Debating the curse of resources - The Case of Nigeria.

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Debating the curse of resources - The Case of Nigeria."

Transcription

1 Debating the curse of resources - The Case of Nigeria. Natasha Horsfield Abstract This paper critically addresses one of the primary assumptions underlying the hypothesis of a resource curse ; that resource abundance will lead to increased incidence, intensity and duration of armed conflict. Through an in depth examination of the crisis in the Niger Delta, it argues that rather than an being inevitable outcome of natural resource abundance, the curse of conflict is instead a political and economic construct born out of opposition to class structures and global power relations which spawn inequality and perceptions of illegitimacy at the heart of the accumulation process. Finally, it challenges the prevailing perceptions of rebel activity underwritten by resource curse theory in favour of an alternative view of conflict as a means of opposing liberalisation viewed as inherently illegitimate. POLIS Journal Vol.5, Summer

2 Introduction Persistent underdevelopment and a plethora of so called resource wars across Africa in recent decades, has led to the establishment of a body of literature pertaining to the existence of a resource curse, which postulates that natural resource abundance significantly increases the prevalence, intensity and duration of violent conflict and restricts development. The main purpose of this dissertation is thus to critically examine resource curse theory as a means of explanation for the crises faced by those developing nations heavily endowed with natural resources by interrogating the link between resource abundance and conflict. Since its emergence, the resource curse argument has been used increasingly in academic explanations for armed conflict and has influenced policy widely in this area; yet a body of criticism has emerged over the last few years highlighting a number of important flaws in the assumptions therein, particularly the notion that the risk of violent conflict will inevitably be increased by resource abundance. This raises the need to question such assumptions, and this analysis thus explores the theoretical claims of the resource curse hypothesis in detail, addressing the assumptions of its argument by highlighting a number of methodological criticisms and challenging the reductionism and determinism inherent within its thesis. Through a more nuanced examination of the petro-state in Nigeria and the crisis in the Niger Delta, it is argued that the assumptions made by the resource curse thesis are insufficient, and even obstructive to our understanding of the nature of violent conflict in Africa, by reducing complex social, political, and historical processes to statistical explanations of causality. The case specific analysis of Nigeria highlights the weight of political decision in determining the outcome of natural resource abundance as well as the constraints posed by historical legacy and international power relations on those decisions. Particular focus is placed on the salience of the process of accumulation by dispossession in producing resistance in the Delta, as well as the important role of international actors which is absent from resource curse theory. Furthermore, the case study is used to highlight the problem of assumed legitimacy and the serious implications posed for policy by this and the obstructive explanatory nature of resource curse theory; emphasising the importance of understanding the complex roots and nature of conflict on a case by case basis and challenging our perceptions of motivations in the interests of achieving resolution. POLIS Journal Vol.5, Summer

3 The central lessons of the Nigerian case are finally used to establish an alternative path of conflict analysis based on class structures and the international political economy, arguing that the curse of conflict, rather than an a priori outcome of resource abundance, is instead a political and economic construct, resulting from the inequality and opposition generated by class formation and international power relations; thus rejecting the central assumptions of resource curse theory by refuting the inevitability that resource abundance will produce a curse. 1. The resource curse and conflict Proponents of the resource curse hypothesis, such as Collier and Hoeffler, De Soysa, Ross, Karl, Shafer, seek to explain the linkages connecting the paradox of resource abundance, low economic growth and high incidence of conflict. Despite the long standing assumption that resource abundance would facilitate and enhance development, the paradoxically poor economic success and high incidence of conflict in developing countries rich in mineral resources has increased the influence of the resource curse theory, which postulates that an abundance of natural resources, instead of proving beneficial to development, actually causes poor growth and raises the incidence, intensity and duration of conflict (Di John 2007: 961). This runs in contrast to neo-malthusian theories of conflict which posit that resource scarcity, rather than abundance fuels conflict in underdeveloped countries (De Soysa 2000). Based on the resource curse concept, those countries whose economy is heavily reliant on resource endowments, as typified by resources revenue accounting for a large percentage of their export revenues, are likely to exhibit worse growth rates and higher incidence of conflict (Bush 2007: 131). Resource curse theory is rooted in the causal mechanisms underlying the paradoxical development characteristics of resource abundance, and endeavours to explain conflict and underdevelopment statistically by drawing correlations between resource abundance and its prevailingly negative outcomes which provide both the justification and evidence for the thesis (Obi 2010: 484). Resource curse theory offers two significant areas of explanation for the resource curse-conflict connection, that of rent-seeking behaviour and the rentier state model which must be explained to provide a basis for their critical analysis. POLIS Journal Vol.5, Summer

4 Rent-seeking theory and the rentier state model Rent seeking theory explains the resource curse conflict connection by focusing on greed as both an explanation and a motivation for armed rebellion, as well as its superiority over the traditional rebel discourse of socio-political grievances (Collier 2007; Collier and Hoeffler 2004). Since the opportunity to extort natural resource abundance provides an opportunity to finance rebellion, the presence of primary commodities is seen to substantially increase the risk of conflict (Collier and Hoeffler 2004). Furthermore, the potential economic gains to be made from natural resource extraction in underdeveloped countries not only create the opportunity to finance rebellion but also produce motivation to instigate it (Collier 2007). The rent-seeking argument is based on the notion that the existence of a honey pot of valuable rents produced by natural resource abundance in developing countries generates violent rentseeking behaviour in the shape of insurgencies motivated by greed (De Soysa 2000). Additionally, the resulting low economic growth rates and underdevelopment characteristic of the resource curse often create high levels of unemployment and poor access to education, which further increase the likelihood of conflict by skewing the cost-benefit analysis of civilians, particularly young males who make up the primary recruitment base for rebel groups, in favour of joining or mounting a rebellion, as they have financially far less to lose and more to gain through violent conflict (Collier and Hoeffler 2004). As the main proponent of the greed thesis, Collier (2007) argues that where greed is a primary driver of conflict, as in the case of those developing countries cursed with natural resource abundance, the potential gains to be made from the opportunity to continually extract those natural resources will also contribute significantly to the duration of conflict. Under these circumstances natural resource abundance perpetuates conflict in two ways; first by maintaining the ability of rebels to propagate conflict by providing a continued source of finance and second, where rebels are able to profit from the continued looting of resources, by providing an incentive to perpetuate conflict to continually satisfy their greed. Furthermore, it is argued that the lower the income of a country at the onset of conflict, the longer a conflict will last since both sides are more likely to develop economic interests in prolonging conflict to maintain access to resource rents (Collier 2007). The continuation of civil conflict thus typifies the establishment of a new system where certain groups stand to benefit to the detriment of others (Reno 2000). On this basis, combined with the idea that POLIS Journal Vol.5, Summer

5 internal conflict is development in reverse (Collier 2007: 27), the resource curse represents the creation of a vicious cycle where resource abundance perpetuates conflict and thus underdevelopment, which in turn feed on one another to further compound the negative outcomes of resource endowment. The second theory of explanation for the resource curse relates to the idea of the impact resource extraction has on the creation of a rentier state. Theories of the rentier state are based on the argument that the extensive revenues generated by mineral resource abundance hinder development by impairing the functioning of state institutions, resulting in perverse policies and fiscal management, and promoting corruption (De Soysa 2000). The main principle of rentier state theory is that where states gain an ongoing and considerable proportion of their revenue from external sources, as in the case of mineral resource rents, the need to levy domestic taxes is diminished. This reliance on unearned state income creates a so called political Dutch Disease which negates the establishment of reciprocal responsibility with citizens and decreases government accountability and legitimacy (Karl 2007; Ross 1999). In addition, the absence of the need to create strong bureaucracies to raise revenues results in weak state structures. The weak and illegitimate state is thus susceptible to insurgency in the form of violent mobilisation on the basis of grievances which the state lacks the strength and ability to counter (Di John 2007). The presence of abundant resource rents is also seen by the rentier state model to erode regime legitimacy through promoting corruption and the politics of patronage. Under these circumstances, construction of a legitimate social contract founded on the provision of public goods financed by domestic duties is replaced by the misappropriation of resource rents by political elites to purchase security (Di John 2007). This creates a perpetual cycle of corruption where abundant resource rents enable elites to maintain their privileged position and thus their continued access to resource rents to the detriment of national development (Karl 1997). This also has a significant effect on undermining the functioning of democracy by altering the conduct of electoral competition (Collier 2007: 42). Indeed, the skewed political system created by political patronage and the lack of public scrutiny over revenue spending has been proposed as an explanation for the tendency towards autocracy in many resource rich societies (Collier 2007: 44). According to Karl (1997) the characterisation of mineral producers in the developing world as rentier states can be attributed to the fact that the unearned income from resource rents accrue directly to the state without the mediation of private domestic actors, an argument that POLIS Journal Vol.5, Summer

6 is echoed elsewhere in the literature (Ross 1999; Shafer 1986). As a result, the state becomes the funnel through which all resource revenues pass, creating a mentality of rentier politics where control of the state, and thus the control of wealth becomes the prize in political contest (Shafer 1986: 919). This produces two effects; firstly, it fuels myopia among political leaders, where resource revenues become improperly directed away from development and towards the immediate maintenance of the corrupt status quo through channels of patronage (Ross 1999). Secondly, where wealth is dependent upon access to the state, competition to gain or maintain access to power and the revenues which come with it is likely to result in violent conflict (Bush 2007). It is also argued that the inflexibility of the mineral sector further ensures the weakness of state capacity to promote development by contributing to the myopic psychology of the rentier state (Karl 1997; Ross 1999; Shafer 1986). Karl (1997) explains how a continued dependence on mineral rents exacerbates the disparity between this weakened state capacity and extensive state jurisdiction to create an overextended and inefficient state. In the context of continued or at least the expectation of continued revenue flow, the concentration of state control through the centralisation of power and wealth happens almost automatically. However, the lack of sufficient and consistent development of political authority and institutional capacity to match this expansion of state control results in a weak and inefficient state, characterised by political rent seeking and completely unable to effectively devise and implement policies to counter the effects of the resource curse (Karl 1997). Under theories of the rentier state, the high incidence of conflict characteristic of the resource curse is the result of the violent expression of socio-political grievances generated by a perpetual and seemingly unbreakable cycle of corruption and patronage politics, underdevelopment and poor governance in the context of weak and inefficient state capacity to exercise authority. These factors are the creation of large resource revenues funnelled through the state, where the centralisation of wealth also produces violent attempts to capture the state as a means of accessing that wealth (De Soysa 2000; Shafer 1986). In addition to the ideas offered by the rentier state model, Ross (1999) sites a number of economic explanations for the poor economic growth produced by a high reliance on natural resources. First, that a decline in the terms of trade (a decrease in the value of exports in relation to the value of imports) for primary commodity exporters in the developing world, POLIS Journal Vol.5, Summer

7 results in a widening gap between underdeveloped resource exporters and wealthy industrialised states, which accounts to a large degree for the impoverishment of resource rich developing nations (Ross 1999). Secondly that heavy reliance on primary commodity exports would result in the transfer of sharp price fluctuations in the international market to the domestic economies of resource exporters. A third premise of such economic theory is that poor linkages between resource and non-resource sectors mean the stimulation of growth in non-resource sectors by the resource rich sector is improbable, especially where domination by foreign multinationals results in the repatriation of revenues to the detriment of local investment. (Ross 1999). The final and most commonly cited economic explanation for the resource curse is a phenomenon known as Dutch Disease. This describes the combined influence of two common resource boom effects, where a sharp increase in exports resulting in an appreciation of a state s real exchange rate combines with the tendency for capital to be drawn away from manufacturing and agricultural sectors by a country s successful resource sector, thus driving up production costs; leading to a decline in agricultural and manufacturing exports and inflating the cost of imported goods and services (Ross 1999). Although this and the afore mentioned economic hypotheses are influential in explaining the economic basis of the resource curse, they fail to encapsulate the political and institutional processes which result in the failure of government action to mitigate the negative impacts of resource abundance (Karl 1997; Ross 1999) and thus are mainly used in conjunction with the rentier state model. In recent times a partial move away from debates over greed and grievance, which in many ways typifies the divergence between the two strands of explanation for the resource curse, has resulted in an emphasis towards the onset, duration and intensity of conflict in resource curse theory (Obi 2010). In this respect, relating the characteristics of a country s resource curse and the nature of violent conflict to the type of natural resource available, and its prevailing socio-political characteristics, has become of significant importance to resource curse theorists. To this end, attempts to predict the type of conflict have been put forward on the basis of a resource s lootability and location as a point or diffuse resource (Ross 2002). It is postulated by resource curse theorists that lootable resources, such as alluvial diamonds, which are more easily extracted, will create greater incentive and opportunity for violent rent seeking behaviour on the basis of increased ease of opportunity (Collier and Hoeffler 2004). Furthermore, it is hypothesised that diffuse resources, which are also POLIS Journal Vol.5, Summer

8 typically lootable, are less likely to require direct challenge to the state since their ease of lootability requires only controlling a geographical area rather than the political domain of state power. In contrast, resource curse theory postulates that point resources such as oil which are assumed to be non-lootable are significantly associated with secessionist wars since their extraction requires means beyond the control of geographical area alone (Collier 2007; Ross 2002). Lujala (2009) has further hypothesised as to how the type of resource available affects the severity of armed conflict, positing that where lootable resources are available, protracted conflict typified by long periods of low intensity warfare is more likely; firstly as sustained conflict is preferred over peace to provide continued opportunity for rebels (and military forces) to gain economically from resource looting, and secondly since combative forces are likely to spend more time exploiting resources, and so less time in actual combat. Alternatively, in the case of point resources such as hydrocarbon products, which are characterised by extensive state control and expensive extraction processes, it is assumed that benefits are only likely to be gained by rebels through capturing the state or achieving regional autonomy, which is likely to entail more intensive fighting (Lujala 2009). Furthermore, the strong incentive to protect exploitation rights induced by the high value of extraction for the state is likely to result in more extensive involvement of state military forces, resulting in more intensive combat (Lujala 2009). In addition, it has been argued by Karl (1997) that the strategic value of oil in the international market coupled with the extraordinary rents accruing to oil exporting nations produces a more pronounced manifestation of the rentier state known as the petro-state. Critical analyses of this more specific oil curse have in part framed their discussion of the oil curse-conflict connection around the apparently unique nature of petro-violence (Di John 2007; Obi 2010; Watts 2007). Debating resource curse theory While resource curse theory offers two slightly diverging paths of explanation for the resource curse, the common characteristic of the resource curse thesis is the underlying assumption that conflict (and underdevelopment) will inevitably result from natural resource abundance. For this reason an important body of criticism has emerged which seeks to POLIS Journal Vol.5, Summer

9 challenge the assumptions and methods of the resource curse and move beyond resource curse determinism to provide a more nuanced understanding of the resource-conflict connection. Cramer (2002) describes the generalisation that the very presence of primary commodities increases the probability of civil war as absurdly simplistic, and argues that while it is clear that primary commodities and material interests play an intrinsic role in many conflicts, it is extremely difficult to distinguish between their role in the origins of conflict and their influence on the features and durability of that conflict (Cramer 2002). In particular, the econometric models applied to theories of rent-seeking behaviour reduce complex structures and motivations rooted in history to causal binaries of rational choice (Lawrence 2010). The presumption that conflict is the outcome of conscious rational decisions made by rebels in the pursuit of economic gain incited by the presence of natural resource abundance has been criticised as ignoring relational rationality, social and historical restrictions on choice, and conceivably overestimating the distinction between choice and compulsion in human nature (Cramer 2002 p1850). Indeed, a similar criticism can also been applied to the assumptions made by the rentier state model that the predatory behaviour of the state is based on rational aims of rapacity as opposed to development. Furthermore, the assumption that such decisions will be the predominant outcome of resource abundance needs to be explained rather than just being described (Di John 2007: 969). A further set of criticisms which has been levied against resource curse theory are the presence of opaque causality and use of spurious correlations. The presence of a strong statistical relationship between resource abundance, poor economic development and high incidence of conflict does not necessarily demonstrate causality and can not in itself explain in which direction an arrow of causality runs (Di John 2007; Lawrence 2010). Furthermore, it is entirely possible that the correlations on which the resource curse is founded could be spurious, and that the connections linking the negative outcomes of resource abundance could be the result of an unmeasured third variable not included in the resource curse paradigm (Ross 2004). This is supported by Di John s (2007) proposal that the statistical models which provide the basis for resource curse theory lose their significance with the removal of a small set of countries; and are thus likely to be the victim of selection bias to support the resource curse model; indeed, as will be shown, assumptions underpinning the labelling of a resource as lootable or unlootable stand in clear disparity with important case study evidence (Watts POLIS Journal Vol.5, Summer

10 2007). The fragility of such models therefore also forces us to question the robustness of generalising the resource curse as a theory. Furthermore, resource curse models of conflict focus on conflict as a singular phenomenon which ignores the presence of multiple overlapping conflicts (Lawrence 2010). Indeed, based on an examination of the interaction of political and private activities during conflict, Kalyvas (2003: 475) asserts that civil wars are not binary conflicts but complex ambiguous processes that foster an apparently massive, though variable mix of identities and actions. The reductionism critique can also be applied to the assumptions of resource curse theory more generally, which largely ignore the complexity of social, cultural, historical processes which forge the socio-political and class structures within which an apparent resource curse is situated (Bush 2007; Di John 2007; Obi 2010). Resource curse theory also overlooks the uniqueness of individual cases by homogenising the causes and motivations of conflict and underdevelopment across a diverse set of countries solely on the basis of the shared characteristic of resource endowment (Bush 2007; Obi 2010). Indeed more attention needs to be given to the theoretical assumptions which underline the hypothetical leap between statistical correlations and apparent explanations in resource curse theory, and the reductionist value judgements involved (Lawrence 2010: 9). Furthermore, resource curse theory ignores the extent to which imperialist interventions and the nature of the global political economy of resources has shaped the subordinate role of primary commodity exporting developing countries within the global capitalist system and the global security nexus (Bush 2007; Lawrence 2010; Obi 2010). Moreover, the role played by international actors such as foreign mining companies in the political dynamics of internal conflict, particularly in relation to grievances over the extraction process and the use of militias for private protection, is overlooked in much of the resource curse literature (Obi 2010; Watts 2007). Finally, perhaps the most important problem belying the validity of resource curse theory as an explanation for conflict is the extreme determinism implicit within the resource curse ideology (Di John 2007; Obi 2010). It is imperative to question the inherent inevitability that resource abundance will produce the negative effects underpinning the resource curse as a theory. The criticisms raised call into question the validity of resource curse as an explanation for conflict, and it is thus necessary to examine the assumptions and implications of resource curse theory by analysing both the role of natural resources in exacerbating and shaping existing socioeconomic problems and POLIS Journal Vol.5, Summer

11 how country specific socio-political and historical factors may drive the characteristics pertaining to a resource curse. To more accurately inform our understanding, this must be done not only within the context of a case study, but also through a class-based analysis within the context of the global political economy (Di John 2007). 2. The political economy of oil in Nigeria Nigeria provides an ideal case through which to interrogate the affliction of resource abundance in the context of oil, which because of its high value has seemingly become the most cursed of resources. Oil presents a particularly interesting commodity through which to examine Africa s resource curse because of the rising strategic importance of African oil in both the global capitalist system and the contemporary struggle for energy security. Indeed no other country presents a more striking example of the oil curse than Nigeria (Bush 2007), whose oil industry has, according to Peel (2009: xviii) almost become [its] raison d être. The case of Nigeria and particularly the crisis in the Niger Delta are a crucial example of why it is necessary to understand how socio-economic, historical and political factors, under the influence of global forces, forge the conditions of inequality and structural violence contextual of conflict and underdevelopment (Obi and Rustad 2011). It is this context which moulds the nature of resource reliance within a state and within which one must examine the negative outcomes of such reliance to interrogate the inevitability of a resource curse. This chapter therefore examines the Nigerian political economy of oil in terms of internal socio-economic and political factors, the implications of its role in the wider international political economy, and against the historic context of colonialism and class formation in Nigeria; in doing so providing a more nuanced background through which the crisis of insurgency and underdevelopment in the Niger Delta can then be explored. To simply say that the Nigerian state, where oil now accounts for over 80 percent of government revenues and 90 percent of export earnings (Obi and Rustad 2011), has become reliant upon oil would be a gross understatement. For this reason, Nigeria has been seen as a classic example of the resource curse; exhibiting the many shortfalls of the rentier state. Although oil exportation began in 1958, two years after its discovery, it initially only accounted for less than 2 percent of national exports, which were dominated by cash crops and other minerals (Obi and Rustad 2011; Watts 2004). From 1960 to 1973 however, oil exports rose dramatically, and as a result of the global price increases in petroleum in 1973 and 1979, the Nigerian economy enjoyed a huge oil boom (Bush 2007; Obi and Rustad POLIS Journal Vol.5, Summer

12 2011). During this time, Nigeria s agricultural exports became less profitable in comparison to the extensive revenues accruing from oil, and production subsequently collapsed (Collier 2007) leading to increasing state reliance upon oil marked by the centralisation of oil wealth, which shifted power from the state based agricultural elites to the previously weak central government of the Federation (Shafer 1986). The increase in oil rents during boom time also freed the Nigerian government from the need for domestic taxation, producing an archetype example of the rentier state, with the expected implications for state institution representation and accountability (Mustapha 2009). The Nigerian oil boom however, was characterised by authoritarianism, heavy borrowing and wasteful spending on projects swamped by corruption (Bush 2007; Collier 2007) which, following the 1986 world oil price crash, led to a drastically diminished source of state revenue with which to repay an extensive burden of debt; resulting in the halving of Nigerian living standards and the introduction of an IMF sponsored structural adjustment programme (SAP) to manage the switch from borrowing to repayment (Collier 2007). The fall in per capita income from $250 to $212 between 1965 and 2004 was marked by a stark deterioration in income distribution (Watts 2007: 641) where 55.5 percent of income accrued to the top twenty percent of the population, while only 4.4 percent accrued to the bottom 20 percent (Bush 2007: ). Indeed by 2003 most Nigerians were poorer than in 1970 (Bush 2007) with the number of people living below the poverty line increasing from 36 to 70 percent during this time; a massive jump from 19 million to 90 million Nigerians (Watts 2007: 641). Furthermore, the extent of Nigerian state corruption is evident in the fact that during this time perhaps a quarter of the $400 billion accruing to the state in oil revenues has basically gone missing (Watts 2007: 641). The centralisation of the extensive oil wealth under the state, a paramount characteristic of the resource curse, also elevated competition for access to the state, resulting in a revolving door syndrome of successive military coups (Mustapha 2009; Shafer 1986) and a disproportionate level of expenditure on civil servant amenities at the expense of development funding (Shafer 1986). The rentier nature of the Nigerian state and the poor record of economic development characteristic of the resource curse have thus been portrayed as the unavoidable consequence of oil dependence (Shafer 1986: 951). Bush (2007: 135) however, has asserted that if Nigeria is illustrative of the negative consequences of an apparent resource curse, there was no inevitability about the trajectory of its outcome. While rentier politics may POLIS Journal Vol.5, Summer

13 explain to a certain extent the government s failure to rectify the negative consequences of resource dependency, Nigeria s crises should be understood in the context of decisions made within the constraints of both rentier politics and other historical and external factors which require explanation, rather than as an a priori fate set in motion by its national resource endowment (Bush 2007: 135). In the Nigerian case, decisions within such contexts have led to the failure to manage resource booms, failure to expand capital outside the oil sector and the widening inefficiency of the public sector. Perhaps of primary significance however has been the way in which rentier politics has influenced state decisions of how to manage the distribution of oil revenues, which sparked the political dynamics of consolidation and domination of wealth, and thus power, under the state apparatus, establishing the state as the funnel for resource rent distribution, and engendering the problems classically associated with the rentier state (Bush 2007: 135). Prior to 1969, revenue allocation was based on one of the foundations of Nigerian federalism, the derivation principle, which allowed the allocation of 50 percent of resource revenues to the states from which that resource was derived (Mustapha 2009; Ukiwo 2011). However, the rising importance of oil as key source of revenue in the late 1960s led to the devaluation of the derivation principle through the construction of oil as a national asset by the state and dominant social classes (Ukiwo 2011). This was enshrined through the Petroleum act (Decree No.51) of 1969 which concentrated control and ownership of all petroleum under the state (Obi and Rustad 2011) at the expense of the states of the Niger Delta, whose share of government revenues dropped to 1.5 percent by 1982 under the Federation Account (Mustapha 2009: 77). This shift from fiscal federalism to fiscal centralism had wide reaching consequences for the Niger Delta and is paramount to understanding the crisis there, not least because oil from the Niger Delta was the only resource to be presented as a national asset under the Federation Account (Ukiwo 2011). Since the reintroduction of civilian rule in Nigeria in 1999 there has been an important reversal from fiscal centralism back to fiscal federalism which has directed more oil revenues back to the Niger Delta (see chapter 3). Watts (2007: 642) describes how this changing politics of fiscal centralisation and decentralisation has produced a new Nigerian political economy characterised by the decentralisation of corruption, the rise of power and wealth at state level and a democratisation of the means of violence. While these shifts in policy have important ramifications for the crisis in the Niger Delta which need to be explored in detail (Chapter 3), what is of note here is how the link between these changing characteristics and state methods POLIS Journal Vol.5, Summer

14 of revenue allocation depict how the effects ascribed to a high value resource such as oil pivot on state judgements, albeit judgements constrained by the politics of rentierism, rather than the inevitable driving force of oil abundance itself. While domestic constraints are of paramount importance, the decisions of the Nigerian state elites cannot be fully understood independently from the influences of the international political economy of oil, and in particular the strategic importance of Nigeria s oil to the United States. Being the largest oil exporter in Africa and one of the tenth largest in the world, Nigeria s role in the global oil market is significantly sizeable (Peel 2009). The new gulf oil states of West Africa, which Nigeria dominates, have surfaced as crucial to US global energy security calculations in recent years, with around 40 percent of Nigerian oil accounting for 10 percent of US crude imports (Ukiwo 2011), the fifth largest source of US oil imports (Bush 2007). Nigeria s rising significance as a major oil supplier to the US is linked to both its geo-strategic advantage and geo-political importance for the western market. Geo-strategically, the proximity of the large accessible Nigerian reserves of easily refinable crude to the US market, along with the equally convenient expanding reserves of natural gas are of obvious favourability (Obi and Rustad 2011). Geo-politically, concerns in Washington over the United States precarious reliance on Middle Eastern oil, which have been dramatically amplified in the wake of 9/11 (and will be heightened further by the recent Arab awakening), have significantly increased the strategic value of access to Nigerian reserves; further pressurised by the mounting competition in the new scramble for oil arising from China and other Asian powers expanding presence in Africa (Watts 2007: 638). Indeed, the magnitude of Nigeria s role in this ever tightening global market could not be more abundantly clear, with the launch of Africom, a special US military command, in 2007 prompting the active militarisation of US energy security policy on the continent (Peel 2009; Watts 2007). The strategic importance of Nigeria s reserves in this international oil complex has not been without its influence on Nigerian politics. During the extremes of military dictatorship, the role of Nigerian oil was significant in US negligence to condemn repression and autocracy (Bush 2007). Peel (2009) describes how the British policy of military support for the Nigerian dictatorship throughout the Biafran war was driven by strategic decisions over how best to safeguard the interests and access of British oil companies to Nigerian deposits. Indeed, international influence over Nigeria s internal affairs has by no means been confined POLIS Journal Vol.5, Summer

15 to the energy interests of foreign governments, of which the recently leaked cable from Royal Dutch Shell to the US embassies is testament. The cable revealed the extent of exploitation of Nigerian political channels by the largest oil company operating in the Niger Delta, which claimed to have staff working within every major ministry of the Nigerian government in order to ensure the companies interests. The level of internal manipulation uncovered was so extensive that Shell was described as having more power than the government itself (Smith 2010). In addition to this, Shell and other oil MNCs are complicit with internal elites in extensive corruption in Nigeria, including bribery of powerful government officials to increase profit and direct implication in assisting with the distortion of the electoral process (Obi 2010; Okonta 2005). If Nigeria has indeed become as Peel (2009: xvi) describes, a laboratory for the arrogance of a fossil-fuel obsessed world, then the powerful oil multinationals and their home governments are most evidently the scientists running the experiment. The Nigerian political elite are however in no way removed from the workings of international oil interests in Nigeria. In fact the corporate interests of the Nigerian state and its ascendant class are inherently tied to those of the international capitalist system (Ukiwo 2011), and so to ensure the security of its own interests, through internal military activities and by welcoming those of the international military (Ukiwo 2011), this class and the state have been complicit in ensuring global capitalism s grip on Nigerian oil, and the political channels through which the resource is controlled. The final and perhaps most fundamental context within which the political economy of oil in Nigeria must be understood is that of colonialism, and how the colonial legacy has shaped the political, economic and class systems into which the Nigerian oil industry was born. Indeed, the inter-linkage of the interests of Nigeria s economic and political elite with those of the global capitalist powers is an intentional outcome of the colonial legacy. Nafziger (1973) describes how the dominant Nigerian class was formed by the British administration in the final decade of colonial rule through the provision of patronage and economic benefits, to ensure that post-independence Nigerian rule was favourably placed to continue British capitalist trade interests in the post-colonial era. The roots of patronage and class subordination can also be traced to the colonial project as the post-independence Nigerian ruling elite inherited channels of patronage directly from the colonial administration, which it was then able to utilise to retain its position and to ensure the subordination of the underprivileged Nigerian classes (Nafziger 1973); a condition which oil revenues rather than creating purely engorged. The intervention of imperialist interests through colonialism must POLIS Journal Vol.5, Summer

16 also bear some responsibility for the dominance of natural resource exports in the Nigerian economy, in that Nigeria s primary role on integration into this system was as an economic protectorate focusing specifically on the production of raw materials (Nafziger 1973). British colonialism is also of particular importance in understanding the post-independence Nigerian political system into which oil revenues were introduced (Watts 2004). Nafziger (1973) describes how the establishment of a federation in 1954, which granted the three regions of the federation self-government six years before central independence, reduced the strength of the federal centre, to which oil revenues would later accrue. Furthermore, the institutionalisation of regional derivation, political representation and the division of power along these provincial lines reinforced the dominance of the three powerful ethnic majorities, further marginalising the ethnic minorities, particularly in the Delta, who had already occupied a subordinate position under colonialism, which later had important ramifications upon the introduction of oil revenues (see chapter 3) (Obi and Rustad 2011; Watts 2004). The fact that ethnic hegemony had been the basis for the consolidation of local class power under Native authority also led to ethnicised civic rights post-independence (Obi and Rustad 2011; Watts 2004). The legislative equation of political identity on the basis of cultural identity converted ethnicity into a political force which entrenched ethnic rivalry over access to local government and the state. It was into this mix that valuable oil revenues entered, with the centralisation of oil rents designating state creation as a precondition to gain access to oil wealth, resulting in the multiplication of the number of states from the original 3 to 36 (Watts 2004: 74). While on the surface the case of Nigeria appears to present the epitome of the resource curse, it is evident that the negative effects associated with the increased reliance on oil are in no way an a priori outcome of resource abundance. Instead, the rise of Nigeria as a petrostate can only be explained through deeper understanding of the formation of the state, political economy and class system, as well as contestation over resource distribution, in the context of rentier politics, international imperialist intervention and colonial legacy. Understanding these formations and how they have shaped and continue to shape the characteristics of resource abundance in Nigeria forms the basis for a nuanced analysis of the crisis in the Niger Delta which challenges the reductionism, determinism and validity of the resource curse-conflict paradigm as an explanation for conflict. POLIS Journal Vol.5, Summer

17 3. Crisis in the Niger Delta As the source of Nigeria s oil and as a site of violent insurgency and gross underdevelopment, the crisis in the Niger Delta has been explored from a resource curse perspective. However, an in-depth analysis of the socio-political, economic and historical roots of political mobilisation and catalysts to violent insurgency highlight the resource curse viewpoint as obstructive to our understanding of the complex struggles in the Delta and thus provide the basis upon which to challenge the assumptions of resource curse theory. The Niger Delta, is made up of 9 states and 185 local government areas, covering around 75,000 square kilometres with an estimated population of 31 million people. Composed of fine agricultural land, extensive forests and fisheries, the Delta supports a fragile ecosystem of biodiversity to which the lives of its inhabitants are intrinsically linked, where as one of the most populous places on the planet, land scarcity poses a constant challenge for its 60 or more ethnic groups (Obi and Rustad 2011: 3-4; UNDP 2006; Watts 2007: 641). As the host to the Nigerian oil industry, consisting of 606 oil fields, 5,284 wells, 7,000 kilometres of pipeline, ten export terminals, four refineries and a massive liquefied natural gas (LNG) sector (Watts 2007: 639) the Delta s delicate environment and its residents are subject to the overwhelming ecological impacts of some of the most extensive levels of oil pollution and the highest rate of gas flaring in the world, posing a constant threat to the devastation of local livelihoods (Obi and Rustad 2011). Compounding these environmental conditions is a bleak human development situation where unemployment is widespread, access to healthcare and educational facilities is inadequate and the most basic of amenities such as potable water and electricity are scarce; a situation which stands in appalling contrast to the level of wealth accruing from the regions oil fields to both federal and local governments (UNDP 2006). In late 2005, fifteen years of increasing political unrest and violence in the region ruptured into insurgency, rendering the Delta to most extents ungovernable. Violent hostility towards oil operations has been characterised by direct attacks on federal and state security forces, offshore and onshore oil instillations and the kidnap of foreign workers (Watts 2007). Sabotage of the oil industry in the Delta has been a direct objective of militias, who succeed in deferring around 900,000 barrels, as well as the theft of another 100,000 barrels daily; over a third of national output. Such activities have been at extensive cost to the Nigerian government, which loses around $4.4 billion annually as a result (Watts 2007: 639). POLIS Journal Vol.5, Summer

18 The Delta conflict has been examined by resource curse theorists as both a greed based rebellion from the angle of rent-seeking behaviour and in the context of poor governance and poor security response of the weak Nigerian petro-state, leading to the assumption that corruption, malfunctioning democracy and voraciously motivated conflict are the result of Nigeria s high dependency on oil revenues (Obi 2010). Of particular salience in the case of the crisis in the Niger Delta are examinations of resource induced violent rapacity, based around the criminalisation of militant activities of oil bunkering in the Delta. Such examinations seek to illustrate how the networking of criminal syndicates in the Delta epitomises the raison d être of the ongoing violence in the region, and how motivations of grievance related to socio-economic and political marginalisation and environmental degradation, while initially plausible as the basis for protest, in their shift towards violence have evolved into greed (Collier 2007; Watts 2007). Collier s (2007) examination of violence in the Niger Delta, exploring the incidence of violence in relation to the number of oil wells in an area, deduces that the story of violence in the Delta is more resembling of a protection racket than the grievances posited by initial protests. The notion proposed by this is that rebellion in the Delta equates to organised crime rather than a politically motivated insurgency (Watts 2007). Focus on the criminal objectives of militias in both literature and policy has significantly influenced the securitisation of the Nigerian state response to the Niger Delta crisis, resulting in government failure to redress the root causes of conflict in the region (Ukiwo 2011). As has already been shown in chapter 2, resource curse theories of the weak Nigerian petro state overlook important historic context and the role of international actors in shaping resource dependency and its effects on growth, development, corruption and democracy. This too is the case in relation to theories of both resource fuelled violent criminal activity and the resource induced weak Nigerian petro state as explanations for conflict in the Niger Delta. Resource curse determinism cannot adequately account for the complex multilayered motivations of militias operating in the Delta, leaving open the need to explore the historical and structural bases of the crisis, as well as the interlinking role of the state and international community in alienating the people of the Delta. Rather than focusing on oil abundance as the singular cause of violence in the Delta, it is necessary therefore to recognise the complex webs of petro-violence which requires more nuanced analysis of the interface between a multitude of factors (Obi and Rustad 2011: 2). Indeed, instead of justifying the postulation that grievance has evolved into greed as a result of the opportunity to profit from oil POLIS Journal Vol.5, Summer

19 bunkering, it is more suitable to move beyond the resource curse hypothesis to engage in an in depth contextual analysis of how and why civilian resistance to the complex social paradoxes and environmental issues presented by the international oil industries presence in the Delta have transformed into violent conflict and taken on new characteristics over time. Background to the crisis Movements for autonomy in the Niger Delta preceded the oil-complex. Indeed, the shifting dynamic of the Nigerian state to one of petro-reliance in the 1970s only served as a volatile catalyst to pre-existing grievances surrounding the marginalisation of the Delta s ethnic minority groups by ethnic majorities during the formation of Nigeria as a federation (Obi 2010; Ukiwo 2011). The most significant of these early movements for self-determination in terms of the present crisis was the declaration of a Niger Delta Republic in 1966 by the nonelitist Niger Delta Volunteer Force (NDVF), aimed at ensuring Ijaw ownership and control over oil in the area and autonomy from the dominant Igbo elite. Isaac Boro who led this secession attempt has become a modern inspiration for Ijaw youth militias in the Delta who were disillusioned by the exploitation of the Delta s oil by the ethnic majority leadership (Obi and Rustad 2011; Ukiwo 2011). Aside from the iconic Boro movement, the resistive roots of the contemporary near permanent state of disorder in the Niger Delta date back to the Movement for the Survival of Ogoni People (MOSOP) in the early 1990s (Peel 2009). In 1990, as the representation for the smallest ethnic minority group in the Delta, MOSOP targeted the Nigerian federal government and Shell with demands for local autonomy, the right to control over their resources and compensation for exploitation and pollution of their land. The international MOSOP campaign, led by the writer and activist Ken Saro-Wiwa, engaged in a pacifist strategy framed in the discourse of endangerment of the Ogoni as an indigenous population, which was widely publicised and supported by international advocacy groups (Obi and Rustad 2011; Ukiwo 2011). However the Ogoni protests, which eventually forced the shutdown of Shell operations in the area, were met with a harsh military response and the systematic repression of the movement marked by allegations of human rights abuses committed by the Nigerian state. Military raids on Ogoni villages culminated in the arrest and contentious trial of Saro-Wiwa and eight other MOSOP members, who were subsequently POLIS Journal Vol.5, Summer

Globalization and Inequality: A Structuralist Approach

Globalization and Inequality: A Structuralist Approach 1 Allison Howells Kim POLS 164 29 April 2016 Globalization and Inequality: A Structuralist Approach Exploitation, Dependency, and Neo-Imperialism in the Global Capitalist System Abstract: Structuralism

More information

Environmental grievances along the Extractive Industries Value Chain

Environmental grievances along the Extractive Industries Value Chain Environment Programme Environmental grievances along the Extractive Industries Value Chain Dag Seierstad, UNEP Mismanagement of oil exploitation sparks civil uprising in Ogoniland, Nigeria Uprisings in

More information

High School Model United Nations 2009

High School Model United Nations 2009 GA IV (SPECPOL) The Question of Stewardship of Natural Resources in Conflict OVERVIEW The question of stewardship of natural resources in conflict extends far beyond the concept of sustainability. Mismanagement

More information

Vision A people-centred agenda for the extractive sector. Our strategic goals for

Vision A people-centred agenda for the extractive sector.   Our strategic goals for Hundreds of PWYP members have contributed to the development of this strategy throughout 2017 and 2018. Vision 2025 A people-centred agenda for the extractive sector Email: info@publishwhatyoupay.org @PWYPtweets

More information

THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF HYDROCARBON REVENUE CYCLING IN TRINIDAD AND TOBAGO

THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF HYDROCARBON REVENUE CYCLING IN TRINIDAD AND TOBAGO THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF HYDROCARBON REVENUE CYCLING IN TRINIDAD AND TOBAGO Richard Auty (Lancaster University) 1. Rent Cycling Theory and Growth Collapses 2. Initial Conditions Render T+T Vulnerable 3.

More information

SHOULD THE UNITED STATES WORRY ABOUT LARGE, FAST-GROWING ECONOMIES?

SHOULD THE UNITED STATES WORRY ABOUT LARGE, FAST-GROWING ECONOMIES? Chapter Six SHOULD THE UNITED STATES WORRY ABOUT LARGE, FAST-GROWING ECONOMIES? This report represents an initial investigation into the relationship between economic growth and military expenditures for

More information

Oxfam Education

Oxfam Education Background notes on inequality for teachers Oxfam Education What do we mean by inequality? In this resource inequality refers to wide differences in a population in terms of their wealth, their income

More information

POLI 12D: International Relations Sections 1, 6

POLI 12D: International Relations Sections 1, 6 POLI 12D: International Relations Sections 1, 6 Spring 2017 TA: Clara Suong Chapter 10 Development: Causes of the Wealth and Poverty of Nations The realities of contemporary economic development: Billions

More information

This paper examines the successes and failures of the Kimberley Process and provides recommendations for improving it, placing particular emphasis on

This paper examines the successes and failures of the Kimberley Process and provides recommendations for improving it, placing particular emphasis on THE FUND FOR PEACE GLOBALIZATION & HUMAN RIGHTS SERIES THE EFFECT OF THE KIMBERLEY PROCESS ON GOVERNANCE, CORRUPTION, & INTERNAL CONFLICT This paper examines the successes and failures of the Kimberley

More information

Chapter 8 Government Institution And Economic Growth

Chapter 8 Government Institution And Economic Growth Chapter 8 Government Institution And Economic Growth 8.1 Introduction The rapidly expanding involvement of governments in economies throughout the world, with government taxation and expenditure as a share

More information

Intelligence brief 19 March 2014

Intelligence brief 19 March 2014 Intelligence brief 19 March 2014 Maritime insecurity in the Gulf of Guinea Summary 1. Maritime insecurity incorporates a range of criminal activities, including piracy, smuggling and illegal fishing. 2.

More information

The Economics, Culture, and Politics of Oil in Venezuela. By Gregory Wilpert.

The Economics, Culture, and Politics of Oil in Venezuela. By Gregory Wilpert. The Economics, Culture, and Politics of Oil in Venezuela By Gregory Wilpert www.venezuelanalysis.com Perhaps the most important thing to know about Venezuela is that it is an oil exporting country, the

More information

Democracy Building Globally

Democracy Building Globally Vidar Helgesen, Secretary-General, International IDEA Key-note speech Democracy Building Globally: How can Europe contribute? Society for International Development, The Hague 13 September 2007 The conference

More information

2017 SADC People s Summit Regional Debates and Public Speaking Gala. Strengthening Youth Participation in Policy Dialogue Processes

2017 SADC People s Summit Regional Debates and Public Speaking Gala. Strengthening Youth Participation in Policy Dialogue Processes 2017 SADC People s Summit Regional Debates and Public Speaking Gala Strengthening Youth Participation in Policy Dialogue Processes Constitutional Hill, Johannesburg South Africa 16 18 August 2017 Introduction

More information

Analysing the relationship between democracy and development: Basic concepts and key linkages Alina Rocha Menocal

Analysing the relationship between democracy and development: Basic concepts and key linkages Alina Rocha Menocal Analysing the relationship between democracy and development: Basic concepts and key linkages Alina Rocha Menocal Team Building Week Governance and Institutional Development Division (GIDD) Commonwealth

More information

The Chad Cameroon Pipeline Project

The Chad Cameroon Pipeline Project The Chad Cameroon Pipeline Project A failed attempt to beat the Resource Curse Master s Thesis Copenhagen Business School: Cand.merc.int Business and Development Studies Anna Villumsen May 12 th 2010 Taps:

More information

Is Economic Development Good for Gender Equality? Income Growth and Poverty

Is Economic Development Good for Gender Equality? Income Growth and Poverty Is Economic Development Good for Gender Equality? February 25 and 27, 2003 Income Growth and Poverty Evidence from many countries shows that while economic growth has not eliminated poverty, the share

More information

Governance & Development. Dr. Ibrahim Akoum Division Chief Arab Financial Markets Arab Monetary Fund

Governance & Development. Dr. Ibrahim Akoum Division Chief Arab Financial Markets Arab Monetary Fund Governance & Development Dr. Ibrahim Akoum Division Chief Arab Financial Markets Arab Monetary Fund 1. Development: An Elusive Goal. 2. Governance: The New Development Theory Mantra. 3. Raison d être d

More information

THE ROLE OF NIGER DELTA DEVELOPMENT COMMISSION IN SOLVING THE PROBLEM OF UNEMPLOYMENT IN BAYELSA STATE

THE ROLE OF NIGER DELTA DEVELOPMENT COMMISSION IN SOLVING THE PROBLEM OF UNEMPLOYMENT IN BAYELSA STATE THE ROLE OF NIGER DELTA DEVELOPMENT COMMISSION IN SOLVING THE PROBLEM OF UNEMPLOYMENT IN BAYELSA STATE DUKE EBIKELA Department of Banking and Finance, School of Management Sciences, Federal Polytechnic,

More information

The crisis of democratic capitalism Martin Wolf, Chief Economics Commentator, Financial Times

The crisis of democratic capitalism Martin Wolf, Chief Economics Commentator, Financial Times The crisis of democratic capitalism Martin Wolf, Chief Economics Commentator, Financial Times WU-Lecture on Economics 19 th January 2017 Vienna University of Economics and Business The crisis of democratic

More information

Nigeria (Federal Republic of Nigeria)

Nigeria (Federal Republic of Nigeria) Nigeria (Federal Republic of Nigeria) Demographics Poverty 70% of Nigerians live below poverty line, with many living in absolute poverty. Gap between Rich & Poor Health Issues Nigeria has the second

More information

EMERGING PARTNERS AND THE SCRAMBLE FOR AFRICA. Ian Taylor University of St Andrews

EMERGING PARTNERS AND THE SCRAMBLE FOR AFRICA. Ian Taylor University of St Andrews EMERGING PARTNERS AND THE SCRAMBLE FOR AFRICA Ian Taylor University of St Andrews Currently, an exciting and interesting time for Africa The growth rates and economic and political interest in Africa is

More information

Corruption: Costs and Mitigation Strategies

Corruption: Costs and Mitigation Strategies Corruption: Costs and Mitigation Strategies Presented by Bernardin AKITOBY Assistant Director INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND SEPTEMBER 2017 Motivation Corruption has been identified as one of the most important

More information

Koreafrica : An Ideal Partnership for Synergy?

Koreafrica : An Ideal Partnership for Synergy? Koreafrica : An Ideal Partnership for Synergy? by Young-tae Kim Africa, composed of 54 countries, occupies 20.4 percent (30,221,532 square kilometers) of the total land on earth. It is a huge continent

More information

HOW ECONOMIES GROW AND DEVELOP Macroeconomics In Context (Goodwin, et al.)

HOW ECONOMIES GROW AND DEVELOP Macroeconomics In Context (Goodwin, et al.) Chapter 17 HOW ECONOMIES GROW AND DEVELOP Macroeconomics In Context (Goodwin, et al.) Chapter Overview This chapter presents material on economic growth, such as the theory behind it, how it is calculated,

More information

Book Review: Natural Resources and Conflict in Africa: The Tragedy of Endowment

Book Review: Natural Resources and Conflict in Africa: The Tragedy of Endowment Journal of Global Initiatives: Policy, Pedagogy, Perspective Volume 3 Number 2 Globalization and the Unending Frontier Article 10 June 2010 Book Review: Natural Resources and Conflict in Africa: The Tragedy

More information

Building the South African Developmental State: Elusive Pipe Dream?

Building the South African Developmental State: Elusive Pipe Dream? Building the South African Developmental State: Elusive Pipe Dream? Khwezi Mabasa (FES Programme Manager ) Society Work and Development Institute, University of Witwatersrand) (Department of Political

More information

BREAKING THE CURSE IN AFRICA Yes, the Resource Curse!

BREAKING THE CURSE IN AFRICA Yes, the Resource Curse! GEIA POLICY BRIEF NO. 2016/007 BREAKING THE CURSE IN AFRICA Yes, the Resource Curse! www.econinstitute.org BREAKING THE CURSE IN AFRICA Yes, the Resource Curse! 1.0 Background Do natural resources automatically

More information

GLOBALIZATION AND DEVELOPMENT

GLOBALIZATION AND DEVELOPMENT GLOBALIZATION AND DEVELOPMENT JOSEPH E. STIGLITZ TOKYO JULY 2007 The Successes of Globalization China and India, with 2.4 billion people, growing at historically unprecedented rates Continuing the successes

More information

NATURAL RESOURCES, CORRUPTION, & THE SDGS

NATURAL RESOURCES, CORRUPTION, & THE SDGS NATURAL RESOURCES, CORRUPTION, & THE SDGS JODI VITTORI SENIOR POLICY ADVISER, GLOBAL WITNESS ADJUNCT PROFESSOR, GEORGETOWN UNIVERSITY DECEMBER 9, 2015 THERE IS NO NATURAL RESOURCES SDG, BUT THEY ARE EMBEDDED

More information

Thomas Piketty Capital in the 21st Century

Thomas Piketty Capital in the 21st Century Thomas Piketty Capital in the 21st Century Excerpts: Introduction p.20-27! The Major Results of This Study What are the major conclusions to which these novel historical sources have led me? The first

More information

The Resource Curse? Mineral Rents and the Financing of Social Policy. Katja Hujo UNRISD Seminar Series, 6th December 2012

The Resource Curse? Mineral Rents and the Financing of Social Policy. Katja Hujo UNRISD Seminar Series, 6th December 2012 The Resource Curse? Mineral Rents and the Financing of Social Policy Katja Hujo UNRISD Seminar Series, 6th December 2012 The issue UNRISD research on Financing Social Policy: How can developing countries

More information

Ordering Power: Contentious Politics and Authoritarian Leviathans in Southeast Asia

Ordering Power: Contentious Politics and Authoritarian Leviathans in Southeast Asia Ordering Power: Contentious Politics and Authoritarian Leviathans in Southeast Asia Review by ARUN R. SWAMY Ordering Power: Contentious Politics and Authoritarian Leviathans in Southeast Asia by Dan Slater.

More information

EMPOWERMENT FOR ECONOMIC & SOCIAL JUSTICE

EMPOWERMENT FOR ECONOMIC & SOCIAL JUSTICE 1 Photo: Misha Wolsgaard-Iversen EMPOWERMENT FOR ECONOMIC & SOCIAL JUSTICE Oxfam IBIS THEMATIC PROFILE AND ADDED VALUE IN OXFAM Good governance and sound democracies are the pillars of a number of Oxfam

More information

Natural Resources and Democracy in Latin America

Natural Resources and Democracy in Latin America Natural Resources and Democracy in Latin America Thad Dunning Department of Political Science Yale University Does Oil Promote Authoritarianism? The prevailing consensus: yes Seminal work by Ross (2001),

More information

SITUATION COUNTRY REPORT: NIGERIA AS EMPIRICAL STUDY.

SITUATION COUNTRY REPORT: NIGERIA AS EMPIRICAL STUDY. SITUATION COUNTRY REPORT: NIGERIA AS EMPIRICAL STUDY. Introduction: Overview of Nigeria Economy Nigeria is the most populous country in Africa, with a population of over 130 million people. Nigeria operates

More information

The Resource Curse. Simply put, OPEC members saw per capita income decline by 35% between 1965 and 1998,

The Resource Curse. Simply put, OPEC members saw per capita income decline by 35% between 1965 and 1998, * Gylfason, Lessons from the Dutch disease: Causes, treatment, and cures in Paradox of Plenty: The Management of Oil Wealth, Report 12/02, ECON, Centre for Economic Analysis, Oslo, 2002. The Resource Curse

More information

Financial Crisis and East Asian Development Model

Financial Crisis and East Asian Development Model Financial Crisis and East Asian Development Model Kyung Tae Lee (KIEP) After Asia was struck by a series of foreign currency crises, government officials, academia and international organizations from

More information

Helen Clark: Opening Address to the International Conference on the Emergence of Africa

Helen Clark: Opening Address to the International Conference on the Emergence of Africa Helen Clark: Opening Address to the International Conference on the Emergence of Africa 18 Mar 2015 It is a pleasure to join the President of Cote d Ivoire, H.E. Alassane Ouattara, in welcoming you to

More information

Under-five chronic malnutrition rate is critical (43%) and acute malnutrition rate is high (9%) with some areas above the critical thresholds.

Under-five chronic malnutrition rate is critical (43%) and acute malnutrition rate is high (9%) with some areas above the critical thresholds. May 2014 Fighting Hunger Worldwide Democratic Republic of Congo: is economic recovery benefiting the vulnerable? Special Focus DRC DRC Economic growth has been moderately high in DRC over the last decade,

More information

The Importances of Economic Development to Consolidate Political Stability in Oromia

The Importances of Economic Development to Consolidate Political Stability in Oromia The Importances of Economic Development to Consolidate Political Stability in Oromia 1. Introduction Dr. Teshome Adugna 1,October 30, 2018 The social and economic transformation in the given region or

More information

Revisiting Socio-economic policies to address poverty in all its dimensions in Middle Income Countries

Revisiting Socio-economic policies to address poverty in all its dimensions in Middle Income Countries Revisiting Socio-economic policies to address poverty in all its dimensions in Middle Income Countries 8 10 May 2018, Beirut, Lebanon Concept Note for the capacity building workshop DESA, ESCWA and ECLAC

More information

CORRUPTION & POVERTY IN NIGERIA

CORRUPTION & POVERTY IN NIGERIA CORRUPTION & POVERTY IN NIGERIA Finding the Linkages NIGERIA $509bn Africa Largest Economics $509bn - Nigeria is the largest economy in Africa with a revised GDP of $509bn as at 2013. (Africa) 26 Nigeria

More information

Following are the introductory remarks on the occasion by Khadija Haq, President MHHDC. POVERTY IN SOUTH ASIA: CHALLENGES AND RESPONSES

Following are the introductory remarks on the occasion by Khadija Haq, President MHHDC. POVERTY IN SOUTH ASIA: CHALLENGES AND RESPONSES The Human Development in South Asia Report 2006 titled Poverty in South Asia:Challenges and Responses, was launched on May 25, 2007 in Islamabad, Pakistan. The Prime Minister of Pakistan, Mr. Shaukat Aziz

More information

REGIONAL POLICY AND THE LISBON TREATY: IMPLICATIONS FOR EUROPEAN UNION-ASIA RELATIONSHIPS

REGIONAL POLICY AND THE LISBON TREATY: IMPLICATIONS FOR EUROPEAN UNION-ASIA RELATIONSHIPS REGIONAL POLICY AND THE LISBON TREATY: IMPLICATIONS FOR EUROPEAN UNION-ASIA RELATIONSHIPS Professor Bruce Wilson European Union Centre at RMIT; PASCAL International Observatory INTRODUCTION The Lisbon

More information

Dirty Work: Shell s security spending in Nigeria and beyond

Dirty Work: Shell s security spending in Nigeria and beyond Dirty Work: Shell s security spending in Nigeria and beyond Recommendations While the recommendations below are ambitious in scope, their implementation is necessary to bring about substantial improvements

More information

Introduction. Post Conflict Reconstruction. Conflict. Conflict

Introduction. Post Conflict Reconstruction. Conflict. Conflict Introduction Post One of the major concerns facing the developing world is how to deal with the aftermath of conflict. s can be immensely damaging to economies, but also leave scars on society that go

More information

THE IMPACT OF OIL DEPENDENCE ON DEMOCRACY

THE IMPACT OF OIL DEPENDENCE ON DEMOCRACY THE IMPACT OF OIL DEPENDENCE ON DEMOCRACY A Thesis submitted to the Faculty of the Graduate School of Arts and Sciences of Georgetown University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree

More information

What is corruption? Corruption is the abuse of power for private gain (TI).

What is corruption? Corruption is the abuse of power for private gain (TI). Outline presentation What is corruption? Corruption in the water sector Costs and impacts of corruption Corruption and human rights Drivers and incentives of corruption What is corruption? Corruption is

More information

Final exam: Political Economy of Development. Question 2:

Final exam: Political Economy of Development. Question 2: Question 2: Since the 1970s the concept of the Third World has been widely criticized for not capturing the increasing differentiation among developing countries. Consider the figure below (Norman & Stiglitz

More information

Responding to conflict in Africa Mark Bowden February 2001

Responding to conflict in Africa Mark Bowden February 2001 Responding to conflict in Africa Mark Bowden February 2001 1. In 1990, the Secretary General of the OAU presented a report to the OAU council of Ministers on the changes taking place in the world and their

More information

and with support from BRIEFING NOTE 1

and with support from BRIEFING NOTE 1 and with support from BRIEFING NOTE 1 Inequality and growth: the contrasting stories of Brazil and India Concern with inequality used to be confined to the political left, but today it has spread to a

More information

Paul Collier: Wars, Guns, and Votes: Democracy in Dangerous Places

Paul Collier: Wars, Guns, and Votes: Democracy in Dangerous Places Book Reviews Paul Collier: Wars, Guns, and Votes: Democracy in Dangerous Places Harper/Harper Collins Publishers 2009, 255 pp. ISBN-10: 9780061479632 Reviewed by Ondřej Filipec If there is one book from

More information

6. Problems and dangers of democracy. By Claudio Foliti

6. Problems and dangers of democracy. By Claudio Foliti 6. Problems and dangers of democracy By Claudio Foliti Problems of democracy Three paradoxes (Diamond, 1990) 1. Conflict vs. consensus 2. Representativeness vs. governability 3. Consent vs. effectiveness

More information

Ken Saro-Wiwa. Roy Doron and Toyin Falola O H I O UN I VERSI T Y PRESS ATHENS

Ken Saro-Wiwa. Roy Doron and Toyin Falola O H I O UN I VERSI T Y PRESS ATHENS Ken Saro-Wiwa Roy Doron and Toyin Falola O H I O UN I VERSI T Y PRESS ATHENS Contents List of Illustrations 7 Preface 9 Introduction 13 1. Nigeria and Saro-Wiwa s World to 1960 20 2. Saro-Wiwa s Childhood

More information

Programme Specification

Programme Specification Programme Specification Non-Governmental Public Action Contents 1. Executive Summary 2. Programme Objectives 3. Rationale for the Programme - Why a programme and why now? 3.1 Scientific context 3.2 Practical

More information

GLOBALIZATION A GLOBALIZED AFRICAN S PERSPECTIVE J. Kofi Bucknor Kofi Bucknor & Associates Accra, Ghana

GLOBALIZATION A GLOBALIZED AFRICAN S PERSPECTIVE J. Kofi Bucknor Kofi Bucknor & Associates Accra, Ghana GLOBALIZATION A GLOBALIZED AFRICAN S PERSPECTIVE J. Kofi Bucknor Kofi Bucknor & Associates Accra, Ghana Some Thoughts on Bridging the Gap The First UN Global Compact Academic Conference The Wharton School

More information

AN ADDRESS TO THE UNITED NATIONS WORKING GROUP ON IN INDIGENOUS POPULATIONS, JULY 1992

AN ADDRESS TO THE UNITED NATIONS WORKING GROUP ON IN INDIGENOUS POPULATIONS, JULY 1992 AN ADDRESS TO THE UNITED NATIONS WORKING GROUP ON IN INDIGENOUS POPULATIONS, JULY 1992 Madam Chairperson, I wish to thank you for offering me the opportunity of addressing the tenth session of the working

More information

THE LEGAL CASE FOR THE UNIVERSAL DECLARATION OF THE RIGHTS OF MOTHER EARTH. By Cormac Cullinan

THE LEGAL CASE FOR THE UNIVERSAL DECLARATION OF THE RIGHTS OF MOTHER EARTH. By Cormac Cullinan 1 THE LEGAL CASE FOR THE UNIVERSAL DECLARATION OF THE RIGHTS OF MOTHER EARTH By Cormac Cullinan The Declaration The Universal Declaration of the Rights of Mother Earth ( the Declaration ), like the Universal

More information

TOWARDS A JUST ECONOMIC ORDER

TOWARDS A JUST ECONOMIC ORDER TOWARDS A JUST ECONOMIC ORDER CONCEPTUAL FOUNDATIONS AND MORAL PREREQUISITES A statement of the Bahá í International Community to the 56th session of the Commission for Social Development TOWARDS A JUST

More information

The Political Challenges of Economic Reforms in Latin America. Overview of the Political Status of Market-Oriented Reform

The Political Challenges of Economic Reforms in Latin America. Overview of the Political Status of Market-Oriented Reform The Political Challenges of Economic Reforms in Latin America Overview of the Political Status of Market-Oriented Reform Political support for market-oriented economic reforms in Latin America has been,

More information

Authors: Julie M. Norman, Queen s University Belfast Drew Mikhael, Durham University

Authors: Julie M. Norman, Queen s University Belfast Drew Mikhael, Durham University Lost Generation? Youth Mobility, Risk, and Resilience in Protracted Refugee Situations Authors: Julie M. Norman, Queen s University Belfast (j.norman@qub.ac.uk) Drew Mikhael, Durham University (drewmikhael@gmail.com)

More information

Rising inequality in China

Rising inequality in China Page 1 of 6 Date:03/01/2006 URL: http://www.thehindubusinessline.com/2006/01/03/stories/2006010300981100.htm Rising inequality in China C. P. Chandrasekhar Jayati Ghosh Spectacular economic growth in China

More information

The Political Economy of Governance in the Euro-Mediterranean Partnership

The Political Economy of Governance in the Euro-Mediterranean Partnership The Political Economy of Governance in the Euro-Mediterranean Partnership Deliverable No. 10 Working Package 8 New Challenges: Regional Integration Working Package Summary: Working Package 8 New Challenges:

More information

From Inherit Challenges facing the Arab State to the Arab Uprising: The Governance Deficit vs. Development

From Inherit Challenges facing the Arab State to the Arab Uprising: The Governance Deficit vs. Development From Inherit Challenges facing the Arab State to the Arab Uprising: The Governance Deficit vs. Development Break-out Group II: Stakeholders Accountability in Public Governance for Development Tarik Alami

More information

Open Session on the Nexus between Corruption and Conflict Resolution: The Importance of Promoting Good Economic Governance in Africa

Open Session on the Nexus between Corruption and Conflict Resolution: The Importance of Promoting Good Economic Governance in Africa AFRICAN UNION ADVISORY BOARD ON CORRUPTION CONSEIL CONSULTATIF DE L UNION AFRICAINE SUR LA CORRUPTION CONSELHO CONSULTIVO DA UNIÃO AFRICANA SOBRE CORRUPÇÃO P.O Box 6071, ARUSHA, TANZANIA -Tel: +255 27

More information

WAR, CONFLICT AND ORGANISED CRIME CONFERENCE

WAR, CONFLICT AND ORGANISED CRIME CONFERENCE WAR, CONFLICT AND ORGANISED CRIME CONFERENCE RESEARCHERS: GAIL WANNENBURG (SAIIA) JENNIFER IRISH AND KEVIN QOBOSHEANE (INJOBO NE BANDLA), GREGORY MTHEMBU-SLATER AND LOCAL PARTNERS SOUTH AFRICAN INSTITUTE

More information

Executive summary 2013:2

Executive summary 2013:2 Executive summary Why study corruption in Sweden? The fact that Sweden does well in international corruption surveys cannot be taken to imply that corruption does not exist or that corruption is not a

More information

Ogoni People. Unrepresented Nations and Peoples Organization UPR submission Nigeria September 2008 (4 th session)

Ogoni People. Unrepresented Nations and Peoples Organization UPR submission Nigeria September 2008 (4 th session) (UNPO) Executive summary: Ogoni People, racial discrimination, minority rights, land rights, environmental protection, ILO convention 169, judicial inefficiency, language rights. 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40

More information

The Impact of Decline in Oil Prices on the Middle Eastern Countries

The Impact of Decline in Oil Prices on the Middle Eastern Countries The Impact of Decline in Oil Prices on the Middle Eastern Countries Dr. Shah Mehrabi Professor of Economics Montgomery College Senior Economic Consultant and Member of the Supreme Council of the Central

More information

Natural Resource Abundance: Blessing or Curse

Natural Resource Abundance: Blessing or Curse Natural Resource Abundance: Blessing or Curse Robert T. Deacon Department of Economics; Bren School of Environmental Science & Management UCSB Zaragoza, Spain, Feb. 2011 1 Why do some countries grow economically

More information

Feminist Critique of Joseph Stiglitz s Approach to the Problems of Global Capitalism

Feminist Critique of Joseph Stiglitz s Approach to the Problems of Global Capitalism 89 Feminist Critique of Joseph Stiglitz s Approach to the Problems of Global Capitalism Jenna Blake Abstract: In his book Making Globalization Work, Joseph Stiglitz proposes reforms to address problems

More information

Arab Development Challenges Background Paper 2011

Arab Development Challenges Background Paper 2011 Arab Development Challenges Background Paper 2011 3/13/12 4:36 PM Introduction: Toward the Arab Renaissance Sanjay G. Reddy United Nations Development Programme Arab Development Challenges Report Background

More information

SECTION IV: PRAXIS. Section IV Praxis

SECTION IV: PRAXIS. Section IV Praxis SECTION IV: PRAXIS The execution of Ken Saro-Wiwa and eight other environmental activists in Nigeria on 10 th November 1995 and the subsequent disruption to the international reputation of the Shell Group

More information

How s Life in the United Kingdom?

How s Life in the United Kingdom? How s Life in the United Kingdom? November 2017 On average, the United Kingdom performs well across a number of well-being indicators relative to other OECD countries. At 74% in 2016, the employment rate

More information

COUNTRY REPORT. by Andrei V. Sonin 1 st Secretary, Ministry of Foreign Affairs

COUNTRY REPORT. by Andrei V. Sonin 1 st Secretary, Ministry of Foreign Affairs Regional Workshop on Capacity-Building in Governance and Public Administration for Sustainable Development Thessaloniki, 29-31 July 2002 Ladies and Gentlemen, Dear colleagues, COUNTRY REPORT B E L A R

More information

the two explanatory forces of interests and ideas. All of the readings draw at least in part on ideas as

the two explanatory forces of interests and ideas. All of the readings draw at least in part on ideas as MIT Student Politics & IR of Middle East Feb. 28th One of the major themes running through this week's readings on authoritarianism is the battle between the two explanatory forces of interests and ideas.

More information

The Politics of Egalitarian Capitalism; Rethinking the Trade-off between Equality and Efficiency

The Politics of Egalitarian Capitalism; Rethinking the Trade-off between Equality and Efficiency The Politics of Egalitarian Capitalism; Rethinking the Trade-off between Equality and Efficiency Week 3 Aidan Regan Democratic politics is about distributive conflict tempered by a common interest in economic

More information

MONEY AS A GLOBAL PUBLIC GOOD

MONEY AS A GLOBAL PUBLIC GOOD MONEY AS A GLOBAL PUBLIC GOOD Popescu Alexandra-Codruta West University of Timisoara, Faculty of Economics and Business Administration, Eftimie Murgu Str, No 7, 320088 Resita, alexandra.popescu@feaa.uvt.ro,

More information

IMPROVING INSTITUTIONAL SUPPORT TO PROMOTE SUSTAINABLE LIVELIHOODS IN SOUTHERN AFRICA

IMPROVING INSTITUTIONAL SUPPORT TO PROMOTE SUSTAINABLE LIVELIHOODS IN SOUTHERN AFRICA IMPROVING INSTITUTIONAL SUPPORT TO PROMOTE SUSTAINABLE LIVELIHOODS IN SOUTHERN AFRICA Ian Goldman Khanya-managing rural change cc, South Africa Keywords: Sustainable Livelihoods, governance, institutions,

More information

President Jacob Zuma: Broad-Based Black Economic Empowerment Summit

President Jacob Zuma: Broad-Based Black Economic Empowerment Summit President Jacob Zuma: Broad-Based Black Economic Empowerment Summit 03 Oct 2013 The Minister of Trade and Industry and all Ministers and Deputy Ministers present, Members of the Presidential Broad-based

More information

Remittances and the Macroeconomic Impact of the Global Economic Crisis in the Kyrgyz Republic and Tajikistan

Remittances and the Macroeconomic Impact of the Global Economic Crisis in the Kyrgyz Republic and Tajikistan Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized China and Eurasia Forum Quarterly, Volume 8, No. 4 (2010), pp. 3-9 Central Asia-Caucasus

More information

Contents. List of Tables and Figures. Foreword, Justice I. A. Umezulike. Acknowledgements. List of Abbreviations. General Introduction 1

Contents. List of Tables and Figures. Foreword, Justice I. A. Umezulike. Acknowledgements. List of Abbreviations. General Introduction 1 Contents List of Tables and Figures Foreword, Justice I. A. Umezulike Acknowledgements List of Abbreviations vi vii viii x General Introduction 1 0.1 Motivation for the Research 1 0.2 Official Response

More information

Accessing Home. Refugee Returns to Towns and Cities: Experiences from Côte d Ivoire and Rwanda. Church World Service, New York

Accessing Home. Refugee Returns to Towns and Cities: Experiences from Côte d Ivoire and Rwanda. Church World Service, New York Accessing Home Refugee Returns to Towns and Cities: Experiences from Côte d Ivoire and Rwanda Church World Service, New York December 2016 Contents Executive Summary... 2 Policy Context for Urban Returns...

More information

Lessons from the Gulf s Twin Shocks

Lessons from the Gulf s Twin Shocks Lessons from the Gulf s Twin Shocks Ibrahim Saif Stanford April 26, 2012 Outlining the Twin Crisis The oil-rich economies of the Gulf Cooperation Council (GCC) are facing a twin challenge to their stability

More information

THE NATURAL RESOURCE CURSE IN XINJIANG. Yin Weiwen Graduate School of Public Policy, MPP/IP

THE NATURAL RESOURCE CURSE IN XINJIANG. Yin Weiwen Graduate School of Public Policy, MPP/IP THE NATURAL RESOURCE CURSE IN XINJIANG Yin Weiwen Graduate School of Public Policy, MPP/IP 51-128231 Background Information about Xinjiang In 2012, Xinjiang has a resident population of 22.32 million.

More information

CHAPTER 2

CHAPTER 2 CHAPTER 2 www.eisourcebook.org 2.3 Understanding the Challenges: Changing Perspectives Research into the benefits and costs of extractive resource development has been voluminous and has gone through a

More information

MEND: The Niger Delta s Umbrella Militant Group

MEND: The Niger Delta s Umbrella Militant Group Page 1 of 7 Home > By Publication Type > Backgrounders > MEND: The Niger Delta s Umbrella Militant Group Backgrounder MEND: The Niger Delta s Umbrella Militant Group Author: Stephanie Hanson March 22,

More information

SECTION II Methodology and Terms

SECTION II Methodology and Terms SECTION II Methodology and Terms This analysis draws on information gathered through assessment interviews conducted in May and August 2004, NDI program experience with Bolivian political party actors,

More information

Intersections of violence against women and girls with state-building and peace-building: Lessons from Nepal, Sierra Leone and South Sudan

Intersections of violence against women and girls with state-building and peace-building: Lessons from Nepal, Sierra Leone and South Sudan POLICY BRIEF Intersections of violence against women and girls with state-building and peace-building: Lessons from Nepal, Sierra Leone and South Sudan Josh Estey/CARE Kate Holt/CARE Denmar In recent years

More information

Journal of Conflict Transformation & Security

Journal of Conflict Transformation & Security Louise Shelley Human Trafficking: A Global Perspective Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press, 2010, ISBN: 9780521130875, 356p. Over the last two centuries, human trafficking has grown at an

More information

Executive Summary and Recommendations

Executive Summary and Recommendations 1 Executive Summary and Recommendations This Report examines how the multilateral trade regime can better serve the global community. It does so by asking if the sustained and uneven transformation of

More information

Gender, labour and a just transition towards environmentally sustainable economies and societies for all

Gender, labour and a just transition towards environmentally sustainable economies and societies for all Response to the UNFCCC Secretariat call for submission on: Views on possible elements of the gender action plan to be developed under the Lima work programme on gender Gender, labour and a just transition

More information

The Ghost Town Manifesto

The Ghost Town Manifesto 4406 Nelson Mandela Street Kokosi Location FOCHVILLE 2515 Cell: 078 810 1162 Email: thabiso.monyatsi@gmail.com The Ghost Town Manifesto We, the community members of Merafong, a major host city of mining

More information

Corruption and Good Governance

Corruption and Good Governance Corruption and Good Governance Discussion paper 3 Management Development and Governance Division Bureau for Policy and Programme Support United Nations Development Programme New York July 1997 Copyright

More information

INDEPENDENT SCHOOL DISTRICT 196 Rosemount-Apple Valley-Eagan Public Schools Educating our students to reach their full potential

INDEPENDENT SCHOOL DISTRICT 196 Rosemount-Apple Valley-Eagan Public Schools Educating our students to reach their full potential INDEPENDENT SCHOOL DISTRICT 196 Rosemount-Apple Valley-Eagan Public Schools Educating our students to reach their full potential Series Number 619 Adopted November 1990 Revised June 2013 Title K-12 Social

More information

CHAPTER 12: The Problem of Global Inequality

CHAPTER 12: The Problem of Global Inequality 1. Self-interest is an important motive for countries who express concern that poverty may be linked to a rise in a. religious activity. b. environmental deterioration. c. terrorist events. d. capitalist

More information

Submission to the Standing Committee on Community Affairs regarding the Extent of Income Inequality in Australia

Submission to the Standing Committee on Community Affairs regarding the Extent of Income Inequality in Australia 22 August 2014 Committee Secretary Senate Standing Committees on Community Affairs PO Box 6100 Parliament House Canberra ACT 2600 Via email: community.affairs.sen@aph.gov.au Dear Members Submission to

More information

THE DURBAN STRIKES 1973 (Institute For Industrial Education / Ravan Press 1974)

THE DURBAN STRIKES 1973 (Institute For Industrial Education / Ravan Press 1974) THE DURBAN STRIKES 1973 (Institute For Industrial Education / Ravan Press 1974) By Richard Ryman. Most British observers recognised the strikes by African workers in Durban in early 1973 as events of major

More information

HSX: MIDDLE EAST INSTABILITY FUELS EXTREMISM AND TERRORISM

HSX: MIDDLE EAST INSTABILITY FUELS EXTREMISM AND TERRORISM HSX: MIDDLE EAST INSTABILITY FUELS EXTREMISM AND TERRORISM February 2017 CONTEXT: HOW WE GOT HERE! Middle East instability has been driven by several intertwined political, social, economic factors, including:

More information