Evidence on the importance of spatial voting models in presidential nominations and elections

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Evidence on the importance of spatial voting models in presidential nominations and elections"

Transcription

1 Public Choice (2005) 123: DOI: /s C Springer 2005 Evidence on the importance of spatial voting models in presidential nominations and elections LAWRENCE W. KENNY 1, &BABAK LOTFINIA 2 1 Department of Economics, University of Florida, Gainesville, Florida , U.S.A.; 2 Bureau of Economic and Business Research, University of Florida, Gainesville, Florida , U.S.A. ( Author for correspondence: larry.kenny@cba.ufl.edu) Accepted 6 March 2004 Abstract. ADA scores and Nominate scores are used for the first time to examine the influence of spatial voting records on which candidate wins the party s presidential nomination and on which nominee wins the general election. We find that the most conservative Republican candidate and moderately liberal Democrats were most likely to win their party s nomination. For general elections we find that the candidate s spatial record has nearly as much impact on the outcome as economic growth, which has been the focus of most past empirical research. The nominee whose voting record is more moderate is more likely to be elected. Introduction In the spatial voting literature, the median voter model asserts that both candidates for an office select the same platform, that which is preferred by the median voter. 1 On the other hand, in the divergent platform or two constituencies model, candidates offer distinctly different platforms that straddle the median voter s position; thus the more conservative candidate receives votes from conservatives, and liberals support the more liberal candidate. 2 There is strong evidence that spatial voting plays an important role in determining the outcome of congressional elections. Legislators whose voting records are far from what would be predicted for their district are less likely to get reelected. 3 Research on U.S. Senate elections has found that the divergent platform (or two constituency) model outperforms the median voter model empirically. Democratic senators almost always have a more liberal voting record than Republican senators from the same state, who represent the same geographic constituency. 4 These differences have origins in the party nomination process. House members whose record is far from the party position in their state are less likely to run for the Senate and to be selected their party s standard bearer (Francis, Kenny, Morton, & Schmidt, 1994). Recognizing this, House members who later run for the Senate edge steadily toward the winning state party position (Francis & Kenny, 1996). Furthermore, the median voter s preferred position does not appear to be ideal for winning the general election. Senators who deviate from their party s position are less likely to get reelected, or even to seek reelection, than those whose records are close to the appropriate

2 440 state party platform. 5 More importantly, Schmidt, Kenny, and Morton (1996) found that distance to the state party position better explains reelection success than distance to the median voter s position. The relevance of spatial voting models often is illustrated in class with examples of voters punishing presidential candidates for taking the wrong platform. Goldwater lost in 1964 because he was too conservative. Mondale was trounced in 1984 for being too liberal. Thus it is surprising that the statistical literature examining the factors affecting the outcomes of multiple presidential elections has focused almost exclusively on whether the incumbent party is rewarded for economic performance or punished for unpopular wars. 6 Afew studies, however, have relied on perceptions about candidate spatial positions to explain the outcome of multiple presidential elections. 7 Zaller (1998) used a research assistant s ratings on a seven-point conservative liberal scale of presidential nominees from 1948 to 1996 and found that the more moderate nominee did better, ceteris paribus. Bartels and Zaller s (2001) estimates of the nominees spatial positions is based on expert ratings of candidates in elections between 1948 and and survey data on candidates between 1984 and 1996 (from better informed respondents in American National Election Studies surveys...). The research assistant s and experts estimates of candidate positions are, however, subjective and may be biased with the ex post rationalization that often accompanies hindsight. And although Francis et al. (1994) have examined the role of spatial voting records on success in becoming a nominee for the U.S. Senate, no study appears to have examined how candidates spatial voting records affect who wins the presidential nomination. Several ideological measures are available for evaluating the performance of these spatial models in explaining which candidate obtains the party s presidential nomination and which nominee wins the general election. Ratings produced by Americans for Democratic Action (ADA) place the voting records of members of Congress on the crucial conservative liberal dimension that seems to explain most political conflict, 8 and comparable scores for presidents in have been constructed by Zupan (1992). Groseclose, Levitt, and Snyder (1999) have transformed the raw House and Senate ADA scores to make them comparable across chambers and over time and claim that their indexed ADA scores should perform better than the raw ADA scores produced by the Americans for Democratic Action. Poole and Rosenthal (1997) tout their Nominate scores as preferable to interest group ratings such as the ADA scores for a variety of reasons. We use their common space coordinates, which also are comparable across chambers and over time, for members of Congress and for Eisenhower and subsequent presidents. This paper makes numerous contributions to the literature. We extend Zupan s presidential ADA score series of 11 years to Then, we use these three spatial measures of ideology to ascertain whether the candidates

3 441 actual or inferred spatial voting records matter in determining the winners of the presidential nominations and presidential elections, and, if so, whether spatial competition is better described by the median voter model or the divergent platform model. Ours is the first study to use the candidate s voting record in Congress to explain success in seeking the presidency. Our use of the voting record, as opposed to an expert s estimate of the candidate s spatial position, provides an important tie to the extensive literature as cited, which examines the effect of the voting record on subsequent success in getting reelected or in seeking higher office. 9 We find that the candidates spatial records play an important role in selecting their party s nominee. Democrats with a centrist or far-left voting record are less likely to get nominated than are candidates who are only moderately liberal. Similarly moderate Republicans are less likely to be nominated than candidates with a very conservative voting record. Thus the party nominees in the general election have spatially distinct platforms, which supports the divergent platform model. Spatial records also are very important in determining the winner of the general election. The median voter and divergent models fare equally well. In half the regressions, the median voter model provides the better fit; in these nominees who were closer to the median voter were more likely to win. In the other regressions, the divergent platform better explained the outcome. The nominee who was closer to the optimal party position was more successful. Note, however, that the optimal party positions for winning the general election were not that far apart. Our empirical analysis also provides evidence on the relative performance of the three spatial voting record variables in explaining candidate success. Measuring the Ideological Record of Presidents and Presidential Candidates Zupan (1992) developed an ingenious way to determine U.S. presidents spatial positions. The widely used Americans for Democratic Action rating equals the percentage of times the legislator supported a liberal position in key roll-call votes selected by the ADA. For about half the House or Senate votes selected by the ADA, the Congressional Quarterly Almanac has identified whether the president took a personal position on the vote. Using these votes, Zupan determined for each year from 1947 to 1989 the percentage of times the president s position on these House and Senate votes agreed with the ADA s liberal position. We have extended this series through Since Zupan s presidential ADA scores and the congressional ADA scores are based on roughly the same votes, these scores are sufficiently comparable to allow the use of both to examine the role that an ideological record

4 442 plays in determining mobility from Congress, and even from the governor s mansion, to the presidency and the president s subsequent success in getting reelected. 10 The lack of a presidential position on a bill is not counted in Zupan s index as a vote for or against the liberal position. In contrast, the raw ratings compiled by the ADA for Congress divide the votes favoring liberal positions by the total bills considered, thus counting an abstention as anti-liberal. Since Peltzman (1984), Francis et al. (1994), and others feel it more appropriate to treat abstentions as neither a vote for the ADA s position nor a vote against it, they created modified ADA scores, which equal the percentage of votes cast that were cast for liberal positions. 11 The modified ADA scores used in the congressional literature and in this paper deal with abstentions in the same fashion as Zupan s presidential ADA scores. The presidential modified ADA scores are reported in Table 1 and range from 0 to 100. Cumulative scores based on a simple average of each year s ADA scores are also given. It is clear that Eisenhower s career ADA score of 50 places him far from other presidents from either party. Excluding Eisenhower, the average score for Republicans was approximately 8. The average Democratic score was approximately 89. Groseclose, Levitt, and Snyder s conversion formulas were utilized on the modified ADA scores to create indexed ADA scores that are comparable over time and across chambers, with the 1980 House being the base year and chamber. Although in the 1980 House the indexed ADA scores lie between 0 and 100, the conversion formulas allow for other indexed scores to lie outside this range; this is due to some senators and representatives being more liberal or more conservative than the members of the 1980 House. Thus the indexed ADA scores between 1947 and 1999 range from 27 to 129 in the House and fall between 31 and 118 in the Senate. Since the president s ADA score is based on both House and Senate votes used by the ADA, the indexed ADA score for the president is the average of the indexed ADA score calculated using the House formula and the indexed ADA score based on the Senate formula. With two exceptions, the average ADA score over the first 3 years of the president s term is used to gauge the president s ideological record as he seeks reelection. In light of their limited record as president, Ford s votes over his 3 years in office and Johnson s ADA scores for were used for the 1976 and 1964 elections, respectively. 12 For presidential candidates who had served in Congress, we use their ADA scores averaged over the 6 years prior to their bid for president as an estimate of their expected ideological position as president. 13 Forexample, Bob Dole s average ADA score for was used for his 1996 presidential bid. Five presidents elected after Eisenhower had served in Congress. Their congressional indexed ADA scores are fairly close to their subsequent scores as

5 443 Table 1. Presidential modified ADA scores Republican ADA score Democrat ADA score Year President Year Cum. Mean Year President Year Cum. Mean 1953 Eisenhower Truman Eisenhower Truman Eisenhower Truman Eisenhower Truman Eisenhower Truman Eisenhower Truman Eisenhower Kennedy Eisenhower Kennedy Nixon Kennedy Nixon Johnson Nixon Johnson Nixon Johnson Nixon Johnson Nixon Johnson Ford Carter Ford Carter Ford Carter Reagan Carter Reagan Clinton Reagan Clinton Reagan Clinton Reagan Clinton Reagan Clinton Reagan Clinton Reagan Clinton Bush G.H Clinton Bush G.H Bush G.H Bush G.H All Presidents ave. weighted by years ave. weighted by years ave. weighted by Pres ave. weighted by Pres Not including Eisenhower ave. weighted by years 7.95 ave. weighted by Pres Source: : Zupan (1992) : compiled by Lotfinia.

6 444 president. The absolute differences are: Kennedy (2), Ford (6), Nixon (13), G.H. Bush (14), Johnson (25). Gauging the expected ideological record for a presidential candidate who has not served in Congress is more problematic. Since governors and senators run in statewide races, they should be constrained by the same state party position. Accordingly, with one exception we use the average (modified or indexed) ADA scores for a state s senators of the same party over the 11-year period spanning from 5 years before the election to 5 years after the election as the predicted ADA score for governors seeking to be president. 14 As expected, the prediction error is greater for the three governors who became president Reagan (7), Clinton (14), Carter (43) than for the presidents who had served in Congress. Poole and Rosenthal have produced various Nominate scores that measure the spatial location of members of Congress. The common space Nominate scores were used because these are comparable across chambers and over time. Nominate scores for presidents are based on the CQ Presidential Support Roll Calls. There is one lifetime score for each member of Congress and for each president, starting with Eisenhower. For governors running for president, average Nominate scores for senators in their party and state over the five (2 year) Congresses centered around the election are used to produce an expected spatial position. The first dimension of the Nominate scores is highly correlated with the ADA scores. To facilitate comparison with the ADA measures, this first dimension is used and has been rescaled so that the most liberal position in the congressional data ( 0.806) corresponds to 100 and the most conservative position (0.896) is mapped to 0. Selecting the Party s Nominee Now we seek to ascertain whether the candidate s voting record plays any role in whether he is ultimately selected as his party s nominee for president. This reduced form approach explaining the outcome of the nomination process does not delve into the determination of each s state s delegates, which is beyond the scope of this paper. Instead, we ask whether moderates on average over the years are less likely than liberals to become the Democratic party s nominee. Similarly, what is the optimal voting record for garnering the Republican nomination? And does deviation from the winning party position have much impact on the likelihood of being selected? As Cooper and Munger (2000: 338) note, theory does not tell us much about who enters and wins nomination races, which often have three or more candidates. To gain some insight into what might happen, they describe the outcomes of simulated races in which 10 candidates are drawn randomly from

7 445 a normal distribution centered at the party s median voter. In this setting, Cooper and Munger (2000: 346) find a high variance in the winner s position and that the distribution of the winner s position is if anything... multimodal. Because the ADA began evaluating legislators records in 1947, we start with the 13 presidential elections from 1952 to Our sample excludes eight nominations in which the incumbent president was seeking reelection (Eisenhower, 1956; Johnson, 1964; Nixon, 1972; Ford, 1976; Carter, 1980; Reagan, 1984; Bush, 1992; Clinton, 1996) and four nominations in which a sitting vice president ran for office (Nixon, 1960; Humphrey, 1968; Bush, 1988; Gore, 2000), since these candidates were always successful. The 1952 Republican race was tossed out because the major candidate and nominee, Eisenhower, had never held elective office and thus had no predicted ADA score; indeed both parties courted this war hero. Our list of primary candidates in the remaining 13 primaries includes all candidates who ran in at least two primaries, received at least 1% of the total vote across all primaries, and had been governor or a member of Congress. The first two restrictions limit the list of candidates to major candidates. 15 The third requirement limits our analysis to candidates whose ideological position is measurable; this is not exceedingly restrictive, since Eisenhower was the only major-party nominee in the elections not to have been a governor or member of Congress. Under these criteria, there were 17 Republican bids in five nomination races (1964, 1968, 1980, 1996, and 2000) and 38 bids by Democrats in eight nomination races (1952, 1956, 1960, 1972, 1976, 1984, 1988, and 1992). 16 The small number of presidential candidates, particularly Republicans, will limit the number of hypotheses that can be tested with these data. Tables 2 and 3 report estimates of the impact of the candidate s ideological record and whether the candidate was a governor (GOVERNOR = 1) in determining success in obtaining the party nomination. Linear probability regressions explaining whether the candidate won the nomination are found in Table 2; these regressions utilize Huber-White-sandwich robust standard errors to deal with the well-known heteroskedasticity problem in this setting. 17 Table 3 reports regressions, which also employ robust standard errors, explaining the candidate s share of the vote obtained by these candidates in the presidential primaries. Candidates who are farther from their party position are hypothesized to be less likely to win the primary. DISTANCE TO PARTY PRIMARY POSI- TION equals the distance of the candidate s ideological score (I c ) from the winning party primary position (I pp ), i.e. I c I pp.toascertain the winning party primary position, we searched over integer values for the party primary position I pp that produced the best fit, by minimizing the root mean squared

8 446 Table 2. Regression estimates of effect of distance from party position on winning presidential primaries (absolute t-statistic in parentheses, based on robust standard errors) Republican (n = 17) Democrat (n = 38) Modified Indexed Rescaled Modified Indexed Rescaled Modified Indexed Rescaled Modified Indexed Rescaled ADA ADA nominate ADA ADA nominate ADA ADA nominate ADA ADA nominate Measure of position (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12) DISTANCE TO PARTY PRIMARY POSITION (2.78) (3.15) (2.94) (2.78) (2.65) (1.89) RELATIVE DISTANCE TO PARTY PRIMARY POS. (2.93) (3.37) (3.14) (3.03) (2.39) (1.80) GOVERNOR (0.10) (0.04) (0.38) (0.17) (0.13) (0.44) (3.00) (3.02) (3.00) (3.12) (2.94) (2.77) Intercept (2.81) (2.99) (3.60) (2.89) (3.02) (3.40) (2.54) (2.93) (2.35) (2.64) (2.42) (2.30) R Root mean sq. error Overall significance PARTY PRIMARY POSITION

9 447 Table 3. Regression estimates of effect of distance from party position on vote share in presidential primaries (absolute t-statistic in parentheses, based on robust standard errors) Republican (n = 17) Democrat (n = 38) Modified Indexed Rescaled Modified Indexed Rescaled Modified Indexed Rescaled Modified Indexed Rescaled ADA ADA nominate ADA ADA nominate ADA ADA nominate ADA ADA nominate Measure of position (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12) DISTANCE TO PARTY PRIMARY POSITION (2.85) (3.06) (3.30) (2.61) (2.64) (1.80) RELATIVE DISTANCE TO PARTY PRIMARY POS. (2.87) (3.22) (2.97) (2.53) (2.28) (1.93) GOVERNOR (0.40) (0.28) (0.25) (0.47) (0.38) (0.17) (2.07) (2.19) (1.81) (2.06) (1.89) (1.94) Intercept (3.99) (3.97) (4.25) (4.21) (4.18) (4.54) (4.42) (4.27) (4.31) (4.40) (3.93) (4.18) R Root mean sq. error Overall significance PARTY PRIMARY POSITION

10 448 error in a regression. The estimates of I pp are labeled in these tables as PARTY PRIMARY POSITION. This was done for each of the three ideological measures: modified ADA score, indexed ADA score, and rescaled Nominate score. A candidate needs only to be closer than the other candidates in that primary to the winning party position to be the most desirable choice. RELATIVE DISTANCE TO PARTY POS reflects this realization. It equals the candidate s distance from the winning party primary position relative to that of the closest candidate in the primary. That is, it equals I c I pp I closest I pp. This variable equals 0 for the closest candidate in each primary. A search also produced an estimate of the optimal party primary position for this variable, as used with a particular ideological measure. Accordingly, each of the two tables has 12 regressions, representing estimates for two parties, three ideological measures, and two distance variables. Test statistics of overall significance indicate that the regressions in Tables 2 and 3 are significant at the 5% level in all but two instances. The only exceptions occur when rescaled Nominate scores are used to explain the share of votes garnered in Democratic primaries. The estimated optimal party positions are revealing. For Republicans, the most conservative position (among candidates) was almost always the ideal position. On the other hand, the Democratic party clearly is not choosing its most liberal candidate. 18 For each ideological measure there are several Democratic candidates with scores that are at least 5% higher than the typical estimate of the winning party primary position. Candidates need only be closer to the party position than their rivals for the nomination to be preferred over their opponents. Accordingly, relative distance (RELATIVE DISTANCE TO PARTY PRIMARY POS) should better explain who wins the nomination than distance (DISTANCE TO PARTY PRIMARY POSITION). This hypothesis is supported in every comparison for the Republican nominations and in half of the comparisons for the Democratic nominations. For each party, there is evidence that those who are farther from the optimal party primary position are less likely to win the party s nomination. All 24 DISTANCE TO PARTY PRIMARY POSITION or RELATIVE DIS- TANCE TO PARTY PRIMARY POS coefficients in Tables 2 and 3 are negative and thus consistent with this hypothesis. These results, on the other hand, are not consistent with the lack of pattern in the winning position in Cooper and Munger s (2000) simulations of 10 candidate races with random entry. For the Republican primaries, all the regression coefficients are significantly negative at the 0.8% level or better, under a one-tailed test. A one standard deviation rise in distance is estimated to lower the probability of winning

11 449 Table 4. Explaining who wins the democratic primaries: frequency analysis (using modified ADA scores, PARTY PRIMARY POSITION = 92) DISTANCE TO PARTY OUTCOME PRIMARY POSITION WIN LOSE % WIN Toward Liberal Positions Toward Moderate Positions Total 8 30 the nomination by and to reduce the candidate s share of the primary vote by The classification is perfect if the measure of relative distance from the winning Republican position of 3 is used in conjunction with the indexed ADA scores. All five Republican candidates with a relative position of 0 (i.e., the closest candidates to the party primary position of 3) won the nomination, and all 12 candidates who were 3 65 points farther away lost the nomination. A frequency distribution showing how success rates for Democratic candidates depend on the distance from the winning party primary position, based on modified ADA scores, is found in Table 4. The fraction winning the nomination is lower for those who are more moderate or more liberal than the winning Democratic primary position (92), but this relationship is not nearly as striking as that reported for Republicans. The regression results are consistent with this observation. In the Democratic primaries, under a one-tailed test eight coefficients are significant at the 1.5% level or better and four are significant at the % levels. The distance measures based on the Nominate scores are consistently the least significant. Deviating from the optimal party primary platform is less costly for Democrats than for Republicans. For Democrats, a one standard deviation rise in distance causes the probability of winning to fall by and results in a drop in the share of primary votes received. Governors may have an advantage over other presidential candidates because they have experience running a large government, which is valuable to being an effective president. Consistent with this reasoning, 20 of the 24 coefficients on GOVERNOR are positive. They are significant, however, only in the Democrat regressions. For Democrats, governors are estimated to have a higher probability of winning the nomination. Governors also obtain a larger share of the primary vote in Democratic primaries.

12 450 The General Election A variety of variables have been used to explain the success of the incumbent party in the November presidential elections. These measure economic performance, involvement in unpopular wars, candidate ideology, incumbent party fatigue, president s popularity, voter evaluations of the incumbent party s capabilities, primary performance of the incumbent party s nominee, voter support for the incumbent party s nominee (early in the campaign), and so on. 19 The president s popularity and the esteem with which the incumbent party is held undoubtedly reflect the incumbent party s success in bringing about economic prosperity and avoiding unpopular wars. The primary success and initial popularity as president of the incumbent party s nominee also may reflect the ideological position he has taken. Thus, we focus on the more fundamental factors behind the incumbent party s success in the general elections: economic performance, involvement in unpopular wars, and candidate ideology. Bartels and Zaller (2001) estimated 48 regressions using various measures of these three factors and incumbent party fatigue and found (2001: 11) that (Hibbs, 2000) Bread and Peace model is by far the best of the 48 models. Accordingly, we use Hibbs measures of economic performance ( bread ) and peace, supplemented by our novel variables capturing the parties relative spatial positions. Since we have no basis for assigning Eisenhower a predicted ideological score in 1952, the empirical analysis covers the 12 elections from 1956 to Let UNPOPULAR WAR be a dummy variable that equals 1 in 1968 and equals 0 otherwise. Past economic performance is discounted at a rate that is determined by the data. The economic record of the incumbent party for the 15 quarters from the second quarter in the first year in office to the last quarter in the election year is summarized by DISCOUNTED GROWTH t = g t + b g t 1 + b 2 g t 2 + +b 14 g t 14 (1) where g t equals the quarterly growth rate in real personal income per capita and b is the quarterly discount factor that is to be estimated. To this basic Bread and Peace specification, we add the relative closeness of the candidates ideological positions to a winning general election position. Our estimates of the nominees ideological positions are based on the nominees actual voting record, in contrast to earlier research that has relied on experts estimates of the nominees policy positions. Under the median voter model, the median voter s position is the winning general election position. That is, the candidate closer to the median voter s position is more likely to

13 451 win the election, other things equal. Let DIFFERENCE IN DISTANCES TO MEDIAN VOTER = incumbent party s distance from median voter s position challenger party s distance from median voter s position. If the voter s utility is symmetric and the median voter is indifferent between the two party positions, then the median voter s position is the midpoint of the two party positions. One estimate of the party position is the average voting record of the party s presidents, which is reported in panel A of Table The midpoint of the two presidential party averages is indicated Table 5. Party and median voter positions Modified Indexed Rescaled President ADA ADA nominate Panel A: presidents ideological ratings Republicans Eisenhower Nixon Ford Reagan Bush G.H Average Average without Ike Democrats Truman NA Kennedy Johnson Carter Clinton Average Panel B: estimating median voter based on presidents record Republicans a Median voter Democrats Panel C: estimating median voter based on median value of winning party primary positions Republicans Median voter Democrats a Based on mean without Eisenhower.

14 452 as Median Voter in panel B for each of the three ideological measures. The other estimate of the median voter s position is based on the winning party primary positions estimated in Section 3. Panel C lists the median of the winning party primary position estimates for each party and the resulting median voter s position. The estimates for the median voter s position in panels B and C are remarkably close for the modified ADA and Nominate measures. We use the average of the panel B and panel C median voter estimates as the median voter s position in the empirical analysis in this section: 47 for modified ADA, 38 for indexed ADA, 52 for rescaled Nominate. Does the nominee who is closer to the median voter fare better in the general election? Alternatively, is the nominee who is closer to a party position more likely to win the general election? We test this version of the two constituency hypothesis by requiring the parties to be equidistant from the median voter s position and searching for the distance to the median voter that produces the best fit. Table 6 reports regressions explaining the share of the two major party vote received by the incumbent party, which are similar to those found in the literature. Linear probability regressions explaining whether the incumbent party won the general election are found in Table 7. To be consistent with the vote share variable, Gore is coded as winning the 2000 election. Regressions based on the median voter model, in which the candidate closer to the median voter wins, are shown in the top panels of Tables 6 and 7. For half the specifications, we get a better fit allowing the parties to have different winning general election positions that straddle the median voter s position. These divergent platform regressions are reported in the bottom panels in Tables 6 and 7. Half the regressions employ UNPOPULAR WAR. UNPOPULAR WAR has significantly negative coefficients in all of the eight regressions in which it is used. As a result of Vietnam, the incumbent Democratic party is estimated to have lost.023 to.045 of the two-party vote and experienced a.686 to.765 lower probability of winning the election. The literature generally has focused on the role of economic growth in explaining the success of the incumbent party in presidential elections. We also find that the incumbent party is rewarded for rapid growth of the economy. All but two of the 18 coefficients for DISCOUNTED GROWTH are significantly positive. A one standard deviation rise in this variable is estimated to lead to a.033 to.043 increase in the incumbent s vote share and a.217 to.302 higher probability of winning the election. The quarterly discount factor (b) applied to prior economic growth was defined in Equation (1). The estimates of b, which are obtained through another search procedure, average 0.89 and range from 0.83 to To see what these discount factors imply, consider the average value for b. Economic growth four quarters (i.e., 1 year) before the election receives a weight equal

15 453 Table 6. Regression estimates of effect of distance from optimal position on vote share in presidential general elections ( ); dependent variable = incumbent vote share in two party vote (absolute t-statistic in parentheses, based on robust standard errors) Modified Indexed Rescaled Modified Indexed Rescaled Measure of position ADA ADA nominate ADA ADA nominate Median voter result DIFFERENCE IN DISTANCES TO MEDIAN VOTER (3.21) (2.56) (2.91) (3.80) (3.39) (4.59) UNPOPULAR WAR (2.78) (3.38) (1.96) DISCOUNTED GROWTH (5.13) (3.78) (6.73) (5.27) (3.35) (6.48) Intercept (19.9) (20.8) (24.6) (22.0) (24.2) (27.3) R Root mean sq. error Median voter position Qrtly discount factor Annual discount rate Divergent platform result (if better fit than median voter) DIFFERENCE IN DISTANCES TO PARTY POSITION UNPOPULAR WAR (1.88) DISCOUNTED GROWTH (3.02) (4.51) (4.50) (5.11) (5.31) (6.50) Intercept (20.3) (22.6) (27.3) R Root mean sq. error Republican position Democratic position Qrtly discount factor Annual discount rate to (= ). This is equivalent to voters applying an annual rate of discount of 59% to prior economic growth

16 454 Table 7. Linear probability regression estimates of effect of distance from optimal position on winning presidential general elections ( ); dependent variable = incumbent victory dummy (absolute t-statistic in parentheses, based on robust standard errors) Modified Indexed Rescaled Modified Indexed Rescaled Measure of position ADA ADA nominate ADA ADA nominate Median voter result DIFFERENCE IN DISTANCES TO MEDIAN VOTER (4.01) (3.74) (1.83) (3.94) (3.61) (3.14) UNPOPULAR WAR (4.89) (4.65) (2.92) DISCOUNTED GROWTH (3.26) (2.61) (2.99) (2.57) (0.88) (2.02) Intercept (0.13) (0.43) (0.04) (0.23) (0.95) (0.56) R Root mean sq. Error Median voter position Qrtly discount factor Annual discount rate Divergent platform results (if better fit than median voter) DIFFERENCE IN DISTANCES TO PARTY POSITION (3.53) (4.80) (3.86) UNPOPULAR WAR (4.29) DISCOUNTED GROWTH (2.38) (2.34) (0.72) Intercept (0.48) (0.13) (1.02) R Root mean sq. error Republican position Democratic position Qrtly discount factor Annual discount rate This is higher than both the 14% average return on the 5000 most active U.S. stocks for and Hibbs (2000) estimate of the annual discount rate of 23% on prior economic growth in presidential elections (based on b = 0.95) but is smaller than the 79% discount rate that Figlio (2000) estimated voters applied to prior indexed ADA scores for senators. Tables 6 and 7 report the annual rate of discount for each regression, which varies from 0 to 111%.

17 455 There is very little prior evidence on the role that nominee ideology plays in studies of multiple presidential elections, and there is no evidence on the effect of the nominee s voting record. In half the regressions in Tables 6 and 7, the median voter model fits the data best. That is, the nominee who is closer to the median voter s position is more likely to win the election. In the remaining half of the regressions, the nominee who is closer to his estimated winning party position is more likely to win. The winning general election party positions are 4 to 18 points apart, averaging an 11-point difference. These party differences are much smaller than the point spread that separates the average ideological records for Democrat and Republican presidents (see Table 5). Nevertheless, our estimates of the winning general election Democratic position (e.g., 45 in indexed ADA regression 11 in Table 7) are to the left of Carter in 1976 (e.g., 39.5), and our estimates of the winning general election Republican position (e.g., 31) are to the right of Eisenhower (e.g., 37.5); that is, both candidates were more moderate than was optimal in adivergent platform setting in the general election. The winning position equals the median voter s position under the median voter model and equals the winning party position under the divergent platform model. An increase in the incumbent party nominee s distance from the winning position, relative to the challenger party nominee s distance, is expected to cause the incumbent party to fare worse in the election. All 18 coefficients on the DIFFERENCE IN DISTANCES variables in regression Tables 6 and 7 have the predicted negative sign, and all but one are highly significant. 21 A one standard deviation rise in these variables is estimated to result in a decrease in the incumbent party s share of major party votes and a fall in the probability of an incumbent party victory. The importance of relative distance can be seen in Table 8, which shows that, based on the indexed ADA measures, the closer candidate won 10 of the 12 elections. The closer candidate lost only the two elections in which the differences between the candidates closeness to the median voter were the smallest (0.6 and 3.4 points, for the 1996 and 1960 elections, respectively). Note that the divergent platform model has the same success in classifying success with indexed ADA scores. The candidate who is closer to the winning position is favored to win. But it is important to recognize that this does not mean that those who are far from the median voter cannot win the general election. It can be seen in Table 8 that, based on the median voter model and indexed ADA data, three of the 12 elections were won by candidates who were 36 to 40 points from the median voter s position. Johnson defeated Goldwater, who was 3 points farther away, and Reagan trounced Mondale, who was 19 points more distant from the median voter. And Clinton beat Dole, even though Dole s record was less than a point closer to the median voter.

18 456 Table 8. Effect of distance from median voter position on winning presidential general elections ( ) indexed ADA scores (median voter position = 38) Closer candidate More distant candidate Closer candidate Indexed Dist. to Indexed Dist. to Diff in Name ADA Median Name ADA Median Dist. Outcome 1996 Dole Clinton Lose 1960 Nixon Kennedy Lose 1964 Johnson Goldwater Win 1968 Nixon Humphrey Win 1992 Clinton Bush, G.H Win 2000 Gore Bush, G.W Win 1980 Reagan Carter Win 1988 Bush, G.H Dukakis Win 1984 Reagan Mondale Win 1972 Nixon McGovern Win 1976 Carter Ford Win 1956 Eisenhower Stevenson Win Conclusion Although there is a wide range in our estimates of the annual discount rate that voters apply to presidential elections, the average estimated 59% annual discount rate for prior economic growth in presidential elections is quite high but somewhat lower than the 79% discount rate estimated by Figlio (2000) for prior ADA scores in Senate elections. Our study thus provides additional evidence on the but what have you done for me lately phenomenon, as well as confirming a large literature that has found that incumbent parties benefit from strong economic growth. We have extended Zupan s (1992) series on presidential ADA scores by 11 years to 2000 and have combined them with presidential candidates congressional and estimated gubernatorial ADA scores and Nominate scores to examine the influence of spatial voting records on which candidate wins the party s nomination for president and on which nominee wins the general election. The only other statistical analyses of multiple presidential general elections from a spatial perspective rely on subjective estimates of how liberal each nominee was, which may be biased by hindsight. No one appears to have studied the role that spatial position plays in how parties select their candidates for president over multiple elections. We examined the success of 17 Republican candidates in 5 elections and of 38 Democratic candidates in 8 elections. Although moderate candidates do better in the general elections, parties favor extremists in the nomination process.

19 457 Based on indexed ADA scores, the most conservative Republican candidate won each of the five nominations. For Democrats, the winning primary position is slightly more moderate (e.g., an average indexed ADA score of 78). Democratic candidates with more liberal or more moderate records than this are less likely to win the nomination. These results are inconsistent with the lack of pattern for winners in Cooper and Munger s simulations based on random entry in 10 candidate races; this inconsistency could be due to entry not being random or there being far fewer than 10 effective candidates. Our study of 12 general elections for president found that the presidential nominees spatial voting records have an important impact on the outcome of presidential elections. The evidence is mixed on whether a nominee fares better with a record that is close to the median voter s position or with one that is close to his winning party position. Half the regressions found that the median voter s position maximizes the nominee s success. In the other half of the regressions, the winning party positions are 11 points apart on average, which is much smaller than the typical distances that separates party voting records for presidents and members of Congress. Indeed only one of each party s nominees was between his party s winning general election position and the median voter s position. The 11 other nominees in each party were either Republicans who were more conservative than the winning Republican position or Democrats who were more liberal than the winning Democratic position. The relationship between the nominees ideological positions and electoral success is remarkable. Based on indexed ADA scores, the nominee who was closer to the median voter s position won 10 of the 12 elections. And the two misclassified elections were those in which the difference between nominee distances from the winning position was the smallest (1996 and 1960). The relative distance from the winning position is highly significant in explaining the incumbent party s vote share and whether the incumbent party won the election. Spatial position is an important factor in determining the outcome of presidential elections. It has nearly as much impact as economic growth, which has been the focus of much of the empirical research in this area. Our results differ sharply from those of Alvarez and Nagler (1995, 1998), who in their case studies of the 1992 and 1996 U.S. presidential elections found that perceptions about the economy overshadowed perceptions about policy positions in determining voting behavior. Thus, we have found that the nomination process selects candidates who in 11 of 12 elections were more extreme (i.e., more liberal for Democrats and more conservative for Republicans) than the winning party position in the general election. More moderate candidates would have had greater success in the general election. This outcome may be due to the two stage electoral process. In the theoretical literature, if there is some uncertainty about the general election outcome, the Democratic party s median primary voter, for

20 458 example, trades off having a more moderate candidate who is farther from her preferred ideology against that candidate s higher probability of winning the general election. As a result, she may maximize her expected utility by selecting a candidate who is more liberal than the median voter in the general election. 22 Therefore, our findings that party nominees diverge from the median voter s position and that more moderate nominees fare better in the general election are consistent with this set of models. Party primaries pull the nominees away from the winning general election party position. On the other hand, these two stage models are unable to explain Schmidt et al. (1996) finding for U.S. senators and our finding in half the regressions for presidential candidates that candidates who are too moderate are less likely to win. Adams and Merrill (2003a) suggest that this result could be due to a loss of votes from party loyalists caused by alienation as parties converge. This study also provides a comparison of the performance of three prominent ideological measures in explaining the outcomes of presidential primaries and general elections. Each outperforms the other two measures in some context. But the best overall measure is the indexed ADA scores (Groseclose et al., 1999), which are comparable across chambers and over time. This measure produces a better fit than the other two in explaining which candidate wins the Republican primary, which party wins the general election, and the candidate s vote share in the Democratic primary. The modified ADA scores are the best measure for determining who wins the Democratic primary and the vote share in the Republican primary (under one specification). Poole and Rosenthal s Nominate scores beat out the other two ideology variables in explaining the incumbent party s vote share in the general election and the vote share in the Republican primary (under another specification). Acknowledgments We have benefited from comments received at the 2001 Public Choice meetings and at the 2001 Southern Economic Association meetings. We are especially grateful to James F. Adams, Robert Emerson, Bernard Grofman, Rebecca Morton, Ben Russo, Donald Wittman and an anonymous referee for their help. Notes 1. See, for example, Enelow and Hinich (1984). 2. Huntington (1950), Fiorina (1974), Fenno (1977), and Peltzman (1984) were among the most vocal critics of the median voter model, arguing that divergent platforms were needed to adequately explain political behavior. 3. See Johannes and McAdams (1981), Glazer and Robbins (1985), Abramowitz (1988), Westlye (1991), Wright (1993), Goff and Grier (1993), and Figlio (2000).

21 See Bullock and Brady (1983), Peltzman (1984), Wright (1989), Grofman, Griffin, and Glazer (1990), Shapiro, Brady, Brody, and Ferejohn (1990), Poole and Rosenthal (1991), Jung, Kenny, and Lott (1994), and Francis and Kenny (2000). 5. See Whitby and Bledsoe (1986) and Schmidt et al. (1996). 6. Keech (1995) summarizes this literature. See also Peltzman (1990), Hibbs (2000), and Bartels and Zaller (2001). 7. There is a larger empirical spatial literature that uses survey data on perceived candidate positions and voter preferences for individual elections. Enelow and Hinich (1984), Poole and Rosenthal (1984), Erikson and Romero (1990), Alvarez and Nagler (1995, 1998), Adams and Merrill (1999, 2000, 2003b), Alvarez, Nagler, and Bowler (2000), and Alvarez, Nagler, and Willette (2000) describe candidate location, explain voting behavior, and explore the electoral implications of changes in the candidates policy positions. 8. See Poole and Rosenthal (1991). 9. In related research, Jenkins and Sala (1998) found that spatial positions were quite successful in explaining the House vote for presidential candidates in 1825 after no candidate won amajority in the Electoral College in Note that the set of votes used for the House and Senate are somewhat different, reflecting what votes were taken in these two chambers. Also, as indicated, the presidential ADA scores pertain only to those House and Senate ADA votes for which a presidential stance was noted in Congressional Quarterly Almanac. 11. This avoids classifying Ted Kennedy as a conservative in 1980 when he missed 12 of the 18 votes used by the ADA as he ran for President. The ADA gave him a 33 rating, but our modified ADA score for him is Johnson s career indexed ADA score as president (76) was much more liberal than his Senate record (50) but somewhat more conservative than his indexed ADA score in 1964 (82). 13. Earlier scores are used for candidates who had not been in Congress for several years, such as Nixon in the 1960, 1964, and 1968 elections. 14. During this period, as Georgia experienced a transition from a solidly Democratic state to atwo party state, its Democratic senators became much more liberal. Their average ADA scores for is used for Carter s 1976 presidential bid, but this average is still well below his subsequent ADA score as president. 15. Note that under these criteria Eugene McCarthy barely qualifies as a candidate for the Republican nomination in 1968, since he received 1.0% of votes cast over all the Republican primaries, obtaining a sizeable number of votes in six primaries. Write-in votes for him accounted for % of the Republican votes in Nebraska, New Jersey, and Oregon and for % of the Republican votes in Massachusetts, New Hampshire, and Pennsylvania. Source: Congressional Quarterly (1997). 16. The Republican candidates were 1964: Goldwater, Lodge, Nixon, Rockefeller, Scranton, Smith; 1968: Nixon, McCarthy (see footnote 15), Reagan, Rockefeller; 1980: Anderson, G.H. Bush, Reagan; 1996: Alexander, Dole; 2000: G.W. Bush, McCain. The Democratic candidates were 1952: Kefauver, Russell, Stevenson; 1956: Kefauver, Stevenson; 1960: Humphrey, Kennedy, Morse; 1972: Chisholm, Humphrey, Jackson, McCarthy, McGovern, Muskie, Sanford, Wallace; 1976: Brown, R.C. Byrd, Carter, Church, Harris, Jackson, Udall, Wallace; 1984: Glenn, Hart, McGovern, Mondale; 1988: Dukakis, Gephardt, Gore, Hart, Simon; 1992: Brown, Clinton, Harkin, Kerrey, Tsongas. 17. Similar probits explaining which candidate wins the nomination and later whether the incumbent party s nominee wins the general election are not reported because probit (or logit) in several specifications paradoxically is unable to produce an estimate of the impact of the candidate s voting record when the voting record perfectly or nearly perfectly

Explaining Variation in the Degree of Electoral Competition in a Mature Democracy: U.S. Senate Elections, *

Explaining Variation in the Degree of Electoral Competition in a Mature Democracy: U.S. Senate Elections, * This is a work in progress. Please do not cite. Comments are welcome. Explaining Variation in the Degree of Electoral Competition in a Mature Democracy: U.S. Senate Elections, 1922 2005* Stanley L. Winer

More information

Amy Tenhouse. Incumbency Surge: Examining the 1996 Margin of Victory for U.S. House Incumbents

Amy Tenhouse. Incumbency Surge: Examining the 1996 Margin of Victory for U.S. House Incumbents Amy Tenhouse Incumbency Surge: Examining the 1996 Margin of Victory for U.S. House Incumbents In 1996, the American public reelected 357 members to the United States House of Representatives; of those

More information

A positive correlation between turnout and plurality does not refute the rational voter model

A positive correlation between turnout and plurality does not refute the rational voter model Quality & Quantity 26: 85-93, 1992. 85 O 1992 Kluwer Academic Publishers. Printed in the Netherlands. Note A positive correlation between turnout and plurality does not refute the rational voter model

More information

Pavel Yakovlev Duquesne University. Abstract

Pavel Yakovlev Duquesne University. Abstract Ideology, Shirking, and the Incumbency Advantage in the U.S. House of Representatives Pavel Yakovlev Duquesne University Abstract This paper examines how the incumbency advantage is related to ideological

More information

What is The Probability Your Vote will Make a Difference?

What is The Probability Your Vote will Make a Difference? Berkeley Law From the SelectedWorks of Aaron Edlin 2009 What is The Probability Your Vote will Make a Difference? Andrew Gelman, Columbia University Nate Silver Aaron S. Edlin, University of California,

More information

Changes in the location of the median voter in the U.S. House of Representatives,

Changes in the location of the median voter in the U.S. House of Representatives, Public Choice 106: 221 232, 2001. 2001 Kluwer Academic Publishers. Printed in the Netherlands. 221 Changes in the location of the median voter in the U.S. House of Representatives, 1963 1996 BERNARD GROFMAN

More information

Res Publica 29. Literature Review

Res Publica 29. Literature Review Res Publica 29 Greg Crowe and Elizabeth Ann Eberspacher Partisanship and Constituency Influences on Congressional Roll-Call Voting Behavior in the US House This research examines the factors that influence

More information

Changes in Party Identification among U.S. Adult Catholics in CARA Polls, % 48% 39% 41% 38% 30% 37% 31%

Changes in Party Identification among U.S. Adult Catholics in CARA Polls, % 48% 39% 41% 38% 30% 37% 31% The Center for Applied Research in the Apostolate Georgetown University June 20, 2008 Election 08 Forecast: Democrats Have Edge among U.S. Catholics The Catholic electorate will include more than 47 million

More information

AVOTE FOR PEROT WAS A VOTE FOR THE STATUS QUO

AVOTE FOR PEROT WAS A VOTE FOR THE STATUS QUO AVOTE FOR PEROT WAS A VOTE FOR THE STATUS QUO William A. Niskanen In 1992 Ross Perot received more votes than any prior third party candidate for president, and the vote for Perot in 1996 was only slightly

More information

A spatial model of U.S. Senate elections

A spatial model of U.S. Senate elections Public Choice 118: 87 103, 2004. 2004 Kluwer Academic Publishers. Printed in the Netherlands. 87 A spatial model of U.S. Senate elections JAC C. HECKELMAN Wake Forest University, Winston-Salem, NC 27109,

More information

Political Economics II Spring Lectures 4-5 Part II Partisan Politics and Political Agency. Torsten Persson, IIES

Political Economics II Spring Lectures 4-5 Part II Partisan Politics and Political Agency. Torsten Persson, IIES Lectures 4-5_190213.pdf Political Economics II Spring 2019 Lectures 4-5 Part II Partisan Politics and Political Agency Torsten Persson, IIES 1 Introduction: Partisan Politics Aims continue exploring policy

More information

A Media-Based Measure of Presidential Candidate Ideology

A Media-Based Measure of Presidential Candidate Ideology A Media-Based Measure of Presidential Candidate Ideology Gregory A. Caldeira Ohio State University caldeira.1@osu.edu Christopher Zorn Pennsylvania State University zorn@psu.edu Version 2.1 September 12,

More information

The Fundamentals in US Presidential Elections: Public Opinion, the Economy and Incumbency in the 2004 Presidential Election

The Fundamentals in US Presidential Elections: Public Opinion, the Economy and Incumbency in the 2004 Presidential Election Journal of Elections, Public Opinion and Parties Vol. 15, No. 1, 73 83, April 2005 The Fundamentals in US Presidential Elections: Public Opinion, the Economy and Incumbency in the 2004 Presidential Election

More information

How did third parties affect US Presidential Campaigns since 1900? By Tom Hyndman 9E

How did third parties affect US Presidential Campaigns since 1900? By Tom Hyndman 9E How did third parties affect US Presidential Campaigns since 1900? By Tom Hyndman 9E Independent Candidates in the United States since 1900 Introduction In the United States since 1900 a few candidates

More information

Comparing Floor-Dominated and Party-Dominated Explanations of Policy Change in the House of Representatives

Comparing Floor-Dominated and Party-Dominated Explanations of Policy Change in the House of Representatives Comparing Floor-Dominated and Party-Dominated Explanations of Policy Change in the House of Representatives Cary R. Covington University of Iowa Andrew A. Bargen University of Iowa We test two explanations

More information

Guns and Butter in U.S. Presidential Elections

Guns and Butter in U.S. Presidential Elections Guns and Butter in U.S. Presidential Elections by Stephen E. Haynes and Joe A. Stone September 20, 2004 Working Paper No. 91 Department of Economics, University of Oregon Abstract: Previous models of the

More information

Following the Leader: The Impact of Presidential Campaign Visits on Legislative Support for the President's Policy Preferences

Following the Leader: The Impact of Presidential Campaign Visits on Legislative Support for the President's Policy Preferences University of Colorado, Boulder CU Scholar Undergraduate Honors Theses Honors Program Spring 2011 Following the Leader: The Impact of Presidential Campaign Visits on Legislative Support for the President's

More information

Change in the Components of the Electoral Decision. Herbert F. Weisberg The Ohio State University. May 2, 2008 version

Change in the Components of the Electoral Decision. Herbert F. Weisberg The Ohio State University. May 2, 2008 version Change in the Components of the Electoral Decision Herbert F. Weisberg The Ohio State University May 2, 2008 version Prepared for presentation at the Shambaugh Conference on The American Voter: Change

More information

DATA ANALYSIS USING SETUPS AND SPSS: AMERICAN VOTING BEHAVIOR IN PRESIDENTIAL ELECTIONS

DATA ANALYSIS USING SETUPS AND SPSS: AMERICAN VOTING BEHAVIOR IN PRESIDENTIAL ELECTIONS Poli 300 Handout B N. R. Miller DATA ANALYSIS USING SETUPS AND SPSS: AMERICAN VOTING BEHAVIOR IN IDENTIAL ELECTIONS 1972-2004 The original SETUPS: AMERICAN VOTING BEHAVIOR IN IDENTIAL ELECTIONS 1972-1992

More information

Should the Democrats move to the left on economic policy?

Should the Democrats move to the left on economic policy? Should the Democrats move to the left on economic policy? Andrew Gelman Cexun Jeffrey Cai November 9, 2007 Abstract Could John Kerry have gained votes in the recent Presidential election by more clearly

More information

Retrospective Voting

Retrospective Voting Retrospective Voting Who Are Retrospective Voters and Does it Matter if the Incumbent President is Running Kaitlin Franks Senior Thesis In Economics Adviser: Richard Ball 4/30/2009 Abstract Prior literature

More information

SHOULD THE DEMOCRATS MOVE TO THE LEFT ON ECONOMIC POLICY? By Andrew Gelman and Cexun Jeffrey Cai Columbia University

SHOULD THE DEMOCRATS MOVE TO THE LEFT ON ECONOMIC POLICY? By Andrew Gelman and Cexun Jeffrey Cai Columbia University Submitted to the Annals of Applied Statistics SHOULD THE DEMOCRATS MOVE TO THE LEFT ON ECONOMIC POLICY? By Andrew Gelman and Cexun Jeffrey Cai Columbia University Could John Kerry have gained votes in

More information

IDEOLOGY. Paul H. Rubin

IDEOLOGY. Paul H. Rubin IDEOLOGY Paul H. Rubin Correspondence: Paul H. Rubin Department of Economics Emory University Atlanta, GA 30322 (404) 727-6365 prubin@emory.edu Forthcoming in in William F. Shughart II and Laura Razzolini,

More information

Forecasting Elections: Voter Intentions versus Expectations *

Forecasting Elections: Voter Intentions versus Expectations * Forecasting Elections: Voter Intentions versus Expectations * David Rothschild Yahoo! Research David@ReseachDMR.com www.researchdmr.com Justin Wolfers The Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania Brookings,

More information

Midterm Elections Used to Gauge President s Reelection Chances

Midterm Elections Used to Gauge President s Reelection Chances 90 Midterm Elections Used to Gauge President s Reelection Chances --Desmond Wallace-- Desmond Wallace is currently studying at Coastal Carolina University for a Bachelor s degree in both political science

More information

The Interdependence of Sequential Senate Elections: Evidence from

The Interdependence of Sequential Senate Elections: Evidence from The Interdependence of Sequential Senate Elections: Evidence from 1946-2002 Daniel M. Butler Stanford University Department of Political Science September 27, 2004 Abstract Among U.S. federal elections,

More information

The Senator s Strategic Use of Time in Representation

The Senator s Strategic Use of Time in Representation Journal of Power, Politics & Governance June 2017, Vol. 5, No. 1, pp. 29-45 ISSN: 2372-4919 (Print), 2372-4927 (Online) Copyright The Author(s). All Rights Reserved. Published by American Research Institute

More information

The Conditional Nature of Presidential Responsiveness to Public Opinion * Brandice Canes-Wrone Kenneth W. Shotts. January 8, 2003

The Conditional Nature of Presidential Responsiveness to Public Opinion * Brandice Canes-Wrone Kenneth W. Shotts. January 8, 2003 The Conditional Nature of Presidential Responsiveness to Public Opinion * Brandice Canes-Wrone Kenneth W. Shotts January 8, 2003 * For helpful comments we thank Mike Alvarez, Jeff Cohen, Bill Keech, Dave

More information

Forecasting the 2012 U.S. Presidential Election: Should we Have Known Obama Would Win All Along?

Forecasting the 2012 U.S. Presidential Election: Should we Have Known Obama Would Win All Along? Forecasting the 2012 U.S. Presidential Election: Should we Have Known Obama Would Win All Along? Robert S. Erikson Columbia University Keynote Address IDC Conference on The Presidential Election of 2012:

More information

Chapter Four: Chamber Competitiveness, Political Polarization, and Political Parties

Chapter Four: Chamber Competitiveness, Political Polarization, and Political Parties Chapter Four: Chamber Competitiveness, Political Polarization, and Political Parties Building off of the previous chapter in this dissertation, this chapter investigates the involvement of political parties

More information

Macroeconomics and Presidential Elections

Macroeconomics and Presidential Elections Macroeconomics and Presidential Elections WEEKLY MARKET UPDATE JUNE 28, 2011 With the start of July, it s now just 16 months until we have our next presidential election in the United States. Republican

More information

Components of party polarization in the US House of Representatives

Components of party polarization in the US House of Representatives Article Components of party polarization in the US House of Representatives Journal of Theoretical Politics 1 27 ÓThe Author(s) 215 Reprints and permissions: sagepub.co.uk/journalspermissions.nav DOI:

More information

Working Paper: The Effect of Electronic Voting Machines on Change in Support for Bush in the 2004 Florida Elections

Working Paper: The Effect of Electronic Voting Machines on Change in Support for Bush in the 2004 Florida Elections Working Paper: The Effect of Electronic Voting Machines on Change in Support for Bush in the 2004 Florida Elections Michael Hout, Laura Mangels, Jennifer Carlson, Rachel Best With the assistance of the

More information

Primary Elections and Candidate Ideology: Out of Step with the Primary Electorate?

Primary Elections and Candidate Ideology: Out of Step with the Primary Electorate? Primary Elections and Candidate Ideology 79 DAVID W. BRADY Stanford University HAHRIE HAN Wellesley College JEREMY C. POPE Brigham Young University Primary Elections and Candidate Ideology: Out of Step

More information

Presidents and The US Economy: An Econometric Exploration. Working Paper July 2014

Presidents and The US Economy: An Econometric Exploration. Working Paper July 2014 Presidents and The US Economy: An Econometric Exploration Working Paper 20324 July 2014 Introduction An extensive and well-known body of scholarly research documents and explores the fact that macroeconomic

More information

The Case of the Disappearing Bias: A 2014 Update to the Gerrymandering or Geography Debate

The Case of the Disappearing Bias: A 2014 Update to the Gerrymandering or Geography Debate The Case of the Disappearing Bias: A 2014 Update to the Gerrymandering or Geography Debate Nicholas Goedert Lafayette College goedertn@lafayette.edu May, 2015 ABSTRACT: This note observes that the pro-republican

More information

DOES GERRYMANDERING VIOLATE THE FOURTEENTH AMENDMENT?: INSIGHT FROM THE MEDIAN VOTER THEOREM

DOES GERRYMANDERING VIOLATE THE FOURTEENTH AMENDMENT?: INSIGHT FROM THE MEDIAN VOTER THEOREM DOES GERRYMANDERING VIOLATE THE FOURTEENTH AMENDMENT?: INSIGHT FROM THE MEDIAN VOTER THEOREM Craig B. McLaren University of California, Riverside Abstract This paper argues that gerrymandering understood

More information

Randall S. Kroszner Graduate School of Business University of Chicago Chicago, IL and N.B.E.R. and

Randall S. Kroszner Graduate School of Business University of Chicago Chicago, IL and N.B.E.R. and DOES POLITICAL AMBIGUITY PAY? CORPORATE CAMPAIGN CONTRIBUTIONS AND THE REWARDS TO LEGISLATOR REPUTATION* Randall S. Kroszner Graduate School of Business University of Chicago Chicago, IL 60637 and N.B.E.R.

More information

Supplementary Materials A: Figures for All 7 Surveys Figure S1-A: Distribution of Predicted Probabilities of Voting in Primary Elections

Supplementary Materials A: Figures for All 7 Surveys Figure S1-A: Distribution of Predicted Probabilities of Voting in Primary Elections Supplementary Materials (Online), Supplementary Materials A: Figures for All 7 Surveys Figure S-A: Distribution of Predicted Probabilities of Voting in Primary Elections (continued on next page) UT Republican

More information

Report for the Associated Press: Illinois and Georgia Election Studies in November 2014

Report for the Associated Press: Illinois and Georgia Election Studies in November 2014 Report for the Associated Press: Illinois and Georgia Election Studies in November 2014 Randall K. Thomas, Frances M. Barlas, Linda McPetrie, Annie Weber, Mansour Fahimi, & Robert Benford GfK Custom Research

More information

Julie Lenggenhager. The "Ideal" Female Candidate

Julie Lenggenhager. The Ideal Female Candidate Julie Lenggenhager The "Ideal" Female Candidate Why are there so few women elected to positions in both gubernatorial and senatorial contests? Since the ratification of the nineteenth amendment in 1920

More information

Electoral College Reform: Evaluation and Policy Recommendations

Electoral College Reform: Evaluation and Policy Recommendations Electoral College Reform: Evaluation and Policy Recommendations Albert Qian, Alex Hider, Amanda Khan, Caroline Reisch, Madeline Goossen, and Araksya Nordikyan Research Question What are alternative ways

More information

1. The Relationship Between Party Control, Latino CVAP and the Passage of Bills Benefitting Immigrants

1. The Relationship Between Party Control, Latino CVAP and the Passage of Bills Benefitting Immigrants The Ideological and Electoral Determinants of Laws Targeting Undocumented Migrants in the U.S. States Online Appendix In this additional methodological appendix I present some alternative model specifications

More information

Author(s) Title Date Dataset(s) Abstract

Author(s) Title Date Dataset(s) Abstract Author(s): Traugott, Michael Title: Memo to Pilot Study Committee: Understanding Campaign Effects on Candidate Recall and Recognition Date: February 22, 1990 Dataset(s): 1988 National Election Study, 1989

More information

WISCONSIN SUPREME COURT ELECTIONS WITH PARTISANSHIP

WISCONSIN SUPREME COURT ELECTIONS WITH PARTISANSHIP The Increasing Correlation of WISCONSIN SUPREME COURT ELECTIONS WITH PARTISANSHIP A Statistical Analysis BY CHARLES FRANKLIN Whatever the technically nonpartisan nature of the elections, has the structure

More information

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at Economics, Entitlements, and Social Issues: Voter Choice in the 1996 Presidential Election Author(s): R. Michael Alvarez and Jonathan Nagler Source: American Journal of Political Science, Vol. 42, No.

More information

Federal Primary Election Runoffs and Voter Turnout Decline,

Federal Primary Election Runoffs and Voter Turnout Decline, Federal Primary Election Runoffs and Voter Turnout Decline, 1994-2010 July 2011 By: Katherine Sicienski, William Hix, and Rob Richie Summary of Facts and Findings Near-Universal Decline in Turnout: Of

More information

Determinants of legislative success in House committees*

Determinants of legislative success in House committees* Public Choice 74: 233-243, 1992. 1992 Kluwer Academic Publishers. Printed in the Netherlands. Research note Determinants of legislative success in House committees* SCOTT J. THOMAS BERNARD GROFMAN School

More information

Partisan Nation: The Rise of Affective Partisan Polarization in the American Electorate

Partisan Nation: The Rise of Affective Partisan Polarization in the American Electorate Partisan Nation: The Rise of Affective Partisan Polarization in the American Electorate Alan I. Abramowitz Department of Political Science Emory University Abstract Partisan conflict has reached new heights

More information

Methodology. 1 State benchmarks are from the American Community Survey Three Year averages

Methodology. 1 State benchmarks are from the American Community Survey Three Year averages The Choice is Yours Comparing Alternative Likely Voter Models within Probability and Non-Probability Samples By Robert Benford, Randall K Thomas, Jennifer Agiesta, Emily Swanson Likely voter models often

More information

Does Primary Parity Lead to the Presidency?

Does Primary Parity Lead to the Presidency? Does Primary Parity Lead to the Presidency? By Kevin Carter Professor James Lengle 12/4/2009 An Unprecedented Primary On June 2, 2008, then-senator Barack Obama pushed past the minimum 2,118 delegates

More information

Cross-District Variation in Split-Ticket Voting

Cross-District Variation in Split-Ticket Voting Cross-District Variation in Split-Ticket Voting Daniel J. Lee Robert Lupton Department of Political Science Michigan State University January 10, 2014 Abstract We test hypotheses on split-ticket voting

More information

THE EFFECT OF EARLY VOTING AND THE LENGTH OF EARLY VOTING ON VOTER TURNOUT

THE EFFECT OF EARLY VOTING AND THE LENGTH OF EARLY VOTING ON VOTER TURNOUT THE EFFECT OF EARLY VOTING AND THE LENGTH OF EARLY VOTING ON VOTER TURNOUT Simona Altshuler University of Florida Email: simonaalt@ufl.edu Advisor: Dr. Lawrence Kenny Abstract This paper explores the effects

More information

Segal and Howard also constructed a social liberalism score (see Segal & Howard 1999).

Segal and Howard also constructed a social liberalism score (see Segal & Howard 1999). APPENDIX A: Ideology Scores for Judicial Appointees For a very long time, a judge s own partisan affiliation 1 has been employed as a useful surrogate of ideology (Segal & Spaeth 1990). The approach treats

More information

Supporting Information for Signaling and Counter-Signaling in the Judicial Hierarchy: An Empirical Analysis of En Banc Review

Supporting Information for Signaling and Counter-Signaling in the Judicial Hierarchy: An Empirical Analysis of En Banc Review Supporting Information for Signaling and Counter-Signaling in the Judicial Hierarchy: An Empirical Analysis of En Banc Review In this appendix, we: explain our case selection procedures; Deborah Beim Alexander

More information

The Job of President and the Jobs Model Forecast: Obama for '08?

The Job of President and the Jobs Model Forecast: Obama for '08? Department of Political Science Publications 10-1-2008 The Job of President and the Jobs Model Forecast: Obama for '08? Michael S. Lewis-Beck University of Iowa Charles Tien Copyright 2008 American Political

More information

Introduction. Midterm elections are elections in which the American electorate votes for all seats of the

Introduction. Midterm elections are elections in which the American electorate votes for all seats of the Wallace 1 Wallace 2 Introduction Midterm elections are elections in which the American electorate votes for all seats of the United States House of Representatives, approximately one-third of the seats

More information

FORECASTING THE 2012 ELECTION WITH THE FISCAL MODEL. Alfred G. Cuzán

FORECASTING THE 2012 ELECTION WITH THE FISCAL MODEL. Alfred G. Cuzán FORECASTING THE 2012 ELECTION WITH THE FISCAL MODEL Alfred G. Cuzán Prepared for presentation at a Bucharest Dialogue conference on Expert Knowledge, Prediction, Forecasting: A Social Sciences Perspective

More information

The Historical Experience of Experience: How and When Experience in a President Counts Charles O. Jones

The Historical Experience of Experience: How and When Experience in a President Counts Charles O. Jones Number 12 March 2008 Recent Issues in Governance Studies The Future of Red, Blue and Purple America (January 2008) The Politics of Economic Insecurity (September 2007) Shaping the 44th Presidency (August

More information

Reflection moderation in the U.S. Senate on Economics, Social, and Foreign Policy

Reflection moderation in the U.S. Senate on Economics, Social, and Foreign Policy University of Arkansas, Fayetteville ScholarWorks@UARK Theses and Dissertations 8-1998 Reflection moderation in the U.S. Senate on Economics, Social, and Foreign Policy Brian E. Russell University of Arkansas,

More information

ELECTIONS AND VOTING BEHAVIOR CHAPTER 10, Government in America

ELECTIONS AND VOTING BEHAVIOR CHAPTER 10, Government in America ELECTIONS AND VOTING BEHAVIOR CHAPTER 10, Government in America Page 1 of 6 I. HOW AMERICAN ELECTIONS WORK A. Elections serve many important functions in American society, including legitimizing the actions

More information

The Macro Polity Updated

The Macro Polity Updated The Macro Polity Updated Robert S Erikson Columbia University rse14@columbiaedu Michael B MacKuen University of North Carolina, Chapel Hill Mackuen@emailuncedu James A Stimson University of North Carolina,

More information

Attack Politics Negativity in Presidential Campaigns since 1960 by Emmett H. Buell, Jr. and Lee Sigelman

Attack Politics Negativity in Presidential Campaigns since 1960 by Emmett H. Buell, Jr. and Lee Sigelman Attack Politics Negativity in Presidential Campaigns since 1960 by Emmett H. Buell, Jr. and Lee Sigelman The study of several dimensions of presidential campaigns Degree of negativity Topics of campaign

More information

Party Platforms with Endogenous Party Membership

Party Platforms with Endogenous Party Membership Party Platforms with Endogenous Party Membership Panu Poutvaara 1 Harvard University, Department of Economics poutvaar@fas.harvard.edu Abstract In representative democracies, the development of party platforms

More information

A Vote Equation and the 2004 Election

A Vote Equation and the 2004 Election A Vote Equation and the 2004 Election Ray C. Fair November 22, 2004 1 Introduction My presidential vote equation is a great teaching example for introductory econometrics. 1 The theory is straightforward,

More information

Popular Vote. Total: 77,734, %

Popular Vote. Total: 77,734, % PRESIDENTIAL 72: A CASE STUDY The 1972 election, in contrast to the extremely close contest of 1968, resulted in a sweeping reelection victory for President Nixon and one of the most massive presidential

More information

Party Responsiveness and Mandate Balancing *

Party Responsiveness and Mandate Balancing * Party Responsiveness and Mandate Balancing * James Fowler Oleg Smirnov University of California, Davis University of Oregon May 05, 2005 Abstract Recent evidence suggests that parties are responsive to

More information

INTRODUCTION AND SUMMARY

INTRODUCTION AND SUMMARY Gender Parity Index INTRODUCTION AND SUMMARY - 2017 State of Women's Representation Page 1 INTRODUCTION As a result of the 2016 elections, progress towards gender parity stalled. Beyond Hillary Clinton

More information

Party, Constituency, and Constituents in the Process of Representation

Party, Constituency, and Constituents in the Process of Representation Party, Constituency, and Constituents in the Process of Representation Walter J. Stone Matthew Pietryka University of California, Davis For presentation at the Conference on the State of the Parties, University

More information

EXPLORING PARTISAN BIAS IN THE ELECTORAL COLLEGE,

EXPLORING PARTISAN BIAS IN THE ELECTORAL COLLEGE, WHS (2009) ISSN: 1535-4738 Volume 9, Issue 4, pp. 2010 Nova Science Publishers, Inc. EXPLORING PARTISAN BIAS IN THE ELECTORAL COLLEGE, 1964-2008 ABSTRACT The purpose of this work is to examine the sources

More information

DO VOTERS AFFECT OR ELECT POLICIES? EVIDENCE FROM THE U. S. HOUSE*

DO VOTERS AFFECT OR ELECT POLICIES? EVIDENCE FROM THE U. S. HOUSE* EVIDENCE FROM THE U. S. HOUSE* DAVID S. LEE ENRICO MORETTI MATTHEW J. BUTLER There are two fundamentally different views of the role of elections in policy formation. In one view, voters can affect candidates

More information

Faculty Working Papers

Faculty Working Papers Faculty Working Papers THE ACCURACY OF PRESIDENTIAL PREFERENCE PRIMARY POLLS Marcus Felcon and Seymour Sudmtm #196 College of Commerce and Business Administration University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign

More information

Campaign Finance Charges Raise Doubts Among 7% of Clinton Backers FINAL PEW CENTER SURVEY-CLINTON 52%, DOLE 38%, PEROT 9%

Campaign Finance Charges Raise Doubts Among 7% of Clinton Backers FINAL PEW CENTER SURVEY-CLINTON 52%, DOLE 38%, PEROT 9% FOR RELEASE: SUNDAY, NOVEMBER 3, 1996, 5:00 P.M. Campaign Finance Charges Raise Doubts Among 7% of Clinton Backers FINAL PEW CENTER SURVEY-CLINTON 52%, DOLE 38%, PEROT 9% FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT:

More information

FOR RELEASE: SUNDAY, OCTOBER 13, 1991, A.M.

FOR RELEASE: SUNDAY, OCTOBER 13, 1991, A.M. FOR RELEASE: SUNDAY, OCTOBER 13, 1991, A.M. Two In Three Want Candidates To Discuss Economic Issues "DON'T KNOW" LEADS KERREY IN EARLY DEMOCRATIC NOMINATION SWEEPS "Don't Know" leads in the early stages

More information

Supporting Information Political Quid Pro Quo Agreements: An Experimental Study

Supporting Information Political Quid Pro Quo Agreements: An Experimental Study Supporting Information Political Quid Pro Quo Agreements: An Experimental Study Jens Großer Florida State University and IAS, Princeton Ernesto Reuben Columbia University and IZA Agnieszka Tymula New York

More information

2008 AMERICAN PRESIDENTIAL ELECTIONS: AN OVERVIEW

2008 AMERICAN PRESIDENTIAL ELECTIONS: AN OVERVIEW Neslihan Kaptanoğlu TEPAV Foreign Policy Studies Program On November 4, 2008, the United States of America will hold its 55 th election for President and Vice President. Additionally, all 435 members of

More information

NEWS RELEASE. Poll Shows Tight Races Obama Leads Clinton. Democratic Primary Election Vote Intention for Obama & Clinton

NEWS RELEASE. Poll Shows Tight Races Obama Leads Clinton. Democratic Primary Election Vote Intention for Obama & Clinton NEWS RELEASE FOR IMMEDIATE RELEASE: April 18, 2008 Contact: Michael Wolf, Assistant Professor of Political Science, 260-481-6898 Andrew Downs, Assistant Professor of Political Science, 260-481-6691 Poll

More information

The Seventeenth Amendment, Senate Ideology, and the Growth of Government

The Seventeenth Amendment, Senate Ideology, and the Growth of Government The Seventeenth Amendment, Senate Ideology, and the Growth of Government Danko Tarabar College of Business and Economics 1601 University Ave, PO BOX 6025 West Virginia University Phone: 681-212-9983 datarabar@mix.wvu.edu

More information

THE 2008 ELECTION: 1 DAY TO GO October 31 November 2, 2008

THE 2008 ELECTION: 1 DAY TO GO October 31 November 2, 2008 CBS NEWS POLL For Release: Monday, November 3 rd, 2008 3:00 PM (EST) THE 2008 ELECTION: 1 DAY TO GO October 31 November 2, 2008 On the eve of the 2008 presidential election, the CBS News Poll finds the

More information

On the Causes and Consequences of Ballot Order Effects

On the Causes and Consequences of Ballot Order Effects Polit Behav (2013) 35:175 197 DOI 10.1007/s11109-011-9189-2 ORIGINAL PAPER On the Causes and Consequences of Ballot Order Effects Marc Meredith Yuval Salant Published online: 6 January 2012 Ó Springer

More information

CANDIDATE POSITIONING IN U.S. HOUSE ELECTIONS 1

CANDIDATE POSITIONING IN U.S. HOUSE ELECTIONS 1 CANIATE POSITIONING IN U.S. HOUSE ELECTIONS 1 Stephen Ansolabehere epartment of Political Science James M. Snyder, Jr. epartments of Political Science and Economics Charles Stewart, III epartment of Political

More information

Font Size: A A. Eric Maskin and Amartya Sen JANUARY 19, 2017 ISSUE. 1 of 7 2/21/ :01 AM

Font Size: A A. Eric Maskin and Amartya Sen JANUARY 19, 2017 ISSUE. 1 of 7 2/21/ :01 AM 1 of 7 2/21/2017 10:01 AM Font Size: A A Eric Maskin and Amartya Sen JANUARY 19, 2017 ISSUE Americans have been using essentially the same rules to elect presidents since the beginning of the Republic.

More information

Partisan Polarization in Presidential Support: The Electoral Connection. Gary C. Jacobson. University of California, San Diego

Partisan Polarization in Presidential Support: The Electoral Connection. Gary C. Jacobson. University of California, San Diego Partisan Polarization in Presidential Support: The Electoral Connection Gary C. Jacobson University of California, San Diego Prepared for delivery at the 22 Annual Meeting of the American Political Science

More information

The Case of the Disappearing Bias: A 2014 Update to the Gerrymandering or Geography Debate

The Case of the Disappearing Bias: A 2014 Update to the Gerrymandering or Geography Debate The Case of the Disappearing Bias: A 2014 Update to the Gerrymandering or Geography Debate Nicholas Goedert Lafayette College goedertn@lafayette.edu November, 2015 ABSTRACT: This note observes that the

More information

The US Economy: Are Republicans or Democrats Better?

The US Economy: Are Republicans or Democrats Better? The US Economy: Are Republicans or Democrats Better? Before one can address the title question, it is necessary to answer three preliminary questions: What period of time should be used in the comparison?

More information

Chapter 10 Elections and Campaigns

Chapter 10 Elections and Campaigns Chapter 10 Elections and Campaigns WHO GOVERNS? 1. How do American elections determine the kind of people who govern us? 2. What matters most in deciding who wins presidential and congressional elections?

More information

Classical papers: Osborbe and Slivinski (1996) and Besley and Coate (1997)

Classical papers: Osborbe and Slivinski (1996) and Besley and Coate (1997) The identity of politicians is endogenized Typical approach: any citizen may enter electoral competition at a cost. There is no pre-commitment on the platforms, and winner implements his or her ideal policy.

More information

The California Primary and Redistricting

The California Primary and Redistricting The California Primary and Redistricting This study analyzes what is the important impact of changes in the primary voting rules after a Congressional and Legislative Redistricting. Under a citizen s committee,

More information

Term Limits and Electoral Competitiveness: California's State Legislative Races

Term Limits and Electoral Competitiveness: California's State Legislative Races University of Chicago Law School Chicago Unbound Coase-Sandor Working Paper Series in Law and Economics Coase-Sandor Institute for Law and Economics 1997 Term Limits and Electoral Competitiveness: California's

More information

UC Davis UC Davis Previously Published Works

UC Davis UC Davis Previously Published Works UC Davis UC Davis Previously Published Works Title Constitutional design and 2014 senate election outcomes Permalink https://escholarship.org/uc/item/8kx5k8zk Journal Forum (Germany), 12(4) Authors Highton,

More information

BLISS INSTITUTE 2006 GENERAL ELECTION SURVEY

BLISS INSTITUTE 2006 GENERAL ELECTION SURVEY BLISS INSTITUTE 2006 GENERAL ELECTION SURVEY Ray C. Bliss Institute of Applied Politics The University of Akron Executive Summary The Bliss Institute 2006 General Election Survey finds Democrat Ted Strickland

More information

Analyzing presidential elections without incumbents. Alexander Slutsker. University of Maryland. I. Introduction

Analyzing presidential elections without incumbents. Alexander Slutsker. University of Maryland. I. Introduction Analyzing presidential elections without incumbents Alexander Slutsker University of Maryland I. Introduction As pundits and scholars analyze the upcoming 2008 presidential election, it is useful to examine

More information

Political Sophistication and Third-Party Voting in Recent Presidential Elections

Political Sophistication and Third-Party Voting in Recent Presidential Elections Political Sophistication and Third-Party Voting in Recent Presidential Elections Christopher N. Lawrence Department of Political Science Duke University April 3, 2006 Overview During the 1990s, minor-party

More information

TIME FOR A CHANGE? FORECASTING THE 2008 ELECTION Forecasts of the Primary Model

TIME FOR A CHANGE? FORECASTING THE 2008 ELECTION Forecasts of the Primary Model TIME FOR A CHANGE? FORECASTING THE 2008 ELECTION 2008 Forecasts of the Primary Model (Democratic Percentage of 2-Party Vote) (August 1, 2007) Democratic Candidate Republican Candidate Clinton Obama Edwards

More information

2012 FISCAL MODEL FAILURE: A PROBLEM OF MEASUREMENT? AN ASSESSMENT. Alfred G. Cuzán. The University of West Florida.

2012 FISCAL MODEL FAILURE: A PROBLEM OF MEASUREMENT? AN ASSESSMENT. Alfred G. Cuzán. The University of West Florida. 2012 FISCAL MODEL FAILURE: A PROBLEM OF MEASUREMENT? AN ASSESSMENT Alfred G. Cuzán The University of West Florida acuzan@uwf.edu November 20, 2012 Abstract The Fiscal Model forecast of the 2012 presidential

More information

An Overview Across the New Political Economy Literature. Abstract

An Overview Across the New Political Economy Literature. Abstract An Overview Across the New Political Economy Literature Luca Murrau Ministry of Economy and Finance - Rome Abstract This work presents a review of the literature on political process formation and the

More information

U.S. Circuit and District Court Nominations During President Trump s First Year in Office: Comparative Analysis with Recent Presidents

U.S. Circuit and District Court Nominations During President Trump s First Year in Office: Comparative Analysis with Recent Presidents U.S. Circuit and District Court Nominations During President Trump s First Year in Office: Comparative Analysis with Recent Presidents Barry J. McMillion Analyst in American National Government May 2,

More information

Research Statement. Jeffrey J. Harden. 2 Dissertation Research: The Dimensions of Representation

Research Statement. Jeffrey J. Harden. 2 Dissertation Research: The Dimensions of Representation Research Statement Jeffrey J. Harden 1 Introduction My research agenda includes work in both quantitative methodology and American politics. In methodology I am broadly interested in developing and evaluating

More information

A Record Shortfall in Personal Popularity Challenges Romney in the Race Ahead

A Record Shortfall in Personal Popularity Challenges Romney in the Race Ahead ABC NEWS/WASHINGTON POST POLL: Favorability #23 EMBARGOED FOR RELEASE AFTER 5 p.m. Monday, April 16, 2012 A Record Shortfall in Personal Popularity Challenges Romney in the Race Ahead Mitt Romney has emerged

More information

The Effect of Electoral Geography on Competitive Elections and Partisan Gerrymandering

The Effect of Electoral Geography on Competitive Elections and Partisan Gerrymandering The Effect of Electoral Geography on Competitive Elections and Partisan Gerrymandering Jowei Chen University of Michigan jowei@umich.edu http://www.umich.edu/~jowei November 12, 2012 Abstract: How does

More information