Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at"

Transcription

1 The Emergence of a Market Society: Changing Mechanisms of Stratification in China Author(s): Victor Nee Source: American Journal of Sociology, Vol. 101, No. 4 (Jan., 1996), pp Published by: The University of Chicago Press Stable URL: Accessed: :47 UTC JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org. Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at The University of Chicago Press is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to American Journal of Sociology

2 SYMPOSIUM ON MARKET TRANSITION The Emergence of a Market Society: Changing Mechanisms of Stratification in China' Victor Nee Cornell University This article examines the effect of institutional change-the shift from redistribution to markets-in altering the mechanisms of stratification. New institutionalists maintain that interests are embedded ip institutional arrangements and change as institutions change. China has undergone rapid and extensive household income mobility, incrementally altering the stratification order based on socialist redistribution. The shift to markets causes a decline in the significance of positional power based on redistribution relative to the gains of producers and entrepreneurs. Comparative institutional analysis is employed to examine the effect of regional variation in the extent of institutional change. The emergence of a market society in China provides a rare natural experiment involving change in the stratification order on a scale reminiscent of that experienced in the West during the rise of capitalism. Comparative stratification research builds on modernization theory in assuming that industrial development, whether socialist or capitalist, leads to convergence (Lipset and Zetterberg 1959; Treiman 1970; Grusky and 1 The research for this paper was funded by a grant from the National Science Fo dation (SES ). I also wish to express appreciation of the Russell Sage Foundation, which supported work on this article during my year in residence as a visiting scholar, I am grateful to Chen Junshi and T. Colin Campbell for the data set used in this study. Special thanks to Raymond L. Liedka and Rebecca Matthews for research assistance and comments. Deborah Davis, Rachel Davis, Nan Lin, Robert K. Merton, William L. Parish, Jimy M. Sanders, Andrew G. Walder, Yu Xie, and AJS reviewers provided helpful criticism and comments. An earlier draft was presented at the Eighty-eighth Annual Meeting of the American Sociological Association in Miami, Florida, August 13-16, 1993, and at the Tianjin Academy of Social Sciences, August 24-26, Direct correspondence to Victor Nee, Department of Sociology, Cornell University, Ithaca, New York vgnl@cornell.edu?) 1996 by The University of Chicago. Ali rights reserved /96/ $ AJS Volume 101 Number 4 (January 1996):

3 Symposium: Nee Hauser 1984; Hauser and Grusky 1988). Institutional theorists, however, are skeptical about theories of convergence. If convergence pointed the way to state socialism's future, the sweeping measures to institute a market economy in industrially developed Eastern Europe and the former Soviet Union would not have been necessary. Rather than focusing on the effects of industrial growth, institutionalists insist that research on state socialism needs also to take into account underlying differences in institutional forms. Such a focus on alternative institutional forms that provide a deep structure for economic action underlies my argument that the shift from redistribution to markets gives rise to different mechanisms of stratification. New institutionalist theory in sociology maintains that institutions shape the structure of incentives and thereby establish the constraints within which rational actors identify and pursue their interests (Nee and Ingram, in press; Cook and Levi 1990). It builds on Polanyi's (1944; North 1977, 1981) insight that economies are embedded in definite institutional arrangements. In Polanyi's view, the problem with neoclassical economics is that its formal models assume the existence of a market economy. Yet comparative studies of human societies, past and present, have demonstrated a variety of institutional forms giving rise to economies organized around fundamentally different operating principles (Polanyi 1957). Hence, the movement of goods and services in an economy is not simply a product of the aggregation of individual maximizing behavior as assumed in neoclassical economics. In societies integrated by redistribution, goods and services are collected and distributed from a center in accordance with the customs, regulation, ideology, and ad hoc decisions of those social groups that hold redistributive power. Producers pass on a larger share of the economic surplus to the state precisely because they have less bargaining power over the terms of exchange than in a market economy. Instead, the state requisitions their products and compels them to work for prices and wages fixed by central bureaus (Szelenyi 1978). As a consequence, the institutional logic of redistributive economies differs substantively from market economies where goods and services are exchanged directly between buyer and seller (Polanyi 1957; Kornai 1980), and from economies based on reciprocity where trust and cooperation in local social orders allow for balanced exchange (Homans 1950; Sahlins 1972). Redistribution, market, and reciprocity, as alternative institutional forms, incorporate different structures of incentives and constraints and therefore distinct parameters of choice. Elements of each coexist in every society, at various levels, but Polanyi claimed that only one can constitute the dominant integrative mechanism of an economy. It is not narrowly economic but is embedded in customs, social norms, laws, regulations, and the state. Fundamentally, differences in institu- 909

4 American Journal of Sociology tional framework are reflected in contrasting structures of property rights (Pryor 1973; Eggertsson 1990). The transition from one institutional form to another entails remaking the fundamental rules that shape economies, from formal regulations and laws to informal conventions and norms. The shift to markets-well underway but far from complete in China-involves changing structures of opportunity (Merton 1949). Whereas opportunities for advancement were previously centered solely on decisions made by the redistributive bureaucracy and within the economy controlled by it, markets open up alternative avenues for mobility through emergent entrepreneurship and labor markets. Under conditions of expanding markets, economic actors strive to institute new rules of competition and cooperation that serve their interests, both through informal arrangements and through formal institutional channel.s. This entails efforts to change the structure of property rights in a manner that enables entrepreneurs and producers to capture a greater proportion of the economic surplus, previously transferred to the state by administrative fiat. Political actors contribute to instituting change in the formal rules of the game insofar as gains in productivity increase revenues to the state (North 1981). Such action at the margins is cumulative and gradually results in transformation of the institutional environment. Market transition theory (Nee 1989, 1991, 1992; Nee and Lian 1994) maintains that as power-control over resources-shifts progressively from political disposition to market institutions, there will be a change in the distribution of rewards favoring those who hold market rather than redistributive power. Compared to nonmarket allocation, market exchange enhances the bargaining power of producers. Incentives are improved as producers retain a greater share of the economic surplus. Opportunities for gain depend less on the personal discretion of cadres in positional power. Consequently, the growth of market institutions (i.e., labor markets, subcontracting arrangements, capital markets, and business groups) causes a decline in the significance of socialist redistributive power even in the absence of fundamental change in the political order. In sectors of the socialist economy where a decisive shift to markets has occurred, officials are less likely to gain a dominant advantage from positional power in the state socialist redistributive bureaucracy. Contingent on continuing allocative control over key factor resources, their relative advantage declines as a function of the extent to which markets replace redistribution as the coordinating mechanism of the economy. In the state socialist redistributive economy, officials act as monopolists who specify and enforce the rules of exchange by administrative fiat and exclude private entrepreneurs from taking part in legitimate economic activities. Because economic actors depend on resources allocated from 910

5 Symposium: Nee above, they strive to secure favorable access to these decision makers in order to maximize their access to scarce resources (Walder 1986). By contrast, the shift to the market mechanism reduces dependence on superordinate bureaucratic agencies, as producers and consumers increasingly get needed goods and services through market exchanges. Marketbased exchanges stimulate the development of horizontal ties between buyers and sellers, in labor and production markets, resulting in an incremental decline in the relative value of vertical connections-political capital-and an increasing importance of network ties between economic actors in society.2 In sum, changes in the mechanisms of stratification stem from the expansion of opportunities for gain and profit centering on market institutions. Opportunities are more broadly based and diverse when markets replace and augment the opportunity structure controlled by the state. The more developed the market economy, the greater the breadth and diversity of opportunities that develop outside the boundaries of the redistributive economy. Groups and individuals who were formerly barred from advancement in the state socialist bureaucracy and economy gain chances for social mobility through emergent labor markets and private entrepreneurship. Such growth of opportunities undermines the political power of indigenous elites in small communities (Yan 1995). To the extent that new bases of opportunity expand, resources become embedded in alternative networks and institutions, dependence on the established elite declines, and excluded groups gain in power relative to the established elite. Importantly, such shifts in power do not entail a direct transfer of power as in a regime change but do occur as an unintended by-product of institutional change. Reflecting the changing institutional basis of power and privilege in society, elements of the administrative elite adapt to the emerging market society by becoming entrepreneurs. The movement of cadres into private entrepreneurship accelerates the decline of state socialist redistributive power because it contributes to opportunism and malfeasance among party members, exacerbating a crisis of legitimacy (Nee and Lian 1994). As in the rise of capitalism in the West, change in the stratification order is incremental and over time. LOCAL CORPORATISM AS A SOCIETAL INSTITUTION Reports of local accommodations that combine redistribution and markets underscore the importance of hybrid institutional forms in the transi- 2 This argument is consistent with power dependence theories (Emerson 1962; Hechter 1987) and social resource theory (Lin 1982). As China shifts to market coordination, family firms and social networks will grow in importance in economic transactions (Hamilton 1991). 911

6 American Journal of Sociology tion from state socialism in China. Hybrid corporatist forms proliferate in mixed economies to capture the gains from trade under conditions of widespread institutional uncertainty (Nee 1992). Local corporatism is a societal arrangement loosely coupling the formal rules of the game specified by the state and the informal procedures devised by local political and economic actors to promote market-oriented growth. Such corporatist arrangements are characterized by informality and flexibility, with long-standing personal relationships providing a foundation for complex economic transactions (Nee and Su, in press). The cement that holds corporatist arrangements together appears to be generalized reciprocity in network-based social exchanges (Wilson 1994). Reciprocity involves generalized exchanges based on trust and cooperation; it is fostered in symmetrical social structures, as in a kinship group or village community (Sahlins 1972). Reciprocity differs from market exchanges insofar as it does not involve haggling over price, and it differs from redistributive exchange where the pattern of resource movement conforms to the principle of centricity with goods and services flowing to and from a central point. Corporatist arrangements involve both market and nonmarket allocation of labor, capital, and land and entail a partitioning of property rights over collective assets between local government and economic actors through leasing agreements and responsibility contracts. As a governance structure, local corporatism conforms to the needs of industrial firms under conditions of partial reform. It reduces transaction costs by securing credible commitment in an institutional environment characterized by weak property rights and irregular monitoring and enforcement of formal rules by the central state. Socialist local governments themselves engage in political entrepreneurship, constructing institutional rules and myths to build and legitimize corporatist strategies of economic development (e.g., Lin 1995). Rather than producing for the redistributive state, corporatist strategies are oriented to the marketplace, but they also provide welfare services to the community (Oi 1990). In corporatist local economies, redistribution limits the profit-making activities of entrepreneurs and maintains a safety net for the poor and weak, resulting in lower levels of income inequality; by contrast in other regions, income inequality increased following an initial decline in the early 1980s (Nee and Liedka 1995). Though it is a loosely coupled societal arrangement, solidarity is manifest in market competition with external groups and in response to predatory encroachment by the central state. The rapid and sustained economic growth of local corporatist communities has strengthened the capacity of local government. Nonetheless, the development of rural industry is not likely to provide a viable economic base enabling redistributors to reconsolidate state socialist redis- 912

7 Symposium: Nee tributive power. Analysis of the organizational dynamics of market transition indicates that change in the institutional environment brought about by the spread of markets and expansion of private property rights induces corresponding changes in the behavior of industrial firms (Nee 1992; Qian and Xu 1993). Collective ownership forms coexist and even flourish in a market environment, but the discipline and incentives imposed by market competition lead to behavior more similar to private firms. As nonstate firms marketize, they are less likely to serve redistributive purposes (Byrd and Lin 1990). Workers are rewarded on the basis of performance. Firms compete for better qualified workers in quasi labor markets. Managers strive to improve profitability and efficiency (Su 1994). Peng's (1992) analysis comparing workers' wages in rural industry and state enterprises supports this view. He argues that even while rural industry remains under collective ownership, rural firms already display behavior similar to that of private firms, which is why he classifies rural industry as "semiprivate." And indeed there is extensive informal privatization of collective-owned assets and firms (Nee and Su, in press). Higher productivity in marketized firms and increased demand for labor in quasi labor markets tend to push up wages, resulting in improved wages for producers (workers and managers) relative to redistributors. Hence, market transition theory predicts that the transformation of public firms into marketized firms induces a decline in the income advantage of positional power based on redistribution even in the industrial sector of the economy. Local corporatism to be sure entails strong government, but the role of government is transformed into one similar to corporatist political institutions in market economies (Williamson 1989). THE LIMITS OF STATE-CENTERED ANALYSIS OF TRANSITION Social scientists have long highlighted the commanding role of the state in controlling the socialist economy and society. The extreme formulation of state-centered analysis was the totalitarian model, which portrayed the Leninist state as imposing total control over Soviet society through the party apparat and mass terror (Arendt 1951; Friedrich 1954). Subsequent perspectives sought to soften the harsh totalitarian imagery of an atomized society subjugated by an impersonal party-state. Skilling and Griffiths (1971) introduced the idea of interest groups and political competition to dispel the perception of a monolithic party-state. Then by highlighting the role of patron-client ties through which state control is maintained, Walder (1986) incorporated an emphasis on the informal mechanisms of state control. Despite such modifications, the focus of analysis remained centered on political dynamics within the party-state 913

8 American Journal of Sociology and on the mechanisms, formal and informal, through which the state controlled the economy and society. The response of state-centered analysts to economic reform and regime change has been to emphasize structural continuity with unreformed state socialism. Walder (1995b), for example, argues that it is an intensification of state control through more effective monitoring and enforcement by local government, stemming from downward transfer of property rights in the state hierarchy-and not the action of economic actors in society seeking higher returns for their investment and work-that accounts for the dramatic improvement of economic performance in industry. Similarly, state-centered analysts describe a local stratification order in which the cadre elite continue to control the economy even under conditions of rapid market penetration and corresponding decentralization of economic decision making to firms and households (Oi 1992). These scholars argue that the marketization of the industrial economy need not diminish the redistributive power of the cadre elite. Like modernization theory, state-centered analysis minimizes the effect of institutional change on the stratification order. Emphasizing the persistence of the old stratification order, state-centered analysts claim that "the primary beneficiary of marketization is the old elite" (Rona-Tas 1994, p. 44). The main proponents of the "political capitalism" or ''power conversion" hypothesis of augmented cadre advantage elaborate their arguments in extended discursive commentaries on the Polish (Staniszkis 1991) and Hungarian (Hankiss 1990) revolutions. According to them, the cadre elite adeptly transforms its political capital into economic capital as it faces the impending collapse of state socialism. They engage in various forms of rent seeking in which they utilize their control over public assets and their political connections to reap private advantages in the emergent market economy. As their final redistributive act, cadres transfer to themselves ownership rights in privatized firms, and, by building on their initial control of firms and financial institutions, they are able to establish themselves in businesses and thereby secure increasing income advantage as the economy shifts to markets. Although similar points with respect to the commodification of bureaucratic power were developed in market transition theory (Szelenyi and Manchin 1987; Nee 1991; Nee and Lian 1994), state-centered analysts emphasize continuity in the stratification order insofar as the cadre elite benefits more than other groups from the transition to a market economy. The evidence supporting this claim, however, is weak.3 I The only systematic empirical study is R6na-Tas's (1994) analysis of Hungarian survey data collected in the springs of 1989 and This study has several limitations. First, as R6na-Tas points out, state-directed market transition in Hungary 914

9 Symposium: Nee State-centered analysis focuses explanatory attention on the power of the state and its agents, the administrative elite. Without taking into account a broader societal perspective, state-centered analysts of market transition impose on themselves a conceptual blinder. Their analysis of economic reform focuses only on changing incentives for political actors in the state organizational hierarchy and overlooks the incentives and actions of economic actors in society; hence state-centered analyses are unable to provide a convincing explanation for gains in productivity. Further, the state-centered lens leads analysts to overlook the societal outcome that results in a relative decline in cadre advantage. As Kenneth Burke has said, "a way of seeing is also a way of not seeing-a focus on object A involves a neglect of object B" (quoted in Merton 1949, p. 252). Focusing on the administrative elite, they are apt to see no evidence of such a decline in the absence of a statistically significant negative effect of cadre status on the determination of income. But this is to ignore the relative position of cadres vis-a-vis others. Power is not zero sum in the relationship between redistributor and producer, as evidenced by the rapid increase in both state revenues and household savings in China. commenced in 1989 and was completed sometime in 1991; however, his models demonstrating "cadre" advantage regressed on 1990 income. Because R6na-Tas emphasized transition from above, the 1990 income data pose a problem for causal inference in the sequencing of events. Second, the "cadres" in his sample were former cadres, not government officials currently in power. This is a limitation because market transition theory is an argument about the declining significance of positional power of current government officials. Former cadres indeed have political capital-vertical networks-which they can mobilize to secure advantages in the new market economy. This is what R6na-Tas actually examines. However, he does not mention that his findings are very similar to those reported in the original test of market transition theory, despite the differing contexts of rural China and industrialized Hungary. In both settings, entrepreneurs from cadre backgrounds are advantaged, but cadres who are not entrepreneurs do not profit from accumulated political capital. The higher proportion of cadres entering into entrepreneurship and an income advantage for cadres operating private businesses were first reported by Nee (1989, pp , see tables 3 and 4) and explained as a function of politically bounded markets and financial institutions (Nee 1991, pp ). Market transition theory interprets the absence of an income advantage for cadres (current and former) who are not entrepreneurs as evidence of declining relative value of political capital. These members of the cadre status group are far more numerous, and their experience is modal for the administrative elite. Few of the studies R6na-Tas (1994, p. 44) cites as supporting the claim that the administrative elite are the primary beneficiary of marketization actually state this claim as a central point; most of them say so only in passing, and none provide other than impressionistic evidence. This, e.g., from Shirk (1989, p. 340): "Already grumblings can be heard about the unfair advantages of cadres and their families in rural commerce; they can use their connections to gain access to lucrative business opportunities and avoid the extortionary license fees slapped on other rural businessmen by local officials." 915

10 American Journal of Sociology In other words, state revenues can improve even while the significance of redistributive power in shaping the distribution of rewards declines. Despite appearances, the "power persistence" hypothesis is consistent with the declining-significance-of-redistributive-power hypothesis (Nee 1991, p. 268; Bian and Logan 1996).4 Cadre income need not declineand can even increase, as it has in China-for the declining-significanceof-redistributive-power hypothesis to be verified: if the earnings of many economic actors in society increase at a faster rate than that of political actors, the advantage of the cadre elite declines. For this reason, analysts of the postreform/revolution stratification order need to examine the relative gains and losses of both political and economic actors, as market transition theory does. The new institutionalist framework incorporates the state as a potent causal force but also assigns an independent role to social and economic forces, which in a period of societal transformation exert a growing causal influence on the state (Nee and Matthews 1996; Stark and Nee 1989). ADJUDICATING THE COMPETITIVE HYPOTHESES The "power conversion" hypothesis of state-centered analysis, asserting that the administrative elite are the primary beneficiary of marketization, predicts increasing income growth for cadres (relative to producers). Because markets purportedly enable cadres to convert political capital to economic capital, the predicted income advantage of the administrative elite should be evident for cadres holding positional power as well as former cadres, especially those who establish private businesses. Not only should current cadres qua cadre derive income advantages for their positional power, but cadre entrepreneurs should be advantaged and obtain greater income gains from operating private businesses than do noncadre entrepreneurs. Market transition theory predicts that the administrative elite's controlling position in the stratification order will decline and the value of their political capital depreciate incrementally following a shift to markets and corresponding changes in property rights.5 The decliningsignificance-of-redistributive-power hypothesis would be verified by a higher-income growth for producers (including entrepreneurs, managers, I The power persistence hypothesis states that market action can reinforce and even amplify redistributive power. In the original test of the theory, the mean household income of cadres more than doubled from 1980 to 1985 but so did that of ordinary farming households, while that of entrepreneurs increased at a more rapid rate. 5 The ability to buy and sell in markets assumes private rights to assets, including one's own labor power. Hence changes in the structure of property rights accompany marketization. 916

11 Symposium: Nee and technicians) relative to current cadres. This key reversal in relative income advantage would reveal that social inequalities structured by redistribution are declining, even while inequalities generated by market forces increase.6 Such predicted trends will not be linear because no economy is purely coordinated by markets, and mixed economies combining markets and redistribution are the likely outcome of market transition. In other words, redistributive power will persist as a source of advantage, even while its significance declines as a function of the shift to markets. Another obvious caveat is that income gains for producers are adversely affected by economic downturns. Both arguments recognize that during the course of market transition, cadres often strive to broker redistributive power to establish themselves in private businesses. Another way in which the hypotheses differ is with respect to the predicted trends of the cadre advantage in entering private entrepreneurship. The declining-significance-of-redistributive-power hypothesis predicts a diminishing cadre advantage in entering into and profiting from private entrepreneurship as markets thicken and a market economy is instituted. The "power conversion" hypothesis makes the opposite prediction, arguing that cadres are more likely to shift into and prosper from ownership of private businesses when the institutional framework for a market economy has been instituted by the state. COMPARATIVE REGIONAL ANALYSIS Regional variation in extent of institutional change-market penetration and the structure of property rights-complicates the analysis of the effect of markets in changing the stratification order in China. The predicted decline of redistributive power is likely to be more apparent in areas where markets are more developed, while in regions where markets are less developed, there may be a greater continuity with the old stratification order based on redistribution. The maritime provinces-targeted by Beijing as the experimental grounds of market reforms-have experienced a more rapid shift to markets, which sparked more rapid economic growth there. Though the maritime provinces were more developed economically prior to economic reform, the gap between coastal and inland provinces increased through the 1980s. Thus the ratio between industrial and agricultural output value of the coastal and inland regions widened, resulting in growing interregional income inequality. Even within provinces, there is considerable variation in the extent of market penetration and institutional environment. In both the highly marketized Pearl River 6 The decline of income inequality following the shift to markets is transitory. The predicted initial decline was also found by Bian and Logan (1996) in their study of income inequality in Tianjin. 917

12 American Journal of Sociology Delta in Guangdong Providence, near Hong Kong and Macao, and the "Golden Triangle" area of Fujian, there is a surprising diversity of marketized forms (Johnson 1994; Huang 1989; Nee and Su 1990). Further north along the coast, Zhejiang and Jiangsu provinces show a variety of local corporatist institutional arrangements (Huang 1990; Brown 1992; Liu 1992; Liang 1994). Analysis of the effect of regional variation in marketization needs to take such provincial and community-level variation into account. On this scale, does the extent of institutional change covary with a declining significance of redistributive power in shaping the stratification order? INSTITUTIONAL CHANGE AND INDUSTRIAL GROWTH There may be important factors exogenous to market transition theory that explain the declining significance of redistributive power under conditions of market reform. According to modernization theory, the more industrialized a community, the more similar the mechanisms of stratification will be to those found in other industrial societies. In other words, the accumulation of capital, rising income, and new jobs, not institutional change, explain the decline in the significance of positional power. The industrialism hypothesis maintains that without change in the structure of property rights or economic institutions, a rise in the number of high-paying factory jobs will improve the relative income of producers (workers and managers) and diminish that of the administrative elite. However, prior to market reforms, industrialized regions and urban centers provided a strong economic base for state socialist redistribution (Whyte and Parish 1984; Walder 1986). Hence, there is no inherent incompatibility between an industrial economy and socialist redistribution. By contrast to petty commodity production, the factory regime enables the socialist state to monitor and enforce communist rule more effectively (Burawoy and Lukaics 1992). Indeed, state socialist redistributive power is well suited for organizing extensive industrial growth as long as surplus labor power can be shifted out of agriculture into industry (Szelenyi 1989). In any case, whether industrialization and redistributive power are positively or negatively correlated, an attempt to verify a causal link between institutional change and the declining significance of redistributive power must control for the level of industralization. These unresolved issues point to the need to test propositions from market transition theory using a national data set collected at a different point in time than the original 1985 survey that was used in the preliminary confirmation of the theory. The 1985 sample involved households 918

13 Symposium: Nee in two periurban counties in a highly marketized southeastern coastal province. A national sample, with far greater variation in both the endogenous and exogenous variables, offers a more nearly definitive test of the theory. It allows a quasi experiment controlling for community-level variation in the level of industralization and taking into account regional variation in the extent of institutional change. With such more detailed analysis, it may be possible to test the new institutionalists' claim that in transition societies, underlying differences in the mechanism of stratification are caused by changes in the institutional framework that shape the structure of incentives and opportunities, and hence the parameters of choice within which political and economic actors strive to optimize power and plenty. DATA AND MODEL The data for this study come from a multistage, multilevel nationwide social survey of 138 administrative townships (xiang), 138 villages (cun) and 7,950 households in rural China carried out in the fall and winter of Twenty-five of China's 29 provinces were included in the survey. The data were collected by the Chinese Academy of Preventive Medicine (CAPM), using trained teams of public health field interviewers, and provide a multidimensional view of a society in transition. The first survey, involving principally nutritional and biological samples to study the relationship between nutrition and cancer, had been conducted in Sixty-five counties were selected nonrandomly; within each of these counties, two townships and then two villages were selected randomly, as were the households interviewed for the survey in each village (see Chen et al. 1989; Parpia 1994). The 1989 resurvey added four additional counties and incorporated multilevel socioeconomic questionnaires. The household as opposed to the individual is the unit of analysis, for in Chinese rural society the household serves as the production and accounting unit. Regression analyses of household income employ maximum-likelihood estimates of multilevel models. Structural models utilize both a static and dynamic approach employing a lagged dependent variable. Static mixed models are used to examine the effect of selected variables on household income in When lagged income variables are used, the regression analysis points to net returns of the exogenous variables on change in the dependent variable. With multilevel models, to the extent households share common attributes by virtue of residence in the same locality, the assumption of uncorrelated error terms of household-level observations is violated, primarily affecting the standard errors of contextual variables (Mason, Wong, and 919

14 American Journal of Sociology Entwisle 1983). To deal with this problem, multilevel models were developed, allowing researchers to test hypotheses on how contextual variables at one level affect relations at another level (Searle, Casella, and McCulloch 1992). The multilevel model (Aitkin and Longford 1986) used in the analysis is Yi= j o + IXlij + yx2yx...,+ x + where x indicates the explanatory microlevel variables and (xx are the township/village contextual effects, assumed to be a random sample from N(O,U2), and independent of the household-level errors Eij [E(ox) = 0; var(oxx) = o2; var(ei) = os]. To examine the cross-effect of the macro context on the micro variable, interaction between the macrolevel and microlevel variables are employed (Bryk and Raudenbush 1992; e.g., interacting the marketization variable with cadre status tests for the effect of a thicker market environment on advantage stemming from positional power in the administrative elite). Mixed model computations employ the SAS/STAT MIXED software, and in the case of the poisson and logistic regressions the GLIMMIX SAS macro was used. In a large sample, the difference between restricted maximum-likelihood (REML) and maximum-likelihood (ML) estimation procedures are minimal; both are maximum-likelihood based. Searle, Casella, and McCulloch (1992) write that "with balanced data REML solutions are identical to ANOVA estimators which have optimal minimum variance properties-and to many users this is a sufficiently comforting feature of REML they prefer it over ML" (p. 255). Hierarchical poisson and logistic regression analyses are employed to test hypotheses on the effect of cadre power in securing nonfarm jobs and establishing nonfarm private businesses, the principal means by which households can achieve income gains in the era of market reform. Poisson regression models are used where the dependent variable is a count (e.g., the number of nonfarm workers). The nonlinear model employed in the hierarchical discrete regression is p. = f(xox + Z13), where ox is a vector of p unknown fixed-effects parameter with known model matrix X, P is a vector of f unknown random-effects parameter with known model matrix Z, and the function f are evaluations of g -1, where g() is a link function (Wolfinger 1993). The model assumes E(y p) = p and cov(y I.A) = A jl.r 112RR /2. 920

15 Symposium: Nee R is a diagonal matrix that contains evaluations at pu of a known variance function for the model and R is unknown. The estimation involves a generalized linear mixed model with a log link and poisson error employing the Lindstrom and Bates (1990) algorithm derived from Laplace's approximation. Restricted pseudolikelihood (REPL) procedures are used in estimating a., P, D, and R (Wolfinger and O'Connell 1993). In Wolfinger's approach, a. and P are estimated from the mixed-model equa tions, and D and R are estimated using REML. When evidence of overdispersion is found, an overdispersion parameter is estimated and standard errors adjusted accordingly (McCullagh and Nelder 1983). Following Lenski (1966), who maintained that the distribution of rewards-income-is a function of the distribution of power in society, I measure change in relative power by reference to 1989 income and the change in household income from 1983 to The income variables are the natural log of total deflated household income for 1983 and All income data were collected at the time of the resurvey. Although retrospective income data are known to be prone to error, informants are better able to make accurate comparisons by reference to years well etched in their memory: 1978, the start of post-mao reform, and 1983, the year of the last survey when provincial public health workers visited the villages and collected data from the same households surveyed in Separate analysis was conducted using the 1978 household income variable. The results were largely identical to those when 1983 household income was used as the lagged dependent variable. Household income is the sum of the net income from the sale of agricultural products, the cost of food produced by the household, and the contribution of nonagricultural income-private business, cadre salary, factory jobs, service, sidelines, and an unspecified "other" category.7 Cadre households reported the highest mean income in the sample, reflecting their continuing elite status. In 1989, 29.5% of cadre and 50% of cadre entrepreneur I The income reported for cadre households is not likely to be biased downward. First, the income questions were placed in the middle of a long household questionnaire administered by public health field-workers. The items inquiring whether a cadre is present in the household appeared near the end of the questionnaire. Cadres and cadre-entrepreneurs reported the highest median income of any group except noncadre-entrepreneurs. In comparing cadre- and noncadre-entrepreneur households there is no statistically significant difference between the size of their homes and the pattern of ownership of most consumer durables (tape recorders, televisions, washing machines, sewing machines, motorcycles, and cars). Where there is a difference, all entrepreneurial households are more likely to own an electric fan and a refrigerator. On the other hand, cadre households are statistically more likely to own the above consumer durables, excepting cars, when compared to nonentrepreneurial households. For these reasons, it is unlikely that cadre households systematically underreported their rewards. 921

16 American Journal of Sociology households reported household income that placed them in the top income quintile. The human capital of the household head is measured by the levels of formal schooling and by work experience. Primary, junior, and advanced are dummy variables for household heads who either attended or graduated from primary school, junior middle school, or senior middle school, technical school, college, or university. Because there were so few household heads with education above the senior middle school level, those attending technical school, college, or university were pooled together with those who received senior middle school education. The omitted reference category is household heads who never attended school. Age squared is added to the model in order to adjust for the assumed nonlinear relationship at the effect of age of the household head on household income. Chayanov (1966) demonstrated the importance of change in household labor power and composition in the determination of the rural stratification order. Respondents were asked the gender of the current household head and the composition of the household labor force, male and female, for 1978, 1983, and Household characteristics are controlled for by reference to dummy variablesfemale head (female = 1) of the household and male household labor: and female household labor: the change in the number of male and female adults contributing income to the household from 1983 to Because I use household income as a measure of power, the control for the number of income earners is more satisfactory than the number of adult laborers and children. Farm labor measures the number of adults who derive income from agricultural work. Nonfarm labor is the number of male and female peasant workers who contribute nonagricultural income to the household, excluding cadres and entrepreneurs.8 Most of the nonfarm workers in the sample find jobs in the local economy in township industry, service, and construction, but others migrate to find jobs in county towns and cities, and some leave the province altogether. Another major source of nonfarm income is private entrepreneurship. Entrepreneur is a dummy variable indicating whether a household has established a private nonfarm business (entrepreneur = 1). The foregoing variables include all adults in the household (except current cadres) and thus serve as a control for the number of producers contributing income to the household. In a socialist redistributive economy, cadres maintain direct control over the allocation of resources. They embody the elite group at each level of the state-constructed hierarchy. Cadre is a dummy variable pointing to 8 Part-time nonfarm workers earning less than 500 yuan per annum, however, were not included in the above category. 922

17 Symposium: Nee the presence in the household of a current cadre holding positional power in local government. All the various ranks of cadres comprising the local administrative elite are represented in the cadre variable, from countylevel officials down to cadres in the natural village. The specifications of the cadre variables are the same as those used in the preliminary verification of market transition theory. This facilitates comparisons between the results reported in this article and the earlier study. Separate analyses using the rank of current cadres were conducted, and similar results were obtained. Since the start of reform some cadres have sought profit in the marketplace as private entrepreneurs. The model has three variables that purport to measure the political capital of households other than those of current cadres. Former cadre is a dummy variable identifying households with members who in the past held positions as redistributors and who still have political capital insofar as they still belong to the cadre status group. Their political capital provides them with greater ease of access to redistributors who currently hold power in local government. Cadre relation is a dummy variable identifying households having close relatives as redistributors. These households have a strong informal tie with officeholders in local government. All of the political capital variables identify households that are likely to enjoy advantages from ease of access to officials who hold formal power in the local bureaucracy. In addition to the above set of household-level variables are contextual variables that control for the institutional environment. These data were gained through key informant interviews with township and village officials. Production market is the number of private and collective firms in the township. This variable serves as a measure for marketization at the local level, conforming to White's (1981) specification of a production market. As a measure of marketization, it focuses analytic attention on the effect of firms in creating a market environment. This is particularly important with respect to the emergence of labor markets. Given the skewed distribution, I use the natural log of the number of private and collective firms. Collective firms are pooled with private firms because they also depend on markets for their survival and growth. The higher the number of private and collective firms, the thicker the local market environment. Production market is used in hierarchical models for the nation as a whole (table 2) but not when the extent of marketization is operationalized by regional grouping (table 5). Labor market measures the extent of the market for nonfarm labor by reference to the proportion of the village population engaged in nonfarm work outside the village. It is based on the sum of peasant workers in construction, factories, and workshops and the self-employed engaged in private business, traveling craftsmen, and peddlers outside the village. The higher the proportion 923

18 American Journal of Sociology of off-village nonfarm workers, the greater the extent of the local labor market. The number of nonstate firms, however, is not a reliable indicator of the level of industrialization because the nature and size of the firmcommercial or industrial-is not revealed. Also 4% of township firms in the sample are state owned. The correlation between the number of private and collective firms with industrial output per capita is.04 and.03 respectively. Industrial output-the per capita industrial outputmeasures the extent of rural industrialization in the township. This variable is a useful indicator of the level of local economic development, permitting a control for the effect of industrial growth on stratification. As a control on local economic development, it is employed in analyses both of the nation as a whole (table 2) and of specific regions (table 4). Although China has made more rapid progress toward instituting a market economy than Eastern Europe and the former Soviet Union, it remains a mixed redistributive and market economy. Government finds nonfarm job is a village-level variable that specifies how most people find nonfarm jobs outside the village. If "most people find jobs through government" (findjob + 1), this indicates that the village government retains substantial redistributive power. If most people find jobs through friends and relatives or through advertisement or private job agencies, then findjob = 0, which I interpret as indicating weak local redistributive power insofar as the local government controls neither the agricultural economy nor the allocation of nonfarm jobs, the highest-paying jobs. Community income provides a control for the mean household income in a village. This allows us to distinguish household income gains net of the community mean. By controlling for the mean village income, we are able to assess cadre income relative to other households in the community, as opposed to households in the region. The emergence of a market economy is better operationalized as a regional, rather than a local, phenomenon. Controlling only for local conditions fails to take into account the full scope of institutional environments that shape incentives and opportunities for rural households. The substantial internal labor migration reported by households in the sample, for example, highlights the importance of extralocal demand for nonfarm labor. Also, marketization should be operationalized at the regional level insofar as local firms compete with firms in other areas. The coastal region includes provinces that experienced significant and often decisive shifts to reliance on market coordination and rapid integration with global markets (Yang 1990). Substantial foreign investments have accompanied market reform here, especially in the southeast coastal provinces, the Yangzi Delta region near Shanghai, and the Bohai Bay region, resulting in rapid incorporation into the world market economy. 924

19 Symposium: Nee I examine the effects of regional variation in the coastal provinces by distinguishing between relatively laissez-faire (Fujian and Guangdong), corporatist (Jiangsu and Zhejiang), and redistributive (Hebei, Shandong, Shanghai) provinces. I contrast these with the much less marketized inland provinces. These regional groupings represent a preliminary classification scheme for the extent of institutional change in the structure of property rights in the industrial economy after the first decade of market transition. They were identified by cluster analysis of provincial data on the relative industrial output of private, collective, and state-owned firms from 1987 to In the inland regions, state-owned firms produced 65.9% of the industrial output in 1989, with collective and private firms producing only 27.2% and 6.9% respectively. The dominance of state-owned firms in the industrial economy is also found in the coastal redistributive provinces. State-owned firms in the coastal redistributive provinces produced 53.8% of industrial output, while 37.6% and 8.6% were accounted for by collective and private firms. This contrasts with the dominance of collective firms-owned by local governments-in the corporatist provinces, where 60.8% of industrial output was produced by collective firms and 33.9% and 7% by state and private firms. Only in the laissez-faire provinces do we find a mixed industrial economy in which no property form is dominant, but the output of firms that rely on markets is over 50%. There 19.4% and 35.8% of industrial output were produced by private and collective firms, with 44.8% produced by state-owned firms. Marketdriven economic growth has stimulated growing internal migration and urbanization in small towns and cities (Liang and White, in press; Parish 1994). The shift of surplus labor from agriculture to industry is fueled to a large extent by the increasing share of industrial output and demand for labor of the nonstate property forms, growing rapidly in the coastal provinces. By contrast, state-owned firms, which acquire labor through bureaucratic allocation, are less likely to generate labor demand that reaches beyond the urban population. Table 1 shows that townships located in the relatively laissez-faire I The cluster analysis confirmed that the industrial economy of inland provinces should be treated separately from the coastal provinces. It also confirmed the existence of the three coastal subregions-laissez-faire, corporatist, and redistributive. The results of the cluster analysis were supported by F-tests using the China-Cornell-Oxford data set. By estimating modified human capital and household composition models of household income for regional distinctions as an analysis of covariance and then estimating the model by pooling the regions a second time, it is possible to test whether regions exhibit different processes of stratification. They also conform to the qualitative studies of market transition written by field researchers: laissez-faire (Vogel 1989; Nee and Su 1990; Su 1993; Johnson 1994), corporatist (Huang 1990; Oi 1990; Brown 1992; Liu 1992; Liang 1994; Wilson 1994), redistributive (Lin 1995). 925

20 TABLE 1 MEANS AND STANDARD DEVIATIONS OF SELECTED HOUSEHOLD AND INSTITUTIONAL CHARACTERISTICS COASTAL INLAND Redistributive Corporatist Laissez-Faire N , ,086 1, household income , (638.00) (794.00) (704.37) (1,131.34) 1983 household income... 1, , , , (931.92) (1,003.86) (981.12) (1,338.93) 1989 household income... 1, , , , (1,332.87) (1,323.43) (1,012.16) (2,451.46) 1989 agricultural income (721.09) (604.15) (501.59) (943.64) 1989 private business income (260.28) (437.29) (444.10) (1,009.29) 1989 nonfarm income (323.74) (960.44) (817.03) (1,596.98) Age (9.88) (10.49) (10.71) (9.68) % primary SChOOl (.495) (.498) (.499) (.500) % junior middle school (.388) (.433) (.396) (.381) % advanced schooling (.218) (.218) (.212) (.250) % female head of household (.375) (.386) (.372) (.408) Male household labor: (.847) (.676) (.841) (.945) Female household labor: (.865) (.762) (.869) (.928) Farm labor (1.725) (1.563) (1.410) (1.690) Nonfarm labor (.553) (1.080) (.962) (.918) Entrepreneur (.237) (.251) (.273) (.305) % cadre (.341) (.376) (.322) (.397) %cadre entrepreneur (. 091) (.092) (.080) (.134) % former cadre (.389) (.416) (.387) (.403)

21 Symposium: Nee TABLE 1 (Continued) COASTAL INLAND Redistributive Corporatist Laissez-Faire % former cadre entrepreneur (.122) (.121) (.091) (.144) % cadre relation (.335) (.284) (.304) (.358) Industrial output per capita t (.009) (.075) (.033) (.019) Median N nonstate firms (interquartile range)* (23) (51) (63) (269.5) Median N collective firms (interquartile range) (10) (56) (49) (162) Median N private firms (interquartile range) (12) (9) (35) (86) % government finds nonfarm jobs (.501) (.514) (.514) (.224) Labor market (.055) (.120) (.080) (.108) Mean community household income... 1, , , , ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) NOTE.-SDs are given in parentheses. * The remaining six variables are measured at the village and township levels. The corresponding Ns are inland (N = 86), redistributive (N = 14), corporatist (N = 18), and laissez-faire (N = 20). t Defined as the industrial output per capita divided by 100,000. provinces have the highest median number of market-oriented nonstate firms (83.5), followed by the coastal corporatist (47), and coastal redistributive (22.5) provinces, with townships in the inland provinces (8) showing the lowest number of such firms. Disaggregating this category (separating private and collective firms) reveals that townships in the inland and coastal redistributive provinces report virtually no private firms, whereas townships in the corporatist and laissez-faire provinces already have wellestablished private economies, with the ratio between collective and private approaching parity in the laissez-faire subregion. Similarly, the highest percentage of village-level private entrepreneurs reside in the laissez-faire provinces, followed by the corporatist and then the redistributive coastal provinces, with the lowest percentage of private entrepre- 927

22 American Journal of Sociology neurs in the inland provinces. This pattern is seen also in the mean household income derived from private businesses. With well-established rural labor markets, the laissez-faire market provinces are the least reliant on redistribution in the allocation of off-village nonfarm jobs; only 5% of village governments in the Guangdong and Fujian sample find most of those jobs, whereas elsewhere it is close to 50%. Combined, these data confirm the utility of the regional groupings arrived at through cluster analysis. They indicate that the shift to a market economy has progressed furthest in the laissez-faire provinces, followed by the coastal corporatist and redistributive provinces, and least in the inland region. The level of rural industrialization, however, follows the reverse order, with the redistributive coastal townships in the sample having the highest per capita industrial output and the laissez-faire townships the lowest among the coastal provinces. This is reflected in the mean number of nonfarm laborers by region reported in table 1. Overall gains in household income from 1978 to 1989 were largest in the laissez-faire provinces. In the inland region, rural income stagnated after an initial period of rapid growth. FINDINGS Changes in the mechanism of stratification in the transitions from state socialism are caused, I claim, by changing institutions-the shift to markets and corresponding changes in the structure of property rights. Sixty percent of rich households experienced relative decline in economic standing from 1978 to Even more poor households moved up in their relative economic standing than the rich experienced decline. Only 34.8% of the poorest households remained in the bottom income quintile, while 41.7% moved up at least two income quintiles during the decade of reform. The extent of income mobility is even greater in the middle three income quintiles, where 75%-80% of households experienced change in their relative economic standing. The transition to a mixed market economy was accompanied by a quickening pace of change in relative economic standing among rural households. To what extent did the administrative elite hold on to their power and privileges in the midst of all this change? Table 2 shows that in 1989 in the nation as a whole, cadre households still enjoyed a statistically significant net advantage. Likewise, households gain higher income when village governments assign nonfarm jobs, indicating persistent local redistributive power. These findings may be viewed by state-centered analysts as evidence of persistent redistributive power and privilege of the administrative elite in rural China, which market transition theory does not dispute. No claim is made that the administrative elite no longer 928

23 TABLE 2 MAxIMuM-LIKELIHOOD (REML) ESTIMATES OF THE EFFECTS OF HOUSEHOLD CHARACTERISTICS AND INSTITUTIONAL ENVIRONMENT ON HOUSEHOLD EARNINGS, BY SOURCE AND TOTAL, 1989 Independent Variable Model 1 Model 2 Intercept **** **** A. Human capital of household head: (.482) (.489) Age ****.068**** (.013) (.013) Age **** **** (.0001) (.0001) Primary school *.067* (.039) (.039) Junior middle school *.096* (.050) (.050) Advanced schooling * B. Household composition: (.076) (.076) Female head of household C. Producers: (.042) (.042) Farm labor...113****.113**** (.010) (.010) Nonfarm labor ****.475**** (.021) (.021) Entrepreneur ****.505**** D. Redistributors: (.068) (.068) Cadre **** 1.929**** Cadre x production market *** (.088) (.586) (.024) Cadre x community income -.232*** Cadre x entrepreneur E. Political capital: (.082) (.173) (.173) Former cadre (.042) (.042) Former cadre x entrepreneur (.149) (.149) Cadre relation F. Institutional environment: (.047) (.047) Government finds nonfarm jobs **.128** (.054) (.054) Production market (.016) (.015)

24 American Journal of Sociology TABLE 2 (Continued) Independent Variable Model 1 Model 2 Industrial output per capita (.884) (.886) Community income.1.007**** 1.041**** (.055) (.056) Variance components: Contextual..061****.062**** (.011) (.012) Household.1.543**** 1.543**** (.026) (.026) N... 7,149 7,149-2 REML log likelihood , , NOTE.-SEs (corrected for dispersion) are given in parentheses. * P <.10. ** P <.05. *** P <.01. **** P <.001. have power and privilege. Even in a market economy, bureaucrats have power and privilege, though much less relative to such an elite in a socialist redistributive economy. What the theory claims is that cadre power declines incrementally relative to producers and entrepreneurs as a function of the shift to a market economy. This prediction is verified in the interaction between cadre status and the extent of the production market in equation (1). The cross-effect interaction confirms a negative effect of local marketization on income returns to cadre status. Examining the cadre advantage a standard deviation above and below the mean for production markets reveals a contrast of.16 [ ( )] and.42, respectively. Where the production market is most developed, cadre status has a net negative effect on household income (-.09) and, in areas with the fewest nonstate firms, the net cadre advantage is greatest (.5 0). These findings confirm that the thicker the market environment, the lower the income return for local cadres. A similar effect of market-oriented economic growth can be seen in the interaction between cadre status and mean community income reported in equation (2). (The analysis was done separately due to collinearity between the two crosseffect interactions.) The finding indicates that the more affluent the community, the smaller the income advantage of cadres holding positional power in the county bureaucracy. The cadre advantage is substantially less (.20) in affluent communities than it is in poorer communities (.43) based on the mean community income plus or minus the standard devia- 930

25 Symposium: Nee tion. Table 1 indicates that the richest communities are located in the marketized laissez-faire provinces. Other possible interactions between the contextual and household variables were not significant. Overall, after taking into account the interaction effects, the betas for entrepreneur and nonfarm labor are substantially larger than that for cadres, which suggests a household may now be better off pursuing economic goals, rather than securing positional power in the local bureaucracy as in the past. An extra nonfarm laborer in the household has a much larger effect on nonfarm income than cadre position. None of the political capital variables is significant, nor is the cadre entrepreneur advantaged. This was not the case in the earlier tests of market transition theory, and the change reflects the greater extent of the market by In the pursuit of plenty, the labor force participation of nonfarm entrepreneurs and workers, and the human capital of the household head predict higher household income. Moreover, female-headed households are not disadvantaged. In sum, comparison of the income returns of both political and economic actors supports the claim of a declining significance of the positional power of the administrative elite as a function of the extent of market transition. That nonfarm jobs are secured through local government in many communities suggests a direct mechanism through which the administrative elite can benefit their immediate family, friends, and relatives, especially since local government retains formal property rights over collective-owned enterprises. To what extent have cadres used their redistributive power to secure lucrative nonfarm jobs for their own kind? Table 3 reports findings from a hierarchical poisson regression analysis of the determinants of nonfarm employment. These findings do not show a statistically significant effect of cadre power or former cadre status on the number of nonfarm workers in the household in any region of China. The first column shows a weak negative effect of cadre status on obtaining nonfarm work for the nation as a whole. Households in villages where most nonfarm jobs are found by local government have a lower chance of obtaining nonfarm jobs. By contrast, the labor market variable is strongly positive for the nation as a whole and in all regions except the laissez-faire provinces. In other words, labor markets more reliably promote the movement of surplus agricultural labor into off-village nonfarm jobs than local governments, just the opposite from the prereform period. The level of industrialization in rural townships has a strong effect on the chances of households gaining nonfarm employment but not in the more marketized corporatist and laissez-faire provinces. The main effects of the contextual variables are consistent with the new institutionalist model, but cross-effect interactions with political capital variables 931

26 .g * * - * * * * * * * * * * * * * * * * V)? X * **_qn * _* _* _*_ X o m X N s o o m X s e 0 0 'IC I X~~~~0 C,- ir 00 'IC oeo m ONo O Do t ~O so-c t ln N e z 0 * * z * * * * * Ev~~~~~~~~~~~- H.~~~~~~ -4 C-- O4 O-- O N-@ -I N- -4 z., Q * ~ ~~* * * * ** O n? nn* z o ce cn v t ~~~~~~~~~~t- t)on O n)?on 00 0 X Q * ~ ~ ~~~~~~~~~* * e g *Ws * * _* *~~~~~~~* **.. Y * _ * _ qd* n-* _* _* * _ 1too o \ o - ( 0-0 ' - o o? C Q1 ' '* - c?n 0 -H * * * * * * O * * * * * * * v ~~~* * * _* * * * * 0 * * * _ CD_* _ *,_-* - * H -9~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~cn b h~~~~~~~~0 m cl- (D 00 - Or Or 'I O 0 m Olz 8. Z 0 0:~~~~~~-40 - Z IZ CC E Cd > C 932

27 * t- *o ir ir ir - */-* * ** oo m n 'IC m (N qqt 00ooo ooonoo m 71~~~~- e No -I~ ~~~~~~~~~ -4 *~~~~1 0 *0 * *~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~C N o t o t e t e oo ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~ln O e q~~~~~~~~~d q l t- t- /- * t- t- t- t- * t-~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~c t ln N O t e e t O~~~C ~~ c * * *~~~~~~3

28 American Journal of Sociology were not significant. However, Parish, Zhe, and Li (1995) found diminished redistributive power of the administrative elite in the wake of expanding local labor markets. At the household level, work experience and household size and composition predict the chances of obtaining nonfarm jobs. Except for the laissez-faire provinces, education has a strong effect on the chances of obtaining nonfarm work. As for households reporting a cadre relative, this variable is significant for the nation as a whole. In the regional analyses, only (surprisingly) in the laissez-faire subregion is the variable a statistically significant predictor of participation in nonfarm work. Other measures of political capital fail to show a significant effect. It may be that kinship constitutes a bridge tie (Granovetter 1973)-and not the "strong tie" that opens the door to opportunity for the job-seekerespecially in large lineage villages common to the southeastern coastal provinces where 15% of the sample report a cadre relative. According to this interpretation, kinship ties to cadres serve as a conduit of information about the availability of jobs outside the village. Turning now to the question of laissez-faire exceptionalism, in these provinces it appears that none of the contextual and few of the household variables predict the chances of obtaining nonfarm jobs. Why? In the laissez-faire provinces market-induced economic growth was so rapid that rural households with surplus labor could readily find nonfarm jobs. So plentiful are nonfarm jobs that these provinces serve as a virtual magnet drawing millions of migrants from poorer inland provinces in search of nonfarm jobs unwanted by local farm households. In any case, households in the marketized coastal provinces have on average 2.73 times as many male nonfarm workers as households in the inland areas, and this increases to 5.58 times as many in the case of female nonfarm workers. Although kinship ties to cadres in the laissez-faire provinces confer some advantages in securing nonfarm jobs, the greater advantage stems from residence in a marketized region. Thus far we have focused on the relative standing of cadre and other households in But the declining-significance-of-redistributivepower hypothesis emphasizes the trajectory of income change, rather than privileges currently held.10 Accordingly, let us now ask to what extent local officials did or did not make exceptional economic gains during the transition period.11 In other words, were households that 10 Because the dependent variable pools agricultural income together with income streams derived directly from market transactions, the test is biased to favor the null hypothesis. " The same models were computed for a static analysis of household income by region and similar results were obtained. Interested readers may write to the author for copies of these tables. 934

29 Symposium: Nee possessed a greater stock of political capital able to achieve an advantage in growth of income relative to other households? By comparing the betas affecting change in household income, it is possible to identify which social group-entrepreneurs, producers, or local officials-is likely to gain the most relative to others from the shift to a market economy. According to market transition theory, the less marketized inland provinces experience less change compared to the more marketized southeastern coastal provinces, which shifted to a stratification order shaped more by market than by redistributive institutions. The parameter estimates in table 4 for the less marketized inland provinces conform to an expectation of slower incremental change. In the inland provinces, the administrative elite continue to enjoy positive returns on positional power in local government (reflected in increase in household income). However, the betas for entrepreneur and nonfarm labor are larger than that for cadres, indicating that a noncadre household with an entrepreneur or nonfarm worker experiences greater gains in household income than a household with a current cadre. 2 Neither cadre entrepreneurs nor households with former cadres and cadre relations experience advantages in income growth. The analyses of household income for the coastal redistributive provinces (table 4, col. 2) show that cadres lack a statistically significant advantage; however, the interaction between cadre status and entrepreneur shows a net positive return, while entrepreneurs without redistributive power are at a relative disadvantage. The "power conversion" hypothesis finds support in the finding that the income growth of cadre entrepreneurs is highest of any group in the coastal redistributive provinces. However, these cadre entrepreneurs (N = 8) constitute.9% of the sample in this region, whereas households of current cadres make up 17%. In coastal redistributive provinces, the more broadly based source of relative gains in household earning are nonfarm jobs. The interaction between current cadre and entrepreneur suggests that local officials may be using their political power to establish private businesses. Table 5 reports results of a mixed model logistic regression analysis. It shows that neither current nor former cadre status has a statistically significant effect on the odds of entering into entrepreneurship in the 12 In a separate analysis not reported here, I controlled for the amount of start-up capital used by entrepreneurs and found that it failed to achieve statistical significance in all regions of China. The lack of a significant return to the amount of start-up capital indicates that the commitment to private entrepreneurship is more important than the actual amount of capital invested. In other words, private entrepreneurship results in a higher rate of growth in household income whether a household has greater or lesser accumulated capital to invest in starting up a business. 935

30 z C1 m 0 In inooo m s O it) -I ON m - oeo In C ou o N 0 0 o M Oo :m P. oo OC 1' r ' - I ON ON - q I - -I - - o r C 3- V. ** U W ** V 0 ONo 20 t.n~~~~~~~~~ m t- C1 m o In In m -* cn Z Z cr nooo m 0c m o od m ON e o - O? `: 4 C) _ C* _ C* _ X : ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~OC : : : : : : : : : (n O~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~C S t : :~ ~~~~~~ : : : : :. u 2 2, a, i w.~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~u c 936

31 0 oc) 0 cl-i CN in ir) OC) ir)m t- ir) Ir) In,o er) - 0,o 'o -.-I ir) m I- 0 m ir) in C:) -A C ir) -A -A C-4 -A.-I ir) C:) -A rq t- t- t ) cl 00 in CN in CN CN in ON Irlo CN o 00 CN m 00 I- CN CN ON CN t- CN t m,i- C4, in - 00 in 'o --i -.-I m in in r- ON 00 rq ON I- ir) ON -I- 00 in.-i.-i in 00 in r- 00 r- C) in 06 in C4, CN r- 0 CN m m II-) 0 CN ON r-,i- 11) -I- 0 m CN CN II),o 00 t in in r- 'IO rq in t m 110 O m o C,-)0 rq CD Cd Cd s:i0 0 z eii 4.1 > u(u %AJ Cd cd Cd Cd Cd 4-i C 1 1 Cd 4-j C's C's c, o o Cd u u u rq Cd cn v v v v 937

32 * * * * * * * * * * * * Cu2 * * * * * * * * t4,o m 0 CN t o C men 00 - m 0 NN z oo N1 00 CN m I-t m 00 m m m Oo o o 000 X s e wo~~o 0 t- - I t- OC,o,o ono ow * t * m o on Z~~~~~~~~~ t- in t-.- * '.j- t v ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~* 1 * * * * * 4 v~~~~7 a D 'D 0c I, CN -- in OC OOON O NoO Hv uz 0 t t- m o 0 C-N t- t- Co H i~~~~~~~~~ ~~~~~- ~0 0 CN t 0- z~~~~~0 Cv Cv cl 11 '1 C l l rq ll 1 1 ll i t" CD O F~~~~~~ Q 0)* ~. -/ m * */-* * oow O oo * oo F 0 N m 0t 0 U O) m O w CN t- C 0 0 * *--*---.~~CN 10 0 > C0 X * * * * O =~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~C * * ** 0~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~ 0 * -* * ~-i* * z 0d C ~C I ~~~~~~~~~~2 0/) I ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ 0-~~~~~~~; ~ Iv v 9:1 ga, Cd 0 Q., Q.,00 H 0 0 C, z 0) 0 0)~~ 0.) ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~C z -~~~ -e 00 ~~~~OOO ~~ 0) > 1 U VVVVC/

33 Symposium: Nee maritime provinces. Only in the inland provinces does political capitalformer cadres-increase the odds of entering into entrepreneurship; but, there, cadres entrepreneurs failed to obtain a net income advantage over other households. When viewed from the vantage of the nation as a whole, the effect of cadre status on the odds of becoming an entrepreneur is negative and significant. This is in line with market transition theory's prediction that over time, the initial cadre advantage in becoming entrepreneurs declines. Overall, these findings fail to support the "power conversion" hypothesis of state-centered analysis that cadres readily convert their political capital into economic capital by becoming entrepreneurs and thereby becoming the primary beneficiaries of marketization. The coastal corporatist provinces exhibit processes of stratification that represent a significant departure from the pattern of social inequality produced by state socialist redistribution (Szelenyi 1978). Initially it would appear that the corporatist region is similar to the inland region: cadre position has a significant effect on change in household income (table 4). But distinctive to the corporatist provinces, the income returns of nonfarm workers, entrepreneurs, and cadres fall within a narrow band, with somewhat higher income returns to nonfarm laborers and entrepreneurs. Corporatist communities appear to be able to specify and enforce rules of income distribution consistent with egalitarian principles, resulting in declining income inequality between households from 1978 to As a result, income inequality declined steadily as seen in the coefficient of variation over the three years (1978, 1983, 1989) income data was collected (Zhejiang,.767 ->.649 ->.674; Jiangsu, >.711). In every other region of China, income inequality increased during the mid- to late 1980s. Whether the coastal corporatist region can continue to buck the national trend of increasing income inequality is not clear. The institutional environment giving rise to local corporatism is in dynamic transition. The collective ownership form remains dominant in corporatist communities so long as local governments exclude private firms from subcontracting arrangements with state-owned enterprises and control quasi markets for key factor resources and financial capital. Should barriers to entry be lowered in the industrial economy, markets thicken, and competition from private firms intensify, the profits of entrepreneurs in the corporatist region are likely to increase as they have in the laissez-faire provinces. Whether local corporatist communities can persist in upholding egalitarian rules in the distribution of rewards depends on the persistence of social institutions and collective action giving rise to a moral order that constrains rent seeking by cadres and limits the profits of entrepreneurs. These include social sanctions, threat of ostracism, protest, sabotage, violence, and other forms of collective action (Lyons 1994). 939

34 American Journal of Sociology The last column in table 4 reports estimates of change in household income for the laissez-faire provinces. Cadres do not retain an advantage in the most marketized of the coastal provinces. This finding replicates the results reported in the early test of market transition theory. 13 It also corresponds with the analysis reported in table 2. In the laissez-faire provinces, most nonfarm jobs are secured in labor markets through social networks and job referral agencies and are not allocated by local government.14 Combined, these findings confirm a diminished significance of socialist redistributive power as a function of the extent of the market. 15 Not surprisingly entrepreneurs here enjoy the greatest gains in household income of all the regions. An increase in the number of laborers, male and female, has a statistically significant effect on gains in household income. Hence, the pattern is quite clear: in the coastal laissez-faire provinces, producers and entrepreneurs experience greater gains in income than the local administrative elite. Moreover, current officials in the southeastern coastal region are not advantaged as cadre entrepreneurs, nor does political capital contribute to growth of household income. In the laissez-faire provinces, household heads unexpectedly receive no advantage to education. The income effects of junior middle and advanced education do not turn statistically significant and negative until after controlling for nonfarm workers. This is because the household head is more apt to be involved in agriculture.'6 Analysis of discrete income streams for the nation as a whole by agriculture, private business, and nonfarm sources not reported here indicates that education has a 13 In a separate analysis not reported here, I control for the rank of cadres. In this analysis village-level cadres exhibit a positive significant effect, while market town cadres show a negative effect. Unlike the inland region where market town, administrative town, and village were significant, other ranks in the laissez-faire provinces show no positive income effect for cadre status. 14 In other regions of China, the absence of a statistically significant income effect of nonfarm jobs found by village governments may be interpreted as evidence of the emergence of quasi labor markets. 15 Some might point to the smaller sample size between the inland region (N = 4,175) and the coastal subregions (N = 673; N = 1,009; N = 1,098) as accounting for the differences in the statistical significance of test variables. Yet the same pattern of decline in the effects of cadre position on nonfarm jobs and household income obtains when the coastal subregions are pooled (N = 2,780). 16 In the preliminary test of market transition theory, a summary measure of the educational attainment of both husband and wife was employed. When the human capital of only the household head was used, statistical significance was not obtained for education. An index of educational attainment that included the educational attainment of nonfarm workers in industry and the spouse of the household head might have conveyed a different story, one more in line with earlier findings on the effect of education (see Peng 1992). 940

35 Symposium: Nee negative effect on agricultural income, though it is statistically significant only for advanced schooling. It has a significant positive effect in the sectors of the rural economy that experienced a shift to greater reliance on markets (private business and nonfarm income). Separate mixed models of the determination of these income streams computed for the laissezfaire provinces reveal the same negative effect of education in the determination of agricultural income, but the effects of schooling on private business and nonfarm income are not statistically significant. Market transition theory claims that the shift to a market economy improves incentives at the individual level. That the incentive to work has improved a great deal in the laissez-faire provinces is confirmed at the aggregate level in their unprecedented rates of economic growth. It is also seen in the higher income returns of entrepreneurs. The logistic regression results reported in table 5 show that education increases the odds of becoming an entrepreneur in the laissez-faire provinces. The predicted effect of education is mediated through entrepreneurship. For whatever reason, what normally should have served as a reliable measure of the incentive to work-income returns to education-did not perform as expected for heads of households who are more likely to remain in agriculture. Is the education of the household head not a sensitive measure of the incentive to work in a household economy in which agriculture comprises a declining source of cash income contributed by income earners? This is suggested by the positive returns to education in the inland region where nonfarm jobs are relatively scarce and agriculture remains the only source of income for all but a few.'7 Or could it be that the rough and tumble of early capitalism is such that education does not matter in the pursuit of power and plenty? It may be that under conditions of exceptionally rapid economic growth, opportunities for advancement abound to the extent that formal schooling no longer serves as a screening mechanism. Across all of the regions, the impact of producers on the household's earnings is positive and robust. Moreover, the contribution of a nonfarm worker to the household's income stream is greater than that made by a cadre. In all but the coastal redistributive provinces, the income gains of private entrepreneurs are greater than those of cadres. The widest gap in income growth favoring producers-farm and nonfarm workers and entrepreneurs-relative to cadres occurs in the laissez-faire provinces. 17 In the earlier test of market transition theory, the education of the head of household also failed to have a significant effect. Only when the educations of husband and wife were pooled did education show an effect on household income (Nee 1989). This was not possible here because the spouse's education was not available. 941

36 American Journal of Sociology Such evidence, combined with the control on the level of local industralization, lends support to the new institutionalist causal arguments on change in the mechanism of stratification.'8 Contradicting the industralism hypothesis, the less industrialized and more marketized coastal provinces-guangdong and Fujian-showed the least continuity with the old stratification order. Moreover, the more industrialized coastal provinces revealed more continuity with the stratification order structured by redistribution. However, though cadre entrepreneurs were advantaged in the coastal redistributive provinces, officials not in private business were not. Though current cadres experienced significant income returns in the corporatist region, this did not entitle them to a higher growth of income relative to other groups. Rural industry is more highly developed in the coastal redistributive and corporatist provinces, yet members of the cadre status group are not advantaged in securing nonfarm jobs for family members and relatives and in becoming private entrepreneurs. CONCLUSION The analysis here confirms that the stratification order of rural China began a transformative change during the 1980s. Especially in the marketized coastal region, households moved up and down in relative economic standing, driven by new rules and mechanisms for getting ahead. The old rules of the game no longer worked as they did in the Maoist era, and households that followed those rules discovered that they fell in relative economic standing. However, households that were quick to adjust to an emergent market economy discovered new rules for getting ahead. These households experienced rapid increases in household earning power. By 1989, only 30% of cadre households in the sample were in the top income quintile. That cadre households make up a relatively small percentage of the households in the top income quintile supports the main claim of market transition theory. Most households in the top income group were newly affluent producers and entrepreneurs not from cadre background. Even in the absence of regime change, a rapid shift to markets incrementally causes a relative decline in the significance of positional power based on redistribution and relative gain in the power of producers and entrepreneurs. The interactions testing the effect of local marketization and resulting affluence on the income returns to the administrative elite 18 The control on industrial output indicates that in the maritime provinces, the level of industrialization does not directly effect change in household income; but it has a significant negative effect in the inland region. Yet, table 4 shows that industrial output has a robust effect on nonfarm income in the nation as a whole, though its effect on total household income is negative. 942

37 Symposium: Nee confirm a causal relationship between institutional change and decline in the significance of positional power in the government bureaucracy. In the relatively laissez-faire coastal provinces, where no direct advantage was found for cadre position, the decline in the significance of redistributive power on household earning is more manifest. The contextual variable indicating whether nonfarm jobs are gained through political allocation or through markets is perhaps the best indicator of the redistributive power of local government. It showed a net negative effect in the laissezfaire coastal provinces. However, the more important evidence is seen in the higher income gains of producers and entrepreneurs relative to cadres in the country as a whole and especially in the laissez-faire subregion. Some results were inconsistent with the predictions of market transition theory. These include the absence of a positive income effect of education in the coastal provinces. No doubt others will be uncovered in the course of future research. Theory cannot yet readily anticipate how redistributive institutions combine with market forces (Stark, in this issue). Hybrid state-controlled markets in which cadres set the price by administrative fiat, often according to political favor, are a feature of China's mixed economy; these are likely to persist as long as land and major fixed capital assets remain under redistributive control. An example is the housing market in urban China where quasi markets have introduced elements of a commodity exchange but within the existingthough changing-institutional framework of state ownership of real property (Zhou and Logan 1994). For these reasons, many of the unanticipated features of the emergent stratification order are likely to stem from the impact of socialist hybrids and their governance structure, local corporatism, in altering the mechanisms of stratification. In the stratification order based on socialist redistribution, the political power of cadres entitles them to a greater share of the rewards than others with the same human capital and household characteristics. This condition persists in urban centers where the structure of property rights remains largely unchanged and redistribution continues to be institutionally dominant, as Walder's (1992) analysis of nonwage benefits using 1986 data from Tianjin, a northern industrial city, indicates. In cities, nonmarket allocation of labor continues, and emergent labor markets are confined mainly to the second economy. For these reasons, cadre status continues to be associated with controlling the distribution of rewards. In socialist redistributive economies, cadres stand at the pinnacle of the stratification order. The main mechanism of stratification is bound up with access to and control over redistributive institutions: mainly the party and state bureaucracies. Households compete to secure redistributive power, either directly by holding office or through the acquisition of network ties that guarantee ease of access to officials in power. In con- 943

38 American Journal of Sociology trast, gains in earning power in the emerging stratification order shaped by market forces are derived through jobs in marketized firms (e.g., joint ventures) or through entrepreneurship. Like other households, cadres too strive to adjust to the new opportunity structure created by markets. Many in fact turn to entrepreneurship seeking to secure a privileged place in the new stratification order. In the initial stages of market transition, cadre entrepreneurs enjoy an advantage in the pursuit of market power. Their control over the disposition of scarce resources not available in the marketplace confers class advantages based on redistributive power. However, the cadre advantage is diminished as the leverage gained from redistributive power erodes in the wake of expanding markets and corresponding changes in the structure of property rights. Tests of market transition arguments in the urban context are at an early stage. Analyses of income returns in Tianjin (Bian and Logan 1996) and Shanghai (Nee and Cao 1995) report a persistence of cadre power in the redistributive sector and evidence of decline in income returns to party membership in the marketized sectors. The extent of decline is greatest in Shanghai where the data were collected in There party membership shows a significant negative effect in the marketized sector of the urban economy. Also as predicted by the theory, in both Tianjin and Shanghai, human capital obtains its largest return in the marketized and private economic sectors. These findings are consistent with results which verify the declining-significance-of-redistributive-power hypothesis in the rural setting. More recently, Walder's (1995a) analysis of career mobility in Tianjin concludes that the power and advantages of the redistributive elite are shallow when perceived from the vantage point of the potential for gain and profit in a market economy. His prediction that marketization will erode the advantages of the redistributive elite, especially after inflation takes its toll on the salary of government employees, leads him toward convergence with explanations and predictions developed by market transition theory. Xie and Hannum (in this issue) conflate the still dominant governmentcontrolled urban redistributive economy with the emergent marketized sectors, resulting in erroneous interpretations of continuing income returns to party membership. Their findings are inconclusive because they use the wrong exogenous variable to test market transition theory. Their multilevel analysis examines the effect of extensive industrial growth on returns to human capital and party membership in Chinese cities. I use industrial output as a control for the industrialism hypothesis, not as in Xie and Hannum, a measure of the extent of the shift to markets. They assert their hypotheses are derived from my earlier work (Nee 1989), but market transition theory makes no claim about industrial growth. The application of the Stalinist growth model produced extensive in- 944

39 Symposium: Nee dustrial growth without markets in the Soviet Union and Eastern Europe (Erlich 1977; Szelenyi 1989). Similarly in China, industrial growth in the 1950s was accomplished through the elimination of markets and bureaucratic mobilization of resources (Schurmann 1966). After 1989, Eastern European societies experienced rapid marketization, yet this did not give rise to economic growth. Hence, extensive industrial growth is an inappropriate, and at best, faulty measure of the extent of marketization. Market transition theory maintains that institutional change-the emergence of market institutions (e.g., labor and capital markets)-causes the predicted change in the mechanisms of stratification. In the absence of such institutional change, it predicts continuity in the stratification order. In focusing almost solely on change in the state organizational hierarchy and on the fate of the cadre elite, state-centered analysis overlooks the pursuit of power and plenty by economic actors in society. Although the state plays a critical role in initiating and sustaining the transition to a market society, research needs to move beyond the limits of statecentered analysis to take into account the societal wellspring of transformative institutional change. REFERENCES Aitkin, M., and N. Longford "Statistical Modeling Issues in School Effectiveness Studies." Journal of the Royal Statistical Academy 149:1-43. Arendt, Hannah Totalitarianism, part 3. The Origins of Totalitarianism. New York: Harcourt, Brace & World. Bian, Yanjie, and John Logan "Income Inequality in Tianjin: 1978 to 1993." American Sociological Review, in press. Brown, George P "Rural Reforms and the Sunan Model." Paper presented at the Annual Meeting of the Association for Asian Studies, Washington, D.C., April. Burawoy, Michael, and Janos Lukacs The Radiant Past: Ideology and Reality in Hungary's Road to Capitalism. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Byrd, William A., and Lin Qingsong, eds China's Rural Industry: Structure, Development, and Reform. New York: Oxford University Press. Bryk, Anthony S., and Stephen W. Raudenbush Hierarchical Linear Models: Applications and Data Analysis Methods. Newbury Park, Calif.: Sage. Chayanov, A. V The Theory of Peasant Economy. Homewood, Ill.: Richard D. Irwin for the American Economic Association. Chen Junshi, T. Colin Campbell, Li Junyao, and Richard Peto Diet, Life-Style, and Mortality in China: A Study of the Characteristics of 65 Chinese Counties. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Cook, Karen Schweers, and Margaret Levi, eds The Limits of Rationality. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Eggertsson, Thrainn Economic Behavior and Institutions. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Emerson, Richard A "Power-Dependence Relations." American Sociological Review 27: Erlich, A "Stalinism and Marxian Growth Models." Pp in Stalinism:

40 American Journal of Sociology Essays in Historical Interpretation, edited by R. Tucker. New York: W. W. Norton. Friedrich, Carl J., ed Totalitarianism. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press. Granovetter, Mark "The Strength of Weak Ties." American Journal of Sociology 78: Grusky, David B., and Robert M. Hauser "Comparative Social Mobility Revisited: Models of Convergence and Divergence in 16 Countries." American Sociological Review 49: Hamilton, Gary G., ed Business Networks and Economic Development in East and Southeast Asia. Hong Kong: University of Hong Kong, Centre of Asian Study. Hankiss, Elemer East European Alternatives. Oxford: Clarendon Press. Hauser, Robert M., and David B. Grusky "Cross-National Variation in Occupational Distribution, Relative Mobility Chances, and Intergenerational Shifts in Occupational Distributions." American Sociological Review 41: Hechter, Michael Principles of Group Solidarity. Berkeley: University of California Press. Homans, George C The Human Group. New York: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich. Huang, Philip The Peasant Family and Rural Development in the Yangzi Delta: 1350 to Palo Alto, Calif.: Stanford University Press. Huang Shu-min The Spiral Road: Change in a Chinese Village through the Eyes of a Communist Party Leader. Boulder, Colo.: Westview. Johnson, Graham E "Open for Business, Open to the World: Consequences of Global Incorporation in Guangdong and the Pearl River Delta." Pp in The Economic Transformation of South China, edited by T. Lyons and V. Nee. Cornell East Asia Series, no. 70. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University, East Asia Program. Kornai, Janos The Economics of Shortage. Amsterdam: North-Holland. Lenski, Gerhard Power and Privilege. New York: McGraw-Hill. Liang, Echo Hang "Contractual Arrangements and Labor Incentives in Rural China: A Case Study of Northern Jiangsu." Pp in The Economic Transformation of South China, edited by T. Lyons and V. Nee. Cornell East Asia Series, no. 70. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University, East Asia Program. Liang, Zai, and Michael White. In press. "Market Transition, Government Policies, and Interprovincial Migration in China: " Economic Development and Cultural Change. Lin, Nan "Social Resources and Instrumental Action." Pp in Social Structure and Network Analysis, edited by P. Marsden and N. Lin. Beverly Hills, Calif.: Sage "Local Market Socialism: Local Corporatism in Action in Rural China." Theory and Society 24: Lindstrom, M. J., and D. M. Bates "Nonlinear Mixed Effects Models for Repeated Measures Data." Biometrics 46: Liu, Yia-ling "Reform from Below: The Private Economy and Local Politics in the Rural Industralization of Wenzhou." China Quarterly 130: Lipset, Seymour Martin, and Hans L. Zetterberg "Social Mobility in Industrial Societies." Pp in Social Mobility in Industrial Society, edited by S. M. Lipset and R. Bendix. Berkeley: University of California Press. Lyons, Thomas P "Economic Reform in Fujian: Another View from the Villages." Pp in The Economic Transformation of South China, edited by T. Lyons and V. Nee. Cornell East Asia Series, no. 70. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University, East Asia Program. Mason, William M., George Y. Wong, and Barbara Entwisle "Contextual 946

41 Symposium: Nee Analysis through the Multilevel Linear Model." Pp in Sociological Methodology, edited by S. Leinhardt. San Francisco: Jossey-Bass. McCullagh, P., and J. A. Nelder Generalized Linear Models. London: Chapsman & Hill. Merton, Robert K Social Theory and Social Structure. New York: Free Press. Nee, Victor "A Theory of Market Transition: From Redistribution to Markets in State Socialism." American Sociological Review 54: "Social Inequalities in Reforming State Socialism: Between Redistribution and Markets in China." American Sociological Review 56: "Organizational Dynamics of Market Transition: Hybrid Forms, Property Rights, and Mixed Economy in China." Administrative Science Quarterly 37:1-27. Nee, Victor, and Yang Cao "Testing Market Transition Theory in the Urban Context." Paper to be presented at the Market Transition Debate workshop at the University of California, Los Angeles, May. Nee, Victor, and Paul Ingram. In press. "Embeddedness and Beyond: Institutions, Exchange and Social Structure." In The New Institutionalism in Economic Sociology, edited by M. Brinton and V. Nee. New York: Russell Sage Foundation. Nee, Victor, and Peng Lian "Sleeping with the Enemy: A Dynamic Model of Declining Political Commitment in State Socialism." Theory and Society 23: Nee, Victor, and Raymond V. Liedka "Institutions, Income Mobility, and the Production of Inequality in Reforming State Socialism." Working Papers on the Transitions from State Socialism, no Cornell University, Einaudi Center for International Studies. Nee, Victor, and Rebecca Matthews "Market Transition and Societal Transformation in Reforming State Socialism." Annual Review of Sociology 22, in press. Nee, Victor, and Su Sijin "Institutional Change and Economic Growth: The View from the Villages." Journal of Asian Studies 39: "Institutions, Social Ties, and Commitment in China's Corporatist Transformation" In Remaking Asian Economies: The Growth of Market Institutions, edited by J. McMillan and B. Naughton. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press. North, Douglass C "Markets and Other Allocation Systems in History: The Challenge of Karl Polanyi." Journal of European Economic History 6: Structure and Change in Economic History. New York: Norton. Oi, Jean C "The Fate of the Collective after the Commune." Pp in Chinese Society on the Eve of Tiananmen: The Impact of Reform, edited by D. Davis and E. Vogel. Cambridge, Mass.: Council of East Asian Studies "Fiscal Reform and the Economic Foundations of Local State Corporatism in China." World Politics 45: Parish, William L "Rural Industralization in Fujian and Taiwan." Pp in The Economic Transformation of South China, edited by T. Lyons and V. Nee. Cornell East Asia Series, no. 70. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University, East Asia Program. Parish, William L., Xiaoye Zhe, and Fang Li "Nonfarm Work and Marketization of the Chinese Countryside." China Quarterly 143: Parpia, Banoo "Socioeconomic Determinants of Food and Nutrient Intakes in Rural China." Doctoral dissertation. Cornell University, Department of Sociology. Peng, Yusheng "Wage Determination in Rural and Urban China: A Comparison of Public and Private Industrial Sectors." American Sociological Review 57: Polanyi, Karl The Great Transformation: The Political and Economic Origins of Our Time. New York: Rinehart. 947

42 American Journal of Sociology "The Economy as Instituted Process." Pp in Trade and Market in Early Empires, edited by K. Polanyi, C. Arensberg, and H. Pearson. Glencoe, Ill.: Free Press. Pryor, Frederick L Property and Industrial Organization in Communist and Capitalist Nations. Bloomington: Indiana University Press. Qian, Yingyi, and Chenggang Xu "Why China's Economic Reforms Differ: The M-Form Hierarchy and Entry/Expansion of the Non-State Sector." Economics of Transition 1: R6na-Tas, Akos "The First Shall Be Last? Entrepreneurship and Communist Cadres in the Transition from Socialism." American Journal of Sociology 100: Sahlins, Marshall Stone Age Economics. New York: Aldine. Schurmann, Franz Ideology and Organization in Communist China. Berkeley: University of California Press. Searle, Shayle R., George Casella, and Charles E. McCulloch Variance Components. New York: John Wiley. Shirk, Susan "The Political Economy of Chinese Industrial Reform." Pp in Remaking the Economic Institutions of Socialism: China and Eastern Europe, edited by V. Nee and D. Stark. Stanford, Calif.: Stanford University Press. Skilling, H. Gordon, and Franklyn Griffith, eds Interest Groups in Soviet Politics. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press. Staniszkis, Jadwiga The Dynamics of the Breakthrough in Eastern Europe: The Polish Experience. Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of California Press. Stark, David "Recombinant Property in East European Capitalism." American Journal of Sociology, in this issue. Stark, David, and Victor Nee "Towards an Institutional Analysis of State Socialism." Pp in Remaking the Economic Institutions of Socialism, edited by V. Nee and D. Stark. Stanford, Calif.: Stanford University Press. Su, Sijin "Institutional Change and Dynamics of Market Growth in Chinese Firms." Doctoral dissertation. Cornell University, Department of Sociology "Hybrid Organizational Forms in South China: 'One Firm, Two Systems."' Pp in The Economic Transformation of South China, edited by T. Lyons and V. Nee. Cornell East Asia Series, no. 70. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University, East Asia Program. Szelenyi, Ivain "Social Inequalities in State Socialist Redistributive Economies. International Journal of Comparative Sociology 19: "Eastern Europe in Transition." Pp in Remaking the Economic Institutions of Socialism: China and Eastern Europe, edited by V. Nee and D. Stark. Stanford, Calif.: Stanford University Press. Szelenyi, Ivan, and Robert Manchin "Social Policy under State Socialism." Pp in Stagnation and Renewal in Social Policy, edited by G. Esping- Anderson, L. Rainwater, and M. Rein. White Plains, N.Y.: M. E. Sharpe. Treiman, Donald J "Industralization and Social Stratification." Pp in Social Stratification: Research and Theory for the 1970s, edited by E. 0. Laumann. Indianapolis: Bobbs-Merrill. Vogel, Ezra F One Step Ahead in China: Guangdong under Reform. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press. Walder, Andrew G Communist Neo-Traditionalism: Work and Authority in Chinese Industry. Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of California Press "Property Rights and Stratification in Socialist Redistributive Economies." American Sociological Review 57: a. "Career Mobility and the Communist Political Order." American Sociological Review 60:

MARKET TRANSITION AND SOCIETAL TRANSFORMATION IN REFORMING STATE SOCIALISM

MARKET TRANSITION AND SOCIETAL TRANSFORMATION IN REFORMING STATE SOCIALISM Annu. Rev. Sociol. 1996. 22:401 35 Copyright c 1996 by Annual Reviews Inc. All rights reserved MARKET TRANSITION AND SOCIETAL TRANSFORMATION IN REFORMING STATE SOCIALISM Victor Nee and Rebecca Matthews

More information

MARKET TRANSITION: AN ASSESSMENT OF THE STATE OF THE FIELD

MARKET TRANSITION: AN ASSESSMENT OF THE STATE OF THE FIELD MARKET TRANSITION: AN ASSESSMENT OF THE STATE OF THE FIELD LISA A. KEISTER E. PAIGE BORELLI Duke University ABSTRACT: Dramatic changes in global politics and economics have led a large number of economies

More information

Migration and Transformation of Rural China* (Preliminary Draft) Zai Liang and Miao David Chunyu

Migration and Transformation of Rural China* (Preliminary Draft) Zai Liang and Miao David Chunyu Migration and Transformation of Rural China* (Preliminary Draft) Zai Liang and Miao David Chunyu Department of Sociology State University of New York 1400 Washington Ave. Albany, NY 12222 Phone: 518-442-4676

More information

THE WILLIAM DAVIDSON INSTITUTE AT THE UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN BUSINESS SCHOOL

THE WILLIAM DAVIDSON INSTITUTE AT THE UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN BUSINESS SCHOOL THE WILLIAM DAVIDSON INSTITUTE AT THE UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN BUSINESS SCHOOL Embracing the Market: Entry into Self-Employment in Transitional China, 1978-1996 By: Xiaogang Wu William Davidson Working Paper

More information

The interaction term received intense scrutiny, much of it critical,

The interaction term received intense scrutiny, much of it critical, 2 INTERACTIONS IN SOCIAL SCIENCE The interaction term received intense scrutiny, much of it critical, upon its introduction to social science. Althauser (1971) wrote, It would appear, in short, that including

More information

11/7/2011. Section 1: Answering the Three Economic Questions. Section 2: The Free Market

11/7/2011. Section 1: Answering the Three Economic Questions. Section 2: The Free Market Essential Question Chapter 6: Economic Systems Opener How does a society decide who gets what goods and services? Chapter 6, Opener Slide 2 Guiding Questions Section 1: Answering the Three Economic Questions

More information

5. Destination Consumption

5. Destination Consumption 5. Destination Consumption Enabling migrants propensity to consume Meiyan Wang and Cai Fang Introduction The 2014 Central Economic Working Conference emphasised that China s economy has a new normal, characterised

More information

Roles of children and elderly in migration decision of adults: case from rural China

Roles of children and elderly in migration decision of adults: case from rural China Roles of children and elderly in migration decision of adults: case from rural China Extended abstract: Urbanization has been taking place in many of today s developing countries, with surging rural-urban

More information

The Role of the State in the Process of Institutional Evolvement in Agricultural Land after the Founding of PRC

The Role of the State in the Process of Institutional Evolvement in Agricultural Land after the Founding of PRC The Role of the State in the Process of Institutional Evolvement in Agricultural Land after the Founding of PRC Xin Shang College of Economics and Management, Jilin Agricultural University Changchun 130118,

More information

The impacts of minimum wage policy in china

The impacts of minimum wage policy in china The impacts of minimum wage policy in china Mixed results for women, youth and migrants Li Shi and Carl Lin With support from: The chapter is submitted by guest contributors. Carl Lin is the Assistant

More information

Chapter 8 Government Institution And Economic Growth

Chapter 8 Government Institution And Economic Growth Chapter 8 Government Institution And Economic Growth 8.1 Introduction The rapidly expanding involvement of governments in economies throughout the world, with government taxation and expenditure as a share

More information

Overview The Dualistic System Urbanization Rural-Urban Migration Consequences of Urban-Rural Divide Conclusions

Overview The Dualistic System Urbanization Rural-Urban Migration Consequences of Urban-Rural Divide Conclusions Overview The Dualistic System Urbanization Rural-Urban Migration Consequences of Urban-Rural Divide Conclusions Even for a developing economy, difference between urban/rural society very pronounced Administrative

More information

Domestic and International Migration from China: the Impact of Migration Networks and Rural Political Economy* (draft) Zai Liang and Miao David Chunyu

Domestic and International Migration from China: the Impact of Migration Networks and Rural Political Economy* (draft) Zai Liang and Miao David Chunyu Domestic and International Migration from China: the Impact of Migration Networks and Rural Political Economy* (draft) Zai Liang and Miao David Chunyu Department of Sociology State University of New York

More information

Comparison on the Developmental Trends Between Chinese Students Studying Abroad and Foreign Students Studying in China

Comparison on the Developmental Trends Between Chinese Students Studying Abroad and Foreign Students Studying in China 34 Journal of International Students Peer-Reviewed Article ISSN: 2162-3104 Print/ ISSN: 2166-3750 Online Volume 4, Issue 1 (2014), pp. 34-47 Journal of International Students http://jistudents.org/ Comparison

More information

Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance by Douglass C. North Cambridge University Press, 1990

Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance by Douglass C. North Cambridge University Press, 1990 Robert Donnelly IS 816 Review Essay Week 6 6 February 2005 Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance by Douglass C. North Cambridge University Press, 1990 1. Summary of the major arguments

More information

Inequality in China: Rural poverty persists as urban wealth

Inequality in China: Rural poverty persists as urban wealth Inequality in China: Rural poverty persists as urban wealth balloons 29 June 2011 Last updated at 22:36 GMT By Dr Damian Tobin School of Oriental and African Studies The rapid growth of China's economy

More information

Birth Control Policy and Housing Markets: The Case of China. By Chenxi Zhang (UO )

Birth Control Policy and Housing Markets: The Case of China. By Chenxi Zhang (UO ) Birth Control Policy and Housing Markets: The Case of China By Chenxi Zhang (UO008312836) Department of Economics of the University of Ottawa In partial fulfillment of the requirements of the M.A. Degree

More information

Social Mobility in Modern China

Social Mobility in Modern China Social Mobility in Modern China Jing YANG University of Oxford Most socialist countries in East Europe and Asia implemented economic reforms in the early 1980s. Among them, China is a unique case in that

More information

Openness and Poverty Reduction in the Long and Short Run. Mark R. Rosenzweig. Harvard University. October 2003

Openness and Poverty Reduction in the Long and Short Run. Mark R. Rosenzweig. Harvard University. October 2003 Openness and Poverty Reduction in the Long and Short Run Mark R. Rosenzweig Harvard University October 2003 Prepared for the Conference on The Future of Globalization Yale University. October 10-11, 2003

More information

What accounts for the variance of democratization in Rural China -- A study on village elections in rural Guangdong

What accounts for the variance of democratization in Rural China -- A study on village elections in rural Guangdong What accounts for the variance of democratization in Rural China -- A study on village elections in rural Guangdong By Ting Luo 1 China s development in advoating elections at grassroots level, namely,

More information

Family Ties, Labor Mobility and Interregional Wage Differentials*

Family Ties, Labor Mobility and Interregional Wage Differentials* Family Ties, Labor Mobility and Interregional Wage Differentials* TODD L. CHERRY, Ph.D.** Department of Economics and Finance University of Wyoming Laramie WY 82071-3985 PETE T. TSOURNOS, Ph.D. Pacific

More information

Internal Migration and Living Apart in China

Internal Migration and Living Apart in China Internal Migration and Living Apart in China Center for Population and Development Studies Renmin University of China Beijing 100872, PRC Juhua.Yang00@gmail.com Abstract: While there is a tendency that

More information

Changing income distribution in China

Changing income distribution in China Changing income distribution in China Li Shi' Since the late 1970s, China has undergone transition towards a market economy. In terms of economic growth, China has achieved an impressive record. The average

More information

Europe China Research and Advice Network (ECRAN)

Europe China Research and Advice Network (ECRAN) Europe China Research and Advice Network (ECRAN) 2010/256-524 Short Term Policy Brief 26 Cadre Training and the Party School System in Contemporary China Date: October 2011 Author: Frank N. Pieke This

More information

ECONOMIC SYSTEMS AND DECISION MAKING. Understanding Economics - Chapter 2

ECONOMIC SYSTEMS AND DECISION MAKING. Understanding Economics - Chapter 2 ECONOMIC SYSTEMS AND DECISION MAKING Understanding Economics - Chapter 2 ECONOMIC SYSTEMS Chapter 2, Lesson 1 ECONOMIC SYSTEMS Traditional Market Command Mixed! Economic System organized way a society

More information

INSTITUTIONS MATTER (revision 3/28/94)

INSTITUTIONS MATTER (revision 3/28/94) 1 INSTITUTIONS MATTER (revision 3/28/94) I Successful development policy entails an understanding of the dynamics of economic change if the policies pursued are to have the desired consequences. And a

More information

Rural-urban Migration and Urbanization in Gansu Province, China: Evidence from Time-series Analysis

Rural-urban Migration and Urbanization in Gansu Province, China: Evidence from Time-series Analysis Rural-urban Migration and Urbanization in Gansu Province, China: Evidence from Time-series Analysis Haiying Ma (Corresponding author) Lecturer, School of Economics, Northwest University for Nationalities

More information

11. Demographic Transition in Rural China:

11. Demographic Transition in Rural China: 11. Demographic Transition in Rural China: A field survey of five provinces Funing Zhong and Jing Xiang Introduction Rural urban migration and labour mobility are major drivers of China s recent economic

More information

Is Economic Development Good for Gender Equality? Income Growth and Poverty

Is Economic Development Good for Gender Equality? Income Growth and Poverty Is Economic Development Good for Gender Equality? February 25 and 27, 2003 Income Growth and Poverty Evidence from many countries shows that while economic growth has not eliminated poverty, the share

More information

PROGRAM ON HOUSING AND URBAN POLICY

PROGRAM ON HOUSING AND URBAN POLICY Institute of Business and Economic Research Fisher Center for Real Estate and Urban Economics PROGRAM ON HOUSING AND URBAN POLICY PROFESSIONAL REPORT SERIES PROFESSIONAL REPORT NO. P07-001 URBANIZATION

More information

Metropolitan Characteristics and Immigrant Entrepreneurship. Eric Fong, Junmin Jeong, Julie Jo. University of Toronto

Metropolitan Characteristics and Immigrant Entrepreneurship. Eric Fong, Junmin Jeong, Julie Jo. University of Toronto Metropolitan Characteristics and Immigrant Entrepreneurship Eric Fong, Junmin Jeong, Julie Jo University of Toronto October, 2012 It has become more common to find immigrant entrepreneurs not only in immigrant

More information

Vote Buying and Clientelism

Vote Buying and Clientelism Vote Buying and Clientelism Dilip Mookherjee Boston University Lecture 18 DM (BU) Clientelism 2018 1 / 1 Clientelism and Vote-Buying: Introduction Pervasiveness of vote-buying and clientelistic machine

More information

Notes on Charles Lindblom s The Market System

Notes on Charles Lindblom s The Market System Notes on Charles Lindblom s The Market System Yale University Press, 2001. by Christopher Pokarier for the course Enterprise + Governance @ Waseda University. Events of the last three decades make conceptualising

More information

SIMPLE LINEAR REGRESSION OF CPS DATA

SIMPLE LINEAR REGRESSION OF CPS DATA SIMPLE LINEAR REGRESSION OF CPS DATA Using the 1995 CPS data, hourly wages are regressed against years of education. The regression output in Table 4.1 indicates that there are 1003 persons in the CPS

More information

Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation

Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation S. Roy*, Department of Economics, High Point University, High Point, NC - 27262, USA. Email: sroy@highpoint.edu Abstract We implement OLS,

More information

Migration Networks, Hukou, and Destination Choices in China

Migration Networks, Hukou, and Destination Choices in China Migration Networks, Hukou, and Destination Choices in China Zai Liang Department of Sociology State University of New York at Albany 1400 Washington Ave. Albany, NY 12222 Phone: 518-442-4676 Fax: 518-442-4936

More information

CHAPTER 2 LITERATURE REVIEWS

CHAPTER 2 LITERATURE REVIEWS CHAPTER 2 LITERATURE REVIEWS The relationship between efficiency and income equality is an old topic, but Lewis (1954) and Kuznets (1955) was the earlier literature that systemically discussed income inequality

More information

MATERIAL REWARDS TO MULTIPLE CAPITALS UNDER MARKET-SOCIALISM IN CHINA 1. Deborah Davis, Bian Yan-jie and Wang Shaoguang

MATERIAL REWARDS TO MULTIPLE CAPITALS UNDER MARKET-SOCIALISM IN CHINA 1. Deborah Davis, Bian Yan-jie and Wang Shaoguang STCS_31-58 3/22/06 1:16 PM Page 31 MATERIAL REWARDS TO MULTIPLE CAPITALS UNDER MARKET-SOCIALISM IN CHINA 1 Deborah Davis, Bian Yan-jie and Wang Shaoguang Abstract Using data from a yearlong interview project

More information

The Consequences of Marketization for Health in China, 1991 to 2004: An Examination of Changes in Urban-Rural Differences

The Consequences of Marketization for Health in China, 1991 to 2004: An Examination of Changes in Urban-Rural Differences The Consequences of Marketization for Health in China, 1991 to 2004: An Examination of Changes in Urban-Rural Differences Ke LIANG Ph.D. Ke.liang@baruch.cuny.edu Assistant Professor of Sociology Sociology

More information

Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US

Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US Ben Ost a and Eva Dziadula b a Department of Economics, University of Illinois at Chicago, 601 South Morgan UH718 M/C144 Chicago,

More information

Relative Performance Evaluation and the Turnover of Provincial Leaders in China

Relative Performance Evaluation and the Turnover of Provincial Leaders in China Relative Performance Evaluation and the Turnover of Provincial Leaders in China Ye Chen Hongbin Li Li-An Zhou May 1, 2005 Abstract Using data from China, this paper examines the role of relative performance

More information

Stratification: Rich and Famous or Rags and Famine? 2015 SAGE Publications, Inc.

Stratification: Rich and Famous or Rags and Famine? 2015 SAGE Publications, Inc. Chapter 7 Stratification: Rich and Famous or Rags and Famine? The Importance of Stratification Social stratification: individuals and groups are layered or ranked in society according to how many valued

More information

The Chinese Economy. Elliott Parker, Ph.D. Professor of Economics University of Nevada, Reno

The Chinese Economy. Elliott Parker, Ph.D. Professor of Economics University of Nevada, Reno The Chinese Economy Elliott Parker, Ph.D. Professor of Economics University of Nevada, Reno The People s s Republic of China is currently the sixth (or possibly even the second) largest economy in the

More information

Immigrant Legalization

Immigrant Legalization Technical Appendices Immigrant Legalization Assessing the Labor Market Effects Laura Hill Magnus Lofstrom Joseph Hayes Contents Appendix A. Data from the 2003 New Immigrant Survey Appendix B. Measuring

More information

Rural Labor Force Emigration on the Impact. and Effect of Macro-Economy in China

Rural Labor Force Emigration on the Impact. and Effect of Macro-Economy in China Rural Labor Force Emigration on the Impact and Effect of Macro-Economy in China Laiyun Sheng Department of Rural Socio-Economic Survey, National Bureau of Statistics of China China has a large amount of

More information

Brain Drain, Brain Gain, and Economic Growth in China

Brain Drain, Brain Gain, and Economic Growth in China MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Brain Drain, Brain Gain, and Economic Growth in China Wei Ha and Junjian Yi and Junsen Zhang United Nations Development Programme, Economics Department of the Chinese

More information

Remarks on the Political Economy of Inequality

Remarks on the Political Economy of Inequality Remarks on the Political Economy of Inequality Bank of England Tim Besley LSE December 19th 2014 TB (LSE) Political Economy of Inequality December 19th 2014 1 / 35 Background Research in political economy

More information

Chapter 7 Institutions and economics growth

Chapter 7 Institutions and economics growth Chapter 7 Institutions and economics growth 7.1 Institutions: Promoting productive activity and growth Institutions are the laws, social norms, traditions, religious beliefs, and other established rules

More information

IS STARE DECISIS A CONSTRAINT OR A CLOAK?

IS STARE DECISIS A CONSTRAINT OR A CLOAK? Copyright 2007 Ave Maria Law Review IS STARE DECISIS A CONSTRAINT OR A CLOAK? THE POLITICS OF PRECEDENT ON THE U.S. SUPREME COURT. By Thomas G. Hansford & James F. Spriggs II. Princeton University Press.

More information

Labour Market Reform, Rural Migration and Income Inequality in China -- A Dynamic General Equilibrium Analysis

Labour Market Reform, Rural Migration and Income Inequality in China -- A Dynamic General Equilibrium Analysis Labour Market Reform, Rural Migration and Income Inequality in China -- A Dynamic General Equilibrium Analysis Yinhua Mai And Xiujian Peng Centre of Policy Studies Monash University Australia April 2011

More information

Economic swings, political instability and ethnic-specific migration in Kyrgyzstan*

Economic swings, political instability and ethnic-specific migration in Kyrgyzstan* Economic swings, political instability and ethnic-specific migration in Kyrgyzstan* Victor Agadjanian Evgenia Gorina Center for Population Dynamics Arizona State University Abstract Studies of the effects

More information

Lessons of China s Economic Growth: Comment. These are three very fine papers. I say that not as an academic

Lessons of China s Economic Growth: Comment. These are three very fine papers. I say that not as an academic Lessons of China s Economic Growth: Comment Martin Feldstein These are three very fine papers. I say that not as an academic specialist on the Chinese economy but as someone who first visited China in

More information

The Role of Migration and Income Diversification in Protecting Households from Food Insecurity in Southwest Ethiopia

The Role of Migration and Income Diversification in Protecting Households from Food Insecurity in Southwest Ethiopia The Role of Migration and Income Diversification in Protecting Households from Food Insecurity in Southwest Ethiopia David P. Lindstrom Population Studies and Training Center, Brown University Craig Hadley

More information

Understanding China s Middle Class and its Socio-political Attitude

Understanding China s Middle Class and its Socio-political Attitude Understanding China s Middle Class and its Socio-political Attitude YANG Jing* China s middle class has grown to become a major component in urban China. A large middle class with better education and

More information

ENTRY INTO THE EMERGING PRIVATE SECTOR AN INSTITUTIONAL ANALYSIS OF ENTREPRENEURSHIP IN URBAN CHINA

ENTRY INTO THE EMERGING PRIVATE SECTOR AN INSTITUTIONAL ANALYSIS OF ENTREPRENEURSHIP IN URBAN CHINA ENTRY INTO THE EMERGING PRIVATE SECTOR AN INSTITUTIONAL ANALYSIS OF ENTREPRENEURSHIP IN URBAN CHINA LU ZHENG Department of Sociology Stanford University Stanford, CA 94305-2047 Phone (650) 723-1106, Fax

More information

Methods and Characteristics of Political Participation by Private Entrepreneurs --- A Case Study of Zhejiang Province

Methods and Characteristics of Political Participation by Private Entrepreneurs --- A Case Study of Zhejiang Province Methods and Characteristics of Political Participation by Private Entrepreneurs --- A Case Study of Zhejiang Province Yuxin Wu School of Public Administration, Zhejiang Gong shang University Hangzhou 310018,

More information

From the Culture of Migration to the Culture of Remittances: Evidence from Immigrant-sending Communities in China* (Preliminary Draft)

From the Culture of Migration to the Culture of Remittances: Evidence from Immigrant-sending Communities in China* (Preliminary Draft) From the Culture of Migration to the Culture of Remittances: Evidence from Immigrant-sending Communities in China* (Preliminary Draft) Zai Liang and Qian Jasmine Song Department of Sociology State University

More information

Determinants of Entrepreneurial Activities in China

Determinants of Entrepreneurial Activities in China Determinants of Entrepreneurial Activities in China Jiangyong LU Department of Business Strategy and Policy, and Center for China in the World Economy, Tsinghua University, Beijing, 100084, China 86-10-62792726,

More information

Research Statement. Jeffrey J. Harden. 2 Dissertation Research: The Dimensions of Representation

Research Statement. Jeffrey J. Harden. 2 Dissertation Research: The Dimensions of Representation Research Statement Jeffrey J. Harden 1 Introduction My research agenda includes work in both quantitative methodology and American politics. In methodology I am broadly interested in developing and evaluating

More information

Cai et al. Chap.9: The Lewisian Turning Point 183. Chapter 9:

Cai et al. Chap.9: The Lewisian Turning Point 183. Chapter 9: Cai et al. Chap.9: The Lewisian Turning Point 183 Chapter 9: Wage Increases, Labor Market Integration, and the Lewisian Turning Point: Evidence from Migrant Workers FANG CAI 1 YANG DU 1 CHANGBAO ZHAO 2

More information

Unit 1 Introduction to Comparative Politics Test Multiple Choice 2 pts each

Unit 1 Introduction to Comparative Politics Test Multiple Choice 2 pts each Unit 1 Introduction to Comparative Politics Test Multiple Choice 2 pts each 1. Which of the following is NOT considered to be an aspect of globalization? A. Increased speed and magnitude of cross-border

More information

There is a seemingly widespread view that inequality should not be a concern

There is a seemingly widespread view that inequality should not be a concern Chapter 11 Economic Growth and Poverty Reduction: Do Poor Countries Need to Worry about Inequality? Martin Ravallion There is a seemingly widespread view that inequality should not be a concern in countries

More information

The Chinese Housing Registration System (Hukou): Bridge or Wall?

The Chinese Housing Registration System (Hukou): Bridge or Wall? The Chinese Housing Registration System (Hukou): Bridge or Wall? April 2016 Bemidji State University Andrew Kryshak Political Science and Sociology Senior Thesis Kryshak 1 Abstract In 1958 the Chinese

More information

Asian Development Bank Institute. ADBI Working Paper Series HUMAN CAPITAL AND URBANIZATION IN THE PEOPLE S REPUBLIC OF CHINA.

Asian Development Bank Institute. ADBI Working Paper Series HUMAN CAPITAL AND URBANIZATION IN THE PEOPLE S REPUBLIC OF CHINA. ADBI Working Paper Series HUMAN CAPITAL AND URBANIZATION IN THE PEOPLE S REPUBLIC OF CHINA Chunbing Xing No. 603 October 2016 Asian Development Bank Institute Chunbing Xing is a professor at Beijing Normal

More information

Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printed page of such transmission.

Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printed page of such transmission. Comment on Steiner's Liberal Theory of Exploitation Author(s): Steven Walt Source: Ethics, Vol. 94, No. 2 (Jan., 1984), pp. 242-247 Published by: The University of Chicago Press Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/2380514.

More information

Occupation and Growing Wage Inequality in the United States,

Occupation and Growing Wage Inequality in the United States, Occupation and Growing Wage Inequality in the United States, 1983-2002. PRC-Brown Bag ä ù Changhwan Kim Department of Sociology University of Texas at Austin Feb 4, 2005 - p. 1/43 Presentation about...

More information

Remittances and Poverty. in Guatemala* Richard H. Adams, Jr. Development Research Group (DECRG) MSN MC World Bank.

Remittances and Poverty. in Guatemala* Richard H. Adams, Jr. Development Research Group (DECRG) MSN MC World Bank. Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Remittances and Poverty in Guatemala* Richard H. Adams, Jr. Development Research Group

More information

Wealth in Polk County, Florida

Wealth in Polk County, Florida Wealth in Polk County, Florida Background & Introduction In our county or community 1 analysis we address four key awareness areas: The Transfer of Wealth (TOW) Opportunity Findings Indicators of Wealth

More information

Albert Park, University of Oxford Meiyan Wang, Chinese Academy of Social Sciences Mary Gallagher, University of Michigan

Albert Park, University of Oxford Meiyan Wang, Chinese Academy of Social Sciences Mary Gallagher, University of Michigan Albert Park, University of Oxford Meiyan Wang, Chinese Academy of Social Sciences Mary Gallagher, University of Michigan John Giles, World Bank China s new labor law implemented in 2008 was hotly debated

More information

China s (Uneven) Progress Against Poverty. Martin Ravallion and Shaohua Chen Development Research Group, World Bank

China s (Uneven) Progress Against Poverty. Martin Ravallion and Shaohua Chen Development Research Group, World Bank China s (Uneven) Progress Against Poverty Martin Ravallion and Shaohua Chen Development Research Group, World Bank 1 Around 1980 China had one of the highest poverty rates in the world We estimate that

More information

The Transition Generation s entrance to parenthood: Patterns across 27 post-socialist countries

The Transition Generation s entrance to parenthood: Patterns across 27 post-socialist countries The Transition Generation s entrance to parenthood: Patterns across 27 post-socialist countries Billingsley, S., SPaDE: Linnaeus Center on Social Policy and Family Dynamics in Europe, Demography Unit,

More information

WEEK 1 - Lecture Introduction

WEEK 1 - Lecture Introduction WEEK 1 - Lecture Introduction Overview of Chinese Economy Since the founding of China in 1949, it has undergone an unusual and tumultuous process (Revolution Socialism Maoist radicalism Gradualist economic

More information

REMITTANCE TRANSFERS TO ARMENIA: PRELIMINARY SURVEY DATA ANALYSIS

REMITTANCE TRANSFERS TO ARMENIA: PRELIMINARY SURVEY DATA ANALYSIS REMITTANCE TRANSFERS TO ARMENIA: PRELIMINARY SURVEY DATA ANALYSIS microreport# 117 SEPTEMBER 2008 This publication was produced for review by the United States Agency for International Development. It

More information

Migration Patterns in The Northern Great Plains

Migration Patterns in The Northern Great Plains Migration Patterns in The Northern Great Plains Eugene P. Lewis Economic conditions in this nation and throughout the world are imposing external pressures on the Northern Great Plains Region' through

More information

1. GNI per capita can be adjusted by purchasing power to account for differences in

1. GNI per capita can be adjusted by purchasing power to account for differences in Chapter 03 Political Economy and Economic Development True / False Questions 1. GNI per capita can be adjusted by purchasing power to account for differences in the cost of living. True False 2. The base

More information

Lecture 3 THE CHINESE ECONOMY

Lecture 3 THE CHINESE ECONOMY Lecture 3 THE CHINESE ECONOMY The Socialist Era www.youtube.com/watch?v=3xiyb1nmzaq 1 How China was lost? (to communism) Down with colonialism, feudalism, imperialism, capitalism,,,, The Big Push Industrialization

More information

Empirical Analysis of Rural Citizens Political Participation in the Underdeveloped Regions of Chinese Eastern Provinces

Empirical Analysis of Rural Citizens Political Participation in the Underdeveloped Regions of Chinese Eastern Provinces Empirical Analysis of Rural Citizens Political Participation in the Underdeveloped Regions of Chinese Eastern Provinces Zhenjun Mao Department of Politics and Law, Dezhou University Dezhou 253012, China

More information

Rising inequality in China

Rising inequality in China Page 1 of 6 Date:03/01/2006 URL: http://www.thehindubusinessline.com/2006/01/03/stories/2006010300981100.htm Rising inequality in China C. P. Chandrasekhar Jayati Ghosh Spectacular economic growth in China

More information

Revisiting Socio-economic policies to address poverty in all its dimensions in Middle Income Countries

Revisiting Socio-economic policies to address poverty in all its dimensions in Middle Income Countries Revisiting Socio-economic policies to address poverty in all its dimensions in Middle Income Countries 8 10 May 2018, Beirut, Lebanon Concept Note for the capacity building workshop DESA, ESCWA and ECLAC

More information

INDUSTRIAL POLICY UNDER CLIENTELIST POLITICAL SETTLEMENTS

INDUSTRIAL POLICY UNDER CLIENTELIST POLITICAL SETTLEMENTS INDUSTRIAL POLICY UNDER CLIENTELIST POLITICAL SETTLEMENTS THE CASE OF PAKISTAN USMAN QADIR RESEARCH ECONOMIST PAKISTAN INSTITUTE OF DEVELOPMENT ECONOMICS Background Political Settlements Concepts Growth

More information

Land Use, Job Accessibility and Commuting Efficiency under the Hukou System in Urban China: A Case Study in Guangzhou

Land Use, Job Accessibility and Commuting Efficiency under the Hukou System in Urban China: A Case Study in Guangzhou Land Use, Job Accessibility and Commuting Efficiency under the Hukou System in Urban China: A Case Study in Guangzhou ( 论文概要 ) LIU Yi Hong Kong Baptist University I Introduction To investigate the job-housing

More information

Analysis on the Causes of the Plight of Chinese Rural Migrant Workers Endowment Insurance

Analysis on the Causes of the Plight of Chinese Rural Migrant Workers Endowment Insurance Sociology Study, March 2016, Vol. 6, No. 3, 204 209 doi: 10.17265/2159 5526/2016.03.006 D DAVID PUBLISHING Analysis on the Causes of the Plight of Chinese Rural Migrant Workers Endowment Insurance Huofa

More information

Rural Poverty Alleviation in China: Recent Reforms and Challenges

Rural Poverty Alleviation in China: Recent Reforms and Challenges National University of Singapore From the SelectedWorks of Jiwei QIAN Fall 2016 Rural Poverty Alleviation in China: Recent Reforms and Challenges Jiwei QIAN Available at: https://works.bepress.com/jiwei-qian/24/

More information

Paradox in Political Participation and Economic Development A Study of Congressional Voting in Urban China in 1993 and 2002

Paradox in Political Participation and Economic Development A Study of Congressional Voting in Urban China in 1993 and 2002 J OF CHIN POLIT SCI (2009) 14:167 190 DOI 10.1007/s11366-009-9047-9 RESEARCH ARTICLE Paradox in Political Participation and Economic Development A Study of Congressional Voting in Urban China in 1993 and

More information

A Study on the Role of UIG Triple Helix Intensity in the Level of Regional Entrepreneurship Abstract Keywords: 1. Introduction

A Study on the Role of UIG Triple Helix Intensity in the Level of Regional Entrepreneurship Abstract Keywords: 1. Introduction A Study on the Role of UIG Triple Helix Intensity in the Level of Regional Entrepreneurship Xiaobao Peng 1 Shanwei Liu 2* 1.School of Public Affairs, University of Science and Technology of China, 96 Jinzhai

More information

Rethinking Migration Decision Making in Contemporary Migration Theories

Rethinking Migration Decision Making in Contemporary Migration Theories 146,4%5+ RETHINKING MIGRATION DECISION MAKING IN CONTEMPORARY MIGRATION THEORIES Rethinking Migration Decision Making in Contemporary Migration Theories Ai-hsuan Sandra ~ a ' Abstract This paper critically

More information

Economic Returns to Communist Party Membership: Evidence from Urban Chinese Twins

Economic Returns to Communist Party Membership: Evidence from Urban Chinese Twins DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 2118 Economic Returns to Communist Party Membership: Evidence from Urban Chinese Twins Hongbin Li Pak Wai Liu Junsen Zhang Ning Ma May 2006 Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft

More information

Introduction to New Institutional Economics: A Report Card

Introduction to New Institutional Economics: A Report Card Introduction to New Institutional Economics: A Report Card Paul L. Joskow Introduction During the first three decades after World War II, mainstream academic economists focussed their attention on developing

More information

Urban income inequality in China revisited,

Urban income inequality in China revisited, Urban income inequality in China revisited, 1988-2002 Sylvie Démurger, Martin Fournier, Shi Li To cite this version: Sylvie Démurger, Martin Fournier, Shi Li. Urban income inequality in China revisited,

More information

Pluralism and Peace Processes in a Fragmenting World

Pluralism and Peace Processes in a Fragmenting World Pluralism and Peace Processes in a Fragmenting World SUMMARY ROUNDTABLE REPORT AND RECOMMENDATIONS FOR CANADIAN POLICYMAKERS This report provides an overview of key ideas and recommendations that emerged

More information

the two explanatory forces of interests and ideas. All of the readings draw at least in part on ideas as

the two explanatory forces of interests and ideas. All of the readings draw at least in part on ideas as MIT Student Politics & IR of Middle East Feb. 28th One of the major themes running through this week's readings on authoritarianism is the battle between the two explanatory forces of interests and ideas.

More information

Urban!Biased!Social!Policies!and!the!Urban3Rural!Divide!in!China! by! Kaijie!Chen! Department!of!Political!Science! Duke!University!

Urban!Biased!Social!Policies!and!the!Urban3Rural!Divide!in!China! by! Kaijie!Chen! Department!of!Political!Science! Duke!University! UrbanBiasedSocialPoliciesandtheUrban3RuralDivideinChina by KaijieChen DepartmentofPoliticalScience DukeUniversity Date: Approved: ProfessorKarenRemmer,Supervisor ProfessorPabloBeramendi ProfessorAnirudhKrishna

More information

Gender Gap of Immigrant Groups in the United States

Gender Gap of Immigrant Groups in the United States The Park Place Economist Volume 11 Issue 1 Article 14 2003 Gender Gap of Immigrant Groups in the United States Desislava Hristova '03 Illinois Wesleyan University Recommended Citation Hristova '03, Desislava

More information

IMMIGRATION REFORM, JOB SELECTION AND WAGES IN THE U.S. FARM LABOR MARKET

IMMIGRATION REFORM, JOB SELECTION AND WAGES IN THE U.S. FARM LABOR MARKET IMMIGRATION REFORM, JOB SELECTION AND WAGES IN THE U.S. FARM LABOR MARKET Lurleen M. Walters International Agricultural Trade & Policy Center Food and Resource Economics Department P.O. Box 040, University

More information

Sociological Theory II SOS3506 Erling Berge. Introduction (Venue: Room D108 on 31 Jan 2008, 12:15) NTNU, Trondheim. Spring 2008.

Sociological Theory II SOS3506 Erling Berge. Introduction (Venue: Room D108 on 31 Jan 2008, 12:15) NTNU, Trondheim. Spring 2008. Sociological Theory II SOS3506 Erling Berge Introduction (Venue: Room D108 on 31 Jan 2008, 12:15) NTNU, Trondheim The Goals The class will discuss some sociological topics relevant to understand system

More information

Where Are the Surplus Men? Multi-Dimension of Social Stratification in China s Domestic Marriage Market

Where Are the Surplus Men? Multi-Dimension of Social Stratification in China s Domestic Marriage Market 1 Where Are the Surplus Men? Multi-Dimension of Social Stratification in China s Domestic Marriage Market Yingchun Ji Feinian Chen Gavin Jones Abstract As the most populous country and the fastest growing

More information

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr Abstract. The Asian experience of poverty reduction has varied widely. Over recent decades the economies of East and Southeast Asia

More information

IS THE MEASURED BLACK-WHITE WAGE GAP AMONG WOMEN TOO SMALL? Derek Neal University of Wisconsin Presented Nov 6, 2000 PRELIMINARY

IS THE MEASURED BLACK-WHITE WAGE GAP AMONG WOMEN TOO SMALL? Derek Neal University of Wisconsin Presented Nov 6, 2000 PRELIMINARY IS THE MEASURED BLACK-WHITE WAGE GAP AMONG WOMEN TOO SMALL? Derek Neal University of Wisconsin Presented Nov 6, 2000 PRELIMINARY Over twenty years ago, Butler and Heckman (1977) raised the possibility

More information

1. The Relationship Between Party Control, Latino CVAP and the Passage of Bills Benefitting Immigrants

1. The Relationship Between Party Control, Latino CVAP and the Passage of Bills Benefitting Immigrants The Ideological and Electoral Determinants of Laws Targeting Undocumented Migrants in the U.S. States Online Appendix In this additional methodological appendix I present some alternative model specifications

More information

University Press, 2014, 192p. Citation Southeast Asian Studies (2015), 4(1.

University Press, 2014, 192p. Citation Southeast Asian Studies (2015), 4(1. Andrew Mertha. Broth Title Aid to the Khmer Rouge, 1975 1979 University Press, 2014, 192p. Author(s) Path, Kosal Citation Southeast Asian Studies (2015), 4(1 Issue Date 2015-04 URL http://hdl.handle.net/2433/197726

More information