Small Employers, Large Employers and the Skill Premium

Similar documents
Is inequality an unavoidable by-product of skill-biased technical change? No, not necessarily!

Skilled Immigration and the Employment Structures of US Firms

Trade and Inequality: From Theory to Estimation

Do (naturalized) immigrants affect employment and wages of natives? Evidence from Germany

Occupational Concentration, Wages, and Growing Wage Inequality. Elizabeth Weber Handwerker U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics

The interaction effect of economic freedom and democracy on corruption: A panel cross-country analysis

Volume 35, Issue 1. An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach

Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation

F E M M Faculty of Economics and Management Magdeburg

Immigrant Children s School Performance and Immigration Costs: Evidence from Spain

Cities, Skills, and Inequality

CENTRO STUDI LUCA D AGLIANO DEVELOPMENT STUDIES WORKING PAPERS N April Export Growth and Firm Survival

Explaining the Unexplained: Residual Wage Inequality, Manufacturing Decline, and Low-Skilled Immigration

UK wage inequality: An industry and regional perspective

Boston Library Consortium Member Libraries

Labor Market Deregulation and Wage Dispersion: Does Product Market Competition Matter? The case of the EU Electricity Industry

5A. Wage Structures in the Electronics Industry. Benjamin A. Campbell and Vincent M. Valvano

High Technology Agglomeration and Gender Inequalities

Computerization and Immigration: Theory and Evidence from the United States 1

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES HOMEOWNERSHIP IN THE IMMIGRANT POPULATION. George J. Borjas. Working Paper

Explaining the Unexplained: Residual Wage Inequality, Manufacturing Decline, and Low-Skilled Immigration. Unfinished Draft Not for Circulation

Industrial & Labor Relations Review

Labour demand and the distribution of wages in South African manufacturing exporters

Family Ties, Labor Mobility and Interregional Wage Differentials*

Justin Wolfers Wharton School, U.Penn CEPR, IZA & NBER. Princeton, New Directions Conference April 8, 2006

Household Inequality and Remittances in Rural Thailand: A Lifecycle Perspective

Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US

Research Report. How Does Trade Liberalization Affect Racial and Gender Identity in Employment? Evidence from PostApartheid South Africa

I'll Marry You If You Get Me a Job: Marital Assimilation and Immigrant Employment Rates

Exporters and Wage Inequality during the Great Recession - Evidence from Germany

The Improving Relative Status of Black Men

IS THE MEASURED BLACK-WHITE WAGE GAP AMONG WOMEN TOO SMALL? Derek Neal University of Wisconsin Presented Nov 6, 2000 PRELIMINARY

Is Corruption Anti Labor?

Revisiting the Great Gatsby Curve

The China Syndrome. Local Labor Market Effects of Import Competition in the United States. David H. Autor, David Dorn, and Gordon H.

Immigrant-native wage gaps in time series: Complementarities or composition effects?

On Trade Policy and Wages Inequality in Egypt: Evidence from Microeconomic Data

The Effect of Immigration on Native Workers: Evidence from the US Construction Sector

FOREIGN FIRMS AND INDONESIAN MANUFACTURING WAGES: AN ANALYSIS WITH PANEL DATA

Human Capital and Income Inequality: New Facts and Some Explanations

Firm Dynamics and Immigration: The Case of High-Skilled Immigration

Growth, Volatility and Political Instability: Non-Linear Time-Series Evidence for Argentina,

Quantitative Analysis of Migration and Development in South Asia

The role of part-time work in rising wage inequality

The impact of Chinese import competition on the local structure of employment and wages in France

The Impact of Unionization on the Wage of Hispanic Workers. Cinzia Rienzo and Carlos Vargas-Silva * This Version, May 2015.

Unequal Recovery, Labor Market Polarization, Race, and 2016 U.S. Presidential Election. Maoyong Fan and Anita Alves Pena 1

Within-Groups Wage Inequality and Schooling: Further Evidence for Portugal

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE LABOR MARKET IMPACT OF HIGH-SKILL IMMIGRATION. George J. Borjas. Working Paper

Human rights, political instability and investment in south Africa: a note

Technological Change, Skill Demand, and Wage Inequality in Indonesia

Why are the Relative Wages of Immigrants Declining? A Distributional Approach* Brahim Boudarbat, Université de Montréal

The Impact of Deunionisation on Earnings Dispersion Revisited. John T. Addison Department of Economics, University of South Carolina (U.S.A.

Crime and Unemployment in Greece: Evidence Before and During the Crisis

PROJECTION OF NET MIGRATION USING A GRAVITY MODEL 1. Laboratory of Populations 2

THE GENDER WAGE GAP AND SEX SEGREGATION IN FINLAND* OSSI KORKEAMÄKI TOMI KYYRÄ

The Economic and Social Review, Vol. 42, No. 1, Spring, 2011, pp. 1 26

The wage gap between the public and the private sector among. Canadian-born and immigrant workers

Edward L. Glaeser Harvard University and NBER and. David C. Maré * New Zealand Department of Labour

The Impact of Immigration on the Wage Structure: Spain

Is the Great Gatsby Curve Robust?

Immigrant Legalization

Income inequality and crime: the case of Sweden #

Remittances and the Brain Drain: Evidence from Microdata for Sub-Saharan Africa

Parental Response to Changes in Return to Education for Children: The Case of Mexico. Kaveh Majlesi. October 2012 PRELIMINARY-DO NOT CITE

Crime and Corruption: An International Empirical Study

Different Endowment or Remuneration? Exploring wage differentials in Switzerland

Wage Structure and Gender Earnings Differentials in China and. India*

Residual Wage Inequality: A Re-examination* Thomas Lemieux University of British Columbia. June Abstract

Gender wage gap in the workplace: Does the age of the firm matter?

Wage Trends among Disadvantaged Minorities

(V) Migration Flows and Policies. Bocconi University,

Table A.2 reports the complete set of estimates of equation (1). We distinguish between personal

Immigration and property prices: Evidence from England and Wales

International Import Competition and the Decision to Migrate: Evidence from Mexico

Online Appendix for. Home Away From Home? Foreign Demand and London House Prices

I ll marry you if you get me a job Marital assimilation and immigrant employment rates

Economic Origins of Authoritarian Values. Evidence from Local Trade Shocks in the United Kingdom

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr

DETERMINANTS OF IMMIGRANTS EARNINGS IN THE ITALIAN LABOUR MARKET: THE ROLE OF HUMAN CAPITAL AND COUNTRY OF ORIGIN

The Impact of Unionization on the Wage of Hispanic Workers. Cinzia Rienzo and Carlos Vargas-Silva * This Version, December 2014.

Skill Classification Does Matter: Estimating the Relationship Between Trade Flows and Wage Inequality

Human capital transmission and the earnings of second-generation immigrants in Sweden

Educational Qualifications and Wage Inequality: Evidence for Europe

The Dynamic Response of Fractionalization to Public Policy in U.S. Cities

The labor market in Brazil,

Immigration and Internal Mobility in Canada Appendices A and B. Appendix A: Two-step Instrumentation strategy: Procedure and detailed results

Income and Democracy

Impacts of International Migration on the Labor Market in Japan

Rethinking the Area Approach: Immigrants and the Labor Market in California,

John Parman Introduction. Trevon Logan. William & Mary. Ohio State University. Measuring Historical Residential Segregation. Trevon Logan.

The Determinants and the Selection. of Mexico-US Migrations

Inequality in Labor Market Outcomes: Contrasting the 1980s and Earlier Decades

Culture, Gender and Math Revisited

Benefit levels and US immigrants welfare receipts

Case Evidence: Blacks, Hispanics, and Immigrants

Labor Reallocation over the Business Cycle: New Evidence from Internal Migration

CEP Discussion Paper No 712 December 2005

The Employment of Low-Skilled Immigrant Men in the United States

Migration and Consumption Insurance in Bangladesh

Transcription:

Small Employers, Large Employers and the Skill Premium January 2016 Damir Stijepic Johannes Gutenberg University, Mainz Abstract I document the comovement of the skill premium with the differential employer size wage premium between high- and low-skill workers in U.S. manufacturing during the postwar era. For the baseline specification, i.e., establishments with at least 500 employees categorized as large employers and non-production workers as high-skilled, I obtain a correlation coefficient of 0.87. Exploiting variations across subindustries while controlling for other potentially relevant factors, I estimate that an increase by ten log-points in the differential size premium is associated with an increase in the skill premium by three log-points. Keywords: skill premium, employer size wage premium, differential employer size wage premium, wage inequality JEL: J00, I26, J31 I thank Jennifer Abel-Koch, Nicola Fuchs-Schündeln, Nils Gornemann, Bradley Heim, Thorsten Schank, Denis Stijepic, Hitoshi Tsujiyama, and two anonymous referees for helpful comments. Furthermore, I thank the Bureau of the Census, especially Asheleigh Perry, for assistance with the data. The usual disclaimer applies. Email address: mail@damir.stijepic.com (Damir Stijepic)

1. Introduction An important and influential strand of labor market research analyzes wage differentials. One of the most prominent stylized facts is that larger employers pay higher wages. The Handbook of Labor Economics dedicates an entire chapter to the relation between wages and the size of the employer (Oi and Idson, 1999). Most of the literature investigates why even observably identical workers enjoy a wage premium at large establishments and firms. I contribute to the literature by uncovering a close relation between the employer size wage premia and another key wage premium. Specifically, I document the comovement of the skill premium with the differential employer size wage premium between high- and low-skill workers in U.S. manufacturing during the postwar era. Most notably, the surge in the skill premium in the 1980s and 1990s coincides with the surge in the differential size premium. This suggests that differences between small and large employers play a potentially important role in explaining the recent increases in wage inequality. The present paper is also related to the literature that stresses the role of establishments and firms in explaining the positive trend in wage inequality that so many countries have experienced over the last decades (e.g., Dunne et al., 2004; Faggio et al., 2010; Card et al., 2013; Barth et al., 2014). I complement this strand of literature by exploring the contribution of the differences between small and large employers to the rising skill premium. 1 2. Differential Size and Skill Premia First, I document the evolution of the differential employer size wage premium and the skill premium in U.S. manufacturing since 1947. I focus here on manufacturing since this industry is traditionally well covered. The empirical study is based on the Census of Manufactures, which collects information on U.S. manufacturing once every five years, combining both administrative records and establishment surveys. Production and non-production workers serve as proxies for low- and high-skill workers, respectively, since this information is consistently 1 Stijepic (2015) studies the impact of the heterogeneous adoption across establishments of a new technology on wage inequality in a search and matching framework. The model, calibrated to match differences in inter-firm mobility between skill groups and rising productivity dispersion across establishments in U.S. manufacturing between the late 1970s and 1990s, attributes onethird of the increase in the skill premium and the entire increase in the differential establishment size wage premium to skill-neutral technical change and the technology diffusion process itself.

available over the entire sample period. I define the employer size wage premium as the wage premium enjoyed by workers at establishments with at least 500 employees relative to workers at establishments with less than 500 employees. 2 The differential size wage premium is the difference between the non-production and production workers establishment size premia. Figure 1 depicts the evolution of the differential employer size premium and the skill premium in U.S. manufacturing during the postwar era. The skill premium rose by 17 percentage points from 56 percent in 1947 to 73 percent in 2007. Most of the increase occurred in the 1980s and 1990s. The U.S. economy in its entirety exhibited similar trends (see, e.g., Acemoglu, 2003). The differential establishment size wage premium rose from -24 percentage points to -4 percentage points over the same time span. Most of the increase occurred after the 1970s. The correlation coefficient of the skill premium and the differential size premium is 0.87 and significant at the one percent level. skill premium (in %) 50 55 60 65 70 75 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 30 25 20 15 10 5 differential size premium (in %) Figure 1: Skill premium and differential employer size wage premium between high- and low-skill workers in U.S. manufacturing. Size premium defined as the wage premium enjoyed by workers at establishments with at least 500 employees relative to workers at establishments with less than 500 employees. Non-production and production workers as proxies for high- and low-skill workers, respectively. Author s calculations based on the Census of Manufactures. In order to shed further light on the relation between the skill premium and the differential size premium, I exploit variations across 20 subindustries while also taking into account other potentially relevant factors. 3 Let w i,t be the average 2 Establishments with less than 500 employees account on average for around 60 percent of overall employment in U.S. manufacturing over the sample period. 3 The industry classification changes from the Standard Industrial Classification (SIC) system

wage in the subindustry i in the year t. Furthermore, let the subscripts s {l, h} and e {s, l} denote the low- and high-skill workers variables, and the small and large establishments variables, respectively. For a given variable x i,t, let s x i,t be the difference between the high- and low-skill workers variables, i.e., s x i,t x s=h i,t x s=l i,t. Similarly, e x i,t is the difference between the large and small establishments variables, i.e., e x i,t x e=l i,t x e=s i,t. Hence, the log-wage skill premium, size premium, and differential size premium are s log(w i,t ), e log(w i,t ), and s e log(w i,t ), respectively. Formally, I estimate the econometric model s log(w i,t ) = α s e log(w i,t ) + βlog(prod i,t ) + γ s log(emp i,t ) + δlog(emp i,t ) + β e log(prod i,t ) + γ e s log(emp i,t ) + δ e log(emp i,t ) + u t + v i + ϵ i,t, where emp i,t and prod i,t denote employment and value added per worker. Furthermore, the subindustry and time fixed effects are v i and u t, respectively, and the unexplained residual is denoted by ϵ i,t. The parameter α reflects the effect of the differential size premium on the skill premium. The parameters β, γ, and δ capture the impact of the subindustry s labor productivity, skill intensity, and size, respectively, while the corresponding parameters β, γ, and δ describe the impact of the differences between the subindustry s large and small establishments in those three variables. 4 Table 1 displays the employment weighted ordinary least squares estimates of the effect of the differential employer size wage premium and the other covariates on the skill premium. 5 An increase in the differential employer size premium by ten log-points is estimated to be associated with an increase in the skill premium by 2.5 to 3.2 log-points. 6 with 20 subindustries to the North American Industry Classification System (NAICS) with 21 subindustries between the survey years 1992 and 1997. 4 While there is strong evidence that a positive skill size relation has existed in recent decades, evidence for the 19th century suggests a negative skill size relation (Holmes and Mitchell, 2008). 5 The year 1947 is omitted since value added in that year is only reported in unadjusted terms. Adjusted value added also takes into account the value added by merchandising operations, and the net change in finished goods and work-in-process inventories between the beginning and the end of the year. 6 While an increase in labor productivity is estimated to decrease the skill premium, an increase in the large establishments relative labor productivity is estimated to raise the skill premium. This pattern is not statistically significant in all the specifications here, but it suggests that differences in the adoption of technologies between establishments may play an important role in explaining the evolution of the skill premium (see, e.g., Stijepic, 2015).

1954 1992 1954 2007 (1) (2) (3) (4) Differential size premium (α) 0.318 0.303 0.312 0.249 (0.143) (0.092) (0.119) (0.082) Basic industry characteristics Labor productivity (β) 0.270 0.043 0.211 0.013 (0.125) (0.040) (0.067) (0.049) Skill intensity (γ) 0.100 0.186 0.090 0.163 (0.090) (0.047) (0.082) (0.046) Size (δ) 0.029 0.072 0.031 0.049 (0.037) (0.029) (0.028) (0.030) Employer size differentials Labor productivity (β ) 0.061 0.124 0.078 0.020 (0.148) (0.050) (0.077) (0.046) Skill intensity (γ ) 0.008 0.109 0.084 0.128 (0.096) (0.049) (0.081) (0.044) Size (δ ) 0.005 0.060 0.001 0.065 (0.031) (0.017) (0.027) (0.016) Subindustry (v i ) x x Year (u t ) x x x x R-squared 0.627 0.973 0.521 0.968 Observations 140 140 203 203 Table 1: Employment weighted ordinary least squares estimates of the effect of the displayed variables on the skill premium, with robust standard errors adjusted for clustering at the subindustry level in parentheses. Size premium defined as the wage premium enjoyed by workers at establishments with at least 500 employees relative to workers at establishments with less than 500 employees. Non-production and production workers as proxies for high- and low-skill workers, respectively. Statistical significance at the 10, 5, and 1 percent level denoted by,, and, respectively. Author s calculations based on the Census of Manufactures. 3. Conclusion In the present paper, I document the comovement of the skill premium with the differential establishment size wage premium between high- and low-skill workers in U.S. manufacturing during the postwar period. Most notably, the surge in the skill premium in the 1980s and 1990s coincides with the surge in the differential establishment size premium. This suggests that differences between small and large employers play a potentially important role in explaining the recent increases in wage inequality.

References Acemoglu, D., 2003. Patterns of Skill Premia. Review of Economic Studies 70 (2), 199 230. Barth, E., Bryson, A., Davis, J. C., Freeman, R. B., 2014. It s Where You Work: Increases in Earnings Dispersion across Establishments and Individuals in the U.S. IZA Discussion Papers 8437, Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA). Card, D., Heining, J., Kline, P., 2013. Workplace Heterogeneity and the Rise of West German Wage Inequality. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 128 (3), 967 1015. Dunne, T., Foster, L., Haltiwanger, J., Troske, K. R., 2004. Wage and Productivity Dispersion in United States Manufacturing: The Role of Computer Investment. Journal of Labor Economics 22 (2), 397 430. Faggio, G., Salvanes, K. G., Reenen, J. V., 2010. The Evolution of Inequality in Productivity and Wages: Panel Data Evidence. Industrial and Corporate Change 19 (6), 1919 1951. Holmes, T. J., Mitchell, M. F., 2008. A Theory of Factor Allocation and Plant Size. RAND Journal of Economics 39 (2), 329 351. Oi, W. Y., Idson, T. L., 1999. Firm Size and Wages. In: Ashenfelter, O., Card, D. (Eds.), Handbook of Labor Economics. Vol. 3. Elsevier, Ch. 33, pp. 2165 2214. Stijepic, D., 2015. Technology Diffusion, Worker Mobility and the Returns to Skill. Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2635538 or http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2635538.

Appendix A. Data Appendix I construct the time series by establishment size from tabulations in various Census of Manufactures reports: 7 1947: U.S. Department of Commerce, B. o. t. C., 1950. 1947 Census of Manufactures. Vol. 1, General Summary. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office. (Chapter 3, pp. 97) 1954: U.S. Department of Commerce, B. o. t. C., 1957. 1954 Census of Manufactures. Vol. 1, Summary Statistics. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office. (Chapter 3, pp. 1) 1958 1967: U.S. Department of Commerce, B. o. t. C., 1971. 1967 Census of Manufactures. Vol. 1, Summary and Subject Statistics. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office. (Chapter 2, pp. 4) 1972: U.S. Department of Commerce, B. o. t. C., 1976. 1972 Census of Manufactures. Vol. 1, Subject and Special Statistics. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office. (Chapter 2, pp. 68) 1977: U.S. Department of Commerce, B. o. t. C., 1981. 1977 Census of Manufactures. Vol. 1, Subject Statistics. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office. (Chapter 1, pp. 59) 1982: U.S. Department of Commerce, B. o. t. C., 1985. 1982 Census of Manufactures. Subject Series. General Summary. Part 2. Industry Statistics by Employment Size of Establishment. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office. (pp. 3) 1987 2007: The series for the years 1987 onwards are directly available in machine readable formats on the website of the United States Bureau of the Census: MC87I4-1 for the year 1987, MC92SF4 for the year 1992, E9731G4 for the year 1997, ECN 2002 US 31SG105 for the year 2002, and ECN 2007 US 31SG3 for the year 2007. 7 Instructions on how to obtain data from the Economic Census are available on the website of the United States Bureau of the Census (http://www.census.gov/econ/census07).

In some subindustries, the statistics for some establishment size classes with few observations have not been disclosed in order to preserve confidentiality. However, the number of establishments is always disclosed. Since the total over all establishment size classes is also always disclosed, the data allows me to compute per-establishment statistics for all subindustries. Finally, the total over all subindustries in a size class and, hence, the total over all not disclosed values in a size class is provided. I exploit this information to impute the not disclosed values so that high value added subindustries remain high value added subindustries, skill intensive subindustries remain skill intensive, and so on. I use a chain-type price index for value added in U.S. manufacturing in order to express all monetary amounts in 2005 prices. Table A.2 displays summary statistics for U.S. manufacturing subindustries in 1954 2007. Establishments All Small Large Wage premia (in %) Skill premium 60.558 70.976 44.181 (25.695) (27.015) (21.729) High-skill size premium 10.168 (10.632) Low-skill size premium 27.121 (17.958) Differential size premium 16.953 (13.775) Basic industry characteristics Value added per worker 710.061 626.235 850.172 (647.561) (519.113) (896.108) Skill share (in %) 27.593 25.823 30.553 (9.651) (8.644) (11.663) Employment 825.988 516.784 309.201 (538.559) (342.034) (331.253) Table A.2: Employment weighted statistics for U.S. manufacturing subindustries in 1954 2007, with standard deviations in parentheses. Size premium defined as the wage premium enjoyed by workers at establishments with at least 500 employees relative to workers at establishments with less than 500 employees. Non-production and production workers as proxies for high- and low-skill workers, respectively. Author s calculations based on the Census of Manufactures.