AN EMPIRICAL ANATOMY OF POLITICAL ACCOUNTABILITY: EXPERIMENTAL EVIDENCE FROM A PRE-ELECTION

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "AN EMPIRICAL ANATOMY OF POLITICAL ACCOUNTABILITY: EXPERIMENTAL EVIDENCE FROM A PRE-ELECTION"

Transcription

1 AN EMPIRICAL ANATOMY OF POLITICAL ACCOUNTABILITY: EXPERIMENTAL EVIDENCE FROM A PRE-ELECTION INFORMATION DISSEMINATION CAMPAIGN IN SENEGAL ABHIT BHANDARI HORACIO LARREGUY JOHN MARSHALL MARCH 2018 The mixed effects of information campaigns on political accountability suggest complex interactions between information content, voters, and politicians. We conducted a field experiment around Senegal s 2017 parliamentary elections to probe the steps linking information dissemination to electoral accountability and non-electoral voter requests from incumbents. We randomized whether leaflets detailing deputies duties, incumbents local and national performance, and benchmarks comparing current to previous incumbent performance. We find that voters immediately processed information as Bayesians, and their updated beliefs persisted for at least a month. Consistent with current incumbents typically outperforming previous incumbents, individual requests of high-performing politicians persistently increase among treated voters, especially following benchmarked information. In contrast, the link from voters immediate intention to vote for better-performing incumbents to actual vote choice weeks later is complicated by interactions among voters and between voters and parties. Nevertheless, better-forming performing incumbents are still rewarded electorally, most likely due to complementary incumbent responses to disseminating strong local performance records. In spite of complex political equilibria, these findings indicate that voters are willing and able to use information to support political accountability. We thank Fodé Sarr and his team of enumerators for invaluable research assistance, and Elimane Kane and LEGS- Africa for partnering with us to implement this project. We thank Kate Orkin, Julia Payson, Arturas Rozenas, Moses Shayo, and participants at the NYU CESS and WGAPE-NYU Abu Dhabi conferences for excellent comments. This project received financial support from the Spencer Foundation, and was approved by the Columbia Institutional Review Board (IRB-AAAR3724) and the Harvard Committee on the Use of Human Subjects (IRB ). Our preanalysis plan was registered with the Social Science Registry, and is available at socialscienceregistry.org/trials/2324. Department of Political Science, Columbia University. ab3901@columbia.edu. Department of Government, Harvard University. hlarreguy@fas.harvard.edu. Department of Political Science, Columbia University. jm4401@columbia.edu. 1

2 1 Introduction As a cornerstone of effective democracy, political accountability has received substantial attention from scholars and policy-makers (see Ashworth 2012; Khemani et al. 2016; Manin, Przeworski and Stokes 1999). It is often argued that providing voters with information about their incumbent s performance in office will help them to retain high-quality politicians (Fearon 1999) and actively engage in non-electoral accountability-seeking behavior. However, a wealth of recent studies examining the effects of informational campaigns on electoral accountability and collective action yield mixed findings (e.g. Banerjee et al. 2010, 2011; Björkman Nyqvist, de Walque and Svensson 2017; Chong et al. 2015; de Figueiredo, Hidalgo and Kasahara 2013; Dunning et al. forthcoming; Ferraz and Finan 2008; Humphreys and Weinstein 2012; Larreguy, Marshall and Snyder 2018; Lieberman, Posner and Tsai 2014; Olken 2007). Given the complex chain of conditions linking the provision of information to better governance (Lieberman, Posner and Tsai 2014), it is often hard to know where accountability breaks down and under what conditions it can succeed. Moreover, little is known about the extent to which information s effects extend to non-electoral forms of political accountability. In this paper, we extensively examine the anatomy of political accountability, and where attempts to stimulate greater accountability might break down. We focus on three key links between the provision of information about the performance of parliamentary deputies and electoral accountability, as well as pre- and post-election voter attempts to make requests from their representatives. First, we vary the content of the information provided to understand what information voters regard as relevant. Specifically, we inform voters about the responsibilities of their deputies and help voters to abstract from district-specific factors that influence the performance of all incumbents by comparing incumbent performance to previous incumbents within the same district. Second, we examine the extent to which voters can process, retain, and ultimately act on incumbent performance information. Third, we study how campaign responses to information provision 2

3 that occur after information dissemination but before elections, both among voters and between voters and local political actors, can alter vote intentions derived purely from updated beliefs. To study these core mechanisms underpinning political accountability, we designed a field experiment and a sequence of panel surveys in rural Senegal around the 2017 parliamentary elections. We consider this a hard test for the broader theory, given the popular belief that the low levels of education and political knowledge in rural Senegal might prohibit effective accountability (e.g. Gomez and Wilson 2006), the prevalence of bloc voting led by chiefs and other local leaders (Gottlieb and Larreguy 2018; Koter 2013), and the traditionally low levels of parliamentary accountability in Senegal s hyper-presidential system (Thomas and Sissokho 2005). We partnered with LEGS-Africa, a Dakar-based civic organization working to increase civic engagement. Across 450 villages from five of Senegal s departments (which serve as parliamentary districts), we distributed informational leaflets to nine young adults (aged 20-38) in treated villages before the election. Our factorial design varied whether respondents were: (1) informed about the duties of their parliamentary deputies; (2) received performance information pertaining to their incumbent s activity in the legislative and the number and value of projects and transfers received by their department; and/or (3) received incumbent performance information benchmarked against the previous incumbent. In most departments, incumbent performance exceeded voter expectations and the performance of previous incumbents. To separate immediate effects on beliefs from the equilibrium responses that could shape longer-term effects of these treatments, we measured the beliefs and (intended and actual) behavioral responses of voters both immediately after treatment and after the election (around a month later). By providing information in the weeks just preceding the election, there was no scope for politicians to alter parliamentary behavior before the election. To understand how voters process the information provided, we elicited detailed pre-treatment prior beliefs and intended voting behavior. Our findings first demonstrate that rural Senegalese process incumbent performance information in a sophisticated manner. Immediately after receiving the information, voters retain the 3

4 leaflets information and update their beliefs accordingly. Voter updating is consistent with the Bayesian tenets that the direction of updating depends on voters prior beliefs, that the extent of updating varies with the signal s content, and that voters with imprecise prior beliefs update more. Moreover, while information about deputy responsibilities does not affect beliefs, we find that benchmarked information substantially influences the extent of voter updating and increases the precision of posterior beliefs. Perhaps most remarkably, we observe similar albeit somewhat weaker results one month after information was provided. Furthermore, voters generally seek to hold politicians to account on the basis of the information provided. Immediately after receiving the information, the average treated voter who updated favorably about the incumbent s performance became three percentage points more likely to intend to vote for the incumbent. Heterogeneity in such rewards is closely tied to the extent to which voters updated their beliefs, and the extent to which the performance information is the most important factor in determining vote choices. These intentions are backed up by behavioral outcomes indicating voters greater willingness to request posters and visits from incumbent candidates about whom they update positively, as well as opportunities to express their views to those candidates. After the elections, in which the incumbent won in each of our five departments, non-electoral behavioral outcomes show that respondents continue to make more requests of the best-performing winning candidates. The 0.1 standard deviation increase in requests does not simply reflect relatively costless requests for victors to call respondents or visit their village, but even when respondents needed to pay to send a message to the election victor using a hotline linked to LEGS-Africa. This effect is particularly pronounced among those receiving benchmarked information. However, in spite of voters updated beliefs persisting after the election and many voters proclaiming a willingness to hold politicians to account on the basis of the type of information provided, electoral accountability materializes to a lesser extent than non-electoral requests or initial vote intentions suggested. Specifically, self-reported and polling station voting behavior suggest that, on average, our leaflets ultimately did not affect vote choice. Nevertheless, heterogeneous 4

5 effects indicate that those caring most about information still rewarded the incumbent. Moreover, the treatments increased the vote shares of the best-performing incumbents, even though we only directly treated less than 2% of registered voters in the electoral precincts containing our villages. These electoral results suggest that election-oriented responses to the provision of information alter voting behavior without substantially changing voters beliefs. Exploring such channels, we document substantial information diffusion, voter coordination, and incumbent and challenger political responses, even to our small-scale intervention. Our detailed descriptions of these events suggest that these equilibrium responses may have played a critical role in mediating the effects of belief-based electoral accountability mechanisms. Most notably, incumbent parties appear to have effectively capitalized on revelations of good performance. Although deciphering the causal effects of such mediators is notoriously challenging (e.g. Bullock, Green and Ha 2010), our results nevertheless highlight the potential importance of such responses in determining voting behavior. Ultimately, our findings suggest that accountability failures are more likely to reflect complex political responses than cognitive constraints afflicting voters. We thus make several main contributions. First, the combination of behavioral outcomes with our endline and pre- and post-treatment baseline survey data enable us to unpack the mechanisms underpinning electoral accountability in unprecedented detail. We thus build on the framework expounded by Lieberman, Posner and Tsai (2014) by specifically designing an experiment to assess the key links in the accountability chain. Contrary to concerns that political accountability relies on highly sophisticated voters (Gomez and Wilson 2006), we show that voters with low levels of education and exposure to political news approximate Bayesian information processors. Rather than reflecting unstable beliefs, the imperfect mapping from initial intentions to voting behavior appears to reflect interactions precipitated by the dissemination of information. Second, our findings chime with larger recent interventions reporting significant political pushback (Arias et al. 2018; Banerjee et al. 2011; Bidwell, Casey and Glennerster 2016; Chauchard and Sircar forthcoming; Cruz, Keefer and Labonne 2017) and engagement with the information across 5

6 voters (Arias, Balán, Larreguy, Marshall and Querubín 2017). Moving beyond such studies, we describe in detail the nature and effectiveness of events that occur in between information dissemination and election day, including voter coordination and responses from local political operatives and village chiefs. Our findings suggest that political pushback mediates, rather than fully inhibits, the effects of information dissemination in a context where incumbent performance generally exceeded previous incumbents performance. Third, we find that performance information also influences non-electoral forms of political accountability. In contrast with the mixed extant findings regarding widely-studied electoral accountability, our original behavioral measures of voter requests from preferred candidates and winning incumbents suggest that changes in beliefs induced by information campaigns also affect non-electoral accountability-seeking political engagement. Although we do not examine the types or success of requests of politicians, our findings suggest that creating the sense that politicians are responsive could help hold politicians to account outside of electoral periods. Although she lacks behavioral measures, Gottlieb (2016) also finds that voters expectations increase upon learning that their representatives are performing comparatively well. Fourth, we further illuminate the types of information that facilitate political accountability. We provide the clearest evidence yet that benchmarking can support political accountability by helping voters to separate elements of an individual incumbent s performance from elements affecting all incumbents performance (e.g. Meyer and Vickers 1997). This finding may reflect our focus on a temporal benchmark, rather than the spatial benchmarks that previous studies have failed to document clear effects of (Arias, Larreguy, Marshall and Querubín 2017; Gottlieb 2016), although it remains possible that our findings are context-specific. Furthermore, we find that Senegalese voters prioritize politicians bringing projects and higher-value transfers to their department. Conversely, greater involvement in parliamentary activities is if anything punished by voters; this adds weight to Adida et al. s (2017) suggestion that Beninese voters seek to remove nationallyoriented politicians. However, we find little evidence that information about incumbent responsi- 6

7 bilities influences voter appraisals on its own, or that this substitutes or complements performance information. This suggests that any accountability-enhancing effects of civic education programs (e.g. Gottlieb 2016) are likely to operate through components of the program beyond information about incumbent responsibilities. 2 Incumbent performance information and political accountability The canonical selection model of electoral accountability reflects the interaction between agents (politicians) and their principals (voters), whereby performance information helps forward-looking voters to identify competent or policy-aligned politicians. In its simplest formulation, voters use incumbent performance information to update their beliefs about the extent to which the incumbent possesses such qualities, and is thus likely to perform well if re-elected (Fearon 1999). In essence, information enables voters to better identify, and then retain, high-quality incumbents. Voters may similarly be more willing to take costly action to engage beyond the ballot box with incumbents that they believe will be responsive to their interests. Although the core accountability insight remains, more complex models overlay other features such as incumbent signaling of quality through their actions in office (e.g. Ashworth and Bueno de Mesquita 2014; Rogoff 1990), or endogenous challenger actions while the incumbent is in office (e.g. Ashworth and Bueno de Mesquita 2008). By providing district-specific information that incumbents could not have anticipated being released just before elections, our design sidesteps these interesting dynamics to focus on whether information can induce voters to sanction and reward incumbents on the basis of their achievements in office. Moreover, by controlling the provision of information, we also abstract from the process through which information is supplied and consumed (see e.g. Besley and Prat 2006; Marshall 2017). The extent to which the canonical model captures electoral and off-election behavior rests upon 7

8 the validity of the model s assumptions regarding the presence of relevant information, voters capacity to process such information, and ultimately voters willingness to act on their updated beliefs about the incumbent s quality. To motivate the hypotheses underpinning our empirical analysis, the following sections describe the anatomy of political accountability by outlining when each of these necessary conditions for political accountability is expected to hold. 2.1 Relevance of novel information The first requirement for information to influence electoral accountability is that voters receive performance information that they perceive to be relevant. Voters are likely to update most from precise signals that convey information about key characteristics that define an incumbent s suitability for office. In this study, we focus on two features about which little is known that could enhance the effects of providing incumbent performance information: information about incumbent responsibilities, and temporal performance benchmarks. First, information about incumbent responsibilities may be required for voters to regard performance information as relevant and attribute outcomes to those responsible. Gottlieb (2016) finds that voters systematically underestimate government capacity in Mali, requiring civics training in order to better identify poorly-performing incumbents. Moreover, where decision-making responsibility is diffuse or unclear, voters may struggle to assign sanctions or rewards upon receiving information (e.g. Powell and Whitten 1993; Duch and Stevenson 2008). While responsibilities are often implicit when incumbent performance scorecards are provided, or provided alongside performance information, we explicitly separate between providing information about responsibilities and performance information by examining the interaction between the two, in order to understand what pieces of information are required to facilitate political accountability. Specifically, we hypothesize that providing information about incumbent duties should accentuate voter updating about incumbent quality, by helping voters to evaluate whether the incumbent has performed well given their responsibilities. 8

9 Second, performance benchmarks can facilitate greater belief updating. A relevant comparison against which performance can be gauged helps voters to filter out common factors that influence the performance of all agents in a given period or location (Meyer and Vickers 1997). Spatial benchmarks factor out common shocks by comparing agents in different contexts at the same time, while temporal benchmarks factors out time-invariant characteristics of the context in which the agent operates. In the context of political accountability, such benchmarks represent an increase in the precision of the signal pertaining to the current incumbent s qualities, and may also provide a credible signal about challengers. However, a key challenge is defining the relevant benchmark. In Mexico, Arias, Larreguy, Marshall and Querubín (2017) and Marshall (2017) find that cross-municipality comparisons do not influence voter beliefs and voting behavior. Gottlieb (2016) does find that greater performance relative to neighbors can raise voters expectations of politicians in Mali, although her design does not distinguish benchmarked from non-benchmarked information. We instead focus on a temporal comparison within the same electoral unit, comparing the current incumbent s performance to their predecessor. Such a benchmark is particularly appropriate in contexts like Senegal, where departments differ substantially. To the extent to abstracting from district-specific characteristics facilitates comparison, we expect favorably benchmarked performance indicators to update voter beliefs more than receiving the same information about only the current incumbent. From the perspective of our hypotheses, the performance benchmark also provides us with a basis for predicting the direction in which incumbent performance information will alter voters beliefs. 2.2 Internalization of relevant information After receiving relevant information, electoral accountability relies on voters comprehending that information and durably updating their beliefs about incumbent quality accordingly (at least until an election). In practice, this entails voters absorbing information that they read, hear, or observe. Political information is often complex, and unsophisticated voters may only exhibit a superficial 9

10 understanding of such information that prohibits them from meaningfully updating their beliefs (e.g. Alt, Lassen and Marshall 2016; Gomez and Wilson 2006; Weitz-Shapiro and Winters 2014). The durable updating of beliefs about incumbent quality is also not trivial over longer periods. For example, Zaller (1992) suggests that opinions reflect recently encountered propositions, rather than an internalized set of beliefs based on information encountered over sustained periods. Moreover, voters may reject novel information that challenges their pre-existing beliefs (Zaller 1992). Beyond the capacity to comprehend and durably update, a second dimension of retention is regarding novel information as sufficiently credible to be worth internalizing. From a Bayesian perspective, this means believing that the information emanates from a signal generating process that correlates with the unknown state about which voters seek to learn. This may not occur where the media is known (or believed) to be biased (e.g. Besley and Prat 2006; Gentzkow and Shapiro 2006), or where voters perceive a source as politically motivated (e.g. Alt, Lassen and Marshall 2016; Chiang and Knight 2011). Consequently, the source of incumbent performance information must be perceived to be sufficiently expert and trustworthy that voters are willing to use the source s information to update their beliefs. Even credible information is only likely to significantly alter behavior to the extent that it differs from voters posterior beliefs about the relative suitability of the incumbent for office. Bayesian voters should alter the position and precision of their posterior beliefs about incumbent suitability most in response to a credible signal when the signal is precise, it deviates from voters priors beliefs, and voters prior beliefs are relatively imprecise (e.g. Arias et al. 2018; Banerjee et al. 2011; Kendall, Nannicini and Trebbi 2014). 1 Importantly, as Arias et al. (2018) and Banerjee et al. (2011) note, the position of prior beliefs relative to the signal is likely to determine the direction in which any behavior changes as a consequence of information provision. 1 Although incumbent performance metrics most directly pertain to incumbents, voters may also update about challengers to the extent that they believe that such signals are correlated (e.g. Arias et al. 2018; Kendall, Nannicini and Trebbi 2014). 10

11 2.3 Acting on internalized beliefs Even if voters meaningfully update their beliefs on the basis of incumbent performance information, political accountability requires that they ultimately act on them. We focus on two forms of resulting action that could reflect such belief updating: voting to re-elect the incumbent and seeking to make requests of the incumbent (both before and after elections). The former captures the standard electoral accountability models, while the latter captures non-electoral accountabilityseeking political engagement that rests on the belief that the incumbent will be responsive to voter requests. Voters are most likely to act on their beliefs under several key conditions. First, voters must be able to connect their beliefs about the incumbent to their available actions. Gomez and Wilson (2006) argue that relatively unsophisticated voters may lack the cognitive capacity to translate their beliefs into political action. In developing contexts, voters may lack the civic skills to draw these connections without basic education (Gottlieb 2016; Weitz-Shapiro and Winters 2014). Second, voters must be willing to vote on the basis of incumbent competence or policy alignment. However, beliefs about competence or policy alignment are likely to be one among many factors that voters consider when deciding how to vote. If previous incumbent performance receives a low weight in voters calculus, then even large changes in beliefs may not influence voting behavior. For example, voters in India engage in limited sanctioning of suspicious financial disclosures because they care more about performance in office and are unwilling to sanction copartisans (Chauchard, Klašnja and Harish 2017). Similarly, voters may be unwilling to sacrifice clientelistic benefits associated with opposing inferior candidates (Adida et al. 2017), or unwilling to deviate from bloc voting agreements (Koter 2013). However, such weights may not be fixed: it is also possible that informational interventions, especially those outlining incumbent responsibilities or documenting extremely high or low levels of performance, could induce voters to upweight incumbent performance in office (Durante and Gutierrez 2014). 11

12 Third, the process of providing information could set in motion other (potentially countervailing) forces that override the influence of voter beliefs on vote choice. At the voter level, information dissemination campaigns particularly those that create public signals, e.g. through the media could induce tacit or explicit voter coordination around particular candidates (Chwe 2000; Morris and Shin 2002). Tacit coordination would entail voters altering their vote choice on the basis that they expect others also to do so. Explicit coordination might involve meetings among voters where collective agreement is reached on which candidate to vote for. While either notion of coordination may often reinforce the effect of voter updating, it could sometimes counteract it (Arias, Balán, Larreguy, Marshall and Querubín 2017). 2 At the political elite level, political parties may seek to counteract or adapt their electoral strategies in response to adverse performance revelations. Recent studies in India, Mexico, Sierra Leone, and the Philippines suggest that incumbents may respond to information campaigns by confiscating leaflets, threatening those disseminating information, increasing their campaign spending, or escalating vote buying campaigns (Arias et al. 2018; Banerjee et al. 2011; Bidwell, Casey and Glennerster 2016; Chauchard and Sircar forthcoming; Cruz, Keefer and Labonne 2017). To the extent that such equilibrium responses affect vote choices, changes in the individual beliefs of voters may not ultimately translate into accountability-seeking behaviors. 3 Accountability in Senegalese parliamentary elections Senegal represents an excellent location to examine electoral accountability. It is one of Africa s oldest and strongest democracies, and has generally experienced robust multi-party political competition since It is one of the few African nations that has never experienced a coup d état, and is known for its vibrant civil society and freedom of press and expression. Having seen two incumbents removed from office through competitive and fair democratic elections Abdou Diouf 2 Arias, Balán, Larreguy, Marshall and Querubín (2017) provide an example where public information dissemination led voters to update favorably about incumbents on the margin, but enabled voters in densely connected precinct to coordinate around challenger candidates still regarded as objectively superior. 12

13 in 2000, and Abdoulaye Wade in 2012 Senegal remains a model of peaceful democratic transition, and thus represents a developing context where voters might given credible and relevant information feasibly hold governments to account. 3.1 Senegal s Assemblée Nationale While Senegal enjoys well-functioning electoral institutions in some important respects, the country is characterized by hyper-presidentialism (Larreguy and Liu 2018; Thomas and Sissokho 2005). Senegal s Assemblée Nationale (Parliament) still plays a limited role in democratic representation, which has prevented full democratic consolidation (Beck 2012; Khagram, Fung and De Renzio 2013; O Donnell 1994). Focusing on legislators has the potential to inform how they can become more active and accountable to voters, and potentially promote socioeconomic development. Representatives to the Assemblée Nationale are elected by a mixed system, wherein 60% of deputies are selected by majoritarian voting at the department level, and the remaining 40% are selected by national-level proportional representation. All competing political coalitions form departmental lists for each of Senegal s 45 departments, as well as an overall national list. At the department level, the coalition that receives the most votes wins all the seats allotted to that particular department s majoritarian list. In 2017, there were 12 single and 33 multi-member departments. Proportional seats, by contrast, are allotted in proportion to a list s national vote share, after which elected deputies are assigned to departments. In the legislative elections of 2012, the president s coalition Benno Bokk Yakkar (BBY) won almost all department-level contests, taking 87 of the 90 departmental seats based on the majoritarian voting system. At the national level, the president s coalition won approximately half of the proportionally allocated seats. The present project focuses on deputies elected from departmental majoritarian lists, as these politicians have distinct constituencies and thus stronger local accountability linkages than deputies elected from national lists. The primary task of deputies in the Assemblée Nationale is amending and voting on laws 13

14 drafted by government ministries. In theory, deputies have the ability to initiate new laws themselves, though this is extremely rare in practice (Thomas and Sissokho 2005). As noted above, Senegal is characterized by hyper-presidentialism and consolidated executive power, and this influence shows in parliament. Very few laws are rejected by the Assemblée Nationale, and its role as a check on executive power is often called into question by civil society (as well as in our interviews with parliamentary deputies). Nonetheless, deputies can still play several important roles through their parliamentary duties. First, they can serve on one or several of the 11 technical parliamentary commissions. When a ministry proposes a law and it is brought to the Assemblée Nationale, it first goes to the technical commission that is paired with that particular ministry. These commissions meet in closed sessions and propose recommendations and amendments to the law, which are eventually debated in open plenary sessions. Leaders of commissions are considered influential in the amending of laws. The finance commission is considered to be particularly influential, as it plays a significant role in the deliberation over the national budget (Thomas and Sissokho 2005). Second, deputies can also submit written or oral questions to the executive government, to be answered by the relevant ministers in open sessions. Participating in these debates, as well as in ordinary plenary sessions, is one of the ways in which deputies can defend and publicize the interests of their constituents. Third, deputies are widely believed to be capable of influencing the allocation of local projects and government transfers. Deputies are not given any specific funds for local development projects in their home districts. Nevertheless, constituents often see local development as the primary responsibility of deputies. Accordingly, as many deputies and their administrative staff note in interviews, deputies are expected to engage in considerable effort to increase transfers to their districts for local development projects by lobbying government ministers. 14

15 3.2 Voter engagement with parliamentary deputies Voter turnout in Senegal generally lies around 60% for presidential elections, and reached 53% in the 2017 parliamentary elections. Confidence in the quality of democracy within Senegal trends upward as well. In the latest Afrobarometer round in Senegal, approximately 87% respondents stated that they consider Senegal to be a democracy, with 64% reporting that they are either fairly or very satisfied with the way democracy functions in Senegal. Nevertheless, voters often have limited access to information. In our rural sample, voters primarily rely on radio broadcasts; 82% and 44% of voters in our sample never obtain news via newspapers and television respectively. Senegalese parties are relatively strong, and are the source of much of the political information distributed to rural communities. This is particularly the case for parliamentary elections, for which available information on candidates is otherwise low. As the ballots during the voting process in legislative elections are grouped by party, it is common for citizens to be unfamiliar with the names of the candidate for whom they are voting, and defer instead to familiarity with the particular party or coalition. Only 35% of our rural sample in the present project knew the name of at least one of their parliamentary representatives. Citizen interactions with deputies in Senegal are rare, and there is significant variation in the amount of time deputies spend in their home districts, despite having a specific budget to make such visits. Citizen interactions with party officials and brokers, however, are much more common. Voters are generally pessimistic about the extent to which deputies listen to voters and respond to requests, while only 9% reported interacting directly with a representative in the last year. Considerations of potential clientelistic returns as a function of the home village of the candidate as well as their ethnicity and religion influence voter choices heavily in rural Senegal. The Sufi Muslim networks, to which the majority of Senegalese citizens belong, intimately shape the political process across the country and moderate access to political resources (Villalón 1995). Political parties attempt to influence rural vote choice by using religious leaders as well as village chiefs 15

16 as intermediaries (Gottlieb and Larreguy 2018; Koter 2013). Group meetings, rallies, and parties organized by parties and their intermediaries in rural villages are common, as is the distribution of gifts to encourage voting. 4 Research design To examine whether and how Senegalese voters hold elected deputies to account for their performance in office, we implemented an information dissemination campaign prior to the 2017 parliamentary elections held on Sunday 30th July. Our field experiment randomized several key components of the information s content across villages, and deployed a panel study that permitted us to track voter beliefs and (intended) actions before the treatments were delivered, immediately after their delivery, and a month after the election. We also implemented a follow-up survey among a subset of respondents four months later. This design enables us to trace in rare detail the process relating the receipt of (different types of) information about incumbent performance to political accountability. 4.1 Sample selection We conducted our study in the five departments shown in Figure 1: Fatick, Foundiougne, Kanel, Oussouye, and Ranérou Ferlo. These departments were selected because they satisfied five criteria that prior theoretical arguments suggest would increase the likelihood that performance information would help voters to hold politicians to account: (1) only a single incumbent was seeking reelection through the majoritarian vote (with the exception of Kanel where two were standing); (2) there were no incumbents from the proportional list (with the exception of Kanel), who face different career incentives and have different accountability links to their constituents; (3) the incumbent could be compared with previous incumbent(s), because no incumbent was seeking re-election for a second time and the department is not a newly-created administrative unit; and (4) given the 16

17 Figure 1: Distribution of departments across Senegal preceding criteria, the selected departments have the lowest number of deputies representing the department. Oussouye and Ranérou Ferlo had one incumbent deputy, although Oussouye had two in the previous legislature. Fatick and Foundiougne had two majoritarian deputies and no deputies from the proportional list. However, both had deputies from the proportional list in the previous legislature. Only Kanel, which has two majoritarian deputies, also has one deputy elected from the proportional list; in Kanel, one majoritarian and the one proportional list incumbent were standing for re-election, both on the majoritarian list. Within these five departments, we selected 450 rural villages for our sample. Starting from the 859 possible villages in these departments, we excluded all villages with fewer than 200 people and all villages with more than 4,000 people. Logistical concerns and access to newly-constructed schools further restricted the set of potential villages. 3 According to the 2013 Census, the popula- 3 Of logistical concerns, 19 villages were dropped because they were too expensive to reach, e.g. because they are located on islands. We had also set out to explore the interaction between information and education by also leveraging variation across cohorts in access to schooling originating from a secondary-school construction program started in 2002 (Larreguy and Liu 2018). As our pre-analysis plan explains in greater 17

18 tion of these villages represented 37% of the average department. Within each village, we aimed to survey nine registered voters aged (stratified by three age groupings) that grew up in each village. 4 The only further restrictions were that the respondents must have a cellphone number that they could be contacted on, that they were eligible to vote, and that they were born in the village or have lived there prior to the age of primary school enrollment (in Senegal, this is typically at 6 years of age). 4.2 Treatment conditions We disseminated information pertaining to legislator duties, as well as current and previous incumbent legislator performance prior to the 2017 election. Regarding legislator duties, we highlighted that legislators can: (1) serve on one or several of the 11 technical parliamentary commissions, where they can influence legislation and budgets in addition to taking on influential leadership conditions; (2) represent constituent interests in parliamentary debates; and (3) lobby government ministers to increase transfers to their districts for local specific projects. Regarding incumbent legislator performance, we focused on five measures of performance in office (over the full five-year electoral cycle, where possible) that relate to deputies primary duties: (1) the commissions they are members of; (2) positions of parliamentary leadership; (3) the number of parliamentary debates participated in; (4) the number of local projects budgeted for their department; and (5) the number and (inflation-adjusted) per capita per year value of ministry transfers received by the department, decomposed by type of transfer. 5 The latter two measures are detail, we excluded villages where the first post-2002 school was built between 2006 and 2010 to facilitate this design (Bhandari, Larreguy and Marshall 2017). We dropped this component of the analysis because access to new schools did not ultimately predict educational attainment among our survey respondents. 4 This restriction also arose from our intention to also examine interaction effects with access to newlyconstructed secondary schools across cohorts (Bhandari, Larreguy and Marshall 2017). 5 Annual transfer data from the government is only available from 2010 to To ensure comparability between current and previous incumbents we convert ministry transfers to a per year basis and adjust for inflation. We further adjust for population size using the 2013 Census. Where transfers affect multiple departments, transfers are distributed in accordance with the share of the 2013 population in each department. 18

19 Table 1: Factorial treatment conditions Performance information provided: None Incumbent Benchmark Duties information provided: None 75 villages [pure control] 75 villages 75 villages Duties 75 villages 75 villages 75 villages department-level variables, and thus do not vary across deputies in multi-member departments. 6 All deputy performance data was obtained from either the Assemblée Nationale or a government department. The relevance of the information on deputy duties and performance was validated by the head of legislative services at the Assemblée Nationale, the librarians and archivists at the Assemblée Nationale, and several active and former deputies. Based on the performance metrics just described, we used a factorial design to randomly assign villages to one of the six experimental conditions shown in Table 1. Treatment conditions vary along two dimensions of content, with the top-left element in the matrix constituting a pure control group where no intervention occurred. First, the duties dimension informs voters of the main functions that their parliamentary deputies can perform relating to the incumbent performance metrics described above. Second, the performance dimension varies two types of information relating to the/a incumbent representative s performance over the preceding five years. The incumbent information reports the five measures of current incumbentperformance described above. In addition to such information, the benchmark variant also provides the same information pertaining to the performance of the department s previous incumbent representative. To maximize the comparability of the previous incumbent to the current incumbent, voters only received performance information about one incumbent drawn from the 2007 majoritarian list. Figure 2 shows the distribution of the main performance metrics provided, where each dot represents a current incumbent-previous incumbent pairing. All dots above the 45 o line are cases where the current incumbent outperformed the previous incumbent. Although there are eight pair- 6 The information on the leaflet makes clear which departments have single or multiple deputies. 19

20 Current incumbent Fatick Committee memberships Kanel Kanel Fatick Foundiougne Ranérou Ferlo Previous incumbent Oussouye Current incumbent Leadership positions Kanel Kanel Ranérou Ferlo Fatick Foundiougne Foundiougne Previous incumbent Oussouye Debates participated in Local projects Current incumbent Kanel Fatick Kanel Oussouye Foundiougne Fatick Ranérou Ferlo Kanel Kanel Previous incumbent Current incumbent Foundiougne Kanel Ranérou Ferlo Oussouye Fatick Previous incumbent Current incumbent Number of transfers Kanel Ranérou Ferlo Foundiougne Oussouye Fatick Previous incumbent Current incumbent Transfer value per capita-year Kanel Ranérou Ferlo Foundiougne Fatick Previous incumbent Oussouye Figure 2: Distribution of treatment information across departments (45 degree line in gray) Note: Cases within departments where previous incumbents performed identically are not duplicated. ings across our five departments, some comparisons are exact duplicates. The figure shows that, in general, the current incumbent outperformed preceding incumbents within the same department, especially with respect to debates, projects, and transfers. 7 If we assume that voters prior expectations are broadly in line with previous incumbents performance, then we expect that our information will increase voters favorability towards current incumbents, on average, across departments. 7 The positive association between current and previous incumbent performance makes it difficult to separate the effect of information content across incumbent and benchmark performance treatments. 20

21 Figure 3: Example of duties + benchmark treatment in Oussouye Each information treatment was distributed to voters through a leaflet like the one shown in Figure 3. 8 The leaflets, which were created specifically for this project by a graphic artist, were designed in partnership with our partnering civil association, LEGS-Africa. At the top of each leaflet variant is the LEGS-Africa logo together with a statement that the organization is non-partisan, while contact information and a description of data sources was provided at the bottom. The particular example in Figure 3 from Oussouye depicts the duties and benchmark treatment variant containing all information. The three paragraphs below the LEGS-Africa logo were provided to all participants receiving a duties variant. The current incumbent performance information on the 8 All leaflet variants are shown in the Appendix. 21

22 left of the remainder of the leaflet was provided to participants receiving the incumbent variant, while the performance information on the left and right was provided to participants receiving the benchmarked incumbent performance information. To ensure factual accuracy and impartiality, our leaflets were pre-tested with the head of legislative services at the Assemblée Nationale, the librarian at the Assemblée Nationale, and several active and former deputies. We also piloted the leaflet with voters to ensure that the information was comprehensible. The leaflet was delivered in person to respondents as part of our baseline survey on behalf of LEGS-Africa. 9 Respondents where informed that we surveying several thousand voters across country. Our enumerators gave each voter a few minutes to read the leaflet and walked through the meaning of each component in the respondent s local language (since many rural Senegalese do not speak French). A key component of our training was to ensure that enumerators who were generally recent university graduates themselves understood and could clearly explain the leaflets content. 10 After receiving treatment, 82% of treated respondents reported that the leaflet came from an NGO, while only 19% believed that it originated from the current deputy or the national government. 4.3 Information provision randomization Leaflet treatment conditions were randomly assigned at the village level to mitigate potential within-village spillovers and John Henry effects. Specifically, we constructed 75 blocks, each containing six similar villages. Village similarity was determined by being in the same department (and thus facing the same parliamentary election), as well as closeness across 24 pre-treatment covariates (including latitude, longitude, prior education levels, population, socioeconomic development indicators, local language, and incumbent presidential vote share). 11 Within each block, 9 We are not aware of other similar campaigns occurring in our sample. 10 Depending on the department in which they worked, enumerators were extensively trained prior to implementation on translating the survey into Diola, Peulh, Serer, or Wolof. 11 We used the R package blocktools to assign blocks, department by department, based on a greedy algorithm using Mahalanobis distance. 22

23 we used complete randomization to one village to each of the experimental conditions. All nine respondents in a village received the same treatment. In departments where there are multiple incumbents or possible benchmarked comparisons, we used complete randomization to assign an incumbent-previous incumbent pair to each block. Consequently, while information content varies across blocks, all villages within a block received the same information. 4.4 Data collection To assess the mechanisms linking incumbent performance information to electoral accountability, we designed a two-wave panel survey and collected administrative electoral returns. The baseline survey of nine young registered voters per village was conducted in person between 4th July and 29th July, and our treatments were administered toward the end of this baseline survey, after baseline beliefs, behaviors, and intentions had been elicited. The shorter post-election survey was conducted by telephone around a month later, between 4th August and 26th August. We also collected polling station-level electoral returns, and mapped each village to its associated polling station based on the electoral register. This combination of data sources allows us to capture self-expressed beliefs and attitudes, voting intentions, and behavioral responses, and examine how treatment effects vary across time and by theoretically-relevant pre-treatment respondent characteristics. We next describe our main outcome variables, while pre-treatment covariates used to estimate heterogeneous effects are introduced as the analysis progresses Measurement of primary outcomes Our primary outcomes focus on voter beliefs about previous and future incumbent performance in office, willingness to hold incumbents to account, and the extent to which such willingness translates into action. We thus distinguish self-reported attitudinal or intended outcomes from behavioral outcomes. Crucially, we measure both types of outcome immediately after the treatment 23

24 was administered before the election, as well as after the election. Before treatment delivery, enumerators elicited baseline respondent characteristics, prior beliefs, and past and intended behavior. We focus on two main classes of attitudinal and intentional outcomes measured in our panel surveys. First, we measured voter beliefs about the performance of their current incumbent standing for re-election, previous incumbents, and challenger candidates on five-point scales. Specifically, this entailed eliciting responses to four questions: how well the incumbent has done overall since they were elected in 2012 ( incumbent overall performance ); how such performance compares to the previous incumbent ( relative performance (v. previous) ); how respondents think that current incumbent seeking re-election would do if re-elected ( prospective incumbent performance ); and how candidates from other parties would do ( prospective challenger performance ). 12 Furthermore, for each variable, we also elicited the strength of voters assessment on a ten-point scale ranging from not at all certain (1) to completely certain (10). 13 Each belief, and its associated certainty, was elicited in the baseline survey before and after any information treatments were delivered for both treated and control respondents. The first two questions were asked again at endline. 14 Summary statistics in the control group are reported at the foot of each column in results tables. Second, we also elicited self-reported (intended) vote choices. This entailed asking respondents whether they intended to vote (before and after treatment in the baseline survey) or actually did vote (at endline), and (if so) for which party or candidate. We code Vote incumbent as an indicator for respondents that stated they would or did vote for the incumbent candidate or the BBY coalition that all incumbents were part of. Around 96% of respondents registered an intention to vote, despite turnout in the polling stations containing our villages ultimately only reaching 60% on average. 15 Since 73% of respondents claimed to have actually voted at endline, we adopt a 12 Don t know responses are coded at the mid-level of the scale. 13 Don t know responses to scales eliciting voter beliefs are coded as the lowest level of certainty. 14 The latter two prospective questions made less sense after the election had occurred. 15 Although our sample of younger voters could vote at higher rates, intentions undoubtedly overstate actual behavior, even as evidenced by self-reported turnout after the election. 24

25 validated vote approach, in addition to examining purely self-reported votes. We register valid votes for the incumbent among the 53% of respondents that correctly recalled both that the ballot contained a picture of a candidate and a logo and the color of the ballot corresponding to the party that they reported voting for. At baseline, we also elicited certainty about intended vote choice on a ten-point scale. While these outcomes allow for a nuanced understanding of voter beliefs and actions, selfreported behaviors especially for voting outcomes could be subject to social desirability bias. Such biases could arise from a desire among respondents to report that they supported the winner after the event (the incumbent in each case), attempts to please the enumerator or respond in the right way to the leaflet provided, or a fear that incumbents would receive survey results (in spite of our efforts to explain that the survey was anonymous and conducted by a non-partisan NGO). Accordingly, we also directly measured behavioral outcomes. First, we obtained polling station-level electoral returns from electoral officials, which enables us to calculate turnout and the incumbent party vote share both as a share of turnout and registered voters at the polling station corresponding to each village in our sample. Since less than 2% of voters at a polling station were actually treated, on average, we expected these estimates to be noisy. Nevertheless, it is possible that votes change enough to manifest at the polling station level, especially if there is information diffusion or coordinated responses within villages. As discussed in detail below, the endline survey also asked about general equilibrium responses namely, the extent to which voters discussed the information with others, coordinated their responses, and reported party responses. We thus also examine effect heterogeneity by the proportion of registered voters at a polling station from villages in our sample. Second, we created several opportunities for voters to make costly requests of the incumbent. In the baseline survey, we offered respondents the opportunity to: request a poster from the party or candidate they intended to vote for, and/or other parties or candidates ( request incumbent poster ); request a visit from the party or candidate they intended to vote for, and/or other parties or candi- 25

26 dates ( request incumbent visit ); and sign up to be contacted to express their views to the party or candidate they intended to vote for, and/or other parties or candidates ( request incumbent conversation ). The first measure captures incumbent support, and thus alleviates concerns about social desirability bias that could afflict vote intentions. The latter two measures capture non-electoral accountability-seeking political engagement. In the endline survey after the election had occurred, we again offered respondents the opportunity to request a visit from and sign up to be contacted by the winning candidate, who was the incumbent in all instances. For each action, the voter s name and village would be shared with the party. After observing high willingness to engage in the preceding actions at baseline, at endline we also created a hotline where respondents could send text messages (costing around US$0.01) or leave voic s (costing around US$0.25) requesting to be contacted by the winning candidate. 16 We measure requests for the associated telephone number ( request hotline number ) and actual calls to this number from telephone numbers linked to the respondent ( called hotline ). Voters were informed that all requests and messages sent to the hotline would be submitted to candidates on behalf of LEGS-Africa. 17 Given the large number of outcomes which engender concerns about multiple comparisons and noise in specific variables we also pool across similar individual-level outcomes using indexes. Separately across baseline and endline panel waves, we created two indexes: self-reported incumbent support (i.e. all attitudinal and (intended) vote choice outcomes, except beliefs about challengers); and behavioral indicators of support for and requests from incumbents. We constructed two types of index in each case: the average across each standardized item (Kling, Liebman and Katz 2007) and the inverse covariance weighted (ICW) average across items (Anderson 2008). The former measure captures the mean across items, while the latter is preferred because it also accounts for correlation among items. Given that it is not obvious whether voters account 16 Phone credit in Senegal is expensive per minute used, and thus especially costly in poor rural areas. Text messages are comparably cheaper. 17 No deception was involved because each commitment was honored. This of course does not guarantee that politicians will respond to voter requests. 26

27 for such correlations, we also report robustness checks for the main results using the Kling, Liebman and Katz (2007) index in the Appendix. Both measures were standardized with respect to the control group, such that differences between groups reflect standard deviation changes in control group outcomes Compliance We were unable to conduct surveys in 7 of our 450 villages. In three cases we were refused entry, while the remaining cases reflected a lack of identity cards among villagers, inability to locate the village, heavy rain, and a village falling under judicial control. We did not start conducting surveys in any of these villages. Consequently, given that we conduced surveys in all villages and we did not allocate different treatment assignments to different times of day, our inability to conduct surveys is uncorrelated with treatment assignment Estimation In accordance with our pre-analysis plan, our fully-saturated treatment specification estimates the within-block average treatment effect of each component of the information leaflet using baseline regressions of the form: Y ivb = β 1 duties v + β 2 incumbent v + β 3 benchmark v + β 4 (incumbent v duties v ) +β 5 (benchmark v duties v ) + αy baseline ivb + η b + θ e + ε ivb, (1) where Y ivb is an outcome for individual i in village v in randomization block b, η b are randomization block fixed effects, and θ e are survey enumerator fixed effects (at baseline and, where relevant, also at endline). Wherever possible, the outcome s pre-treatment baseline counterpart Y baseline ivb 18 Of these seven villages, three were controls and four were benchmarks (one of which included information about duties). is 27

28 included as a control to increase efficiency. 19 For polling station-level outcomes, we substitute a p subscript for the iv subscripts. To weight each village equally, all survey-based regressions are weighted by the inverse of the number of respondents in the corresponding baseline or endline survey. 20 Standards errors are clustered by randomization block and significance tests are based on one-sided t tests for pre-specified hypotheses. To test some hypotheses underpinning the accountability process, we also estimate heterogeneous effects by the content of the information provided and other predetermined covariates such as voters prior beliefs. Taking the simpler case that pools across the duties treatment dimension, which we will do frequently in the analysis, we estimate specifications of the form: Y ivb = β 1 incumbent v + β 2 benchmark v + β 3 (incumbent v X iv ) +β 4 (benchmark v X iv ) + γx iv + αy baseline ivb + η b + θ e + ε ivb, (2) where X iv is a predetermined covariate. 4.6 Experimental validation checks Before turning to our main results, we estimate equation (1) to demonstrate that the randomized treatment assignments for the 443 villages where surveys were conducted are indeed orthogonal to predetermined covariates. Table A1 shows that 90 predetermined individual- and village-level covariates are well-balanced across treatment conditions at baseline: a two-sided joint test of the constraint that each treatment group is indistinguishable from the other was only rejected at the 10% level in 11 cases. Analysis of endline data is more complex, since estimates using endline data could be con- 19 Our pre-analysis plan proposed both first-differencing and a controlling for a lagged dependent variable. We favor the latter due to its efficiency benefits (McKenzie 2012) and because only baseline proxies are available for some outcomes. 20 This ensures that treatment is uncorrelated with blocks containing more observations, which would prevent estimation of average treatment effects under by-block effect heterogeneity. 28

29 founded by selective attrition in response to treatment. Fortunately, we were able to successfully re-interview 96% of the baseline sample. This remarkably high success rate for a telephone followup survey may have reflected the low frequency with which rural Senegalese voters (with access to mobile phones) have opportunities to express their views to survey teams, especially those that offered to pass on requests to politicians at baseline. 21 Unsurprisingly, given the low rates of attrition, Table A3 shows that there is no significant difference in attrition rates across treatment groups. Moreover, Table A2 shows that the balance we observed at baseline continues to hold within the endline response sample: for only 12 of 102 predetermined (baseline and endline) variables do we observe significant differences across treatment conditions. 5 Results To test the mechanisms linking, or failing to link, incumbent performance information and electoral and off-election accountability, we proceed by first examining immediate responses to the treatment before turning to post-election responses. 5.1 Immediate effects of information provision on beliefs, intentions, and requests We start by examining post-treatment voter beliefs, intentions, and behavior in the baseline survey. A key virtue of eliciting responses immediately after our leaflets were provided is that we are able to examine responses uncontaminated by the subsequent interactions with other voters or political actors that we discuss below. 21 In some cases, participants even called us back after an enumerator s initial called went unanswered. 29

30 5.1.1 Voters understand the information contained in the leaflets The first step linking information provision to accountability is that voters are able to comprehend the information provided. To assess this, we asked four multi-choice factual questions of treated and control respondents about the information contained in the leaflets. 22 Each question refers to a particular component of the information the number of commissions in the Assemblée Nationale (four choices), the lack of specific funds available to deputies for development projects in their department (true or false), the number of projects undertaken in the department initiated over the current incumbent s term (four options), and the number of debates that the previous incumbent participated over their term in office (four options). Although these questions could, in theory, have been answered by knowledgeable control respondents, the control group means at the foot of Table 2 indicate that few respondents provided the correct answer. 23 Perhaps unsurprisingly, given the written and verbal explanations, the results in Table 2 demonstrate that immediate comprehension was very high. With respect to the information about deputies duties, columns (1) and (2) indicate that receiving the duties-only information leaflet increased the proportion of respondents correctly identifying the number of parliamentary commissions from 5% to 84% and that deputies lack individual funds for department projects from 14% to 58%. This increase is similar when combined with incumbent or benchmarked performance information, while either type of performance information on their own increased the likelihood that the respondent attempted to answer the question. 24 Column (3) demonstrates that incumbent performance information (whether on its own or with a benchmark), but not the information about duties, increases the proportion of respondents that know the number of local projects received under the current incumbent from 7% to 77%. Similarly, column (4) shows that the benchmark leaflet is the only 22 After the leaflet was provided and explained, respondents were then asked about its provenance before we tested leaflet comprehension. 23 The average is likely below random guesswork because many respondents answered don t know. 24 Inspection of don t know responses suggests that a greater willingness to answer questions after receiving the leaflet primarily accounts for this increase. 30

31 Table 2: Effects of information treatments on leaflet comprehension (baseline survey) Correctly state......number of...deputies...number of...number of parliamentary lack own incumbent s previous commissions fund pots local incumbent s projects debates (1) (2) (3) (4) Duties 0.789*** 0.542*** (0.029) (0.042) (0.032) (0.024) Incumbent 0.205*** 0.118*** 0.699*** 0.052** (0.038) (0.040) (0.041) (0.027) Incumbent Duties *** ** 0.060* (0.045) (0.054) (0.046) (0.041) Benchmark 0.192*** 0.105*** 0.691*** 0.465*** (0.035) (0.036) (0.045) (0.049) Benchmark Duties *** *** (0.048) (0.054) (0.052) (0.054) Observations 3,999 3,999 3,999 3,999 Control outcome mean Control outcome std. dev Notes: Each specification is estimated using OLS, and includes randomization block and baseline enumerator fixed effects. All observations are inversely weighted by the baseline number of respondent surveyed in the village. Standard errors are clustered by randomization block. * denotes p < 0.1, ** denotes p < 0.05, *** denotes p < 0.01 from pre-specified one-sided t tests; + denotes p < 0.1, ++ denotes p < 0.05, +++ denotes p < 0.01 from two-sided tests when coefficients point in the opposite direction to the pre-specified hypothesis. one to substantially increase correct answers regarding the number of debates that the previous incumbent participated in, increasing the share of correct responses by around 0.5. Collectively, these results demonstrate that our respondents were able to immediately recall the information contained in the leaflet shown and explained to them. As in previous studies from across the world (e.g. Dunning et al. forthcoming; Lieberman, Posner and Tsai 2014), voters inability to comprehend the information provided does not seem to be a bottleneck in the political accountability process. 31

32 5.1.2 Voters update their beliefs in a Bayesian manner The preceding results indicate that voters understood the information that they received. However, given that information may not be perceived as credible or useful, this does not necessarily imply that it would alter their beliefs about the incumbent or their intention to vote for them. Moreover, there may be a subtle but important difference between regurgitating and internalizing new information. Although belief updating may not be strictly necessary for information provision to influence electoral accountability (since information provision could stimulate other actions without affecting beliefs), it is generally regarded as the primary mechanism. As columns (1)-(3) in Table 3 illustrate, voters did update their posterior beliefs on average after receiving the leaflet. If voters prior beliefs were not already centered on the truth, we expected that voters would positively update from our performance indicators on the basis that they exceed previous incumbents performance. Indeed, panel A shows that voters who received incumbent and benchmark performance information became substantially more positive about their incumbent deputy across all assessments of their suitability for office. Although column (7) shows that voters receiving the benchmark also updated somewhat positively about challengers, suggesting a perceived positive correlation across all types of politician (as in Arias et al. 2018), these changes are notably smaller than updating relating to the incumbent. The results thus suggest that voters regarded the performance information as credible, and accordingly favorably updated their posterior beliefs about the incumbent. 25 Conversely, information about deputies duties did not systematically affect voter evaluations whether on its own on in conjunction with performance indicators. This suggests that voters may not need additional information about incumbent duties to feel confident in using incumbent perfor- 25 There are several reasons to believe that these results do not simply reflect social desirability bias. First, subsequent behavioral measures show similar results. Second, it is hard to believe that those that learn most, based on the hetereogeneous effects below, are also most susceptible to social desirability bias. Third, Tables A13 and A14 show that the results are robust to removing any treated respondents that did not believe that the leaflets were delivered by an NGO. 32

33 Table 3: Average effects of information treatments on beliefs about incumbent performance, intention to vote for the incumbent, and requests from the incumbent (baseline survey) Self-reported outcomes Behavioral outcomes Incumbent Relative Prospective Incumbent Index Index Prospective Request Request Request Index Index overall performance incumbent vote (average) (ICW) challenger incumbent incumbent incumbent (average) (ICW) performance (v. previous) performance performance poster visit conversation (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12) Panel A: All information treatment conditions Duties * (0.063) (0.052) (0.049) (0.013) (0.042) (0.036) (0.047) (0.019) (0.020) (0.018) (0.038) (0.039) Incumbent 0.362*** 0.221*** 0.239*** 0.030** 0.292*** 0.235*** (0.076) (0.059) (0.069) (0.015) (0.060) (0.052) (0.052) (0.018) (0.020) (0.019) (0.038) (0.037) Incumbent Duties ** * 0.061*** 0.046* 0.113** 0.111** (0.093) (0.076) (0.085) (0.023) (0.074) (0.067) (0.073) (0.029) (0.029) (0.029) (0.060) (0.061) Benchmark 0.457*** 0.353*** 0.376*** 0.037*** 0.413*** 0.343*** 0.074** (0.074) (0.068) (0.063) (0.017) (0.061) (0.055) (0.042) (0.022) (0.021) (0.021) (0.045) (0.045) Benchmark Duties * * 0.084* 0.087* (0.088) (0.082) (0.080) (0.021) (0.066) (0.061) (0.066) (0.027) (0.026) (0.027) (0.055) (0.056) Panel B: Pooling duties treatment conditions Incumbent 0.356*** 0.285*** 0.262*** 0.031*** 0.318*** 0.263*** 0.051* 0.031*** 0.039*** 0.029** 0.076*** 0.075*** (0.055) (0.048) (0.048) (0.011) (0.045) (0.038) (0.038) (0.015) (0.017) (0.017) (0.034) (0.034) Benchmark 0.432*** 0.375*** 0.328*** 0.035*** 0.393*** 0.326*** 0.112*** 0.029** * 0.051* 0.054* (0.055) (0.057) (0.044) (0.012) (0.049) (0.044) (0.033) (0.015) (0.016) (0.015) (0.033) (0.033) Null: Incumbent Benchmark (p value) Observations 3,942 3,932 3,928 3,999 3,999 3,891 3,888 3,998 3,999 3,998 3,999 3,997 Outcome range {1,...,5} {1,...,5} {1,...,5} {0,1} [-2.4,2.2] [-2.3,2.0 {1,...,5}] {0,1} {0,1} {0,1} [-1.6,0.7] [-1.6,0.7] Control outcome mean Control outcome std. dev Notes: Each specification is estimated using OLS, and includes randomization block and baseline enumerator fixed effects. All specifications include a lagged dependent variable as a control; in columns (8)-(12), pre-treatment incumbent vote is used as a proxy. All observations are inversely weighted by the baseline number of respondent surveyed in the village. Standard errors are clustered by randomization block. * denotes p < 0.1, ** denotes p < 0.05, *** denotes p < 0.01 from pre-specified one-sided t tests; + denotes p < 0.1, ++ denotes p < 0.05, +++ denotes p < 0.01 from two-sided tests when coefficients point in the opposite direction to the pre-specified hypothesis. 33

34 mance indicators to evaluate them. The low importance of information about duties is a consistent pattern throughout this study. We thus focus primarily on the comparison between benchmarked and non-benchmarked incumbent performance information (as in panel B). Pooling the control and duty conditions, panel B further demonstrates that voters process within-department benchmarks in a rational manner. In line with theoretical expectations, based on the current incumbent almost always outperforming the previous incumbent (see Figure 2), the F tests at the foot of column (1)-(3) in panel B consistently reject the one-sided null hypothesis that the benchmarked information is no more likely to increase incumbent support. In contrast with extant findings that spatial benchmarks are relatively unimportant (e.g. Arias, Larreguy, Marshall and Querubín 2017), we find that temporal benchmarks can meaningfully influence beliefs by providing a relevant yardstick for appraising incumbent performance. Furthermore, information provision increases the precision of voters beliefs. Consistent with voters possessing relatively imprecise prior beliefs, Appendix Table A4 shows that the leaflets increased voters reported certainty in their beliefs about the incumbent s current and future performance by around half a point or nearly 0.2 standard deviations on our 10-point scale. The benchmark was particularly important in increasing belief precision. Finally, the interactions between information provision, information content, and voter prior beliefs are consistent with Bayesian updating. We illustrate this by examining how the effects of our treatments on posterior beliefs vary with the performance indicators provided and pre-treatment measures of prior beliefs in Table 4. Each interacting variable is standardized within the control group. First, panel A shows that voters updated significantly more positively about the incumbent when the leaflet indicated higher performance (captured by an ICW scale averaging across our six reported performance indicators). 26 Aggregated across measures, the scales in columns (5) and (6) show that this was true of both the incumbent only and benchmarked information, although the level effect of the latter is greater. Panel B reports similar results when reported performance is 26 The results are robust to using the standardized average scale. 34

35 Table 4: Heterogeneous effects of information treatments on beliefs about incumbent performance, intention to vote for the incumbent, and requests from the incumbent, by leaflet content, priors beliefs, and importance of performance information for vote choice (baseline survey) Self-reported outcomes Behavioral outcomes Incumbent Relative Prospective Incumbent Index Index Prospective Request Request Request Index Index overall performance incumbent vote (average) (ICW) challenger incumbent incumbent incumbent (average) (ICW) performance (v. previous) performance performance poster visit conversation (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12) Panel A: Heterogeneity by (standardized) reported performance level Incumbent 0.367*** 0.297*** 0.269*** 0.031*** 0.325*** 0.270*** 0.055* 0.033*** 0.041*** 0.030** 0.078*** 0.078*** (0.048) (0.041) (0.044) (0.011) (0.039) (0.036) (0.038) (0.015) (0.017) (0.017) (0.034) (0.034) Incumbent Overall performance (ICW) 0.244*** 0.198*** 0.185*** 0.022*** 0.186*** 0.135*** 0.051** (0.045) (0.034) (0.035) (0.007) (0.033) (0.028) (0.028) (0.011) (0.015) (0.018) (0.028) (0.027) Benchmark 0.440*** 0.381*** 0.332*** 0.036*** 0.399*** 0.333*** 0.110*** 0.030*** * 0.053* 0.056** (0.051) (0.057) (0.042) (0.011) (0.047) (0.042) (0.034) (0.015) (0.016) (0.015) (0.033) (0.033) Benchmark Overall performance (ICW) 0.220*** 0.149*** 0.154*** 0.034*** 0.170*** 0.145*** (0.039) (0.047) (0.036) (0.008) (0.038) (0.034) (0.026) (0.013) (0.016) (0.015) (0.029) (0.028) Panel B: Heterogeneity by (standardized) relevance-weighted reported performance level Incumbent 0.389*** 0.320*** 0.299*** 0.038*** 0.352*** 0.297*** 0.053* 0.041*** 0.048*** 0.041*** 0.098*** 0.098*** (0.050) (0.043) (0.043) (0.012) (0.040) (0.037) (0.038) (0.017) (0.018) (0.019) (0.038) (0.037) Incumbent Relevant performance (ICW) 0.267*** 0.251*** 0.213*** 0.032*** 0.231*** 0.187*** (0.052) (0.047) (0.046) (0.014) (0.043) (0.041) (0.041) (0.018) (0.020) (0.020) (0.040) (0.040) Benchmark 0.474*** 0.400*** 0.348*** 0.041*** 0.419*** 0.350*** 0.116*** 0.038*** ** 0.069** 0.073** (0.054) (0.060) (0.043) (0.013) (0.048) (0.044) (0.036) (0.017) (0.019) (0.017) (0.037) (0.037) Benchmark Relevant performance (ICW) 0.194*** 0.145*** 0.131*** 0.031*** 0.158*** 0.138*** (0.048) (0.045) (0.040) (0.015) (0.041) (0.040) (0.040) (0.020) (0.023) (0.022) (0.047) (0.046) Panel C: Heterogeneity by (standardized) local and national reported performance level Incumbent 0.391*** 0.309*** 0.286*** 0.034*** 0.343*** 0.288*** *** 0.047*** 0.032** 0.086*** 0.085*** (0.050) (0.043) (0.047) (0.012) (0.040) (0.036) (0.039) (0.016) (0.018) (0.018) (0.036) (0.036) Incumbent National performance (ICW) * (0.070) (0.059) (0.048) (0.010) (0.048) (0.037) (0.042) (0.017) (0.017) (0.017) (0.032) (0.032) Incumbent Local performance (ICW) 0.295*** 0.220*** 0.246*** 0.023* 0.256*** 0.217*** (0.066) (0.057) (0.057) (0.015) (0.052) (0.047) (0.045) (0.020) (0.022) (0.021) (0.043) (0.043) Benchmark 0.450*** 0.400*** 0.345*** 0.040*** 0.414*** 0.349*** 0.102*** 0.034*** 0.023* 0.028** 0.064** 0.067** (0.052) (0.050) (0.040) (0.012) (0.043) (0.039) (0.034) (0.016) (0.017) (0.016) (0.034) (0.034) Benchmark National performance (ICW) (0.072) (0.100) (0.055) (0.010) (0.069) (0.061) (0.035) (0.012) (0.020) (0.017) (0.033) (0.031) Benchmark Local performance (ICW) 0.206*** 0.256*** 0.214*** 0.031*** 0.247*** 0.221*** Observations 3,942 3,932 3,928 3,999 3,999 3,891 3,888 3,998 3,999 3,998 3,999 3,997 Outcome range {1,...,5} {1,...,5} {1,...,5} {0,1} [-2.4,2.2] [-2.3,2.0 {1,...,5}] {0,1} {0,1} {0,1} [-1.6,0.7] [-1.6,0.7] Control outcome mean Control outcome std. dev Overall performance (ICW) range [-2.93,1.27] [-2.93,1.27] [-2.93,1.27] [-2.93,1.27] [-2.93,1.27] [-2.93,1.27] [-2.93,1.27] [-2.93,1.27] [-2.93,1.27] [-2.93,1.27] [-2.93,1.27] [-2.93,1.27] Relevant performance (ICW) range [-2.94,2.03] [-2.94,2.03] [-2.94,2.03] [-2.94,2.03] [-2.94,2.03] [-2.94,2.03] [-2.94,2.03] [-2.94,2.03] [-2.94,2.03] [-2.94,2.03] [-2.94,2.03] [-2.94,2.03] National performance (ICW) range [-1.63,2.03] [-1.63,2.03] [-1.63,2.03] [-1.63,2.03] [-1.63,2.03] [-1.63,2.03] [-1.63,2.03] [-1.63,2.03] [-1.63,2.03] [-1.63,2.03] [-1.63,2.03] [-1.63,2.03] Local performance (ICW) range [-1.10,1.21] [-1.10,1.21] [-1.10,1.21] [-1.10,1.21] [-1.10,1.21] [-1.10,1.21] [-1.10,1.21] [-1.10,1.21] [-1.10,1.21] [-1.10,1.21] [-1.10,1.21] [-1.10,1.21] Notes: Each specification is estimated using OLS, and includes randomization block and baseline enumerator fixed effects. All specifications include a lagged dependent variable as a control; in columns (8)-(12), pre-treatment incumbent vote is used as a proxy. Panel B also includes the interaction between incumbent and benchmark treatments and an indicator for respondents that did not regard local or national performance as one of the top three most important factors in determining their vote choice. All observations are inversely weighted by the baseline number of respondent surveyed in the village. Standard errors are clustered by randomization block. * denotes p < 0.1, ** denotes p < 0.05, *** denotes p < 0.01 from pre-specified one-sided t tests; + denotes p < 0.1, ++ denotes p < 0.05, +++ denotes p < 0.01 from two-sided tests when coefficients point in the opposite direction to the pre-specified hypothesis. (Continued...) 35

36 Table 5 (continued): Heterogeneous effects of information treatments on beliefs about incumbent performance, intention to vote for the incumbent, and requests from the incumbent, by leaflet content, priors beliefs, and importance of performance information for vote choice (baseline survey) Self-reported outcomes Behavioral outcomes Incumbent Relative Prospective Incumbent Index Index Prospective Request Request Request Index Index overall performance incumbent vote (average) (ICW) challenger incumbent incumbent incumbent (average) (ICW) performance (v. previous) performance performance poster visit conversation (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12) Panel D: Heterogeneity by (standardized) prior belief level Incumbent 0.355*** 0.292*** 0.264*** 0.032*** 0.311*** 0.264*** 0.057* 0.032*** 0.041*** 0.031** 0.080*** 0.079*** (0.055) (0.047) (0.049) (0.011) (0.046) (0.040) (0.038) (0.014) (0.016) (0.017) (0.033) (0.033) Incumbent Prior index (ICW) *** *** *** *** *** *** *** ** * ** *** (0.041) (0.031) (0.037) (0.012) (0.034) (0.033) (0.036) (0.014) (0.017) (0.017) (0.033) (0.032) Benchmark 0.435*** 0.378*** 0.331*** 0.038*** 0.390*** 0.328*** 0.117*** 0.029** * 0.054** 0.056** (0.055) (0.058) (0.045) (0.012) (0.051) (0.045) (0.034) (0.015) (0.016) (0.015) (0.032) (0.032) Benchmark Prior index (ICW) *** ** * *** *** *** * (0.039) (0.042) (0.037) (0.011) (0.036) (0.034) (0.035) (0.014) (0.016) (0.016) (0.033) (0.033) Panel E: Heterogeneity by (standardized) prior belief precision Incumbent 0.362*** 0.297*** 0.280*** 0.039*** 0.332*** 0.280*** 0.064* 0.026** 0.034*** 0.033** 0.071*** 0.070*** (0.055) (0.049) (0.049) (0.011) (0.046) (0.039) (0.040) (0.015) (0.017) (0.017) (0.033) (0.033) Incumbent Prior precision index (ICW) *** ** *** * (0.037) (0.030) (0.040) (0.012) (0.030) (0.027) (0.026) (0.017) (0.015) (0.016) (0.031) (0.032) Benchmark 0.440*** 0.388*** 0.352*** 0.044*** 0.412*** 0.345*** 0.123*** 0.028** ** 0.056** 0.058** (0.056) (0.059) (0.045) (0.012) (0.051) (0.046) (0.034) (0.016) (0.017) (0.015) (0.033) (0.033) Benchmark Prior precision index (ICW) ** ** ** *** *** ** * * Panel F: Heterogeneity by (standardized) importance of performance in determining vote choice Incumbent 0.355*** 0.284*** 0.261*** 0.031*** 0.317*** 0.263*** 0.051* 0.032*** 0.039*** 0.029** 0.076*** 0.076*** (0.055) (0.047) (0.048) (0.011) (0.044) (0.038) (0.038) (0.015) (0.017) (0.017) (0.034) (0.034) Incumbent Performance most important *** * 0.019* 0.040* 0.039* (0.036) (0.035) (0.031) (0.009) (0.026) (0.024) (0.027) (0.014) (0.013) (0.013) (0.027) (0.027) Benchmark 0.431*** 0.373*** 0.328*** 0.036*** 0.393*** 0.326*** 0.111*** 0.030** * 0.052* 0.055* (0.054) (0.057) (0.044) (0.012) (0.049) (0.044) (0.033) (0.015) (0.016) (0.015) (0.033) (0.033) Benchmark Performance most important * *** 0.024** 0.019* 0.055*** 0.058*** (0.029) (0.028) (0.031) (0.010) (0.023) (0.021) (0.025) (0.013) (0.014) (0.012) (0.026) (0.026) Panel G: Heterogeneity by (standardized) preference for locally-oriented deputies Incumbent 0.370*** 0.192*** 0.198*** *** 0.180*** * * 0.088* (0.083) (0.083) (0.070) (0.026) (0.066) (0.060) (0.048) (0.027) (0.033) (0.035) (0.066) (0.064) Incumbent Prefer locally-oriented deputies * *** ** (0.075) (0.083) (0.074) (0.029) (0.066) (0.065) (0.061) (0.033) (0.035) (0.037) (0.071) (0.071) Benchmark 0.502*** 0.286*** 0.302*** *** 0.291*** 0.068* 0.040* (0.090) (0.094) (0.070) (0.027) (0.078) (0.074) (0.046) (0.030) (0.031) (0.029) (0.061) (0.061) Benchmark Prefer locally-oriented deputies * (0.081) (0.078) (0.073) (0.029) (0.068) (0.067) (0.056) (0.034) (0.033) (0.032) (0.067) (0.067) Observations 3,908 3,906 3,905 3,922 3,922 3,891 3,847 3,921 3,922 3,921 3,922 3,920 Outcome range {1,...,5} {1,...,5} {1,...,5} {0,1} [-2.4,2.2] [-2.3,2.0 {1,...,5}] {0,1} {0,1} {0,1} [-1.6,0.7] [-1.6,0.7] Control outcome mean Control outcome std. dev Prior index (ICW) range [-2.40,2.12] [-2.40,2.12] [-2.40,2.12] [-2.40,2.12] [-2.40,2.12] [-2.40,2.12] [-2.40,2.12] [-2.40,2.12] [-2.40,2.12] [-2.40,2.12] [-2.40,2.12] [-2.40,2.12] Prior precision (ICW) range [-3.44,1.23] [-3.44,1.23] [-3.44,1.23] [-3.44,1.23] [-3.44,1.23] [-3.44,1.23] [-3.44,1.23] [-3.44,1.23] [-3.44,1.23] [-3.44,1.23] [-3.44,1.23] [-3.44,1.23] Performance most important range {0,1} {0,1} {0,1} {0,1} {0,1} {0,1} {0,1} {0,1} {0,1} {0,1} {0,1} {0,1} Prefer locally-oriented deputies range {0,1} {0,1} {0,1} {0,1} {0,1} {0,1} {0,1} {0,1} {0,1} {0,1} {0,1} {0,1} Notes: Each specification is estimated using OLS, and includes randomization block and baseline enumerator fixed effects. All specifications include a lagged dependent variable as a control; in columns (8)-(12), pre-treatment incumbent vote is used as a proxy. All observations are inversely weighted by the baseline number of respondent surveyed in the village. Standard errors are clustered by randomization block. * denotes p < 0.1, ** denotes p < 0.05, *** denotes p < 0.01 from pre-specified one-sided t tests; + denotes p < 0.1, ++ denotes p < 0.05, +++ denotes p < 0.01 from two-sided tests when coefficients point in the opposite direction to the pre-specified hypothesis. 36

37 weighted by the factors voters regard as most important. 27 Furthermore, panel C shows that voters increased favorability toward the incumbent almost entirely reflects the projects and transfers components of the performance index, suggesting that voters are more concerned about local projects than national processes. As in Adida et al. (2017), appearing to work on national or parliamentary issues if anything sends a negative signal. 28 Second, panel B similarly shows that voters updated most favorably about the incumbent when they had the least favorable prior beliefs. Third, panel C shows that favorable updating was lower among respondents with more precise prior beliefs. Together, these findings paint a clear picture of sophisticated updating, and suggest that beliefs may have changed enough to affect vote choices Performance information alters vote intentions We next examine the extent to which changes in beliefs translate into intended vote choice. Column (4) of Table 3 indicates that higher appraisals of the incumbent are reflected in around a 3 percentage point increase in the probability of reporting an intention to vote for the incumbent. 29 We again find no evidence to suggest that information about incumbent duties moderates the effects of performance information, but some tentative (rather than statistically significant) evidence to suggest that benchmarked information induces greater incumbent support. This increase in incumbent vote intention also varies with several key predictions of the accountability logic. First, the heterogeneous effects in column (4) of panels A-E of Table 4 show that changes in vote intention mirror changes in voter beliefs, such that those updating most positively are also most likely to express an intention to vote for the incumbent. Second, panel F further demonstrates that the 54% of respondents who (before treatment) stated that incumbent 27 In practice, this entailed constructing a relevance-weighted performance index where local and national performance are only included if the respondent regarded either as one of the top three most important factors in determining their vote choice. 28 These coefficients are statistically different under two-tailed tests in some cases. 29 Voters certainty about voting for the incumbent choice was not significantly altered by performance information. 37

38 performance on metrics like those provided are the most important determinant of their vote choice were also significantly more likely to shift their vote intention in favor of the incumbent. Similar results hold in panel G among voters that expressed a preference for a locally-oriented, as opposed to nationally-oriented, politician in a pre-treatment vignette. Exactly as predicted, increased intention to vote for the incumbent is driven by those induced to update most positively on issues they regard as important Performance information increases requests from incumbents The change in self-reported vote intention is generally reinforced by our behavioral outcomes capturing incumbent support and willingness to make forward-looking requests from the incumbent. Specifically, columns (8)-(12) of Table 4 show that those respondents induced to support the incumbent by performance information also become significantly more willing make requests of the incumbents whether for posters or contact. Panel B indicates that the benchmarked information does not differentially influence such requests. To the extent that requests can serve as a behavioral proxy for baseline vote choice, these findings suggest that changes in vote intentions do not simply reflect social desirability bias. Requests represent the one area where information about deputies duties complements performance indicators. Columns (8)-(12) of panel A in Table 4 indicate that learning that the incumbent is generally better than expected primarily translates into requests when voters are aware of what the incumbent could do. These estimates suggest that an understanding of what politicians can do could help voters to make requests from relatively effective politicians. However, as Table 7 below shows, this does not persist at endline. Broadly in line with vote intentions, Table 4 shows that increased incumbent requests also reflect incumbent performance levels, prior beliefs, and the importance of performance to voters. While the interactions with such beliefs are generally weaker, there remains clear evidence that those caring most about performance become significantly more likely to make requests upon 38

39 learning that the incumbent performed better than expected Summary The preceding findings indicate that credible performance information, at least on issues that matter to voters, have the potential to play a key role in electoral and non-electoral accountability. Contrary to concerns that voters lack the sophistication to hold politicians to account, relatively uneducated rural voters comprehend incumbent performance leaflets and correspondingly update their beliefs in a Bayesian manner. Furthermore, this translates into an intention to hold the incumbent to account at the ballot box, and a willingness to make somewhat costly requests from incumbents. In this particular context, information favored the incumbent. However, while such responses demonstrate the potential effects of information dissemination campaigns, the key question is whether immediate changes in voter intentions are ultimately acted upon at the ballot box. 5.2 Longer-term effects on beliefs, voting behavior, and requests To understand electoral behavior several weeks after information was provided and requests of newly re-elected incumbents, we turn to the endline survey and polling station electoral returns Voters correctly recalled treatment information after the election While voters clearly changed their beliefs and vote intentions immediately, such changes could dissipate and thus not affect voting behavior. The endline examines this possibility by asking respondents if voters recall receiving our leaflet, and if so what type of information the leaflet contained. To guard against enumerators replicating baseline answers, no enumerator was permitted to re-interview a respondent that they interviewed at baseline and no enumerator knew the treatment status of their endline survey respondents. The results in Table 5 indicate high leaflet recall around a month after our leaflet was disseminated. Column (1) shows that virtually all (around 98%) treated respondents correctly recall 39

40 Table 5: Effects of information treatments on leaflet recall (endline survey) Received Received Received Received leaflet duties incumbent previous information information incumbent information (1) (2) (3) (4) Duties 0.921*** 0.941*** 0.054*** 0.030*** (0.013) (0.013) (0.014) (0.009) Incumbent 0.918*** 0.072*** 0.938*** 0.022*** (0.014) (0.016) (0.011) (0.008) Incumbent Duties *** *** ** (0.018) (0.021) (0.019) (0.015) Benchmark 0.921*** 0.043*** 0.963*** 0.949*** (0.012) (0.011) (0.008) (0.010) Benchmark Duties *** *** *** *** (0.015) (0.019) (0.014) (0.015) Observations 3,875 3,875 3,875 3,875 Outcome range {0,1} {0,1} {0,1} {0,1} Control outcome mean Control outcome std. dev Notes: Each specification is estimated using OLS, and includes randomization block fixed effects and baseline and endline enumerator fixed effects. All observations are inversely weighted by the endline number of respondent surveyed in the village. Standard errors are clustered by randomization block. * denotes p < 0.1, ** denotes p < 0.05, *** denotes p < 0.01 from pre-specified one-sided t tests; + denotes p < 0.1, ++ denotes p < 0.05, +++ denotes p < 0.01 from two-sided tests when coefficients point in the opposite direction to the pre-specified hypothesis. receiving the LEGS-Africa leaflet, while only 7% of control respondents incorrectly recall receiving the leaflet. In comparison with other contexts, these large numbers may reflect the lack of leaflets being distributed in the remote areas in which we worked. Moreover, columns (2)-(4) demonstrate that almost as many respondents correctly remember the differentiating features of the leaflet s content. Clearly, voter recall of the leaflet is remarkably high, and thus does not represent an impediment to electoral accountability in a context. 40

41 5.2.2 The relative importance of incumbent legislative performance in making vote choices did not change While voter appraisals of their incumbents were immediately altered, the provision of incumbent performance information could also change the relative importance attached to incumbent legislative performance in making voting decisions. Any changes in voting behavior might then reflect changes in salience, rather than changes in beliefs. To examine such salience effects, we asked voters akin to at baseline before treatment what were the three most factors in determining their vote choice in the 2017 election. The results in Table 6 indicate that our leaflets did not increase the weight attached to incumbent performance in determining vote choices. Columns (1)-(3) show that our treatments did not change the probability of ranking performance in the top three most important factors, while columns (4)- (6) similarly report no change in incumbent performance being the most important. This suggests that voters utility functions did not significantly change after information dissemination Beliefs about incumbent performance persist after the election While the salience of incumbent performance on the dimension we provide information about did not change, beliefs about incumbent performance did persist. Reinforcing the findings regarding information recollection, columns (1) and (2) of Table 7 show that a month after the leaflet was provided voters receiving performance information continue to register higher performance rating of the incumbent, and believe that the incumbent performed better than previous incumbents. A comparison with the estimates in Table 3 suggests some decay around a half of the immediate effect of the information provision. The tests at the foot of panel B indicate that this was especially the case for the benchmark information. Since the endline occurred after the election, there is good reason to believe that treated voters were more likely to believe that the incumbent performed well while in office at the time of the election. Moreover, Appendix Table A5 similarly shows that 41

42 Table 6: Effects of information treatments on self-reported importance of performance in making vote choice (endline survey) Performance is one of Performance is the the three most important most important factors in vote choice factor in vote choice (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) Duties (0.014) (0.022) Incumbent * * (0.017) (0.013) (0.021) (0.016) Incumbent Duties (0.024) (0.033) Benchmark (0.014) (0.011) (0.025) (0.019) Benchmark Duties (0.019) (0.035) Performance (0.010) (0.014) Null: Incumbent Benchmark (p value) Observations 3,876 3,876 3,876 3,876 3,876 3,876 Outcome range {0,1} {0,1} {0,1} {0,1} {0,1} {0,1} Control outcome mean Control outcome std. dev Notes: Each specification is estimated using OLS, and includes randomization block fixed effects and baseline and endline enumerator fixed effects and a lagged dependent variable. All observations are inversely weighted by the endline number of respondent surveyed in the village. Standard errors are clustered by randomization block. * denotes p < 0.1, ** denotes p < 0.05, *** denotes p < 0.01 from two-sided t tests. treated voters continue to express greater certainty about their beliefs. The heterogeneous effects in Table 8 generally point in the same direction, but suggest that the exact details of incumbent performance start to become fuzzier over time. The estimates in panel C, however, provide clear evidence though that voters continue to favorably update about incumbents with higher levels of local performance. Again, national-level performance may even be sanctioned. 42

43 Table 7: Average effects of information treatments on beliefs about incumbent performance, reported vote for the incumbent, and requests from the incumbent (endline survey) Self-reported outcomes Behavioral outcomes Incumbent Relative Incumbent Incumbent Index Index Request Request Request Called Index Index overall performance vote vote (average) (ICW) incumbent incumbent hotline hotline (average) (ICW) performance (v. previous) (valid) visit conversation number (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12) Panel A: All information treatment conditions Duties * 0.088* (0.060) (0.063) (0.036) (0.036) (0.071) (0.075) (0.007) (0.021) (0.010) (0.025) (0.061) (0.062) Incumbent 0.153*** 0.118*** ** (0.048) (0.044) (0.034) (0.032) (0.051) (0.056) (0.007) (0.024) (0.012) (0.020) (0.058) (0.059) Incumbent Duties (0.072) (0.079) (0.049) (0.049) (0.085) (0.092) (0.010) (0.025) (0.016) (0.031) (0.083) (0.086) Benchmark 0.242*** 0.262*** *** 0.217*** 0.017*** *** 0.165*** 0.181*** (0.055) (0.049) (0.037) (0.037) (0.061) (0.065) (0.005) (0.037) (0.011) (0.022) (0.052) (0.048) Benchmark Duties (0.077) (0.074) (0.052) (0.050) (0.088) (0.095) (0.008) (0.181) (0.014) (0.034) (0.098) (0.071) Panel B: Pooling duties treatment conditions Incumbent 0.163*** 0.149*** *** 0.118*** (0.037) (0.037) (0.023) (0.023) (0.042) (0.043) (0.005) (0.021) (0.008) (0.015) (0.041) (0.042) Benchmark 0.251*** 0.252*** *** 0.231*** 0.009** * 0.112*** 0.097*** (0.038) (0.037) (0.024) (0.024) (0.041) (0.043) (0.005) (0.058) (0.007) (0.015) (0.044) (0.041) Null: Incumbent Benchmark (p value) Observations 3,834 3,825 3,781 3,781 3,876 3,708 3,876 3,876 3,876 3,876 3,876 3,876 Outcome range {1,...,5} {1,...,5} {0,1} {0,1} [-3.4,2.0] [-2.8,1.9 {0,1}] {0,1} {0,1} {0,1} [-7.3,1.5] [-7.8,1.6] Control outcome mean Control outcome std. dev Notes: Each specification is estimated using OLS, and includes randomization block fixed effects, baseline and endline enumerator fixed effects, and a control for the corresponding pretreatment outcomes. All observations are inversely weighted by the endline number of respondent surveyed in the village. Standard errors are clustered by randomization block. * denotes p < 0.1, ** denotes p < 0.05, *** denotes p < 0.01 from pre-specified one-sided t tests; + denotes p < 0.1, ++ denotes p < 0.05, +++ denotes p < 0.01 from two-sided tests when coefficients point in the opposite direction to the pre-specified hypothesis. 43

44 Table 8: Heterogeneous effects of information treatments on beliefs about incumbent performance, reported vote for the incumbent, and requests from the incumbent, by leaflet content, priors beliefs, and importance of performance information for vote choice (endline survey) Self-reported outcomes Behavioral outcomes Incumbent Relative Incumbent Incumbent Index Index Request Request Request Called Index Index overall performance vote vote (average) (ICW) incumbent incumbent hotline hotline (average) (ICW) performance (v. previous) (valid) visit conversation number (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12) Panel A: Heterogeneity by (standardized) reported performance level Incumbent 0.166*** 0.153*** *** 0.124*** (0.038) (0.037) (0.022) (0.023) (0.041) (0.042) (0.005) (0.021) (0.007) (0.014) (0.041) (0.041) Incumbent Overall performance (ICW) *** * (0.030) (0.036) (0.028) (0.028) (0.041) (0.047) (0.005) (0.009) (0.006) (0.017) (0.034) (0.035) Benchmark 0.254*** 0.255*** *** 0.236*** 0.009** * 0.111*** 0.097*** (0.037) (0.036) (0.023) (0.024) (0.039) (0.041) (0.005) (0.058) (0.007) (0.014) (0.044) (0.041) Benchmark Overall performance (ICW) (0.033) (0.037) (0.031) (0.033) (0.044) (0.051) (0.005) (0.016) (0.008) (0.019) (0.046) (0.044) Panel B: Heterogeneity by (standardized) relevance-weighted reported performance level Incumbent 0.186*** 0.143*** *** 0.117*** * (0.045) (0.043) (0.025) (0.025) (0.050) (0.051) (0.006) (0.017) (0.008) (0.014) (0.046) (0.047) Incumbent Relevant performance (ICW) 0.070* 0.065* *** 0.029** 0.093*** 0.081** (0.045) (0.048) (0.029) (0.029) (0.055) (0.059) (0.005) (0.018) (0.008) (0.016) (0.044) (0.044) Benchmark 0.256*** 0.247*** *** 0.244*** *** 0.117*** 0.096*** (0.042) (0.040) (0.027) (0.027) (0.047) (0.050) (0.006) (0.069) (0.008) (0.015) (0.051) (0.047) Benchmark Relevant performance (ICW) ** (0.042) (0.041) (0.032) (0.031) (0.054) (0.059) (0.007) (0.023) (0.008) (0.016) (0.048) (0.050) Panel C: Heterogeneity by (standardized) local and national reported performance level Incumbent 0.161*** 0.162*** *** 0.128*** (0.039) (0.037) (0.024) (0.024) (0.043) (0.044) (0.005) (0.017) (0.008) (0.014) (0.040) (0.040) Incumbent National performance (ICW) * (0.043) (0.039) (0.026) (0.029) (0.050) (0.056) (0.010) (0.019) (0.009) (0.016) (0.054) (0.057) Incumbent Local performance (ICW) 0.107*** 0.138*** *** 0.108*** 0.015** * *** 0.120*** (0.044) (0.041) (0.026) (0.029) (0.048) (0.051) (0.008) (0.020) (0.010) (0.016) (0.053) (0.054) Benchmark 0.240*** 0.260*** *** 0.235*** 0.010*** * 0.124*** 0.110*** (0.037) (0.034) (0.024) (0.024) (0.039) (0.041) (0.005) (0.057) (0.007) (0.015) (0.042) (0.039) Benchmark National performance (ICW) (0.044) (0.046) (0.041) (0.042) (0.054) (0.065) (0.011) (0.062) (0.008) (0.016) (0.073) (0.075) Benchmark Local performance (ICW) *** ** 0.089* 0.014* *** *** 0.149*** (0.045) (0.043) (0.034) (0.034) (0.049) (0.056) (0.009) (0.025) (0.007) (0.015) (0.057) (0.061) Observations 3,834 3,825 3,781 3,781 3,876 3,708 3,876 3,876 3,876 3,876 3,876 3,876 Outcome range {1,...,5} {1,...,5} {0,1} {0,1} [-3.4,2.0] [-2.8,1.9 {0,1}] {0,1} {0,1} {0,1} [-7.3,1.5] [-7.8,1.6] Control outcome mean Control outcome std. dev Overall performance (ICW) range [-2.93,1.27] [-2.93,1.27] [-2.93,1.27] [-2.93,1.27] [-2.93,1.27] [-2.93,1.27] [-2.93,1.27] [-2.93,1.27] [-2.93,1.27] [-2.93,1.27] [-2.93,1.27] [-2.93,1.27] Relevant performance (ICW) range [-2.94,2.03] [-2.94,2.03] [-2.94,2.03] [-2.94,2.03] [-2.94,2.03] [-2.94,2.03] [-2.94,2.03] [-2.94,2.03] [-2.94,2.03] [-2.94,2.03] [-2.94,2.03] [-2.94,2.03] National performance (ICW) range [-1.63,2.03] [-1.63,2.03] [-1.63,2.03] [-1.63,2.03] [-1.63,2.03] [-1.63,2.03] [-1.63,2.03] [-1.63,2.03] [-1.63,2.03] [-1.63,2.03] [-1.63,2.03] [-1.63,2.03] Local performance (ICW) range [-1.10,1.21] [-1.10,1.21] [-1.10,1.21] [-1.10,1.21] [-1.10,1.21] [-1.10,1.21] [-1.10,1.21] [-1.10,1.21] [-1.10,1.21] [-1.10,1.21] [-1.10,1.21] [-1.10,1.21] Notes: Each specification is estimated using OLS, and includes randomization block fixed effects, baseline and endline enumerator fixed effects, and a control for the corresponding pretreatment outcome. All observations are inversely weighted by the endline number of respondent surveyed in the village. Standard errors are clustered by randomization block. * denotes p < 0.1, ** denotes p < 0.05, *** denotes p < 0.01 from pre-specified one-sided t tests; + denotes p < 0.1, ++ denotes p < 0.05, +++ denotes p < 0.01 from two-sided tests when coefficients point in the opposite direction to the pre-specified hypothesis. (Continued...) 44

45 Table 8 (continued): Heterogeneous effects of information treatments on beliefs about incumbent performance, reported vote for the incumbent, and requests from the incumbent, by leaflet content, priors beliefs, and importance of performance information for vote choice (endline survey) Self-reported outcomes Behavioral outcomes Incumbent Relative Incumbent Incumbent Index Index Request Request Request Called Index Index overall performance vote vote (average) (ICW) incumbent incumbent hotline hotline (average) (ICW) performance (v. previous) (valid) visit conversation number (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12) Panel D: Heterogeneity by (standardized) prior belief level Incumbent 0.167*** 0.157*** *** 0.119*** (0.037) (0.036) (0.023) (0.023) (0.042) (0.043) (0.005) (0.023) (0.008) (0.015) (0.042) (0.042) Incumbent Prior index (ICW) (0.040) (0.039) (0.019) (0.018) (0.041) (0.042) (0.006) (0.026) (0.006) (0.015) (0.045) (0.046) Benchmark 0.247*** 0.256*** *** 0.231*** 0.009** * 0.113*** 0.100*** (0.039) (0.038) (0.024) (0.025) (0.041) (0.043) (0.005) (0.055) (0.007) (0.016) (0.045) (0.042) Benchmark Prior index (ICW) (0.043) (0.039) (0.019) (0.020) (0.041) (0.041) (0.005) (0.011) (0.007) (0.015) (0.042) (0.042) Panel E: Heterogeneity by (standardized) prior belief precision Incumbent 0.165*** 0.162*** *** 0.123*** (0.037) (0.037) (0.024) (0.024) (0.042) (0.044) (0.005) (0.006) (0.008) (0.016) (0.042) (0.043) Incumbent Prior precision index (ICW) (0.040) (0.038) (0.024) (0.024) (0.046) (0.050) (0.006) (0.007) (0.008) (0.014) (0.046) (0.048) Benchmark 0.250*** 0.276*** *** 0.243*** 0.009** *** 0.099*** (0.038) (0.037) (0.024) (0.024) (0.041) (0.043) (0.005) (0.005) (0.008) (0.016) (0.043) (0.043) Benchmark Prior precision index (ICW) * (0.036) (0.037) (0.022) (0.023) (0.041) (0.043) (0.006) (0.006) (0.008) (0.019) (0.051) (0.052) Panel F: Heterogeneity by (standardized) importance of performance in determining vote choice Incumbent 0.162*** 0.149*** *** 0.118*** (0.038) (0.037) (0.023) (0.023) (0.042) (0.043) (0.005) (0.020) (0.008) (0.015) (0.042) (0.042) Incumbent Performance most important (0.037) (0.031) (0.021) (0.021) (0.035) (0.038) (0.005) (0.013) (0.007) (0.013) (0.041) (0.041) Benchmark 0.251*** 0.252*** *** 0.230*** 0.009** * 0.111*** 0.097*** (0.038) (0.037) (0.024) (0.024) (0.041) (0.043) (0.005) (0.058) (0.007) (0.015) (0.044) (0.041) Benchmark Performance most important * 0.032** ** (0.037) (0.035) (0.018) (0.018) (0.035) (0.036) (0.004) (0.060) (0.008) (0.016) (0.046) (0.039) Panel G: Heterogeneity by (standardized) preference for locally-oriented deputies Incumbent 0.103* 0.106* *** ** *** (0.070) (0.071) (0.038) (0.042) (0.079) (0.084) (0.007) (0.022) (0.015) (0.026) (0.073) (0.072) Incumbent Prefer locally-oriented deputies *** 0.081** 0.131* 0.173** 0.026*** * (0.080) (0.079) (0.041) (0.047) (0.083) (0.091) (0.009) (0.038) (0.018) (0.029) (0.091) (0.091) Benchmark 0.194*** 0.233*** *** 0.129* ** 0.158* (0.061) (0.061) (0.041) (0.044) (0.070) (0.079) (0.005) (0.301) (0.015) (0.028) (0.112) (0.062) Benchmark Prefer locally-oriented deputies * 0.075* * 0.017*** (0.074) (0.075) (0.045) (0.047) (0.083) (0.092) (0.007) (0.339) (0.016) (0.033) (0.128) (0.073) Observations 3,834 3,825 3,781 3,781 3,876 3,708 3,876 3,876 3,876 3,876 3,876 3,876 Outcome range {1,...,5} {1,...,5} {0,1} {0,1} [-3.4,2.0] [-2.8,1.9 {0,1}] {0,1} {0,1} {0,1} [-7.3,1.5] [-7.8,1.6] Control outcome mean Control outcome std. dev Prior index (ICW) range [-2.40,2.12] [-2.40,2.12] [-2.40,2.12] [-2.40,2.12] [-2.40,2.12] [-2.40,2.12] [-2.40,2.12] [-2.40,2.12] [-2.40,2.12] [-2.40,2.12] [-2.40,2.12] [-2.40,2.12] Prior precision (ICW) range [-3.44,1.23] [-3.44,1.23] [-3.44,1.23] [-3.44,1.23] [-3.44,1.23] [-3.44,1.23] [-3.44,1.23] [-3.44,1.23] [-3.44,1.23] [-3.44,1.23] [-3.44,1.23] [-3.44,1.23] Performance most important range {0,1} {0,1} {0,1} {0,1} {0,1} {0,1} {0,1} {0,1} {0,1} {0,1} {0,1} {0,1} Prefer locally-oriented deputies range {0,1} {0,1} {0,1} {0,1} {0,1} {0,1} {0,1} {0,1} {0,1} {0,1} {0,1} {0,1} Notes: Each specification is estimated using OLS, and includes randomization block fixed effects, baseline and endline enumerator fixed effects, and a control for the corresponding pretreatment outcome. All observations are inversely weighted by the endline number of respondent surveyed in the village. Standard errors are clustered by randomization block. * denotes p < 0.1, ** denotes p < 0.05, *** denotes p < 0.01 from pre-specified one-sided t tests; + denotes p < 0.1, ++ denotes p < 0.05, +++ denotes p < 0.01 from two-sided tests when coefficients point in the opposite direction to the pre-specified hypothesis. 45

46 5.2.4 Performance information influences vote choices We next examine whether the vote intentions registered at baseline were ultimately acted upon. Given the persistence of beliefs favorable to the incumbents, there is reason to believe that this key component of the electoral accountability dynamic could hold. To test this, we first study self-reported voting for the incumbent before analyzing polling station-level returns. Our individual-level endline survey data provide initially weak evidence that providing performance information translates into holding incumbents to account at the ballot box. On average, columns (3) and (4) in panels A and B of Table 7 do not show significant increases in incumbent voting whether entirely self-reported or after adjusting for our approach to validated voting. Nevertheless, consistent with voter beliefs, the tests in panel B tentatively suggest a larger effect of the benchmark treatment in comparison with the incumbent-only performance information. The heterogeneous effects in Table 8 also provide mixed evidence: while the leaflet s performance content and voters prior beliefs did not influence the self-reported voting of the average respondent, panels F and G show that support for the incumbent was greater among treated respondents receiving the benchmarked indicators that also regard performance information as the most important factor in determining their vote choice or preferred locally-oriented deputies. Appendix Table A9 shows that turnout was not affected. However, our focus on voters aged does not necessarily capture the response of a broader electorate that may also receive the information provided. Differences could arise because younger voters are less likely to vote or respond to information differently. To better approximate polling station-level electoral outcomes, we subset our sample to the set of voters that turned out in the 2012 election a strong predictor of validated turnout in Table 9 suggests that the selfreported vote choices of such voters was more likely to reflect the information provided. While not statistically significant in this smaller sample, columns (1) and (5) show that voters initial increase 30 This eliminates the first-time voters aged 23 and below that were not eligible to vote in

47 in support for the incumbent persists and if anything increases in magnitude by election day. More definitively, column (8) shows that valid votes in favor of the incumbent significantly increase with local performance. The points estimates in columns (2)-(3) and (6)-(7) also suggest persisting from vote intentions to actual vote choices. To the extent that such behavior also proxies for the behavior of older voters that might learn of the information contained in our leaflet, it is possible that the incumbent vote share could change at the polling station level. We now turn to the polling station returns. Such administrative data is a more reliable measure of voting behavior, particularly given the over-reporting of incumbent voting noted above. 31 However, the results may be noisy because only nine voters received a leaflet in each treated village. A key factor is thus the extent to which information provision precipitated other actions, such as information dissemination and coordination among voters; below, we show that such activities were substantial. To account for these dynamics, we primarily focus on heterogeneous treatment effects reflecting the share of the polling station electorate that is registered in the village in our sample ( share ). 32 In our sample, the average village comprises 65% of registered voters at its polling station. The polling station returns suggest significant increases in incumbent voting where the incumbent performed best. The first column for each outcome in Table 10 reports that our intervention did not affect turnout or incumbent party vote share on average, while the second column finds little evidence of greater average effects where the village represents a greater share of the polling station electorate. However, the third, fourth, and fifth columns provide significant evidence of the anticipated heterogeneous effects: as the positive triple interactions show, the marginal effect of the incumbent and especially benchmark treatments on the incumbent s vote share increases with reported primarily local performance when the village represents a large fraction of voters at the 31 For four several villages, we were unable to obtain complete electoral returns. 32 Unreported analyses indicate similar results when examining the actual number of respondents directly treated, and various multipliers of this number. These interactions were not pre-specified, but follow naturally from the discussion of noisy polling station data in our pre-analysis plan. 47

48 Table 9: Effects of information treatments on reported vote for the incumbent among those that turned out in 2012 (baseline and endline survey) Incumbent vote (intention) Incumbent vote (valid) (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) Incumbent (0.018) (0.018) (0.019) (0.019) (0.036) (0.035) (0.036) (0.039) Benchmark (0.017) (0.017) (0.017) (0.018) (0.032) (0.032) (0.034) (0.031) Incumbent Overall performance (ICW) 0.021* (0.012) (0.044) Benchmark Overall performance (ICW) 0.027* (0.014) (0.033) Incumbent Relevant performance (ICW) 0.040* (0.020) (0.049) Benchmark Relevant performance (ICW) (0.022) (0.049) Incumbent National performance (ICW) * ** (0.018) (0.044) Incumbent Local performance (ICW) ** (0.025) (0.047) Benchmark National performance (ICW) (0.021) (0.050) Benchmark Local performance (ICW) ** (0.024) (0.046) Observations 1,528 1,528 1,528 1,528 1,435 1,435 1,435 1,435 Outcome range {0,1} {0,1} {0,1} {0,1} {0,1} {0,1} {0,1} {0,1} Control outcome mean Control outcome std. dev Interaction mean Interaction std. dev Second interaction mean Second interaction std. dev Notes: Each specification is estimated using OLS, and includes randomization block and baseline enumerator fixed effects and pre-treatment incumbent vote intention. All observations are inversely weighted by the baseline number of respondent surveyed in the village. Standard errors are clustered by randomization block. * denotes p < 0.1, ** denotes p < 0.05, *** denotes p < 0.01 from two-sided t tests. 48

49 Table 10: Heterogeneous effects of information treatments on polling station-level turnout and incumbent vote share, by village contribution to polling station and leaflet content (polling station data) Turnout Incumbent vote share Incumbent vote share (proportion of turnout) (proportion of registered voters) (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12) (13) (14) (15) Incumbent (0.011) (0.021) (0.023) (0.023) (0.020) (0.020) (0.039) (0.044) (0.036) (0.034) (0.016) (0.032) (0.034) (0.029) (0.026) Benchmark (0.015) (0.030) (0.036) (0.031) (0.030) (0.018) (0.044) (0.049) (0.044) (0.040) (0.014) (0.035) (0.038) (0.033) (0.031) Incumbent Share (0.031) (0.037) (0.032) (0.030) (0.058) (0.060) (0.056) (0.054) (0.044) (0.046) (0.043) (0.041) Benchmark Share (0.034) (0.040) (0.036) (0.032) (0.067) (0.072) (0.069) (0.065) (0.049) (0.052) (0.048) (0.045) Incumbent Overall performance (ICW) (0.016) (0.034) (0.025) Incumbent Share Overall performance (ICW) (0.054) (0.065) (0.045) Benchmark Overall performance (ICW) (0.026) (0.028) (0.023) Benchmark Share Overall performance (ICW) *** (0.061) (0.049) (0.036) Incumbent Relevant performance (ICW) (0.022) (0.044) (0.032) Incumbent Share Relevant performance (ICW) 0.056** (0.033) (0.063) (0.048) Benchmark Relevant performance (ICW) (0.026) (0.048) (0.037) Benchmark Share Relevant performance (ICW) 0.061** *** (0.033) (0.067) (0.049) Incumbent National performance (ICW) (0.017) (0.063) (0.035) Incumbent Share National performance (ICW) (0.026) (0.101) (0.059) Benchmark National performance (ICW) (0.038) (0.059) (0.037) Benchmark Share National performance (ICW) (0.046) (0.086) (0.052) Incumbent Local performance (ICW) (0.025) (0.058) (0.035) Incumbent Share Local performance (ICW) * (0.040) (0.087) (0.053) Benchmark Local performance (ICW) (0.033) (0.056) (0.036) Benchmark Share Local performance (ICW) 0.081** * (0.044) (0.078) (0.049) Observations Outcome range [.15,1.5] [.15,1.5] [.15,1.5] [.15,1.5] [.15,1.5] [.06,.96] [.06,.96] [.06,.96] [.06,.96] [.06,.96] [.02,.66] [.02,.66] [.02,.66] [.02,.66] [.02,.66] Control outcome mean Control outcome std. dev Notes: Each specification is estimated using OLS, and includes randomization block and baseline enumerator fixed effects and a lagged dependent variable. Observations are not weighted. Standard errors are clustered by randomization block. * denotes p < 0.1, ** denotes p < 0.05, *** denotes p < 0.01 from pre-specified one-sided t tests; + denotes p < 0.1, ++ denotes p < 0.05, +++ denotes p < 0.01 from two-sided tests when coefficients point in the opposite direction to the pre-specified hypothesis. 49

50 polling station. 33 The estimates imply that a standard deviation increase in performance increases the incumbent s vote share by around five percentage points for a village with an above-median share of the polling station electorate. This magnitude of this effect far exceeds the number of survey respondents (the average polling station has over 500 registered voters), suggesting that our leaflets induced a response among voters beyond our panel participants. In sum, these findings indicate that while performance information did not affect incumbent vote share on average, villages did ultimately reward better-performing incumbents at the polls Performance information increases requests from incumbents While electoral accountability weakens between the point of information provision (and intended vote choice) and the election itself (actual vote choice), requests from incumbents represent a somewhat different form of accountability-seeking behavior. The requests that we study are less likely to be the source of election campaign interactions, and thus less subject to interference between survey waves. We evaluate the extent to which such accountability dissipates a month after treatment by examining requests from the newly-elected deputy (always the incumbent). Unlike with voting behavior, treated voters continue to make more requests from incumbents shown to be more responsive on average. Columns (7)-(10) of Table 7 indicate that the benchmark information, in particular, generally increased requests from the government. Aggregated as an index, columns (11) and (12) of panel B report a 0.1 standard deviation increase in such behaviors. Since almost all voters sought a visit or conversation with the incumbent, calling our hotline is perhaps the most useful measure. Despite the financial costs involved, column (10) shows that the benchmark treatment increased attempts to engage with the newly-reelected incumbent by 2.5 percentage points, or around a quarter of the control group mean. The heterogeneous effects in Table 8 further show that these increases in hotline usage were greatest in departments where the 33 Subsetting the sample to villages with above-median shares of the polling station electorate provides similar results. 50

51 incumbent was performing best, particularly on local issues. The heterogeneous effects do not imply that voters actively disengage with poorly-performing politicians they just do not engage more than the control. Moreover, at least in the case of calling the hotline, the benchmark treatment had its largest effects on respondents with imprecise prior expectations and who care most about incumbent performance on the dimensions that information was provided about Summary These findings suggest that information provision has lasting effects: voters remember the leaflet, to a significant degree retain their updated beliefs about incumbents, and continue to make requests of incumbents that they learn performed well. Each feature indicates that information could help hold politicians accountable on the basis of their performance. Given that posterior beliefs and vote intentions also suggested that an electoral shift toward the incumbent would occur, the most notable difference from voters immediate responses in the baseline survey is the relatively small change in voting behavior on average in our sample. This echoes findings from Mexico and the Philippines, where information treatments produced lower average effects than expected (Arias et al. 2018; Cruz, Keefer and Labonne 2017). Nevertheless, rather than voters neglecting the information entirely, polling station returns suggest that the bestperforming incumbents were still rewarded. This raises several key questions: given that treated voters continue to perceive the incumbent more favorably, what altered their average pre-election voting intentions? And why do the heterogeneous effects at the aggregate level imply changes in voting behavior that are greater than if all treated voters switched from a challenger to the incumbent? Since respondent requests persisted into the endline survey, we focus on political responses relating to the election itself. 51

52 5.3 General equilibrium influences on voting behavior We examine three potential explanations for the relatively low average effect, but non-negligible heterogeneous effects, of providing incumbent performance information at the polling station level: village-level social interactions, cross-village spillovers, and politician responses. By also affecting the behavior of other voters, each account could plausibly explain the polling station level outcomes and the disjuncture on the level between immediate vote intentions and ultimate vote choices. The unusually rich data we collected from followup surveys to address the first and last potential mediating factors more broadly highlights the importance of election-based responses to information dissemination campaigns Voter social networks within villages As suggested in Arias, Balán, Larreguy, Marshall and Querubín (2017), social networks could amplify or alter the effect of information provision by respectively diffusing information or inducing voter coordination on a preferred (set of) candidate(s) within villages. Both rely on our treated voters interacting with fellow villagers, either by disseminating the leaflet s information or inducing others to change their voting behavior, although only the former requires that novel information actually be transferred. We use our endline survey to consider whether these explanations could account for our findings by exploring the extent to which the leaflets generated social interactions. The endline survey provides clear evidence of substantial voter engagement with the leaflets within their village. Column (1) of Table 11 demonstrates that nearly 40% of treated respondents discussed the leaflet with others. This suggests that significant information diffusion occurred, which may account for the fact that directly providing leaflets to less than 2% of registered voters still resulted in some discernible polling station-level effects. Furthermore, column (5) indicates that more than half of these people also coordinated their vote as a consequence of their discussion. In both cases, these activities were slightly higher following a benchmarked leaflet. Of those 52

53 Table 11: Effects of information treatments on voter interactions with the leaflets (endline survey) Discussed leaflet with others Discussion led to vote coordination Coordinated vote on incumbent (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12) Incumbent 0.373*** 0.371*** 0.374*** 0.337*** 0.239*** 0.239*** 0.239*** 0.215*** 0.211*** 0.210*** 0.211*** 0.192*** (0.016) (0.017) (0.016) (0.019) (0.020) (0.020) (0.019) (0.019) (0.017) (0.017) (0.017) (0.016) Benchmark 0.391*** 0.390*** 0.392*** 0.358*** 0.260*** 0.261*** 0.262*** 0.241*** 0.233*** 0.234*** 0.235*** 0.216*** (0.019) (0.020) (0.019) (0.021) (0.019) (0.019) (0.019) (0.020) (0.017) (0.017) (0.017) (0.018) Incumbent Overall performance (ICW) (0.015) (0.021) (0.017) Benchmark Overall performance (ICW) (0.019) (0.021) (0.020) Incumbent Relevant performance (ICW) (0.024) (0.025) (0.021) Benchmark Relevant performance (ICW) (0.027) (0.022) (0.021) Incumbent National performance (ICW) (0.031) (0.025) (0.019) Benchmark National performance (ICW) (0.027) (0.029) (0.029) Incumbent Local performance (ICW) (0.029) (0.023) (0.020) Benchmark Local performance (ICW) (0.028) (0.026) (0.025) Null: Incumbent Benchmark (p value) Observations 3,875 3,875 3,875 3,875 3,874 3,874 3,874 3,874 3,874 3,874 3,874 3,874 Outcome range {0,1} {0,1} {0,1} {0,1} {0,1} {0,1} {0,1} {0,1} {0,1} {0,1} {0,1} {0,1} Control outcome mean Control outcome std. dev Notes: Each specification is estimated using OLS, and includes randomization block fixed effects and baseline and endline enumerator fixed effects. All observations are inversely weighted by the baseline number of respondent surveyed in the village. Standard errors are clustered by randomization block. * denotes p < 0.1, ** denotes p < 0.05, *** denotes p < 0.01 from pre-specified one-sided t tests; + denotes p < 0.1, ++ denotes p < 0.05, +++ denotes p < 0.01 from two-sided tests when coefficients point in the opposite direction to the pre-specified hypothesis. 53

54 that coordinated, more than half reported coordinating with six or more people; 10% reported coordinating with the entire village. Importantly, columns (2)-(4) and (6)-(8) suggest that such social interactions were orthogonal to the content of the leaflet, even when focusing on the local information that interested respondents most. Such social interaction around the leaflet s provision could potentially account for the polling station-level electoral shifts, particularly if coordination counteracted the persistent and generally favorable updating about incumbents. Based on our followup survey in December 2017, the vast majority of those that reported coordinating at endline reported engaging in informal interactions rather than organized meetings between voters, although in around one half of cases coordination also involved interacting with candidates (or their operatives) or local traditional leaders that typically approached voters first. Consistent with voters emphasis on local performance, much of the discussion among voters concerned projects and transfers. Although our respondents generally updated their individual beliefs positively, group discussions were equally split between regarding the incumbent s performance as higher or lower than expected. While activity levels in parliament were discussed much less frequently, they were more favorable. Where politicians got involved, they generally promised to improve local project delivery rather than enhance national policies. Ultimately, when voters coordinated, they generally reported siding with the incumbent as shown in column (9) of Table 11. Large majorities agreed that the incumbent would work harder in the chamber and bring their department more projects. Of those that coordinated, 87% reported that their group ultimately coordinated on voting for the incumbent. Since such coordination overwhelmingly favored incumbents, but was not systematically correlated with incumbent performance (as columns (10)-(12) in Table 11 illustrate), the coordination induced by this intervention does not appear to explain polling station level outcomes. To the extent that social networks might explain our findings, it seems more likely that information diffused within the village. Such an explanation would be easiest to square with the results if the information became less favorable toward the incumbent as it passed between voters. 54

55 5.3.2 Cross-village informational spillovers Another possibility is that information crossed from treated to control villages. Such cross-village spillovers could account for the lack of average effects on incumbent vote choice if control villages similarly become more positive about the incumbent. To estimate spillovers to the 75 villages in the pure control group, we restrict the sample to this subset of village and define spillovers as the number of villages within xkm of a treated village receiving performance (incumbent or benchmark) information. Panels A, B, and C of Appendix Table A11 indicate that for treated villages respectively within 1km, 2.5km, and 5km of a village, there is no consistent evidence to suggest that proximity to performance information significantly affected endline voter beliefs or voting behavior, conditional on the number of villages within our sample within the same distance. 34 This applies both on average, as well as by the level of reported performance. Although the final four columns in panels A and C tentatively suggest positive effects, a spillover explanation is hard to substantiate given the lack of change in self-reported beliefs and behaviors unless effects were concentrated entirely among older voters Party responses to information dissemination Politicians rarely stand by when potentially influential information is released (e.g. Arias et al. 2018; Bidwell, Casey and Glennerster 2016; Cruz, Keefer and Labonne 2017). Consequently, another possible explanation for the lack of a persistent average treatment effect on incumbent electoral support, but positive effects when interacted with the information content, is that challenger parties were particularly effective at counteracting information that generally increased favorability toward the incumbent. Incumbents may also respond by highlighting positive information, although to the extent that it is effective this should reinforce the favorable immediate updating of voters. Another channel through which strategic responses could explain our findings is if in- 34 Unreported results also show that leaflet recall is also unaffected. 55

56 cumbents (challengers) reallocate resources from treatment (control) to control (treatment) villages upon learning that favorable information had already been disseminated. We investigated such equilibrium campaign responses to information dissemination by using our endline survey to gauge two types of party or candidate action. First, we asked respondents if, and how, the incumbent or challenger parties (or their agents) responded specifically to the leaflet s provision. Second, we used a list experiment to measure the extent of vote buying, in order to assess whether party electoral strategies change, even without explicitly mentioning the leaflets. 35 As shown in columns (1) and (5) of Table 12, challengers and especially incumbents responded directly to the intervention. As the almost-zero control group mean indicates, responses were concentrated in treated villages. Decomposing candidate responses by type, the vast majority of incumbent responses involved a community meeting or talking with the village chief, while challenger parties held community meetings or had party operatives visit voters. If incumbent responses are at least as effective as challenger responses, it is hard to account for the zero average effects observed at the individual and polling station levels. To better understand what parties did, we used our December followup survey to ask about what actions parties took and whether they were effective. Voters that reported incumbent-held community meetings or discussions with the chief were convinced to vote for the incumbent 70-80% of the time, while the less-frequent challenger community meetings and party visits rarely convinced or even encouraged voters to support them. The interactions with national and local incumbent performance, in column (4), suggest that incumbents capitalized on positive local performance information. Given such responses were compelling to voters, and likely reached a broader electorate that more likely to turn out and which Table 9 found to be more receptive to local performance than our survey respondents, this could 35 Half the sample were subject to a list experiment including incumbent vote buying as the omitted option from the list; vote buying by a challenger party was omitted for the other half of the sample. 56

57 Table 12: Effects of information treatments on incumbent and challenger responses (endline survey) Incumbent response Challenger response (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) Incumbent 0.067*** 0.068*** 0.068*** 0.068*** 0.042*** 0.043*** 0.043*** 0.047*** (0.012) (0.012) (0.012) (0.012) (0.008) (0.008) (0.008) (0.008) Benchmark 0.079*** 0.079*** 0.079*** 0.080*** 0.047*** 0.046*** 0.047*** 0.051*** (0.012) (0.012) (0.012) (0.012) (0.010) (0.010) (0.010) (0.010) Incumbent Overall performance (ICW) (0.011) (0.007) Benchmark Overall performance (ICW) * ** (0.013) (0.008) Incumbent Relevant performance (ICW) (0.015) (0.011) Benchmark Relevant performance (ICW) (0.014) (0.013) Incumbent National performance (ICW) *** *** (0.010) (0.008) Benchmark National performance (ICW) *** *** (0.014) (0.008) Incumbent Local performance (ICW) 0.039*** 0.021** (0.013) (0.008) Benchmark Local performance (ICW) 0.039*** 0.017* (0.013) (0.010) Observations 3,875 3,875 3,875 3,875 3,875 3,875 3,875 3,875 Outcome range {0,1} {0,1} {0,1} {0,1} {0,1} {0,1} {0,1} {0,1} Control outcome mean Control outcome std. dev Notes: Each specification is estimated using OLS, and includes randomization block fixed effects and baseline and endline enumerator fixed effects. All observations are inversely weighted by the baseline number of respondent surveyed in the village. Lower order interactions between the list experiment and performance indexes are omitted. Standard errors are clustered by randomization block. * denotes p < 0.1, ** denotes p < 0.05, *** denotes p < 0.01 from two-sided t tests. 57

58 explain the positive effects of treatment on incumbent vote share at the polling station level where local performance was strongest. The lack of an effect on average at the polling station could then reflect effective but relatively sparse incumbent responses. Column (8) indicates that challengers sought to counteract such efforts, but as noted above these were rarely seen as effective. In contrast, both incumbents and challengers respond more to national performance information when they performed poorly, although this is not a major factor determining vote choices. Although vote buying is prevalent, we were not able to detect a systematic indirect response to information dissemination through vote buying. The results of the list experiment in columns (1) and (5) of Appendix Table A12 indicate that 22% of voters reported receiving a gift from the incumbent, while another 22% reported receiving a gift from a challenger. Although such vote buying was a little lower in treated villages, especially among challengers where local incumbent performance was strong, the estimates are too imprecise to be able to conclude that the substitution of vote buying across villages can account for our findings Summary The preceding discussion highlights the complex interactions that information dissemination campaigns can precipitate. Although it is hard to definitively attribute voting behavior to a particular factor, the results suggest that older, previous voters were influenced most by the treatment, and may have learned about strong local performance primarily through incumbents complementary efforts to publicize their good performance. The former component is consistent with the limited effects among treated young voters, while the relatively limited incumbent response may explain coexistence of no average effect but a strong slope effect at the polling station level. In contrast, the increased support for the incumbent where local performance was greatest is hard to square with voter coordination and cross-village spillovers. This suggests that incumbent efforts to diffuse positive information were more effective than voter diffusion and coordination. These findings pose interesting challengers for future research seeking to unpack these equilibria. 58

59 6 Conclusion In light of the mixed evidence that information campaigns can support electoral accountability, we illuminate step-by-step the process linking incumbent performance information to both voting behavior and requests from politicians among among rural Senegalese voters. We observe that young voters process new information in a Bayesian manner, retain such information at least one month later, and make more requests from and at least initially express an intention to vote for better-performing incumbents. Moreover, such sophisticated responses did not depend on educating voters about the responsibilities of parliamentary deputies. Given the relatively low levels of education in our sample, these findings clearly suggest that information may be sufficient to enable most of the world s voters to hold politicians to account. However, the extent to which politicians are held to account also depends on other forces stimulated by information dissemination. In contrast with voter requests from politicians, which persistently follow the textbook accountability story and are augmented by benchmarked performance information, vote choices appear to reflect a more complex electoral equilibrium that demands further analysis. Our findings suggest that this principally driven by incumbents capitalizing on strong local performance, rather than information diffusion or coordination between voters. The analysis of equilibrium responses remains tentative in light of the difficulties of estimating causal mediation effects. This suggests that future researchers should focus on more directly unpacking political responses. For example, this could involve factorial designs crossing information dissemination with informing incumbent and challenger politicians such campaigns. Less demanding experiments could seek to inform only politicians of events that they may be unaware of, but which could influence their electoral prospects, before measuring their responses. A key question regarding our anatomy of political accountability is the extent to which the findings extend beyond rural Senegal. Rural areas may respond more to information campaigns, given their comparatively low normal levels of exposure to political information and NGO activity. 59

60 Nevertheless, there are several reasons to believe that our results foster a broader understanding of political accountability. First, by documenting sophisticated responses among poorly educated voters with limited interaction with the type of information that we provided, we believe that this study highlights that all types of voters possess the capacity to process simple incumbent performance indicators. While perhaps not surprising to some, this mitigates concerned raised in the American politics literature (e.g. Gomez and Wilson 2006). Second, parliamentary elections in Senegal share many features with elections in other developing democracies, such as non-trivial levels of local clientelism and the ability of local agents to intervene in response to campaigns like ours. In more developed contexts, it is possible that different types of campaign strategy would interact with localized information provision differently. Third, because our leaflets are similar in design to previous studies (e.g. Adida et al. 2017; Arias et al. 2018; Chong et al. 2015; Gottlieb 2016; Humphreys and Weinstein 2012), our findings may help to direct researchers in other contexts toward the types of impediments to electoral accountability that we highlight here. Similarly, our findings suggest to information campaign designers that temporally benchmarking locally-relevant incumbent performance information may be an important way of enhancing accountability, while detailed information about duties and national behaviors may have limited value. 60

61 References Adida, Claire, Jessica Gottlieb, Gwyneth McClendon and Eric Kramon Breaking the Clientelistic Voting Equilibrium: The Joint Importance of Salience and Coordination. AidData Working Paper #48. Alt, James E., David D. Lassen and John Marshall Information sources, belief updating, and the politics of economic expectations: Evidence from a Danish survey experiment. Journal of Politics 78(2): Anderson, Michael L Multiple inference and gender differences in the effects of early intervention: A reevaluation of the Abecedarian, Perry Preschool, and Early Training Projects. Journal of the American Statistical Association 103(484): Arias, Eric, Horacio A. Larreguy, John Marshall and Pablo Querubín Does the Content and Mode of Delivery of Information Matter for Electoral Accountability? Evidence from a Field Experiment in Mexico. Working paper. Arias, Eric, Horacio A. Larreguy, John Marshall and Pablo Querubín Priors rule: When do malfeasance revelations help and hurt incumbent parties? Working paper. Arias, Eric, Pablo Balán, Horacio A. Larreguy, John Marshall and Pablo Querubín Malfeasance Revelations, Coordination Through Social Networks and Electoral Sanctioning: Experimental Evidence from Mexico. Working paper. Ashworth, Scott Electoral accountability: recent theoretical and empirical work. Annual Review of Political Science 15: Ashworth, Scott and Ethan Bueno de Mesquita Electoral selection, strategic challenger entry, and the incumbency advantage. Journal of Politics 70(4):

62 Ashworth, Scott and Ethan Bueno de Mesquita Is Voter Competence Good for Voters? Information, Rationality, and Democratic Performance. American Political Science Review 108(3): Banerjee, Abhijit V., Rukmini Banerji, Esther Duflo, Rachel Glennerster and Stuti Khemani Pitfalls of participatory programs: Evidence from a randomized evaluation in education in India. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy 2(1):1 30. Banerjee, Abhijit V., Selvan Kumar, Rohini Pande and Felix Su Do Informed Voters Make Better Choices? Experimental Evidence from Urban India. Working paper. Beck, Linda J Senegal. In Countries at the Crossroads 2011: An Analysis of Democratic Governance, ed. Jake Dizard, Christopher Walker and Vanessa Tucker. Rowman & Littlefield. Besley, Timothy and Andrea Prat Handcuffs for the grabbing hand? Media capture and government accountability. American Economic Review 96(3): Bhandari, Abhit, Horacio A. Larreguy and John Marshall Learning accountability: Can formal education help hold politicians to account? Pre-analysis plan, Social Science Registry. Bidwell, Kelly, Katherine Casey and Rachel Glennerster Debates: Voting and Expenditure Responses to Political Communication. Working Paper. Björkman Nyqvist, Martina, Damien de Walque and Jakob Svensson Experimental Evidence on the Long-Run Impact of Community-Based Monitoring. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics 9(1): Bullock, John G., Donald P. Green and Shang E. Ha Yes, But What s the Mechanism? (Don t Expect an Easy Answer). Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 98(4): Chauchard, Simon, Marko Klašnja and S.P. Harish The Limited Impact of Information on Political Selection: An Experiment on Asset Disclosures in India. Working paper. 62

63 Chauchard, Simon and Neelan Sircar. forthcoming. Dilemmas and Challenges of Citizen Information Campaigns: Lessons from a Failed Experiment in India. In Information and Political Accountability: A New Method for Cumulative Learning, ed. Thad Dunning, Guy Grossman, Marcatan Humphreys, Susan Hyde and Craig McIntosh. Cambridge University Press. Chiang, Chun-Fang and Brian Knight Media bias and influence: Evidence from newspaper endorsements. Review of Economic Studies 78(3): Chong, Alberto, Ana De La O, Dean Karlan and Leonard Wantchekon Does Corruption Information Inspire the Fight or Quash the Hope? A Field Experiment in Mexico on Voter Turnout, Choice and Party Identification. Journal of Politics 77(1): Chwe, Michael Suk-Young Communication and coordination in social networks. Review of Economic Studies 67(1):1 16. Cruz, Cesi, Philip Keefer and Julien Labonne Incumbent Advantage, Voter Information and Vote Buying. Working paper. de Figueiredo, Miguel F.P., F. Daniel Hidalgo and Yuri Kasahara When Do Voters Punish Corrupt Politicians? Experimental Evidence from Brazil. Working paper. Duch, Raymond M. and Randolph T. Stevenson The Economic Vote: How Political and Economic Institutions Condition Election Results. Cambridge University Press. Dunning, Thad, Guy Grossman, Macartan Humphreys, Susan Hyde and Craig McIntosh. forthcoming. Metaketa I: The Limits of Electoral Accountability. Cambridge University Press. Durante, Ruben and Emilio Gutierrez Political Advertising and Voting Intentions: Evidence from Exogenous Variation in Ads Viewership. Working paper. 63

64 Fearon, James D Electoral Accountability and the Control of Politicians: Selecting Good Types versus Sanctioning Poor Performance. In Democracy, Accountability, and Representation, ed. Adam Przeworski, Susan Stokes and Bernard Manin. Cambridge University Press. Ferraz, Claudio and Frederico Finan Exposing Corrupt Politicians: The Effects of Brazil s Publicly Released Audits on Electoral Outcomes. Quarterly Journal of Economics 123(2): Gentzkow, Matthew and Jesse M. Shapiro Media bias and reputation. Journal of Political Economy 114(2): Gomez, Brad T. and J. Matthew Wilson Cognitive heterogeneity and economic voting: A comparative analysis of four democratic electorates. American Journal of Political Science 50(1): Gottlieb, Jessica Greater Expectations: A Field Experiment to Improve Accountability in Mali. American Journal of Political Science 60(1): Gottlieb, Jessica and Horacio Larreguy An Informational Theory of Electoral Targeting in Young Clientelistic Democracies: Evidence from Senegal. Working Paper. Humphreys, Macartan and Jeremy Weinstein Policing Politicians: Citizen Empowerment and Political Accountability in Uganda Preliminary Analysis. Working paper. Kendall, Chad, Tommaso Nannicini and Francesco Trebbi How do voters respond to information? Evidence from a randomized campaign. American Economic Review 105(1): Khagram, Sanjeev, Archon Fung and Paolo De Renzio Open budgets: The Political Economy of Transparency, Participation, and Accountability. Brookings Institution Press. 64

65 Khemani, Stuti, Ernesto Dal Bó, Claudio Ferraz, Frederico S. Finan, Johnson Stephenson, Louise Corinne, Adesinaola M. Odugbemi, Dikshya Thapa and Scott D. Abrahams Making politics work for development: Harnessing transparency and citizen engagement. World Bank Policy Research Report Kling, Jeffrey R., Jeffrey B. Liebman and Lawrence F. Katz Experimental analysis of neighborhood effects. Econometrica 75(1): Koter, Dominika King makers: Local leaders and ethnic politics in Africa. World Politics 65(2): Larreguy, Horacio, John Marshall and Jr. Snyder, James M Publicizing malfeasance: When Media Facilitates Electoral Accountability in Mexico,.. Larreguy, Horacio and Shelley Liu The Effect of Education on Political Participation: Evidence from a Competitive Consolidating Democracy.. Lieberman, Evan S., Daniel N. Posner and Lily L. Tsai Does information lead to more active citizenship? Evidence from an education intervention in rural Kenya. World Development 60: Manin, Bernard, Adam Przeworski and Susan C. Stokes Introduction. In Democracy, Accountability, and Representation, ed. Adam Przeworski, Susan C. Stokes and Bernard Manin. Cambridge University Press pp Marshall, John Political information cycles: When do voters sanction incumbent parties for high homicide rates? Working paper. McKenzie, David Beyond baseline and follow-up: The case for more T in experiments. Journal of Development Economics 99(2):

66 Meyer, Margaret A. and John Vickers Performance comparisons and dynamic incentives. Journal of Political Economy 105(3): Morris, Stephen and Hyun Song Shin Social value of public information. American Economic Review 92(5): O Donnell, Guillermo A Delegative democracy. Journal of Democracy 5(1): Olken, Benjamin A Monitoring corruption: evidence from a field experiment in Indonesia. Journal of Political Economy 115(2): Powell, G. Bingham, Jr. and Guy D. Whitten A Cross-National Analysis of Economic Voting: Taking Account of the Political Context. American Journal of Political Science 37(2): Rogoff, Kenneth Equilibrium Political Budget Cycles. American Economic Review 80(1): Thomas, Melissa A and Oumar Sissokho Liaison Legislature: The Role of the National Assembly in Senegal. The Journal of Modern African Studies 43(1): Villalón, Leonardo A Islamic Society and State Power in Senegal: Disciples and Citizens in Fatick. Cambridge University Press. Weitz-Shapiro, Rebecca and Matthew S. Winters Discerning corruption: Credible Accusations and the Punishment of Politicians in Brazil. Working paper. Zaller, John R The Nature and Origins of Mass Opinion. Cambridge University Press. 66

67 A Online appendix Contents A.1 All leaflet configurations A1 A.2 Experimental validation tests A1 A.3 Additional results A1 A.1 All leaflet configurations In addition to the duties + benchmark leaflet show in Figure 3, Figures A1-A4 show our other leaflet configurations. A.2 Experimental validation tests Tables A1 and A2 respectively report individual-level and village-level balance across information treatment in the baseline and endline samples. The F test in the final column tests the restriction that all treatment conditions are indistinguishable from the control group, reporting significant differences consistent with chance in both the baseline and endline samples. This reflects the low attrition rate, and the lack of differential attrition demonstrated in Table A3. A.3 Additional results Tables A4 and A5 respectively show that our information treatments increased the precision of respondent beliefs about the incumbent at both baseline and endline. Tables A6 and A7 report our estimates of the survey-level heterogeneous when using the Kling, Liebman and Katz (2007) approach to creating a summative rating scale, instead of our preferred A1

68 LEAFLET - 35.pdf 1 26/06/17 20:08 C M Y CM MY CY CMY K Figure A1: Example of duties treatment A2

69 Figure A2: Example of incumbent treatment in Oussouye A3

70 Figure A3: Example of duties + incumbent treatment in Oussouye A4

71 Figure A4: Example of benchmark treatment in Oussouye A5

AN EMPIRICAL ANATOMY OF POLITICAL ACCOUNTABILITY: EXPERIMENTAL EVIDENCE FROM A PRE-ELECTION

AN EMPIRICAL ANATOMY OF POLITICAL ACCOUNTABILITY: EXPERIMENTAL EVIDENCE FROM A PRE-ELECTION AN EMPIRICAL ANATOMY OF POLITICAL ACCOUNTABILITY: EXPERIMENTAL EVIDENCE FROM A PRE-ELECTION INFORMATION DISSEMINATION CAMPAIGN IN SENEGAL ABHIT BHANDARI HORACIO LARREGUY JOHN MARSHALL FEBRUARY 2018 The

More information

Publicizing malfeasance:

Publicizing malfeasance: Publicizing malfeasance: When media facilitates electoral accountability in Mexico Horacio Larreguy, John Marshall and James Snyder Harvard University May 1, 2015 Introduction Elections are key for political

More information

DfID SDG16 Event 9 December Macartan Humphreys

DfID SDG16 Event 9 December Macartan Humphreys DfID SDG16 Event 9 December 2015 Macartan Humphreys Experimental Research The big idea: Understanding social processes is very often rendered difficult or impossible because of confounding. For example,

More information

SIERRA LEONE 2012 ELECTIONS PROJECT PRE-ANALYSIS PLAN: INDIVIDUAL LEVEL INTERVENTIONS

SIERRA LEONE 2012 ELECTIONS PROJECT PRE-ANALYSIS PLAN: INDIVIDUAL LEVEL INTERVENTIONS SIERRA LEONE 2012 ELECTIONS PROJECT PRE-ANALYSIS PLAN: INDIVIDUAL LEVEL INTERVENTIONS PIs: Kelly Bidwell (IPA), Katherine Casey (Stanford GSB) and Rachel Glennerster (JPAL MIT) THIS DRAFT: 15 August 2013

More information

Can information that raises voter expectations improve accountability?

Can information that raises voter expectations improve accountability? Can information that raises voter expectations improve accountability? A field experiment in Mali Jessica Gottlieb Stanford University, Political Science May 8, 2012 Overview Motivation: Preliminary studies

More information

Harvard University, Ph.D., Government. Dissertation: Information consumption and electoral accountability in Mexico.

Harvard University, Ph.D., Government. Dissertation: Information consumption and electoral accountability in Mexico. JOHN MARSHALL 705 International Affairs Building, 420 West 118th Street, New York, NY 10027 jm4401@columbia.edu (+1) 212-854-5941 www.scholar.harvard.edu/jmarshall ACADEMIC APPOINTMENTS Columbia University,

More information

Ten Things That May Control Corruption

Ten Things That May Control Corruption Ten Things That May Control Corruption None of the initiatives below work all the time. An important research agenda concerns identifying the conditions under which any single item is more or less effective.

More information

JOHN MARSHALL. Harvard University, Ph.D., Government. Dissertation: Information consumption and electoral accountability in Mexico.

JOHN MARSHALL. Harvard University, Ph.D., Government. Dissertation: Information consumption and electoral accountability in Mexico. JOHN MARSHALL 705 International Affairs Building, 420 West 118th Street, New York, NY 10027 jm4401@columbia.edu (+1) 212-854-5941 www.scholar.harvard.edu/jmarshall ACADEMIC APPOINTMENTS Columbia University,

More information

Evidence from Randomized Evaluations of Governance Programs. Cristobal Marshall

Evidence from Randomized Evaluations of Governance Programs. Cristobal Marshall Evidence from Randomized Evaluations of Governance Programs Cristobal Marshall Policy Manager, J-PAL December 15, 2011 Today s Agenda A new evidence based agenda on Governance. A framework for analyzing

More information

Vote Buying and Clientelism

Vote Buying and Clientelism Vote Buying and Clientelism Dilip Mookherjee Boston University Lecture 18 DM (BU) Clientelism 2018 1 / 1 Clientelism and Vote-Buying: Introduction Pervasiveness of vote-buying and clientelistic machine

More information

Improving Electoral Engagement: A Narrative on the Evidence. Tavneet Suri November 5 th 2015

Improving Electoral Engagement: A Narrative on the Evidence. Tavneet Suri November 5 th 2015 Improving Electoral Engagement: A Narrative on the Evidence Tavneet Suri November 5 th 2015 Democracy Expanding Rapidly Across the World Since 1800 In Africa Governance Remains a Challenge Corruption Safety

More information

Online Appendix: The Effect of Education on Civic and Political Engagement in Non-Consolidated Democracies: Evidence from Nigeria

Online Appendix: The Effect of Education on Civic and Political Engagement in Non-Consolidated Democracies: Evidence from Nigeria Online Appendix: The Effect of Education on Civic and Political Engagement in Non-Consolidated Democracies: Evidence from Nigeria Horacio Larreguy John Marshall May 2016 1 Missionary schools Figure A1:

More information

Who Debates, Wins? Experimental Evidence on Debate Participation in a Liberian Election 1

Who Debates, Wins? Experimental Evidence on Debate Participation in a Liberian Election 1 Who Debates, Wins? Experimental Evidence on Debate Participation in a Liberian Election 1 Jeremy Bowles 2 & Horacio Larreguy 3 September 27, 2018 Abstract We study a nationwide debate initiative ahead

More information

political budget cycles

political budget cycles P000346 Theoretical and empirical research on is surveyed and discussed. Significant are seen to be primarily a phenomenon of the first elections after the transition to a democratic electoral system.

More information

Migrants and external voting

Migrants and external voting The Migration & Development Series On the occasion of International Migrants Day New York, 18 December 2008 Panel discussion on The Human Rights of Migrants Facilitating the Participation of Migrants in

More information

SIERRA LEONE 2012 ELECTIONS PROJECT PRE-ANALYSIS PLAN: POLLING CENTERCONSTITUENCY LEVEL INTERVENTIONS

SIERRA LEONE 2012 ELECTIONS PROJECT PRE-ANALYSIS PLAN: POLLING CENTERCONSTITUENCY LEVEL INTERVENTIONS SIERRA LEONE 2012 ELECTIONS PROJECT PRE-ANALYSIS PLAN: POLLING CENTERCONSTITUENCY LEVEL INTERVENTIONS PIs: Kelly Bidwell (JPAL), Katherine Casey (Stanford GSB) and Rachel Glennerster (JPAL) DATE: 2 June

More information

How Coethnicity Moderates the Effect of Information On Voting Behavior: Experimental Evidence from Benin

How Coethnicity Moderates the Effect of Information On Voting Behavior: Experimental Evidence from Benin How Coethnicity Moderates the Effect of Information On Voting Behavior: Experimental Evidence from Benin Claire Adida Jessica Gottlieb Eric Kramon Gwyneth McClendon September 13, 2016 Abstract Scholars

More information

Pre-Analysis Plan Turning Up, Tuning In, Turning Out: Experimental Evidence from Liberia 1

Pre-Analysis Plan Turning Up, Tuning In, Turning Out: Experimental Evidence from Liberia 1 Pre-Analysis Plan Turning Up, Tuning In, Turning Out: Experimental Evidence from Liberia 1 Jeremy Bowles 2 & Horacio Larreguy 3 October 24, 2017 Abstract Understanding the role of information is at the

More information

When Do Voters Punish Corrupt Politicians? Experimental Evidence from Brazil

When Do Voters Punish Corrupt Politicians? Experimental Evidence from Brazil Experimental Evidence from Brazil Miguel F. P. de Figueiredo UC Berkeley F. Daniel Hidalgo MIT Yuri Kasahara University of Oslo CEGA Research Retreat UC Berkeley November 4, 2012 Project Overview Research

More information

Policy Deliberation and Electoral Returns: Experimental Evidence from Benin and the Philippines

Policy Deliberation and Electoral Returns: Experimental Evidence from Benin and the Philippines Policy Deliberation and Electoral Returns: Experimental Evidence from Benin and the Philippines Leonard Wantchekon IGC Growth Week LSE Fall, 2014 Leonard Wantchekon (LSE) Policy Deliberation and Electoral

More information

Report for the Associated Press: Illinois and Georgia Election Studies in November 2014

Report for the Associated Press: Illinois and Georgia Election Studies in November 2014 Report for the Associated Press: Illinois and Georgia Election Studies in November 2014 Randall K. Thomas, Frances M. Barlas, Linda McPetrie, Annie Weber, Mansour Fahimi, & Robert Benford GfK Custom Research

More information

What is The Probability Your Vote will Make a Difference?

What is The Probability Your Vote will Make a Difference? Berkeley Law From the SelectedWorks of Aaron Edlin 2009 What is The Probability Your Vote will Make a Difference? Andrew Gelman, Columbia University Nate Silver Aaron S. Edlin, University of California,

More information

Participation in European Parliament elections: A framework for research and policy-making

Participation in European Parliament elections: A framework for research and policy-making FIFTH FRAMEWORK RESEARCH PROGRAMME (1998-2002) Democratic Participation and Political Communication in Systems of Multi-level Governance Participation in European Parliament elections: A framework for

More information

Improving Government Accountability for Delivering Public Services

Improving Government Accountability for Delivering Public Services Improving Government Accountability for Delivering Public Services Stuti Khemani Development Research Group & Africa Region Chief Economist Office The World Bank October 5, 2013 Background and Motivation

More information

Political Economics II Spring Lectures 4-5 Part II Partisan Politics and Political Agency. Torsten Persson, IIES

Political Economics II Spring Lectures 4-5 Part II Partisan Politics and Political Agency. Torsten Persson, IIES Lectures 4-5_190213.pdf Political Economics II Spring 2019 Lectures 4-5 Part II Partisan Politics and Political Agency Torsten Persson, IIES 1 Introduction: Partisan Politics Aims continue exploring policy

More information

Voting for Quality? The Impact of School Quality Information on Electoral Outcomes

Voting for Quality? The Impact of School Quality Information on Electoral Outcomes Voting for Quality? The Impact of School Quality Information on Electoral Outcomes Marina Dias PUC-Rio Claudio Ferraz PUC-Rio June 2017 Abstract Many developing countries fail to deliver high quality public

More information

Ethnic Diversity and Perceptions of Government Performance

Ethnic Diversity and Perceptions of Government Performance Ethnic Diversity and Perceptions of Government Performance PRELIMINARY WORK - PLEASE DO NOT CITE Ken Jackson August 8, 2012 Abstract Governing a diverse community is a difficult task, often made more difficult

More information

Overcoming or Reinforcing Coethnic Preferences? An Experiment on Information and Ethnic Voting

Overcoming or Reinforcing Coethnic Preferences? An Experiment on Information and Ethnic Voting Overcoming or Reinforcing Coethnic Preferences? An Experiment on Information and Ethnic Voting Claire Adida Jessica Gottlieb Eric Kramon Gwyneth McClendon January 25, 2017 Abstract Social scientists often

More information

Case Study: Get out the Vote

Case Study: Get out the Vote Case Study: Get out the Vote Do Phone Calls to Encourage Voting Work? Why Randomize? This case study is based on Comparing Experimental and Matching Methods Using a Large-Scale Field Experiment on Voter

More information

CREDIBLE SOURCES AND SOPHISTICATED VOTERS: WHEN DOES NEW INFORMATION INDUCE ECONOMIC

CREDIBLE SOURCES AND SOPHISTICATED VOTERS: WHEN DOES NEW INFORMATION INDUCE ECONOMIC CREDIBLE SOURCES AND SOPHISTICATED VOTERS: WHEN DOES NEW INFORMATION INDUCE ECONOMIC VOTING? JAMES E. ALT DAVID D. LASSEN JOHN MARSHALL When does new economic information cause voters to re-evaluate the

More information

Meet the (Opposition) Candidates: How Information Can Overcome Partisanship in a Dominant Party Regime

Meet the (Opposition) Candidates: How Information Can Overcome Partisanship in a Dominant Party Regime Meet the (Opposition) Candidates: How Information Can Overcome Partisanship in a Dominant Party Regime Melina R. Platas and Pia Raffler April 26, 2018 Abstract What is the role of partisanship in shaping

More information

BCGEU surveyed its own members on electoral reform. They reported widespread disaffection with the current provincial electoral system.

BCGEU surveyed its own members on electoral reform. They reported widespread disaffection with the current provincial electoral system. BCGEU SUBMISSION ON THE ELECTORAL REFORM REFERENDUM OF 2018 February, 2018 The BCGEU applauds our government s commitment to allowing British Columbians a direct say in how they vote. As one of the largest

More information

The National Citizen Survey

The National Citizen Survey CITY OF SARASOTA, FLORIDA 2008 3005 30th Street 777 North Capitol Street NE, Suite 500 Boulder, CO 80301 Washington, DC 20002 ww.n-r-c.com 303-444-7863 www.icma.org 202-289-ICMA P U B L I C S A F E T Y

More information

FRED S. MCCHESNEY, Northwestern University, Chicago, IL 60611, U.S.A.

FRED S. MCCHESNEY, Northwestern University, Chicago, IL 60611, U.S.A. 185 thinking of the family in terms of covenant relationships will suggest ways for laws to strengthen ties among existing family members. To the extent that modern American law has become centered on

More information

Following the Leader: The Impact of Presidential Campaign Visits on Legislative Support for the President's Policy Preferences

Following the Leader: The Impact of Presidential Campaign Visits on Legislative Support for the President's Policy Preferences University of Colorado, Boulder CU Scholar Undergraduate Honors Theses Honors Program Spring 2011 Following the Leader: The Impact of Presidential Campaign Visits on Legislative Support for the President's

More information

Methodology. 1 State benchmarks are from the American Community Survey Three Year averages

Methodology. 1 State benchmarks are from the American Community Survey Three Year averages The Choice is Yours Comparing Alternative Likely Voter Models within Probability and Non-Probability Samples By Robert Benford, Randall K Thomas, Jennifer Agiesta, Emily Swanson Likely voter models often

More information

Robert H. Prisuta, American Association of Retired Persons (AARP) 601 E Street, N.W., Washington, D.C

Robert H. Prisuta, American Association of Retired Persons (AARP) 601 E Street, N.W., Washington, D.C A POST-ELECTION BANDWAGON EFFECT? COMPARING NATIONAL EXIT POLL DATA WITH A GENERAL POPULATION SURVEY Robert H. Prisuta, American Association of Retired Persons (AARP) 601 E Street, N.W., Washington, D.C.

More information

Does Political Competition Reduce Ethnic Discrimination?

Does Political Competition Reduce Ethnic Discrimination? Does Political Competition Reduce Ethnic Discrimination? Evidence from the Samurdhi Food Stamp Program in Sri Lanka Iffath Sharif Senior Economist South Asia Social Protection February 14, 2011 Presentation

More information

CREDIBLE SOURCES AND SOPHISTICATED VOTERS: WHEN DOES NEW INFORMATION INDUCE ECONOMIC

CREDIBLE SOURCES AND SOPHISTICATED VOTERS: WHEN DOES NEW INFORMATION INDUCE ECONOMIC CREDIBLE SOURCES AND SOPHISTICATED VOTERS: WHEN DOES NEW INFORMATION INDUCE ECONOMIC VOTING? JAMES E. ALT DAVID D. LASSEN JOHN MARSHALL AUGUST 2015 When does new economic information cause voters to re-evaluate

More information

Appendix for Citizen Preferences and Public Goods: Comparing. Preferences for Foreign Aid and Government Programs in Uganda

Appendix for Citizen Preferences and Public Goods: Comparing. Preferences for Foreign Aid and Government Programs in Uganda Appendix for Citizen Preferences and Public Goods: Comparing Preferences for Foreign Aid and Government Programs in Uganda Helen V. Milner, Daniel L. Nielson, and Michael G. Findley Contents Appendix for

More information

Who says elections in Ghana are free and fair?

Who says elections in Ghana are free and fair? Who says elections in Ghana are free and fair? By Sharon Parku Afrobarometer Policy Paper No. 15 November 2014 Introduction Since 2000, elections in Ghana have been lauded by observers both internally

More information

Policy Deliberation and Electoral Returns: Evidence from Benin and the Philippines. Léonard Wantchékon, Princeton University 5 November 2015

Policy Deliberation and Electoral Returns: Evidence from Benin and the Philippines. Léonard Wantchékon, Princeton University 5 November 2015 Policy Deliberation and Electoral Returns: Evidence from Benin and the Philippines Léonard Wantchékon, Princeton University 5 November 2015 Two decades of sustained economic growth in Africa But growth

More information

Viktória Babicová 1. mail:

Viktória Babicová 1. mail: Sethi, Harsh (ed.): State of Democracy in South Asia. A Report by the CDSA Team. New Delhi: Oxford University Press, 2008, 302 pages, ISBN: 0195689372. Viktória Babicová 1 Presented book has the format

More information

Research Statement. Jeffrey J. Harden. 2 Dissertation Research: The Dimensions of Representation

Research Statement. Jeffrey J. Harden. 2 Dissertation Research: The Dimensions of Representation Research Statement Jeffrey J. Harden 1 Introduction My research agenda includes work in both quantitative methodology and American politics. In methodology I am broadly interested in developing and evaluating

More information

NANOS. Ideas powered by world-class data. Liberals 39 Conservatives 28, NDP 20, Green 6, People s 1 in latest Nanos federal tracking

NANOS. Ideas powered by world-class data. Liberals 39 Conservatives 28, NDP 20, Green 6, People s 1 in latest Nanos federal tracking Liberals 39 Conservatives 28, NDP 20, Green 6, People s 1 in latest Nanos federal tracking Nanos Weekly Tracking, ending November 9, 2018 (released November 13, 2018-6 am Eastern) NANOS Ideas powered by

More information

Policing Politicians: Citizen Empowerment and Political Accountability in Uganda Preliminary Analysis

Policing Politicians: Citizen Empowerment and Political Accountability in Uganda Preliminary Analysis Policing Politicians: Citizen Empowerment and Political Accountability in Uganda Preliminary Analysis Macartan Humphreys Columbia University Jeremy M. Weinstein Stanford University April 19, 2012 Abstract

More information

NANOS. Ideas powered by world-class data. Conservatives 35, Liberals 34, NDP 16, Green 8, People s 1 in latest Nanos federal tracking

NANOS. Ideas powered by world-class data. Conservatives 35, Liberals 34, NDP 16, Green 8, People s 1 in latest Nanos federal tracking Conservatives 35, Liberals 34, NDP 16, Green 8, People s 1 in latest Nanos federal tracking Nanos Weekly Tracking, ending December 7, 2018 (released December 11, 2018-6 am Eastern) NANOS Ideas powered

More information

The California Primary and Redistricting

The California Primary and Redistricting The California Primary and Redistricting This study analyzes what is the important impact of changes in the primary voting rules after a Congressional and Legislative Redistricting. Under a citizen s committee,

More information

The 2014 Ohio Judicial Elections Survey. Ray C. Bliss Institute of Applied Politics University of Akron. Executive Summary

The 2014 Ohio Judicial Elections Survey. Ray C. Bliss Institute of Applied Politics University of Akron. Executive Summary The 2014 Ohio Judicial Elections Survey Ray C. Bliss Institute of Applied Politics University of Akron Executive Summary The 2014 Ohio Judicial Elections Survey offers new findings on the participation

More information

Yet the World Bank Enterprise Surveys suggest that there is much room for improvement in service quality and accountability

Yet the World Bank Enterprise Surveys suggest that there is much room for improvement in service quality and accountability 51 How transparent is business regulation around the world? Nobel Prize winning economist Amartya Sen wrote in 2009 that lack of transparency in the global financial system was among the main factors contributing

More information

Enhancing women s participation in electoral processes in post-conflict countries

Enhancing women s participation in electoral processes in post-conflict countries 26 February 2004 English only Commission on the Status of Women Forty-eighth session 1-12 March 2004 Item 3 (c) (ii) of the provisional agenda* Follow-up to the Fourth World Conference on Women and to

More information

The Case of the Disappearing Bias: A 2014 Update to the Gerrymandering or Geography Debate

The Case of the Disappearing Bias: A 2014 Update to the Gerrymandering or Geography Debate The Case of the Disappearing Bias: A 2014 Update to the Gerrymandering or Geography Debate Nicholas Goedert Lafayette College goedertn@lafayette.edu May, 2015 ABSTRACT: This note observes that the pro-republican

More information

Modernizing Canada s Electoral System: Instant Runoff Voting as the Best Alternative. By Maxime Dubé, as an individual

Modernizing Canada s Electoral System: Instant Runoff Voting as the Best Alternative. By Maxime Dubé, as an individual Modernizing Canada s Electoral System: Instant Runoff Voting as the Best Alternative Summary By Maxime Dubé, as an individual In the context of electoral reform brought about by the current government,

More information

The Influence of Conflict Research on the Design of the Piloting Community Approaches in Conflict Situation Project

The Influence of Conflict Research on the Design of the Piloting Community Approaches in Conflict Situation Project KM Note 1 The Influence of Conflict Research on the Design of the Piloting Community Approaches in Conflict Situation Project Introduction Secessionist movements in Thailand s southernmost provinces date

More information

Openness and Poverty Reduction in the Long and Short Run. Mark R. Rosenzweig. Harvard University. October 2003

Openness and Poverty Reduction in the Long and Short Run. Mark R. Rosenzweig. Harvard University. October 2003 Openness and Poverty Reduction in the Long and Short Run Mark R. Rosenzweig Harvard University October 2003 Prepared for the Conference on The Future of Globalization Yale University. October 10-11, 2003

More information

SIERRA LEONE GENERAL ELECTIONS 2018: COMMONWEALTH OBSERVER GROUP INTERIM STATEMENT 07 March 2018

SIERRA LEONE GENERAL ELECTIONS 2018: COMMONWEALTH OBSERVER GROUP INTERIM STATEMENT 07 March 2018 SIERRA LEONE GENERAL ELECTIONS 2018: COMMONWEALTH OBSERVER GROUP INTERIM STATEMENT 07 March 2018 Statement by: HE John Dramani Mahama, Chair of the Commonwealth Observer Group to Sierra Leone This is the

More information

THE POLITICS OF ECONOMIC EXPECTATIONS:

THE POLITICS OF ECONOMIC EXPECTATIONS: INFORMATION SOURCES, BELIEF UPDATING, AND THE POLITICS OF ECONOMIC EXPECTATIONS: EVIDENCE FROM A DANISH SURVEY EXPERIMENT JAMES E. ALT DAVID D. LASSEN JOHN MARSHALL FIRST DRAFT: FEBRUARY 2014 When and

More information

These are the findings from the latest statewide Field Poll completed among 1,003 registered voters in early January.

These are the findings from the latest statewide Field Poll completed among 1,003 registered voters in early January. THE FIELD POLL THE INDEPENDENT AND NON-PARTISAN SURVEY OF PUBLIC OPINION ESTABLISHED IN 1947 AS THE CALIFORNIA POLL BY MERVIN FIELD Field Research Corporation 601 California Street, Suite 210 San Francisco,

More information

Online Appendix: Robustness Tests and Migration. Means

Online Appendix: Robustness Tests and Migration. Means VOL. VOL NO. ISSUE EMPLOYMENT, WAGES AND VOTER TURNOUT Online Appendix: Robustness Tests and Migration Means Online Appendix Table 1 presents the summary statistics of turnout for the five types of elections

More information

Financial disclosure and political selection: Evidence from India

Financial disclosure and political selection: Evidence from India Financial disclosure and political selection: Evidence from India Ray Fisman Boston University with Vikrant Vig (LBS) and Florian Schulz (UW) 6/26/2018 1 Holding politicians to account: asset declarations

More information

Afrobarometer Briefing Paper No. 51. June 2008 POPULAR ATTITUDES TO DEMOCRACY IN GHANA, 2008

Afrobarometer Briefing Paper No. 51. June 2008 POPULAR ATTITUDES TO DEMOCRACY IN GHANA, 2008 Afrobarometer Briefing Paper No. 51 June 2008 POPULAR ATTITUDES TO DEMOCRACY IN GHANA, 2008 Introduction Ghana embarked on a transition to democratic rule in the early 1990s after eleven years of quasi-military

More information

FINAL REPORT. Public Opinion Survey at the 39th General Election. Elections Canada. Prepared for: May MacLaren Street Ottawa, ON K2P 0M6

FINAL REPORT. Public Opinion Survey at the 39th General Election. Elections Canada. Prepared for: May MacLaren Street Ottawa, ON K2P 0M6 FINAL REPORT Public Opinion Survey at the 39th General Election Prepared for: Elections Canada May 2006 336 MacLaren Street Ottawa, ON K2P 0M6 TABLE OF CONTENTS List of Exhibits Introduction...1 Executive

More information

PRIORS RULE: WHEN DO MALFEASANCE REVELATIONS HELP

PRIORS RULE: WHEN DO MALFEASANCE REVELATIONS HELP PRIORS RULE: WHEN DO MALFEASANCE REVELATIONS HELP OR HURT INCUMBENT PARTIES? ERIC ARIAS HORACIO LARREGUY JOHN MARSHALL PABLO QUERUBÍN OCTOBER 2017 Effective policy-making requires that voters avoid electing

More information

CAN FAIR VOTING SYSTEMS REALLY MAKE A DIFFERENCE?

CAN FAIR VOTING SYSTEMS REALLY MAKE A DIFFERENCE? CAN FAIR VOTING SYSTEMS REALLY MAKE A DIFFERENCE? Facts and figures from Arend Lijphart s landmark study: Patterns of Democracy: Government Forms and Performance in Thirty-Six Countries Prepared by: Fair

More information

Minnesota State Politics: Battles Over Constitution and State House

Minnesota State Politics: Battles Over Constitution and State House Minnesota Public Radio News and Humphrey Institute Poll Minnesota State Politics: Battles Over Constitution and State House Report prepared by the Center for the Study of Politics and Governance Humphrey

More information

IFES PRE-ELECTION SURVEY IN MYANMAR

IFES PRE-ELECTION SURVEY IN MYANMAR IFES PRE-ELECTION SURVEY IN MYANMAR May 2015 The publication was produced by IFES for the Australian Department for Foreign Affairs and Trade (DFAT), the United Kingdom Department for International Development

More information

14.11: Experiments in Political Science

14.11: Experiments in Political Science 14.11: Experiments in Political Science Prof. Esther Duflo May 9, 2006 Voting is a paradoxical behavior: the chance of being the pivotal voter in an election is close to zero, and yet people do vote...

More information

Deliberative Polling for Summit Public Schools. Voting Rights and Being Informed REPORT 1

Deliberative Polling for Summit Public Schools. Voting Rights and Being Informed REPORT 1 Deliberative Polling for Summit Public Schools Voting Rights and Being Informed REPORT 1 1 This report was prepared by the students of COMM138/CSRE38 held Winter 2016. The class and the Deliberative Polling

More information

ONLINE APPENDIX: DELIBERATE DISENGAGEMENT: HOW EDUCATION

ONLINE APPENDIX: DELIBERATE DISENGAGEMENT: HOW EDUCATION ONLINE APPENDIX: DELIBERATE DISENGAGEMENT: HOW EDUCATION CAN DECREASE POLITICAL PARTICIPATION IN ELECTORAL AUTHORITARIAN REGIMES Contents 1 Introduction 3 2 Variable definitions 3 3 Balance checks 8 4

More information

A Tale of Two Villages

A Tale of Two Villages Kinship Networks and Preference Formation in Rural India Center for the Advanced Study of India, University of Pennsylvania West Bengal Growth Workshop December 27, 2014 Motivation Questions and Goals

More information

POLI 359 Public Policy Making

POLI 359 Public Policy Making POLI 359 Public Policy Making Session 9-Public Policy Process Lecturer: Dr. Kuyini Abdulai Mohammed, Dept. of Political Science Contact Information: akmohammed@ug.edu.gh College of Education School of

More information

Women as Policy Makers: Evidence from a Randomized Policy Experiment in India

Women as Policy Makers: Evidence from a Randomized Policy Experiment in India Women as Policy Makers: Evidence from a Randomized Policy Experiment in India Chattopadhayay and Duflo (Econometrica 2004) Presented by Nicolas Guida Johnson and Ngoc Nguyen Nov 8, 2018 Introduction Research

More information

Job approval in North Carolina N=770 / +/-3.53%

Job approval in North Carolina N=770 / +/-3.53% Elon University Poll of North Carolina residents April 5-9, 2013 Executive Summary and Demographic Crosstabs McCrory Obama Hagan Burr General Assembly Congress Job approval in North Carolina N=770 / +/-3.53%

More information

Preferential votes and minority representation in open list proportional representation systems

Preferential votes and minority representation in open list proportional representation systems Soc Choice Welf (018) 50:81 303 https://doi.org/10.1007/s00355-017-1084- ORIGINAL PAPER Preferential votes and minority representation in open list proportional representation systems Margherita Negri

More information

Smart African Politics: Candidates Debating Under a Tree - The N...

Smart African Politics: Candidates Debating Under a Tree - The N... FIXES Smart African Politics: Candidates Debating Under a Tree By Tina Rosenberg November 10, 2015 3:30 am Fixes looks at solutions to social problems and why they work. Political debates are good even

More information

Ohio State University

Ohio State University Fake News Did Have a Significant Impact on the Vote in the 2016 Election: Original Full-Length Version with Methodological Appendix By Richard Gunther, Paul A. Beck, and Erik C. Nisbet Ohio State University

More information

Islamic Republic of Afghanistan. Ministry of Foreign Affairs. Statement by H.E. Prof. Dr. Mohammad Qasim Hashimzai, At the 55 th Session of the

Islamic Republic of Afghanistan. Ministry of Foreign Affairs. Statement by H.E. Prof. Dr. Mohammad Qasim Hashimzai, At the 55 th Session of the Islamic Republic of Afghanistan Ministry of Foreign Affairs Statement by H.E. Prof. Dr. Mohammad Qasim Hashimzai, At the 55 th Session of the Geneva 10 July 2013 Distinguished Members of the Committee,

More information

November 15-18, 2013 Open Government Survey

November 15-18, 2013 Open Government Survey November 15-18, 2013 Open Government Survey 1 Table of Contents EXECUTIVE SUMMARY... 3 TOPLINE... 6 DEMOGRAPHICS... 14 CROSS-TABULATIONS... 15 Trust: Federal Government... 15 Trust: State Government...

More information

Hungary. Basic facts The development of the quality of democracy in Hungary. The overall quality of democracy

Hungary. Basic facts The development of the quality of democracy in Hungary. The overall quality of democracy Hungary Basic facts 2007 Population 10 055 780 GDP p.c. (US$) 13 713 Human development rank 43 Age of democracy in years (Polity) 17 Type of democracy Electoral system Party system Parliamentary Mixed:

More information

Iowa Voting Series, Paper 4: An Examination of Iowa Turnout Statistics Since 2000 by Party and Age Group

Iowa Voting Series, Paper 4: An Examination of Iowa Turnout Statistics Since 2000 by Party and Age Group Department of Political Science Publications 3-1-2014 Iowa Voting Series, Paper 4: An Examination of Iowa Turnout Statistics Since 2000 by Party and Age Group Timothy M. Hagle University of Iowa 2014 Timothy

More information

Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US

Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US Ben Ost a and Eva Dziadula b a Department of Economics, University of Illinois at Chicago, 601 South Morgan UH718 M/C144 Chicago,

More information

Denmark: Uniting local and European perspectives

Denmark: Uniting local and European perspectives FIFTH FRAMEWORK RESEARCH PROGRAMME (1998-2002) Democratic Participation and Political Communication in Systems of Multi-level Governance Denmark: Uniting local and European perspectives Palle Svensson

More information

Sierra Leonean perceptions of democracy Findings from Afrobarometer Round 6 survey in Sierra Leone

Sierra Leonean perceptions of democracy Findings from Afrobarometer Round 6 survey in Sierra Leone WWW.AFROBAROMETER.ORG Sierra Leonean perceptions of democracy Findings from Afrobarometer Round 6 survey in Sierra Leone At a glance Support for democracy: A majority of Sierra Leoneans prefer democracy,

More information

NANOS. Ideas powered by world-class data. Liberals 41, Conservatives 31, NDP 15, Green 6 in latest Nanos federal tracking

NANOS. Ideas powered by world-class data. Liberals 41, Conservatives 31, NDP 15, Green 6 in latest Nanos federal tracking Liberals 41, Conservatives 31, NDP 15, Green 6 in latest Nanos federal tracking Nanos Weekly Tracking, ending September 14, 2018 (released September 18, 2018-6 am Eastern) NANOS Ideas powered by world-class

More information

WP 2015: 9. Education and electoral participation: Reported versus actual voting behaviour. Ivar Kolstad and Arne Wiig VOTE

WP 2015: 9. Education and electoral participation: Reported versus actual voting behaviour. Ivar Kolstad and Arne Wiig VOTE WP 2015: 9 Reported versus actual voting behaviour Ivar Kolstad and Arne Wiig VOTE Chr. Michelsen Institute (CMI) is an independent, non-profit research institution and a major international centre in

More information

Supporting Information Political Quid Pro Quo Agreements: An Experimental Study

Supporting Information Political Quid Pro Quo Agreements: An Experimental Study Supporting Information Political Quid Pro Quo Agreements: An Experimental Study Jens Großer Florida State University and IAS, Princeton Ernesto Reuben Columbia University and IZA Agnieszka Tymula New York

More information

Breaking Out of Inequality Traps: Political Economy Considerations

Breaking Out of Inequality Traps: Political Economy Considerations The World Bank PREMnotes POVERTY O C T O B E R 2 0 0 8 N U M B E R 125 Breaking Out of Inequality Traps: Political Economy Considerations Verena Fritz, Roy Katayama, and Kenneth Simler This Note is based

More information

Resource Manual on Electoral Systems in Nepal

Resource Manual on Electoral Systems in Nepal Translation: Resource Manual on Electoral Systems in Nepal Election Commission Kantipath, Kathmandu This English-from-Nepali translation of the original booklet is provided by NDI/Nepal. For additional

More information

POLICY SEA: CONCEPTUAL MODEL AND OPERATIONAL GUIDANCE FOR APPLYING STRATEGIC ENVIRONMENTAL ASSESSMENT IN SECTOR REFORM EXECUTIVE SUMMARY

POLICY SEA: CONCEPTUAL MODEL AND OPERATIONAL GUIDANCE FOR APPLYING STRATEGIC ENVIRONMENTAL ASSESSMENT IN SECTOR REFORM EXECUTIVE SUMMARY POLICY SEA: CONCEPTUAL MODEL AND OPERATIONAL GUIDANCE FOR APPLYING STRATEGIC ENVIRONMENTAL ASSESSMENT IN SECTOR REFORM EXECUTIVE SUMMARY June 2010 The World Bank Sustainable Development Network Environment

More information

CSES Module 5 Pretest Report: Greece. August 31, 2016

CSES Module 5 Pretest Report: Greece. August 31, 2016 CSES Module 5 Pretest Report: Greece August 31, 2016 1 Contents INTRODUCTION... 4 BACKGROUND... 4 METHODOLOGY... 4 Sample... 4 Representativeness... 4 DISTRIBUTIONS OF KEY VARIABLES... 7 ATTITUDES ABOUT

More information

VoteCastr methodology

VoteCastr methodology VoteCastr methodology Introduction Going into Election Day, we will have a fairly good idea of which candidate would win each state if everyone voted. However, not everyone votes. The levels of enthusiasm

More information

Generally well-administered elections demonstrate significant progress

Generally well-administered elections demonstrate significant progress European Union Election Observation Mission Tripartite Elections 28 September 2006 PRELIMINARY STATEMENT Generally well-administered elections demonstrate significant progress Lusaka, 30 September 2006

More information

Congruence in Political Parties

Congruence in Political Parties Descriptive Representation of Women and Ideological Congruence in Political Parties Georgia Kernell Northwestern University gkernell@northwestern.edu June 15, 2011 Abstract This paper examines the relationship

More information

Voter Participation with Collusive Parties. David K. Levine and Andrea Mattozzi

Voter Participation with Collusive Parties. David K. Levine and Andrea Mattozzi Voter Participation with Collusive Parties David K. Levine and Andrea Mattozzi 1 Overview Woman who ran over husband for not voting pleads guilty USA Today April 21, 2015 classical political conflict model:

More information

Partisan Advantage and Competitiveness in Illinois Redistricting

Partisan Advantage and Competitiveness in Illinois Redistricting Partisan Advantage and Competitiveness in Illinois Redistricting An Updated and Expanded Look By: Cynthia Canary & Kent Redfield June 2015 Using data from the 2014 legislative elections and digging deeper

More information

Amy Tenhouse. Incumbency Surge: Examining the 1996 Margin of Victory for U.S. House Incumbents

Amy Tenhouse. Incumbency Surge: Examining the 1996 Margin of Victory for U.S. House Incumbents Amy Tenhouse Incumbency Surge: Examining the 1996 Margin of Victory for U.S. House Incumbents In 1996, the American public reelected 357 members to the United States House of Representatives; of those

More information

Vote-Buying and Selling

Vote-Buying and Selling The Political Economy of Elections in Uganda: Vote-Buying and Selling Presented during The National Conference on Religion Rights and Peace convened by Human Rights and Peace Centre (HURIPEC) School of

More information

Chapter Four: Chamber Competitiveness, Political Polarization, and Political Parties

Chapter Four: Chamber Competitiveness, Political Polarization, and Political Parties Chapter Four: Chamber Competitiveness, Political Polarization, and Political Parties Building off of the previous chapter in this dissertation, this chapter investigates the involvement of political parties

More information

ONTARIO SUPERIOR COURT OF JUSTICE. JOAN RUSSOW and THE GREEN PARTY OF CANADA. - and -

ONTARIO SUPERIOR COURT OF JUSTICE. JOAN RUSSOW and THE GREEN PARTY OF CANADA. - and - ONTARIO SUPERIOR COURT OF JUSTICE File No.: B E T W E E N: JOAN RUSSOW and THE GREEN PARTY OF CANADA Applicants - and - THE ATTORNEY GENERAL OF CANADA, THE CHIEF ELECTORAL OFFICER OF CANADA and HER MAJESTY

More information

Office of the Ombudsman of Rwanda

Office of the Ombudsman of Rwanda Office of the Ombudsman of Rwanda A Review of the Effectiveness of Anti-Corruption Agencies 1 September 2010 Dan Barnes, Consultant The World Bank 1 This paper is one of the case studies completed as a

More information