability ignore its bounded character. Making use of Mixed Latent Markov Models we measure change and stability of individual-level West German partisan identification captured over a 24 year period via the German Socio-Economic Panel (GSEOP). Results suggest that distinctive subpopulations exist, which follow different patterns of partisan stability. One party s loss is not necessarily another party s gain. 1 Large parts of the paper were written when Daniel Stegmueller was ECASS visitor at the Institute for Social and Economic Research (ISER), University of Essex. We thank Allan McCutcheon, Thomas Gschwend, Andreas Murr, and the participants of the panel Dynamics of attitudes and party choice at the General Conference of the European Consortium of Political Research (September 2009 Potsdam, Germany) for useful comments on earlier versions of the paper. 2 Nuffield College, University of Oxford; anja.neundorf@nuffield.ox.ac.uk. 3 University of Mannheim & University of Frankfurt; mail@daniel-stegmueller.com. 4 University of Essex; tscott@essex.ac.uk.

2 Introduction The last fifty years have seen a growing body of research into the origins, consequences and dynamics of party identification. Despite this scientific effort, our knowledge about the individual level dynamics of party identification is limited at best. While recent research has made some progress on the methodological front, we argue that a key ingredient of a potent model of partisan dynamics is its bounded nature (Clarke and Suzuki 1994; Zuckerman and Kroh 2006; Zuckerman et al. 2007). This implies that there is no party menu from which individuals choose freely every time they are surveyed. Instead, most voters have a limited choice set. Many opt to move from one of the major parties into independence or back but almost never to the competing camp. Even if partisanship is bounded, the classic debate over question of its stability and change that pits a social-psychological against rational updating models of partisanship does not go away. Validation of the notion that few in the electorate switch from one major party to another still leaves patterns of stability and change to be uncovered. Do partisans of different stripes move into and out of parties at the same time, does one party gain at the expense of the other, or do parties have supporters moving to and away from them at different points in time? Importantly, can subsections of the electorate be identified who will remain loyal to one political party through thick and thin? In their recent article appearing in THIS JOURNAL, Clarke and McCutcheon (2009: 21) employed Mixed Latent Markov (MLM) models to make a convincing case that electorates in English speaking democracies were composed of various mixtures of peoples with durable and flexible [partisan] attachments. This model choice allows voters to be one of two types: they are either stable partisans who remain supportive of a political party through good and bad times or citizens prone to change their preferred party as they update their beliefs about party and leader performance. A limitation of Clarke and McCutcheon s (2009) work is that so-called MLM mover-stayer (MS) models employed to establish patterns of partisanship over four and five wave election study panels do not allow for an exploration of patterns of bounded partisanship throughout a long period in a nation s electoral history. Fundamental differences may exist in patterns of movement in and out of major parties, and these may have interesting implications for the nature of party systems in advanced democracies. The MS model assumes that there is one and only one class of flexible partisans, whereas the theory of bounded partisanship suggests that patterns of switching between independence and support for one party might be different from movement to and from the other. In this paper, we examine long term patterns of party identification in West Germany from using data from the German Socio-Economic Panel (GSEOP). We bolster support for the theory of bounded partisanship by establishing that an MLM model with two mover classes, each dominated by flexible supporters of the Christian Democrats (CDU) or the Social Democrats (SPD) is superior to the MS model that lumps flexible partisans of all stripes into a single group. Extending the analysis of patterns of individual level support to the non-english speaking electorate of West Germany is particularly interesting because the period covered by the GSEOP allows us to examine patterns of partisanship over periods of relative political calm and three major political upheavals, the first being reunification and the other two being party specific events of the CDU donation scandal and the SPD platform shift. These events underscore the need for multiple types of movers because bounded partisans of the different parties may have dissimilar reactions to these episodes. 2

3 Table 1: Model Hypotheses Party ID Measurement Unobserved Bounded Model stable error heterogeneity character Social-Psychological yes no no not important Latent Construct yes yes no no Rational Updating no no no no Bounded Partisanship yes + no yes yes yes We proceed with a review of the debate over the stability of party identification in light of unobserved heterogeneity and the bounded nature of partisanship, and then move on to a discussion of major party support in West Germany over the long period. After presenting and estimating the MLM model with multiple mover classes, we discuss the relevance of our results for the study of partisanship in advanced democracies. The Lingering Question of Partisan Stability Rival theories of partisan identification posit that voters face questions tapping party support in one of two ways. Researchers in favor of the social-psychological model think of partisan identification as an identity that emerges from a pre-adult political socialization process and acts as an exogenous predictor of political choice during adulthood. Advocates of this approach believe party identification only changes during major political events, but otherwise is mostly set in stone (e.g. Campbell et al. 1960; Jennings and Niemi 1974; Miller and Shanks 1996). Others view partisanship as an endogenous variable that is subject to change due to rational updating as the voter receives information about the performance of the economy, governments, leaders, and opposition parties (e.g. Jackson 1975; Fiorina 1981; Franklin and Jackson 1983; Achen 1992, 2002; MacKuen et al. 1989; Erikson et al. 2002). Discussions on partisanship as a latent construct due to measurement error adds complexity but does little to resolve the conflict or alter the battle lines. Green and his colleagues (1994; 2002) claim that single questions on surveys make for imperfect instruments when it comes to measuring both partisan attitudes and identities, as it complicates the ability to separate fact from fiction when observing partisan movements. Table 1 summarizes the predicted outcomes and assumptions behind the three models of partisan identification that most frequently appear in the literature. An exclusive belief in one of these models forces scholars to buy into quite rigid assumptions concerning the stability of partisan identification, the influence of time and events on partisan change, the presence of measurement error, or some combination of all of these. Two competing views of partisan (in)stability emerged over the past fifty years: one of a stable electorate composed entirely of those with very strong partisan ties who will not reconsider their loyalties even in the face of poor leadership and governance by their party and another comprised of electorates where each voter is potentially ready to turn on a party in the face of slight leadership or economic hiccups. We argue much of the debate over partisan (in)stability and the models employed to adjudicate the controversy neglect two important points that partisanship is bounded and unobserved heterogeneity drives distinct patterns of stability and change in party support among sub-groups within an electorate. The models we employ aim to incorporate these important details into this and future discussions of 3

4 mass partisan identification. Unobserved Heterogeneity in Individual Partisan (In)Stability Models of political attitudes often make the analytical assumption that all citizens utilize the same thought processes to arrive at a decision, for example which party to support. To date, much of the work relaxing this homogeneity assumption focuses on how different observed levels of political information and sophistication lead voters to consider different types and numbers of variables in arriving at a vote choice or political support (e.g. Rivers 1988; Sniderman et al. 1991; Johnston and Pattie 1996; Gomez and Wilson 2001; Cutler 2002; Box-Steffensmeier et al. 2004; Box-Steffensmeier and De Boef 2008; Carsey and Layman 2006; Roy 2009; Bafumi and Shapiro 2009). However, change and continuity in an individual s political choices and their determinants may also be a function of unobserved heterogeneity or differing forces that cannot be modeled directly. The deployment of modern panel data and latent variable modeling techniques have addressed the issue of unobserved measurement error inherent in most analyses using survey data. Thus, we can model out and ignore chance variations in the data that occur due to lack of question clarity and the presence of politically naive and disinterested voters. However, surveys cannot capture all of the forces that may predispose one to be a stable or an unstable partisan during the life of a panel. The likely presence of substantively meaningful patterns of unobserved heterogeneity in the data requires a model that can consider measurement error and allow samples of electorates to be comprised of multiple groups that follow the different patterns of partisan stability some being stable partisans ( stayers ), while others are predicted by the model to change their party preferences ( movers ). 5 The model for this purpose is the Mixed Latent Markov model that we detail below. However, before doing so, we must further discuss the types of switching we should see among those in the sample who are flexible partisans. Bounded Partisanship and the Question of Individual Change Another issue that is often overlooked in the discussions concerning partisan identification is the nature and content of the voter s selection menu. Decisions concerning the construction of party identification variables often make the implicit assumption that voters select one from all of the available parties, but empirical evidence supplied by election study panels in America and elsewhere suggest that voters engage in a restricted search when choosing a party to support. Clarke and Suzuki (1994) and Clarke and McCutcheon (2009) establish that most of the switching is from identification with one party to non-identification (or independence) or vice versa and not across parties. Furthermore, they find that those who switch from supporting a major party to independence are not just using their new found non-identification as a half-way house en route to forming an identity or supporting another party. Observing such patterns of movement led Zuckerman and Kroh (2006) and Zuckerman et al. (2007) to declare partisanship bounded. Their label underscored the reality that for much of the electorate, partisan choice comes down to the decision to support or not support one of the major parties while declaring an identification with an opposing party is absent from the thoughts of an overwhelming number of voters. By implication, this makes party identification a nominal level variable because people move to and 5 The model yields the probability of switching for those respondents classified in the mover chain(s). Individuals are not necessarily observed as doing so throughout the time period under observation. 4

5 from independence and one of the major parties irrespective of the positions and actions opposing parties. We believe that if theories of bounded partisanship are accurate and most voters never entertain the idea of supporting one of the major parties, then the success or failure of that party should not enter into the citizen s decision process. A party s poor performance while in government may lead flexible supporters of that party to shift away. However, there is no reason why loose partisans who move in between support for the main opposition party should react. Further, major national or party specific effects (e.g. a platform change or a scandal) may only impact volatile supporters of one party. Putting the issues of unobserved heterogeneity and bounded partisanship together, electorates are expected to be made up of a sub-group of stable partisans and sub-groups that are dominated by volatile members of each of the major parties. Party Identification in Germany In this paper we apply the concept of bounded partisanship and its (in)stability to Western Germany, which constitutes an interesting comparative case and extends the study of the impact of unobserved heterogeneity on party identification beyond the English speaking nations studied by Clarke and McCutcheon (2009). Various studies have confirmed that party identification is a valid concept in the German context and that it is quite distinct from actual party choice (for a review see Falter et al. 2000; c.f. Falter 1977, 1984; Gluchowski 1978, 1983; Norpoth 1978, 1984). Nevertheless, the same lingering questions about partisanship remain unanswered for the German mass public. Several studies found partisanship to be highly stable (Klingemann 1985; Falter et al. 2000; Schmitt-Beck and Weick 2001; Arzheimer and Schoen 2005), while others find party identification to be a shaky attachment (Schmitt-Beck et al. 2006; c.f. Zelle 1995; Zuckerman and Kroh 2006; Kroh and Selb 2009). The nature of this instability is however less understood. Even if, as Schmitt-Beck et al. (2006: 598) find, movements out of partisanship into independence are quite common, while direct shifting to another party is a less frequent phenomenon, ideas concerning bounded partisanship have not yet made their way into models of individual level stability and change that allow for unobserved heterogeneity and the presence of measurement error. An initial analysis of data from the German Socio-Economic Panel confirms Zuckerman et al. s (2007) finding that partisan switching mainly occurs between one particular party and independence. Table 2 reveals that less than 1 per cent switched their partisanship between the two major parties from Social Democratic Party (SPD) to Christian Democratic Union (CDU) or vice versa from one year to the next. Table 2 reveals that, on average, 80 per cent of respondents stay loyal to their preferred party or remain independent over the course of two waves of the panel. This might suggest that party identification is indeed quite stable in West Germany. However, to put this question to a rigorous empirical test we need to study partisan instability taking into account its bounded character by unpacking the patterns of movement of different party supporters. If as suggested by the notion of bounded partisanship movements to and from each party follows different patterns, this should be observable at multiple points across the long GSOEP panel. In particular, the major political and party specific events should highlight the fact that the movements of flexible partisans from each major party follow different patterns and respond to different stimuli. In the period under observation, Germany s political system saw three major political events 5

6 Table 2: Average Party switching ( ) PID at t-1 PID at t per cent SPD stable no or other 5.07 CDU 0.45 CDU stable no or other 4.78 SPD 0.44 No or other stable SPD 4.77 CDU 4.49 Note: The average party switches are estimated by a simple Markov model assuming time homogeneous transition probabilities. that are believed to have shaken partisan attachments. In 1990 the divided country was reunited after 40 years of separation. The country observed a time of optimism and shifted to the political right after reunification. However, after a short time, electors and politicians realized that the promised flourished landscapes in East Germany were not achievable without sacrifices. Zelle (1995) argued that the strong political dissatisfaction in the early 1990s affected partisan loyalties, with many citizens turning their back on established parties. Furthermore, two party specific events occurred during the duration of the panel, which both provoked political controversies. First, in late 1999 it was revealed that the Christian Democratic Union (CDU) had repeatedly accepted illegal donations under Chancellor Helmut Kohl. The so-called CDU-Spendenaffäre was the biggest scandal in post-war German political history (Clemens 2000: 25; c.f. Pappi et al. 2004; Scarrow 2006). Second, after receiving another mandate in 2002, the Social Democratic Party (SPD) announced a major political reform in Spring This policy proposal, Agenda 2010, saw a drastic overhaul of the German welfare state and caused nationwide protests (Pappi and Shikano 2005; Niedermayer 2006). Furthermore, as the reform agenda was imposed by the party elite, many party activists left the SPD and founded a new leftist party (which later merged with the Socialist party PDS) (Braunthal 2003; Camerra-Rowe 2004). The party is still struggling with the consequences of this policy shift, and many traditional SPD supporters are said to have defected from their party. These two events can bring to light party specific movements in party identification. If it is indeed necessary to take into account the bounded character of partisanship when studying its dynamics, we should find different patterns of movements among flexible SPD and CDU supporters during major events specific only to one major political party. SPD partisans should not be very impressed by the CDU-Spendenaffäre, while the CDU adherents should not be affected by any policy shifts of the SPD. The next section gives details on why the German Socio-Economic Panel in combination with Mixed Latent Markov models is suitable to test these expectations. 6

7 Measuring the Stability of Party Identification Data The German Socio-Economic Panel (GSOEP), a unique longitudinal database, covers an exceptionally long period between 1984 and No other panel study with political variables encompasses so many years. This offers users the opportunity to analyze the individual level dynamics in party identification over a considerable time span. 6 Information on households and each individual living in a household is obtained through annual face-to-face interviews. 7 The GSOEP is mainly interested in (changes in) the socio-economic status of German households and its members. The study contains various samples, such as separate Eastern German or refreshment samples. We limit our analysis to West German citizens drawn from all the samples that include this sub-group. 8 As the predominant aim of this paper is to investigate individual partisan stability over a rather long period, we only work with a homogeneous group of respondents (at least based on their origin). The inclusion of East Germans or immigrants would yield a different research question, as the political socialization processes experienced by these groups are quite different. In total the selected respondents comprise the 21,915 individuals who had at least three valid observations on the party identification variable. 9 We correct for the fact that respondents living on the same household (the primary sample unite) are non-independent by using cluster-based standard errors (Binder and Roberts 2003; Vermunt 2002). The English language translation of our dependent variable reads: Many people in the Federal Republic of Germany (Germany, after 1990) are inclined to a certain political party, although from time to time they vote for another political party. What about you: Are you inclined generally speaking to a particular party? Those who respond, Yes are then asked, Which one? and handed a card that lists all the parties. Those giving no answer or don t know were set to missing. Those who respond no are considered non-identifiers. This exact question was asked in every year of the study that began in For each time point, respondents are assigned to the following mutually exclusive and exhaustive categories being a (1) Social Democratic Party (SPD), or (2) Christian-Democratic Union (CDU) adherent, or (3) not supporting any of the major parties. The last category encompasses independents as well as partisans of some smaller niche parties Studies that used the GSOEP data to analyze party identification in Germany include Arzheimer and Schoen (2005); Kohler (2005); Schmitt-Beck et al. (2006); Zuckerman and Kroh (2006); Zuckerman et al. (2007); Kroh and Selb (2009). Nevertheless the powerful statistical tool of Mixed Latent Markov modeling has not been used to tackle the question whether or not heterogeneous patterns of partisan (in)stability exist within the sample. 7 For more information on the GSOEP contents and structure see Haisken-DeNew and Frick (2005) and Wagner et al. (2007). 8 Based on GSOEP terminology, this includes sample A (drawn in 1984), sample E (1998), sample F (2000), and sample G (2002). For the latter samples we used the question of the location of the respondents in 1989 to separate East and West Germans. People who do not have German citizenship were excluded from the analysis. 9 Individuals with less than three responses were excluded from the analysis. Our results are robust to choosing a different minimum number of responses. The model can be viewed as a hierarchical setup with responses nested within individuals. Missing responses simply mean less information per individual, but maximum likelihood estimates are still consistent. 10 The proportions of the other parties among those identifying with a political party is as follows: the liberal party, FPD: 4 per cent; the Greens: 8.4 per cent; one of the three possible right-wing parties: 1 per cent; other: 3 per cent. In total 16.4 per cent of all partisans do not support one of the two big parties. This proportion adds to the 45 per cent who do not identify with any party at all. It is worth noting that the overall proportion of non identifiers is relatively high compared to proportions of independents usually observed in political surveys. Arzheimer (2006) 7

8 Mixed Latent Markov Models To analyze change in nominal level variables across time, one needs a method that accommodates unordered dependent variables and the presence of autocorrelation. A Markov model achieves that objective by employing a first-order Markovian structure allowing subsequent individual observations to be correlated. Markov models are not newcomers to political science: In fact, the Columbia group was the first to adumbrate a Markov-process model of partisan transmission. Markov models resurfaced in Converse (1964) and Dobson and Meeter (1974), but these forays did not have much impact on conceptualization in the field (Johnston 2006: 330). Recent discussions of the dynamics of party identification cited above made clear that measurement error is a concern. This amounts to the argument that not each and every observed change in an individual s responses constitutes a true change in identification. Rather, it may reflect idiosyncratic short term forces beyond the grasp of an external observer. A Latent Markov model deals with this phenomenon by specifying true partisan identification to be a nominal latent variable that is measured imperfectly by observed individual choices. This constitutes a typical single indicator latent variable model where partisan identification, the indicator, is measured on multiple occasions (Jackman 2008; Skrondal and Rabe-Hesketh 2004). The change from more well known factor analysis models employed by Green et al. (1994; 2002) is that we employ a latent class model since the indicator is a nominal level variable. 11 Combining a measurement model with a transition structure yields the following equation (c.f. Hagenaars 1990; van de Pol and Langeheine 1990; Collins and Wugalter 1992; Vermunt et al. 1999; Langeheine and van de Pol 2002; Paas et al. 2007; Vermunt et al. 2008): P(y it ) = 3 x 0 =1 3 x T =1 P(x 0 ) 23 t=1 P(x t x t 1 ) 23 t=0 P(y it x t ) (1) In this logit formulation, y it is the observed response of individual i (i = 1,...,I) at time point t (t = 0,...,23) and x i represents the true state purged of measurement error. 12 This models the observed response as resulting from three components: being in one of the latent states at the initial observation P(x 0 ), the measurement error part P(y it x t ) and the transitions from one latent state to the next P(x t x t 1 ). Therefore, it allows us to partition individual movements into true change and measurement error. A graphical description of the model is given in the upper half of figure 1, where we, following the usual convention, denote latent variables by circles and observed variables by squares. It visualizes that transitions occur only between latent states x t, which are connected to observed indicators y t via a probabilistic model, leaving no correlation analyses the development of party identification in the German mass public in a similar time period ( ), but he uses pooled cross-sectional data of a monthly political poll, the Politbarometer. On average about 70 per cent of West Germans indicate a party identification. The GSOEP on the other hand only indicates about 50 per cent identifiers. We believe the more conservative estimate comes from the fact that the GSOEP is not primarily a political survey reducing the propensity of framing effects to motivate answers to the party support question. 11 For an excellent introduction to latent class models in a social science context see McCutcheon (1987). This is more appropriate given the choice set available to voters in the context of bounded partisanship (cf. Clarke and McCutcheon 2009). 12 The model could also be formulated in a log-linear framework (cf. Haberman 1979). Here each latent variable is just an additional dimension in an expanded table. However, when using this framework, estimation becomes cumbersome for large models (i.e. long panels) and it is not as easy to specify constraints. Furthermore, the χ 2 goodness-of-fit test usually associated with log-linear models is problematic for large data sets. The logit formulation yields log-likelihood values and derived information criteria (Burnham and Anderson 2003) which we use to assess fit and compare models. 8

9 ... x 1,t 1 x 1,t x 1,t y t 1 y t y t x 2,t 1 x 2,t x t+1... Figure 1: Illustration of a Mixed Latent Markov Model between observed states. 13 Individuals enter our sample from rather different starting points. To capture some of the observed forces that increase or decrease the propensity of an individual to belong to one of the three partisan classes when they enter the survey, we extend the above model by allowing the initial probabilities to depend on individual level covariates w: P(x 0,w i ). More precisely we condition on a respondent s age, education, gender, and social class position. However, we suspect that unobserved heterogeneity yields distinct types of partisans, namely the movers and stayers, that arise not from measurable social positions but from forces not captured by the sample (Clarke et al. 2004; Clarke and McCutcheon 2009). This can be captured by extending the model with a time constant latent variable m, which partitions it into M latent subgroups or mixtures, yielding the so called Mixture Latent Markov model (van de Pol and Langeheine 1990; Dias et al. 2008): P(y it ) = M 3 m=1 x 0 =1 3 x T =1 P(m) P(x 0,w i ) This model extension can be understood as generating additional Markov chains, each with its own set of parameters as depicted in figure 1 using two chains. Its most well known incarnation is the mover-stayer model (Blumen et al. 1955; Goodman 1961), which is constructed by setting M = 2 (i.e. generating two chains) and fixing the transition probabilities of one chain at zero. This yields a group of individuals who do not change during the panel and another group that has a nonzero probability of moving from one state to the next. Keeping these constraints and increasing the number of mixtures yields models where movers are allowed different movement patterns. The models formulated here can be estimated using an extended variant of the EM algorithm (Baum et al. 1970) which in addition handles missing responses on the 1dependent variable as part of the model. 14 Furthermore, we account for the fact that individuals are not randomly sampled, but 23 t=1 P(x t x t 1,m) 23 t=0 P(y it x t ) (2) 13 This is the local independence assumption commonly made in latent variable models: that there is no relationship between items once we condition on the latent trait (Lazarsfeld 1959). 14 A standard EM algorithm proceeds by estimating the joint conditional distribution of the T + M latent variables 9

10 Table 3: Model Specification and Log likelihood Model Description LogLik par M1a Markov M1b 1a + x 0 covariates M2a Latent Markov M2b 2a + x 0 covariates M3a Mixed Latent Markov, Mover-stayer parametrization M3b 3a + x 0 covariates M4 Mixed Latent Markov, stayer class, two mover chains + x 0 covariates are living in the same households (average household size is 3.35), producing more conservative, clustered standard errors (Binder and Roberts 2003). 15 Empirical Models In order to illustrate the necessity to include measurement error and to allow for unobserved heterogeneity in the case of bounded partisanship, we estimated several model specifications which are summarized in Table All models are fitted in two variants: the first is the standard setup without taking observed individual differences into account (a), whereas the second variant controls for individual s different initial states by including control variables x 0 (b). Comparing the log-likelihood for those two variants clearly shows that specifications which control for observed individual heterogeneity improve our models in each and every case. 17 This yields a clear improvement over MLM model specifications previously employed by political scientists (c.f. Clarke et al. 2004; Clarke and McCutcheon 2009). Contrasting the model obtained from the simple Markov model (M1) with those obtained from the Latent Markov model (M2) reveals the importance of adjusting for measurement error. We describe its implications for predicted individual transition patterns below. In a next step, we further allow for unobserved heterogeneity in the predicted transition probabilities modeled in the Markov process. We first examined the traditional Mover-Stayer model for the West German given model parameters and data (E-step). In the M-step the latent variables are treated as observed and new model probabilities are estimated from a table with M 3 T +1 cells for each subject i. It is easy to see that computation (or rather memory) requirements increase exponentially to enormous levels with large T. The Baum-Welch algorithm implemented with extensions allowing for covariates and mixtures in the Syntax version of LatentGOLD (Vermunt and Magidson 2008) allows estimation with many time-points by exploiting the fact that only marginal distributions of P(m), P(m,x t ) and P(m,x t 1,x t ) are needed in the M-step. 15 The Design Effect (taken from model 4 below) is With models of this level of complexity, convergence to a local instead of a global maxima is a problem. The standard strategy to avoid this problem is to start the maximizing algorithm from a variety of different starting points. Therefore, we started the EM algorithm from 20 random initial values and compared their log-likelihood values after 150 iterations. We selected the two sets of initial values that resulted in the highest log-likelihood and rerun the model for twice the amount of iterations. The best initial values (in terms of log-likelihood) were then used for the final model run. 17 Please refer to the Appendix for the estimates of the covariates on the initial status of partisanship in our final model specification. 10

11 Transition probability Markov Model Latent Markov Model CDU out SPD out year Figure 2: Markov and Latent Markov Model: Predicted outflows electorate (M3) which decomposes the population into a group that never switches party identification (the stayers ) and one that does (the movers ). Since we argue that bounded partisanship leads to distinct movements of identifiers of each major party, our final specification consists of a stayer class and two unrestricted mixture components allowing for different movement patterns among subgroups of the population. We did not implement a priori restrictions mandating that each mover chain be composed of flexible partisans from a single party. Rather, if our theoretical argument is valid, we expect to find a clear separation: one chain should mainly be composed of flexible CDU identifiers, while the other one should be dominated by SPD adherents. 18 The Question of Measurement Error in Partisanship First, we turn to analyzing the observed stability of party identification, modeled using a simple Markov (M) model with time heterogeneous transition probabilities. The two top lines in Figure 2 present the yearly outflow of partisans from the two major German parties, SPD and CDU. We observe quite substantial movement in individual level partisanship: Each year, about 20 to 25 per cent of the respondents switch parties, moving from identifying with one major party to independence or support for another party and vice versa. This finding corresponds to the figures presented in Table 2, which shows an average 20 per cent of the respondents switching parties 18 Including more mixtures as done here, of course, is paid for by using up degrees of freedom. Our impressive number of parameters is due to the large number of transition probabilities freely estimated from wave to wave. Are those models simply overparametrized? We test this objection by re-estimating model 3 constraining all transition probabilities to be equal over time. This strict restriction considerably reduces the number of parameters. However, the larger log-likelihood of suggests that the restricted model specification should be rejected in favor of the model with the freely estimated transition probabilities. 11

12 Table 4: Average Transition Probabilities A: Observed transitions (from Model 1b) state t SPD CDU other state SPD t 1 CDU other B: Latent transitions (from Model 2b) state t SPD CDU other state SPD t 1 CDU other C: Mover transitions (from Model 3b) state t SPD CDU other state SPD t 1 CDU other yearly. Table 4 further provides average transition probabilities over all time points. About 78 per cent of SPD supporters remained loyal to their party during the whole time period. Note that among those switching their party preference, we find evidence that they leave the SPD and go to independence or to one of the smaller parties (presumably the Greens), but not to the CDU. The same pattern holds for the Christian Democrats. Only about 4 per cent of the respondents switch directly between the two major parties. This reinforces our decision to model partisanship as a nominal variable and accords well with the notion that partisan identification is bounded. Green and colleagues (1990; 1997; 2002) have argued that this observed instability presented in the upper lines of Figure 2 is due to measurement error. Following this line of reasoning, we allow for the possibility that observed party identification has a degree of unreliability. The results of this Latent Markov (LM) model are also presented in Figure 2. The lower two lines display predicted transition probabilities in and out of the two major parties, and the contrast between the results of the Markov and Latent Markov model reveals that accounting for measurement error produces a substantial reduction in the volatility of partisanship. Overall, we can summarize the findings of the M and LM models as follows: Allowing partisanship to be measured imperfectly by allowing for measurement error reduces the level of instability of party identification. This suggests Green and his collaborators are correct about the massive impact of measurement error. However, their models assume that the electorate is homogeneous in the manner it develops and maintains identities with the major parties. In the next section, we investigate whether we can distinguish several distinct sup-groups of partisans. We 12

13 Table 5: Partisan composition of Mover and Stayer chains Model 3B Model 4 Movers Stayers Movers 1 Movers 2 Stayers SPD SPD CDU CDU No PID No PID Overall Overall Note: Calculated from model 3b (left panel) and model 4 (right panel). begin by presenting the results of a mover-stayer model. 19 Unobserved Heterogeneity in Partisan Stability Looking at the left part of Table 5, we see that partisans are almost evenly divided between movers (48.4 per cent) and stayers (51.6 per cent). Those without a party identification or adherents of the smaller parties are over-represented in the mover chain. Approximately 54 per cent of the movers belong to this category, while only 44 per cent are stable (in the majority of cases) independents. CDU supporters on the other hand seem to be more stable: 31 per cent of stable partisans are supporting the CDU, while only 21 per cent show substantial instability in their party identification. To investigate the mover chain in more detail, Figure 3 plots the average annual in and outflows for the SPD and CDU, showing the predicted proportion of party supporters who turned their back on a party (outflow, solid lines) and those moving to support a party (inflow, dashed lines). For reasons of space we do not present the movements of the no or other party supporters. As has been shown the Table 4 the movement in and out of one specific party is usually connected to movements in and out of independence. Movement between the two parties is extremely low, which supports the bounded partisanship concept. The predicted transition probabilities presented in Figure 3 can hence be interpreted as e.g. movements from CDU to independents (CDU-out; black, solid line). At the first glance it becomes apparent that both parties seem to have lost supporters between 1984 and 2007, as at most time points the outflow exceed inflows (except in 1987, when the CDU clearly attracted many more new supporters compared to those it lost). Once a respondent is classified into the mover chain (about 48 percent of the sample), even after measurement error is taken into account, their probability of changing identifications is real. This is especially true among those who to cease to support either the SPD or CDU. However, it is difficult to make sense of the movements we see here. Clear patterns connected to external events, such as the policy shift of the SPD in 2003 are not apparent and party specific movements are hard to discern. Figure 3 rather suggests that supporters of the SPD and CDU may follow different transition dynamics. To clarify how individuals change their party identification over time, we now turn to a model specification, which takes into account this bounded character of partisanship. 19 The mover-stayer model is the best known type of Mixed Latent Markov (MLM) models. Converse (1969) introduced this type of modeling to political science research by developing his Black-and-White model. He argued that essentially there were two types of patters of change and stability in the public s attitudes towards issues and politics. One segment of the electorate had stable preferences while the other changed their preferences in a random pattern. However, this approach was shown to be deficient by Clarke and McCutcheon (2009). 13

14 Transition probability CDU out CDU in SPD out SPD in year Figure 3: Predicted in- and outflow of mover chain from model 3b Model 4 entails three mixture components (or chains), one constrained to no transitions (stayer chain) while the remaining two allow free transitions at each time point. 20 If flexible partisans of one party move in and out of party identification independently of variable partisans of the other party, we should observe two distinct mover chains one dominated by flexible partisans of the SPD and the other predominantly comprised of those moving in and out of the CDU. Table 5 presents a decomposition of the revised mixture model and reveals that the size and composition of the stayer chain remains virtually unchanged. It is the homogeneous mover chain of model 4 that is subdivided roughly into two equal halves of 24.6 and 23.8 per cent. Again most respondents in both mover chains are classified as independents (about 52 per cent in each chain). However, a closer look at the composition of the two volatile chains reveals an interesting picture. The first mover chain is dominated by CDU partisans who constitute 36.3 per cent of the mixture. In comparison, only 12.3 per cent of this chain is comprised of flexible SPD adherents. The second mover chain represents mainly SPD supporters: 41.8 per cent are SPD partisans, while only 5.8 per cent in this sub-group support the CDU. This clear division substantiates that the party identifiers of the two major parties in Germany mostly follow different patterns of partisan stability. We have now arrived at an improved classification of true partisans by accounting for measurement error and dividing the population into three (latent) subgroups of stayers and those with different propensities to transition from one state to another. Hence the detailed analysis of disaggregated movements in those two chains provides a clearer picture compared to the observed instabilities in the simple Markov model (c.f. Figure 2), which was compromised by measurement error and by lumping together different types of movers. 20 As before, we include covariates to capture differences in initial state probabilities. 14

15 Transition probability CDU out CDU in SPD out SPD in year (a) Mover chain 1 Transition probability CDU out CDU in SPD out SPD in year (b) Mover chain 2 Figure 4: In and Outflow of two mover chains calculated from model 4 15

16 Figure 4 further provides us with an even more detailed picture of how the two partisan groups differ. The upper graph shows the in and outflow of partisans on the first chain of model 4. Remember that this mixture is dominated by CDU supporters, while the lower graph sets up the movement in the second chain, which is mainly composed of SPD supporters. Turning to the CDU-movers first, Figure 4(a) reveals that these flexible partisans follow some of the patterns we anticipated in the section above. We clearly see the post-reunification disappointment from 1992 to 1994, when annually about 40 per cent in this mixture component turned their back on the CDU and become independent from one year to the next. Also the political scandal surrounding illegal donations uncovered in late 1999 is visible in the predicted outflow. In the following two years, the CDU lost about 45 per cent of their volatile supporters. Equally remarkable is the strong effect of the policy shift of the Social Democrats in Figure 4(b) reveals that in the following year, the SPD lost about half of their volatile partisans without gaining much from new inflows (only 9 per cent). Nevertheless, the party won back some of its base in the following year, when an early election took place. This could partially explain why the party retained its relative strength in the election, coming head-to-head with the CDU in Moreover, model 4 shows that several sub-groups do exist in the population concerning their overall partisan stability. Ignoring this heterogeneity could lead to serious misconceptions about the stability of party identification. Lastly, our findings seem to suggest that partisan (in)stability is connected to political events such as scandals or policy shifts. One theoretical assumption of this model is that three mixtures is the optimum. However, what happens if additional mixtures are identified? In order to empirically justify the theoretical expectation of three mixtures (one stayer and two mover), we additionally estimated two models with 4 and 5 mixtures. The Bayesian Information Criterion (BIC) offers a guideline to choose the preferred model, penalizing models with a greater number of parameters (Burnham and Anderson 2003). As Figure 5 illustrates, the BIC falls approximately 2391 units when moving from 1 to 2 mixtures and a further 2794 units when moving from 2 to 3 mixtures. However, extending the model to 4 mixtures results in a reduction in the BIC of only 442 and moving from 4 to 5 results in an even smaller reduction of 320 units. Furthermore the fifth chain is pathological in the sense that no individual has a posterior chain membership probability that would classify him or her as belonging to that chain. More importantly, theoretical parsimony is sacrificed as there are no natural takeoff points in the literature for why those prone to change their identifications in a political system dominated by two major parties should sub-divide into additional mixtures. Discussion and Conclusion As both a theoretical and manifest construct, partisan identification is almost as old as voting surveys. Nevertheless, its meaning and nature remain highly contested in the literature. The aim of this research was to connect the battle field of partisan (in)stability with the concept of bounded partisanship by making use of recent methodological advances and a data set that is often overlooked by political scientists the German Socio-Economic Panel (GSOEP). This study offers three important conclusions, which have implications for research on partisan stability. First, we reinforce Green et al. s (1994, 2002) assertion that measurement error obscures efforts to understand the individual-level dynamics of party identification. Neglecting measurement error results in serious overestimation of partisan volatility. However, Green et al. 16

17 BIC/ Number of mixtures Figure 5: Bayesian Information criteria for models with different number of mixture components. (2002) and many others usually work on the assumption that partisan identification is an interval level variable. This assumption implies that the distance a person has to travel between major party support and independence and then onto backing another major party is equal. Empirical evidence and the notion of bounded partisanship suggest otherwise. Most flexible partisans in the mover mixtures have a choice set that comprises of identification with one major party and independence, and support for other major parties is not on the menu. Consequently, the distance they must travel between one party and independence is far shorter than the reach the respondent must make to find their way into the opposing camp. Further, if the opposing party does not even appear in the set of available choices throughout much of the life cycle, the ideological direction one has to travel to support this party may be unclear to the voter. Consequently, party identification should be treated as a nominal variable and the estimation techniques employed to study partisanship must take this into account. Secondly, this paper confirms the presence of considerable partisan volatility in a sample of respondents from an advanced democracy, West Germany. Comparing the predicted instability levels estimated by the Latent Markov model presented in Figure 2 and those of the mover chain(s) estimated by the Mixed Latent Markov models, presented in Figure 3 and Figure 4 allows us to reject the assumption made by the latent construct model of Green et al. that partisanship is stable at the individual level. Instead, we discovered that only about half the West Germans in the GSEOP were stable (non) partisans who can be counted on to support or not support the major parties time and again. The other half, a majority of whom at times did identify with one of the two major German parties were those open to shifting their identification. This leads to the conclusion that partisan instability exists. While the approximately 50 per cent who stay loyal to either CDU or SPD (or remain independent) are the stabilizing base of the party system, the 50 per cent who are unstable partisans may be the crucial element in elections and in determining periods where one major party will be dominant over the other. The presence of different types of partisans has consequences for electoral choice. Political parties can rely on a pool of very stable partisans (stayers), but most victories come because the party was able, at least temporarily, to capture the hearts and minds of volatile supporters that can and, in the face of political events, will turn their back on the party of their choice. 17

Personality traits and party identification over time

Personality traits and party identification over time European Journal of Political Research 54: 197 215, 2015 197 doi: 10.1111/1475-6765.12070 Personality traits and party identification over time BERT N. BAKKER, 1 DAVID NICOLAS HOPMANN 2 & MIKAEL PERSSON

More information

Do two parties represent the US? Clustering analysis of US public ideology survey

Do two parties represent the US? Clustering analysis of US public ideology survey Do two parties represent the US? Clustering analysis of US public ideology survey Louisa Lee 1 and Siyu Zhang 2, 3 Advised by: Vicky Chuqiao Yang 1 1 Department of Engineering Sciences and Applied Mathematics,

More information

Methodology. 1 State benchmarks are from the American Community Survey Three Year averages

Methodology. 1 State benchmarks are from the American Community Survey Three Year averages The Choice is Yours Comparing Alternative Likely Voter Models within Probability and Non-Probability Samples By Robert Benford, Randall K Thomas, Jennifer Agiesta, Emily Swanson Likely voter models often

More information

Should the Democrats move to the left on economic policy?

Should the Democrats move to the left on economic policy? Should the Democrats move to the left on economic policy? Andrew Gelman Cexun Jeffrey Cai November 9, 2007 Abstract Could John Kerry have gained votes in the recent Presidential election by more clearly

More information

Table A.2 reports the complete set of estimates of equation (1). We distinguish between personal

Table A.2 reports the complete set of estimates of equation (1). We distinguish between personal Akay, Bargain and Zimmermann Online Appendix 40 A. Online Appendix A.1. Descriptive Statistics Figure A.1 about here Table A.1 about here A.2. Detailed SWB Estimates Table A.2 reports the complete set

More information

Learning and Visualizing Political Issues from Voting Records Erik Goldman, Evan Cox, Mikhail Kerzhner. Abstract

Learning and Visualizing Political Issues from Voting Records Erik Goldman, Evan Cox, Mikhail Kerzhner. Abstract Learning and Visualizing Political Issues from Voting Records Erik Goldman, Evan Cox, Mikhail Kerzhner Abstract For our project, we analyze data from US Congress voting records, a dataset that consists

More information

Supplementary Materials for Strategic Abstention in Proportional Representation Systems (Evidence from Multiple Countries)

Supplementary Materials for Strategic Abstention in Proportional Representation Systems (Evidence from Multiple Countries) Supplementary Materials for Strategic Abstention in Proportional Representation Systems (Evidence from Multiple Countries) Guillem Riambau July 15, 2018 1 1 Construction of variables and descriptive statistics.

More information

Congruence in Political Parties

Congruence in Political Parties Descriptive Representation of Women and Ideological Congruence in Political Parties Georgia Kernell Northwestern University gkernell@northwestern.edu June 15, 2011 Abstract This paper examines the relationship

More information

SHOULD THE DEMOCRATS MOVE TO THE LEFT ON ECONOMIC POLICY? By Andrew Gelman and Cexun Jeffrey Cai Columbia University

SHOULD THE DEMOCRATS MOVE TO THE LEFT ON ECONOMIC POLICY? By Andrew Gelman and Cexun Jeffrey Cai Columbia University Submitted to the Annals of Applied Statistics SHOULD THE DEMOCRATS MOVE TO THE LEFT ON ECONOMIC POLICY? By Andrew Gelman and Cexun Jeffrey Cai Columbia University Could John Kerry have gained votes in

More information

Changing Parties or Changing Attitudes?: Uncovering the Partisan Change Process

Changing Parties or Changing Attitudes?: Uncovering the Partisan Change Process Changing Parties or Changing Attitudes?: Uncovering the Partisan Change Process Thomas M. Carsey* Department of Political Science University of Illinois-Chicago 1007 W. Harrison St. Chicago, IL 60607 tcarsey@uic.edu

More information

1. The Relationship Between Party Control, Latino CVAP and the Passage of Bills Benefitting Immigrants

1. The Relationship Between Party Control, Latino CVAP and the Passage of Bills Benefitting Immigrants The Ideological and Electoral Determinants of Laws Targeting Undocumented Migrants in the U.S. States Online Appendix In this additional methodological appendix I present some alternative model specifications

More information

Online Appendix 1: Treatment Stimuli

Online Appendix 1: Treatment Stimuli Online Appendix 1: Treatment Stimuli Polarized Stimulus: 1 Electorate as Divided as Ever by Jefferson Graham (USA Today) In the aftermath of the 2012 presidential election, interviews with voters at a

More information

F E M M Faculty of Economics and Management Magdeburg

F E M M Faculty of Economics and Management Magdeburg OTTO-VON-GUERICKE-UNIVERSITY MAGDEBURG FACULTY OF ECONOMICS AND MANAGEMENT The Immigrant Wage Gap in Germany Alisher Aldashev, ZEW Mannheim Johannes Gernandt, ZEW Mannheim Stephan L. Thomsen FEMM Working

More information

Analysis of public opinion on Macedonia s accession to Author: Ivan Damjanovski

Analysis of public opinion on Macedonia s accession to Author: Ivan Damjanovski Analysis of public opinion on Macedonia s accession to the European Union 2014-2016 Author: Ivan Damjanovski CONCLUSIONS 3 The trends regarding support for Macedonia s EU membership are stable and follow

More information

Experimental Computational Philosophy: shedding new lights on (old) philosophical debates

Experimental Computational Philosophy: shedding new lights on (old) philosophical debates Experimental Computational Philosophy: shedding new lights on (old) philosophical debates Vincent Wiegel and Jan van den Berg 1 Abstract. Philosophy can benefit from experiments performed in a laboratory

More information

Research Note: Toward an Integrated Model of Concept Formation

Research Note: Toward an Integrated Model of Concept Formation Kristen A. Harkness Princeton University February 2, 2011 Research Note: Toward an Integrated Model of Concept Formation The process of thinking inevitably begins with a qualitative (natural) language,

More information

Wisconsin Economic Scorecard

Wisconsin Economic Scorecard RESEARCH PAPER> May 2012 Wisconsin Economic Scorecard Analysis: Determinants of Individual Opinion about the State Economy Joseph Cera Researcher Survey Center Manager The Wisconsin Economic Scorecard

More information

What is The Probability Your Vote will Make a Difference?

What is The Probability Your Vote will Make a Difference? Berkeley Law From the SelectedWorks of Aaron Edlin 2009 What is The Probability Your Vote will Make a Difference? Andrew Gelman, Columbia University Nate Silver Aaron S. Edlin, University of California,

More information

Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation

Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation S. Roy*, Department of Economics, High Point University, High Point, NC - 27262, USA. Email: sroy@highpoint.edu Abstract We implement OLS,

More information

Party identification, electoral utilities, and voting choice

Party identification, electoral utilities, and voting choice Party identification, electoral utilities, and voting choice Romain Lachat Institute of Political Science, University of Zurich lachat@pwi.unizh.ch First draft comments are welcome Paper prepared for the

More information

Supporting Information Political Quid Pro Quo Agreements: An Experimental Study

Supporting Information Political Quid Pro Quo Agreements: An Experimental Study Supporting Information Political Quid Pro Quo Agreements: An Experimental Study Jens Großer Florida State University and IAS, Princeton Ernesto Reuben Columbia University and IZA Agnieszka Tymula New York

More information

Research Statement. Jeffrey J. Harden. 2 Dissertation Research: The Dimensions of Representation

Research Statement. Jeffrey J. Harden. 2 Dissertation Research: The Dimensions of Representation Research Statement Jeffrey J. Harden 1 Introduction My research agenda includes work in both quantitative methodology and American politics. In methodology I am broadly interested in developing and evaluating

More information

Incumbency as a Source of Spillover Effects in Mixed Electoral Systems: Evidence from a Regression-Discontinuity Design.

Incumbency as a Source of Spillover Effects in Mixed Electoral Systems: Evidence from a Regression-Discontinuity Design. Incumbency as a Source of Spillover Effects in Mixed Electoral Systems: Evidence from a Regression-Discontinuity Design Forthcoming, Electoral Studies Web Supplement Jens Hainmueller Holger Lutz Kern September

More information

Job approval in North Carolina N=770 / +/-3.53%

Job approval in North Carolina N=770 / +/-3.53% Elon University Poll of North Carolina residents April 5-9, 2013 Executive Summary and Demographic Crosstabs McCrory Obama Hagan Burr General Assembly Congress Job approval in North Carolina N=770 / +/-3.53%

More information

Moving the Unmoved Mover?: The Origins and Limitations of Systematic Individual-Level Change in Party Identification

Moving the Unmoved Mover?: The Origins and Limitations of Systematic Individual-Level Change in Party Identification Moving the Unmoved Mover?: The Origins and Limitations of Systematic Individual-Level Change in Party Identification Jacob M. Montgomery, Steven S. Smith, and Patrick D. Tucker Department of Political

More information

Vote Compass Methodology

Vote Compass Methodology Vote Compass Methodology 1 Introduction Vote Compass is a civic engagement application developed by the team of social and data scientists from Vox Pop Labs. Its objective is to promote electoral literacy

More information

Chapter 6 Online Appendix. general these issues do not cause significant problems for our analysis in this chapter. One

Chapter 6 Online Appendix. general these issues do not cause significant problems for our analysis in this chapter. One Chapter 6 Online Appendix Potential shortcomings of SF-ratio analysis Using SF-ratios to understand strategic behavior is not without potential problems, but in general these issues do not cause significant

More information

Immigrant Legalization

Immigrant Legalization Technical Appendices Immigrant Legalization Assessing the Labor Market Effects Laura Hill Magnus Lofstrom Joseph Hayes Contents Appendix A. Data from the 2003 New Immigrant Survey Appendix B. Measuring

More information

The role of Social Cultural and Political Factors in explaining Perceived Responsiveness of Representatives in Local Government.

The role of Social Cultural and Political Factors in explaining Perceived Responsiveness of Representatives in Local Government. The role of Social Cultural and Political Factors in explaining Perceived Responsiveness of Representatives in Local Government. Master Onderzoek 2012-2013 Family Name: Jelluma Given Name: Rinse Cornelis

More information

Moving the Unmoved Mover?: The Origins and Limitations of Systematic Individual-Level Change in Party Identification

Moving the Unmoved Mover?: The Origins and Limitations of Systematic Individual-Level Change in Party Identification Moving the Unmoved Mover?: The Origins and Limitations of Systematic Individual-Level Change in Party Identification Abstract Political scientists have long disagreed about the nature of individual-level

More information

Public Opinion and Political Participation

Public Opinion and Political Participation CHAPTER 5 Public Opinion and Political Participation CHAPTER OUTLINE I. What Is Public Opinion? II. How We Develop Our Beliefs and Opinions A. Agents of Political Socialization B. Adult Socialization III.

More information

The Making of Political Generations: Party Preferences and National Governments across Western Democracies

The Making of Political Generations: Party Preferences and National Governments across Western Democracies Nuffield s Working Papers Series in Politics The Making of Political Generations: Party Preferences and National Governments across Western Democracies Kaat Smets, University of Siena Email: smets@unisi.it

More information

English Deficiency and the Native-Immigrant Wage Gap

English Deficiency and the Native-Immigrant Wage Gap DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 7019 English Deficiency and the Native-Immigrant Wage Gap Alfonso Miranda Yu Zhu November 2012 Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit Institute for the Study of Labor

More information

Case Study: Get out the Vote

Case Study: Get out the Vote Case Study: Get out the Vote Do Phone Calls to Encourage Voting Work? Why Randomize? This case study is based on Comparing Experimental and Matching Methods Using a Large-Scale Field Experiment on Voter

More information

The California Primary and Redistricting

The California Primary and Redistricting The California Primary and Redistricting This study analyzes what is the important impact of changes in the primary voting rules after a Congressional and Legislative Redistricting. Under a citizen s committee,

More information

Can Ideal Point Estimates be Used as Explanatory Variables?

Can Ideal Point Estimates be Used as Explanatory Variables? Can Ideal Point Estimates be Used as Explanatory Variables? Andrew D. Martin Washington University admartin@wustl.edu Kevin M. Quinn Harvard University kevin quinn@harvard.edu October 8, 2005 1 Introduction

More information

Learning from Small Subsamples without Cherry Picking: The Case of Non-Citizen Registration and Voting

Learning from Small Subsamples without Cherry Picking: The Case of Non-Citizen Registration and Voting Learning from Small Subsamples without Cherry Picking: The Case of Non-Citizen Registration and Voting Jesse Richman Old Dominion University jrichman@odu.edu David C. Earnest Old Dominion University, and

More information

RECOMMENDED CITATION: Pew Research Center, May, 2017, Partisan Identification Is Sticky, but About 10% Switched Parties Over the Past Year

RECOMMENDED CITATION: Pew Research Center, May, 2017, Partisan Identification Is Sticky, but About 10% Switched Parties Over the Past Year NUMBERS, FACTS AND TRENDS SHAPING THE WORLD FOR RELEASE MAY 17, 2017 FOR MEDIA OR OTHER INQUIRIES: Carroll Doherty, Director of Political Research Jocelyn Kiley, Associate Director, Research Bridget Johnson,

More information

Discovering Migrant Types Through Cluster Analysis: Changes in the Mexico-U.S. Streams from 1970 to 2000

Discovering Migrant Types Through Cluster Analysis: Changes in the Mexico-U.S. Streams from 1970 to 2000 Discovering Migrant Types Through Cluster Analysis: Changes in the Mexico-U.S. Streams from 1970 to 2000 Extended Abstract - Do not cite or quote without permission. Filiz Garip Department of Sociology

More information

Understanding persuasion and activation in presidential campaigns: The random walk and mean-reversion models 1

Understanding persuasion and activation in presidential campaigns: The random walk and mean-reversion models 1 Understanding persuasion and activation in presidential campaigns: The random walk and mean-reversion models 1 Noah Kaplan, David K. Park, and Andrew Gelman 6 July 2012 Abstract. Political campaigns are

More information

'Wave riding' or 'Owning the issue': How do candidates determine campaign agendas?

'Wave riding' or 'Owning the issue': How do candidates determine campaign agendas? 'Wave riding' or 'Owning the issue': How do candidates determine campaign agendas? Mariya Burdina University of Colorado, Boulder Department of Economics October 5th, 008 Abstract In this paper I adress

More information

Hierarchical Item Response Models for Analyzing Public Opinion

Hierarchical Item Response Models for Analyzing Public Opinion Hierarchical Item Response Models for Analyzing Public Opinion Xiang Zhou Harvard University July 16, 2017 Xiang Zhou (Harvard University) Hierarchical IRT for Public Opinion July 16, 2017 Page 1 Features

More information

Michael Laver and Ernest Sergenti: Party Competition. An Agent-Based Model

Michael Laver and Ernest Sergenti: Party Competition. An Agent-Based Model RMM Vol. 3, 2012, 66 70 http://www.rmm-journal.de/ Book Review Michael Laver and Ernest Sergenti: Party Competition. An Agent-Based Model Princeton NJ 2012: Princeton University Press. ISBN: 9780691139043

More information

Supplementary Tables for Online Publication: Impact of Judicial Elections in the Sentencing of Black Crime

Supplementary Tables for Online Publication: Impact of Judicial Elections in the Sentencing of Black Crime Supplementary Tables for Online Publication: Impact of Judicial Elections in the Sentencing of Black Crime Kyung H. Park Wellesley College March 23, 2016 A Kansas Background A.1 Partisan versus Retention

More information

Appendix: Uncovering Patterns Among Latent Variables: Human Rights and De Facto Judicial Independence

Appendix: Uncovering Patterns Among Latent Variables: Human Rights and De Facto Judicial Independence Appendix: Uncovering Patterns Among Latent Variables: Human Rights and De Facto Judicial Independence Charles D. Crabtree Christopher J. Fariss August 12, 2015 CONTENTS A Variable descriptions 3 B Correlation

More information

Learning and Experience The interrelation of Civic (Co)Education, Political Socialisation and Engagement

Learning and Experience The interrelation of Civic (Co)Education, Political Socialisation and Engagement Learning and Experience The interrelation of Civic (Co)Education, Political Socialisation and Engagement Steve Schwarzer General Conference ECPR, Panel Young People and Politics Two Incompatible Worlds?,

More information

Consideration Sets for Party Choice: Size, Content, Stability and Relevance

Consideration Sets for Party Choice: Size, Content, Stability and Relevance 2015 Gothenburg 2015-04-16 Consideration Sets for Party Choice: Size, Content, Stability and Relevance Maria Oskarson, Henrik Oscarsson & Edvin Boije Report 2015:01 Swedish National Election Studies Program

More information

PSCI4120 Public Opinion and Participation

PSCI4120 Public Opinion and Participation PSCI4120 Public Opinion and Participation Micro-level Opinion Tetsuya Matsubayashi University of North Texas February 7, 2010 1 / 26 Questions on Micro-level Opinion 1 Political knowledge and opinion-holding

More information

Model of Voting. February 15, Abstract. This paper uses United States congressional district level data to identify how incumbency,

Model of Voting. February 15, Abstract. This paper uses United States congressional district level data to identify how incumbency, U.S. Congressional Vote Empirics: A Discrete Choice Model of Voting Kyle Kretschman The University of Texas Austin kyle.kretschman@mail.utexas.edu Nick Mastronardi United States Air Force Academy nickmastronardi@gmail.com

More information

Colorado 2014: Comparisons of Predicted and Actual Turnout

Colorado 2014: Comparisons of Predicted and Actual Turnout Colorado 2014: Comparisons of Predicted and Actual Turnout Date 2017-08-28 Project name Colorado 2014 Voter File Analysis Prepared for Washington Monthly and Project Partners Prepared by Pantheon Analytics

More information

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr Abstract. The Asian experience of poverty reduction has varied widely. Over recent decades the economies of East and Southeast Asia

More information

Cognitive Heterogeneity and Economic Voting: Does Political Sophistication Condition Economic Voting?

Cognitive Heterogeneity and Economic Voting: Does Political Sophistication Condition Economic Voting? 연구논문 Cognitive Heterogeneity and Economic Voting: Does Political Sophistication Condition Economic Voting? Han Soo Lee (Seoul National University) Does political sophistication matter for economic voting?

More information

Turnout and Strength of Habits

Turnout and Strength of Habits Turnout and Strength of Habits John H. Aldrich Wendy Wood Jacob M. Montgomery Duke University I) Introduction Social scientists are much better at explaining for whom people vote than whether people vote

More information

Jürgen Kohl March 2011

Jürgen Kohl March 2011 Jürgen Kohl March 2011 Comments to Claus Offe: What, if anything, might we mean by progressive politics today? Let me first say that I feel honoured by the opportunity to comment on this thoughtful and

More information

Do (naturalized) immigrants affect employment and wages of natives? Evidence from Germany

Do (naturalized) immigrants affect employment and wages of natives? Evidence from Germany Do (naturalized) immigrants affect employment and wages of natives? Evidence from Germany Carsten Pohl 1 15 September, 2008 Extended Abstract Since the beginning of the 1990s Germany has experienced a

More information

Georg Lutz, Nicolas Pekari, Marina Shkapina. CSES Module 5 pre-test report, Switzerland

Georg Lutz, Nicolas Pekari, Marina Shkapina. CSES Module 5 pre-test report, Switzerland Georg Lutz, Nicolas Pekari, Marina Shkapina CSES Module 5 pre-test report, Switzerland Lausanne, 8.31.2016 1 Table of Contents 1 Introduction 3 1.1 Methodology 3 2 Distribution of key variables 7 2.1 Attitudes

More information

Transnational Dimensions of Civil War

Transnational Dimensions of Civil War Transnational Dimensions of Civil War Kristian Skrede Gleditsch University of California, San Diego & Centre for the Study of Civil War, International Peace Research Institute, Oslo See http://weber.ucsd.edu/

More information

POLI 300 Fall 2010 PROBLEM SET #5B: ANSWERS AND DISCUSSION

POLI 300 Fall 2010 PROBLEM SET #5B: ANSWERS AND DISCUSSION POLI 300 Fall 2010 General Comments PROBLEM SET #5B: ANSWERS AND DISCUSSION Evidently most students were able to produce SPSS frequency tables (and sometimes bar charts as well) without particular difficulty.

More information

Patterns of Poll Movement *

Patterns of Poll Movement * Patterns of Poll Movement * Public Perspective, forthcoming Christopher Wlezien is Reader in Comparative Government and Fellow of Nuffield College, University of Oxford Robert S. Erikson is a Professor

More information

Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US

Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US Ben Ost a and Eva Dziadula b a Department of Economics, University of Illinois at Chicago, 601 South Morgan UH718 M/C144 Chicago,

More information

Elite Polarization and Mass Political Engagement: Information, Alienation, and Mobilization

Elite Polarization and Mass Political Engagement: Information, Alienation, and Mobilization JOURNAL OF INTERNATIONAL AND AREA STUDIES Volume 20, Number 1, 2013, pp.89-109 89 Elite Polarization and Mass Political Engagement: Information, Alienation, and Mobilization Jae Mook Lee Using the cumulative

More information

Political Economics II Spring Lectures 4-5 Part II Partisan Politics and Political Agency. Torsten Persson, IIES

Political Economics II Spring Lectures 4-5 Part II Partisan Politics and Political Agency. Torsten Persson, IIES Lectures 4-5_190213.pdf Political Economics II Spring 2019 Lectures 4-5 Part II Partisan Politics and Political Agency Torsten Persson, IIES 1 Introduction: Partisan Politics Aims continue exploring policy

More information

Issue Importance and Performance Voting. *** Soumis à Political Behavior ***

Issue Importance and Performance Voting. *** Soumis à Political Behavior *** Issue Importance and Performance Voting Patrick Fournier, André Blais, Richard Nadeau, Elisabeth Gidengil, and Neil Nevitte *** Soumis à Political Behavior *** Issue importance mediates the impact of public

More information

And Yet it Moves: The Effect of Election Platforms on Party. Policy Images

And Yet it Moves: The Effect of Election Platforms on Party. Policy Images And Yet it Moves: The Effect of Election Platforms on Party Policy Images Pablo Fernandez-Vazquez * Supplementary Online Materials [ Forthcoming in Comparative Political Studies ] These supplementary materials

More information

Party Polarization: A Longitudinal Analysis of the Gender Gap in Candidate Preference

Party Polarization: A Longitudinal Analysis of the Gender Gap in Candidate Preference Party Polarization: A Longitudinal Analysis of the Gender Gap in Candidate Preference Tiffany Fameree Faculty Sponsor: Dr. Ray Block, Jr., Department of Political Science/Public Administration ABSTRACT

More information

A Benchmarking Forecast of the 2013 Bundestag Election. Mark Kayser and Arndt Leininger. Hertie School of Governance, Berlin.

A Benchmarking Forecast of the 2013 Bundestag Election. Mark Kayser and Arndt Leininger. Hertie School of Governance, Berlin. A Benchmarking Forecast of the 2013 Bundestag Election Mark Kayser and Arndt Leininger Hertie School of Governance, Berlin 31 July 2013 Election forecasts are too serious a business to be left to pollsters

More information

political budget cycles

political budget cycles P000346 Theoretical and empirical research on is surveyed and discussed. Significant are seen to be primarily a phenomenon of the first elections after the transition to a democratic electoral system.

More information

Introduction and methodology 1

Introduction and methodology 1 RESEARCH BRIEF Monitoring Target 16.2 of the United Nations Sustainable Development Goals: multiple systems estimation of the numbers of presumed victims of trafficking in persons Romania In partnership

More information

Following the Leader: The Impact of Presidential Campaign Visits on Legislative Support for the President's Policy Preferences

Following the Leader: The Impact of Presidential Campaign Visits on Legislative Support for the President's Policy Preferences University of Colorado, Boulder CU Scholar Undergraduate Honors Theses Honors Program Spring 2011 Following the Leader: The Impact of Presidential Campaign Visits on Legislative Support for the President's

More information

Segal and Howard also constructed a social liberalism score (see Segal & Howard 1999).

Segal and Howard also constructed a social liberalism score (see Segal & Howard 1999). APPENDIX A: Ideology Scores for Judicial Appointees For a very long time, a judge s own partisan affiliation 1 has been employed as a useful surrogate of ideology (Segal & Spaeth 1990). The approach treats

More information

Electoral Studies 32 (2013) Contents lists available at SciVerse ScienceDirect. Electoral Studies

Electoral Studies 32 (2013) Contents lists available at SciVerse ScienceDirect. Electoral Studies Electoral Studies 32 (2013) 305 320 Contents lists available at SciVerse ScienceDirect Electoral Studies journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/electstud The meaning and use of subjective perceptions

More information

Why are Immigrants Underrepresented in Politics? Evidence From Sweden

Why are Immigrants Underrepresented in Politics? Evidence From Sweden Why are Immigrants Underrepresented in Politics? Evidence From Sweden Rafaela Dancygier (Princeton University) Karl-Oskar Lindgren (Uppsala University) Sven Oskarsson (Uppsala University) Kåre Vernby (Uppsala

More information

1 Electoral Competition under Certainty

1 Electoral Competition under Certainty 1 Electoral Competition under Certainty We begin with models of electoral competition. This chapter explores electoral competition when voting behavior is deterministic; the following chapter considers

More information

1. Introduction. Michael Finus

1. Introduction. Michael Finus 1. Introduction Michael Finus Global warming is believed to be one of the most serious environmental problems for current and hture generations. This shared belief led more than 180 countries to sign the

More information

PPIC Statewide Survey Methodology

PPIC Statewide Survey Methodology PPIC Statewide Survey Methodology Updated February 7, 2018 The PPIC Statewide Survey was inaugurated in 1998 to provide a way for Californians to express their views on important public policy issues.

More information

English Deficiency and the Native-Immigrant Wage Gap in the UK

English Deficiency and the Native-Immigrant Wage Gap in the UK English Deficiency and the Native-Immigrant Wage Gap in the UK Alfonso Miranda a Yu Zhu b,* a Department of Quantitative Social Science, Institute of Education, University of London, UK. Email: A.Miranda@ioe.ac.uk.

More information

Publicizing malfeasance:

Publicizing malfeasance: Publicizing malfeasance: When media facilitates electoral accountability in Mexico Horacio Larreguy, John Marshall and James Snyder Harvard University May 1, 2015 Introduction Elections are key for political

More information

Partisan Sorting and Niche Parties in Europe

Partisan Sorting and Niche Parties in Europe West European Politics, Vol. 35, No. 6, 1272 1294, November 2012 Partisan Sorting and Niche Parties in Europe JAMES ADAMS, LAWRENCE EZROW and DEBRA LEITER Earlier research has concluded that European citizens

More information

Is there a relationship between election outcomes and perceptions of personal economic well-being? A test using post-election economic expectations

Is there a relationship between election outcomes and perceptions of personal economic well-being? A test using post-election economic expectations Is there a relationship between election outcomes and perceptions of personal economic well-being? A test using post-election economic expectations Garrett Glasgow University of California, Santa Barbara

More information

Schooling and Cohort Size: Evidence from Vietnam, Thailand, Iran and Cambodia. Evangelos M. Falaris University of Delaware. and

Schooling and Cohort Size: Evidence from Vietnam, Thailand, Iran and Cambodia. Evangelos M. Falaris University of Delaware. and Schooling and Cohort Size: Evidence from Vietnam, Thailand, Iran and Cambodia by Evangelos M. Falaris University of Delaware and Thuan Q. Thai Max Planck Institute for Demographic Research March 2012 2

More information

Do parties and voters pursue the same thing? Policy congruence between parties and voters on different electoral levels

Do parties and voters pursue the same thing? Policy congruence between parties and voters on different electoral levels Do parties and voters pursue the same thing? Policy congruence between parties and voters on different electoral levels Cees van Dijk, André Krouwel and Max Boiten 2nd European Conference on Comparative

More information

ANNUAL SURVEY REPORT: AZERBAIJAN

ANNUAL SURVEY REPORT: AZERBAIJAN ANNUAL SURVEY REPORT: AZERBAIJAN 2 nd Wave (Spring 2017) OPEN Neighbourhood Communicating for a stronger partnership: connecting with citizens across the Eastern Neighbourhood June 2017 TABLE OF CONTENTS

More information

WP 2015: 9. Education and electoral participation: Reported versus actual voting behaviour. Ivar Kolstad and Arne Wiig VOTE

WP 2015: 9. Education and electoral participation: Reported versus actual voting behaviour. Ivar Kolstad and Arne Wiig VOTE WP 2015: 9 Reported versus actual voting behaviour Ivar Kolstad and Arne Wiig VOTE Chr. Michelsen Institute (CMI) is an independent, non-profit research institution and a major international centre in

More information

AMERICAN JOURNAL OF UNDERGRADUATE RESEARCH VOL. 3 NO. 4 (2005)

AMERICAN JOURNAL OF UNDERGRADUATE RESEARCH VOL. 3 NO. 4 (2005) , Partisanship and the Post Bounce: A MemoryBased Model of Post Presidential Candidate Evaluations Part II Empirical Results Justin Grimmer Department of Mathematics and Computer Science Wabash College

More information

Party Platforms with Endogenous Party Membership

Party Platforms with Endogenous Party Membership Party Platforms with Endogenous Party Membership Panu Poutvaara 1 Harvard University, Department of Economics poutvaar@fas.harvard.edu Abstract In representative democracies, the development of party platforms

More information

Party Identification and Party Choice

Party Identification and Party Choice THOMASSEN: The European Voter 05-Thomassen-chap05 Page Proof page 105 31.1.2005 7:52am 5 Party Identification and Party Choice Frode Berglund, Sören Holmberg, Hermann Schmitt, and Jacques Thomassen 5.1

More information

Jeffrey M. Stonecash Maxwell Professor

Jeffrey M. Stonecash Maxwell Professor Campbell Public Affairs Institute Inequality and the American Public Results of the Fourth Annual Maxwell School Survey Conducted September, 2007 Jeffrey M. Stonecash Maxwell Professor Campbell Public

More information

The Causes of Wage Differentials between Immigrant and Native Physicians

The Causes of Wage Differentials between Immigrant and Native Physicians The Causes of Wage Differentials between Immigrant and Native Physicians I. Introduction Current projections, as indicated by the 2000 Census, suggest that racial and ethnic minorities will outnumber non-hispanic

More information

Decomposing Public Opinion Variation into Ideology, Idiosyncrasy and Instability *

Decomposing Public Opinion Variation into Ideology, Idiosyncrasy and Instability * Decomposing Public Opinion Variation into Ideology, Idiosyncrasy and Instability * Benjamin E Lauderdale London School of Economics and Political Science Chris Hanretty University of East Anglia Nick Vivyan

More information

Immigration and Internal Mobility in Canada Appendices A and B. Appendix A: Two-step Instrumentation strategy: Procedure and detailed results

Immigration and Internal Mobility in Canada Appendices A and B. Appendix A: Two-step Instrumentation strategy: Procedure and detailed results Immigration and Internal Mobility in Canada Appendices A and B by Michel Beine and Serge Coulombe This version: February 2016 Appendix A: Two-step Instrumentation strategy: Procedure and detailed results

More information

Job Loss Fears and (Extremist) Party Identification: First Evidence from Panel Data

Job Loss Fears and (Extremist) Party Identification: First Evidence from Panel Data DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 6996 Job Loss Fears and (Extremist) Party Identification: First Evidence from Panel Data Ingo Geishecker Thomas Siedler November 2012 Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der

More information

Response to the Report Evaluation of Edison/Mitofsky Election System

Response to the Report Evaluation of Edison/Mitofsky Election System US Count Votes' National Election Data Archive Project Response to the Report Evaluation of Edison/Mitofsky Election System 2004 http://exit-poll.net/election-night/evaluationjan192005.pdf Executive Summary

More information

Do Individual Heterogeneity and Spatial Correlation Matter?

Do Individual Heterogeneity and Spatial Correlation Matter? Do Individual Heterogeneity and Spatial Correlation Matter? An Innovative Approach to the Characterisation of the European Political Space. Giovanna Iannantuoni, Elena Manzoni and Francesca Rossi EXTENDED

More information

THE EMOTIONAL LEGACY OF BREXIT: HOW BRITAIN HAS BECOME A COUNTRY OF REMAINERS AND LEAVERS

THE EMOTIONAL LEGACY OF BREXIT: HOW BRITAIN HAS BECOME A COUNTRY OF REMAINERS AND LEAVERS THE EMOTIONAL LEGACY OF BREXIT: HOW BRITAIN HAS BECOME A COUNTRY OF REMAINERS AND LEAVERS John Curtice, Senior Research Fellow at NatCen and Professor of Politics at Strathclyde University 1 The Emotional

More information

How Incivility in Partisan Media (De-)Polarizes. the Electorate

How Incivility in Partisan Media (De-)Polarizes. the Electorate How Incivility in Partisan Media (De-)Polarizes the Electorate Ashley Lloyd MMSS Senior Thesis Advisor: Professor Druckman 1 Research Question: The aim of this study is to uncover how uncivil partisan

More information

Who Votes for the Future? Information, Expectations, and Endogeneity in Economic Voting

Who Votes for the Future? Information, Expectations, and Endogeneity in Economic Voting DOI 10.1007/s11109-016-9359-3 ORIGINAL PAPER Who Votes for the Future? Information, Expectations, and Endogeneity in Economic Voting Dean Lacy 1 Dino P. Christenson 2 Springer Science+Business Media New

More information

Appendix for: The Electoral Implications. of Coalition Policy-Making

Appendix for: The Electoral Implications. of Coalition Policy-Making Appendix for: The Electoral Implications of Coalition Policy-Making David Fortunato Texas A&M University fortunato@tamu.edu 1 A1: Cabinets evaluated by respondents in sample surveys Table 1: Cabinets included

More information

Determinants of Return Migration to Mexico Among Mexicans in the United States

Determinants of Return Migration to Mexico Among Mexicans in the United States Determinants of Return Migration to Mexico Among Mexicans in the United States J. Cristobal Ruiz-Tagle * Rebeca Wong 1.- Introduction The wellbeing of the U.S. population will increasingly reflect the

More information

FOURIER ANALYSIS OF THE NUMBER OF PUBLIC LAWS David L. Farnsworth, Eisenhower College Michael G. Stratton, GTE Sylvania

FOURIER ANALYSIS OF THE NUMBER OF PUBLIC LAWS David L. Farnsworth, Eisenhower College Michael G. Stratton, GTE Sylvania FOURIER ANALYSIS OF THE NUMBER OF PUBLIC LAWS 1789-1976 David L. Farnsworth, Eisenhower College Michael G. Stratton, GTE Sylvania 1. Introduction. In an earlier study (reference hereafter referred to as

More information

Sampling Equilibrium, with an Application to Strategic Voting Martin J. Osborne 1 and Ariel Rubinstein 2 September 12th, 2002.

Sampling Equilibrium, with an Application to Strategic Voting Martin J. Osborne 1 and Ariel Rubinstein 2 September 12th, 2002. Sampling Equilibrium, with an Application to Strategic Voting Martin J. Osborne 1 and Ariel Rubinstein 2 September 12th, 2002 Abstract We suggest an equilibrium concept for a strategic model with a large

More information