Institutional Tension

Similar documents
Division of Economics. A.J. Palumbo School of Business Administration. Duquesne University. Pittsburgh, Pennsylvania

Economic Development

Economic Development

Economists have long posited that institutions matter for economic success,

Informal institutions rule: institutional arrangements and economic performance

A Comment on Measuring Economic Freedom: A Comparison of Two Major Sources

ECON 866 Development Economics Fall 2010 Thursday, 4:30-7:10, Robinson Hall A109. Telephone Office Enterprise 326

Understanding institutions

Cultural Context: The Productivity of Capitalism

Civil liberties and economic development

When Does Legal Origin Matter? Mohammad Amin * World Bank. Priya Ranjan ** University of California, Irvine. December 2008

Corruption and Trade Protection: Evidence from Panel Data

Does Paternity Leave Matter for Female Employment in Developing Economies?

Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation

Health Consequences of Legal Origin

Introduction. Cambridge University Press Lopez (1976); Persson (1998); Postan (1973); and Pounds (1994).

Forms of Civic Engagement and Corruption

The transition of corruption: From poverty to honesty

ECON 450 Development Economics

Good Governance and Economic Growth: A Contribution to the Institutional Debate about State Failure in Middle East and North Africa

Personnel Politics: Elections, Clientelistic Competition, and Teacher Hiring in Indonesia

An Austrian Inquiry into the Wealth of Nations: Incorporating Austrian Economics into Economic Development

Cultural Compatibility: Economic Development in Eastern Europe

Civilizing Society: Virtues, Freedom, and Development

Happiness and economic freedom: Are they related?

Do Institutions Cause Growth?

Interest Groups and Political Economy of Public Education Spending

Corruption and Economic Growth

Measuring Corruption: Myths and Realities

Endogenous antitrust: cross-country evidence on the impact of competition-enhancing policies on productivity

Economics 2520 Comparative Institutions Professor Daniel Berkowitz Fall

Laws and Stigma: the Case of Prostitution

Does Owner-Occupied Housing Affect Neighbourhood Crime?

Explaining the two-way causality between inequality and democratization through corruption and concentration of power

The Regulation of Labor

The interaction effect of economic freedom and democracy on corruption: A panel cross-country analysis

Political Economy of Institutions and Development. Lecture 1: Introduction and Overview

Is Corruption Anti Labor?

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr

The Evolutionary Effects of Democracy: In the long run, we are all trading?

Undergraduate Programme, Faculty of Economic Sciences, University of Warsaw

The Importance of Legal Origin on Ownership Concentration: Corruption or Enforcement

Syllabus for 260A: Comparative economics. ( ). Instructor : Gérard Roland

Unit 1 Introduction to Comparative Politics Test Multiple Choice 2 pts each

Ethnic Diversity and Perceptions of Government Performance

The Causes of Civil War

AUTHOR ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT

Globalization and Income Convergence

European Influence and Economic Development *

Decentralized Despotism: How Indirect Colonial Rule Undermines Contemporary Democratic Attitudes

The Journal of Socio-Economics

Crime and Corruption: An International Empirical Study

THE IMPACT OF GOVERNANCE ON ECONOMIC GROWTH IN YEMEN: AN EMPIRICAL STUDY

Institutional Determinants of Growth

Determinants of Institutional Quality in Sub-Saharan African Countries

Democracy and economic growth: a perspective of cooperation

How We Can Save Africa

Institutions Hypothesis. Economic growth is shaped by institution Geography only plays a role indirectly if it shapes them

Impact of Human Rights Abuses on Economic Outlook

Beyond legal origin and checks and balances: Political credibility, citizen information and financial sector development

Introduction Forum Series on the Role of Institutions in Promoting Economic Growth

Natural-Resource Rents

Owner-Occupied Housing and Crime rates in Denmark

Robust Political Economy. Classical Liberalism and the Future of Public Policy

INSTITUTIONS AND GROWTH IN SAARC COUNTRIES

Decentralization and Corruption: Evidence Across Countries?

Chapter 7 Institutions and economics growth

Governance, Economic Growth and Development since the 1960s: Background paper for World Economic and Social Survey Mushtaq H.

POL201Y1: Politics of Development

The Causes of Civil War

Part IIB Paper Outlines

Economic growth and its determinants in countries in transition

Regulation and Corruption

Africa: Why Economists Get It Wrong

Institutions for Economic Development and Growth

Violent Conflict and Inequality

Culture and Contract Enforcement

Thinking Like a Social Scientist: Management. By Saul Estrin Professor of Management

What comes first, agricultural growth or democracy?

An Overview Across the New Political Economy Literature. Abstract

WHO ARE RUSSIA S ENTREPRENEURS?

CHAPTER 2 LITERATURE REVIEWS

Handle with care: Is foreign aid less effective in fragile states?

Michael Kotrous. Creighton University Class of 2015

Social capital accumulation and immigrant integration: a synthesis of New Zealand research Matthew Roskruge and Jacques Poot

political budget cycles

The Influence of Direct Democracy on the Shadow Economy

Measuring Institutional Strength: The Correlates of Growth

Poverty and Inequality

Is the Internet an Effective Mechanism for Reducing Corruption Experience? Evidence from a Cross-Section of Countries

Chapter 8 Government Institution And Economic Growth

The Economic Impact of Crimes In The United States: A Statistical Analysis on Education, Unemployment And Poverty

Residential segregation and socioeconomic outcomes When did ghettos go bad?

Under the Thumb of History: Political Institutions and the Scope for Action. Banerjee and Duflo 2014

ANNUAL SURVEY REPORT: REGIONAL OVERVIEW

The Colonial Origins of Civil War

THE ECONOMIC EFFECT OF CORRUPTION IN ITALY: A REGIONAL PANEL ANALYSIS (M. LISCIANDRA & E. MILLEMACI) APPENDIX A: CORRUPTION CRIMES AND GROWTH RATES

Political Economics II Spring Lectures 4-5 Part II Partisan Politics and Political Agency. Torsten Persson, IIES

Geographic Endowment, Corruption, and Economic Development

Case study commissioned by the Department for International Development, UK. A Contribution to WDR 2005 on Investment Climate, Growth and Poverty

Transcription:

Institutional Tension Dan Damico Department of Economics George Mason University Diana Weinert Department of Economics George Mason University Abstract Acemoglu et all (2001/2002) use an instrumental variable approach to show that the general institutional set up within a country, as determined by its colonial history, has an impact on the country s prosperity. Their work suggests that imposing the right set of formal institutions will eventually lead to economic prosperity. We build on the previous work in the getting the institutions right literature as well as theoretical work by Boettke et al. (2008), Hayek (1960;1973), and Wagner (2007) to show empirically that when an institutional framework lacks the ability to stick it is likely to also have a negative impact on growth, i.e. when formal institutions don t match the underlying local informal institutions they result in negative consequences for prosperity. Keywords: Institutions, Development, Culture, Crime

1 Introduction The getting the institutions right literature in development economics suggests that formal as well as informal institutions within countries impact economic development and prosperity. Acemoglu et all (2001/2002) use an instrumental variable approach to show that the general institutional set up within a country, as determined by its colonial history, has an impact on the countries economic performance. Their work suggests that imposing the right set of formal institutions will eventually lead to economic prosperity. Glaeser et al. (2004, 274) on the other hand point out that The Europeans who settled in the new world may have brought with them not so much their institutions, but themselves, that is, their human capital suggesting that formal institutions as such will not be sufficient to achieve the desired outcome of economic prosperity. On a similar note Tabellini (2005) and Knack and Keefer (1997) highlight the importance of informal institutions and culture for economic performance, and Williamson and Kerekes (working paper) isolate the impact of formal versus informal institutions on property rights, suggesting that codification of property rights is not necessary for prosperity. They define informal institutions as follows: Institutions that are not part of a written legal framework and include private mechanisms that guide everyday transactions. These institutions can be defined as social norms, customs, attitudes, and beliefs that define a way of life within a given region. This includes religion, ideas about right and wrong, and rules on enforcement. In order to correctly be identified as an institution, it needs to be somewhat persistent over time to show depth and durability. While suggesting that formal institutions don t tell the whole story, the empirical evidence on whether formal institutions are necessary for economic performance is indecisive and detail on the interaction between formal and informal institutions is sparse. Boettke et al. (2008) use the Regression theorem as developed by Mises (1912) to provide a framework for 2/13

institutional stickiness, i.e. the ability of new institutional arrangements to take hold. They argue that for formal institutions to stick, they have to match the underlying informal norms and customs. In this paper we build on the previous work as outlined above as well as theoretical work by Hayek (1960;1973) as well as Wagner (2007) to show empirically that when an institutional framework lacks the ability to stick it is likely to also have a negative impact on growth, i.e. when formal institutions don t match the underlying local informal institutions they result in negative consequences for prosperity. More specifically Wagner (2007, XX) suggests that there is a difference between conjunctive political economy, where an exogenous state intervenes into the market-generated arrangements, and disjunctive political economy, of governmental activity as emergent from within a society. Building on Hayek (1960;1973), he points out the distortive effects policy and legislation can have on economic performance and cooperation within a society generally. 2. Institutional Tension: Theory and Empirics In this paper we argue that imposition of a set of formal institutions, which have not evolved based on local informal institutions, lead to institutional tension, which similar to distortive policy and legislation as described by Wagner, has a negative effect on prosperity and the level of cooperation within a society. We design a measure of institutional tension, i.e. the divergence between formal and informal institutions, and estimate its impact on GDP per capita. In addition we use data on corruption, victimization, reported crime and prison statistics as indirect measures for institutional tension. The intuition behind our choice of these statistics as measures for institutional tension is that with the imposition of a set of formal institutions, which are not indigenous, legislation is created making some interactions between economic agents illegal, which by the standards of the local informal institutions are 3/13

permissible. This push of whole chunks of societal interactions into illegality is measurable through crime statistics, victimization and corruption. An example of illegal informal institutions are for instance Hawala networks in India or the Middle East, these networks provide financial intermediation functions, which are historically rooted in the local customs and culture, yet are illegal within the modern nations states, shaped by formal western institutions. Their illegality mainly stems from the inability of government agencies to monitor Hawala transactions and impose taxes, furthermore they subvert monetary restrictions by enabling individuals to send money, particularly remittances, around the world and exchange between currencies at black market rates for currencies that otherwise might have a fixed or regulated exchange rate. Evidence for the existence of Hawala networks reaches back as far as the 11 th century and they emerged specifically where formal enforcement of internal transactions was absent (Schaeffer working paper). In their investigation of institutional stickiness, Boettke et all (2008) distinguish between foreign-introduced exogenous (FEX), indigenously-introduces exogenous (IEX), and indigenously-introduced endogenous (IEN) institutions to describe the origin of institutional arrangements within a society. They point out that even FEX institutions have the ability to stick if they are corresponding to the underlying skills, culture, norms and conventions within a country. They add however, that stickiness is not a measure of the efficiency or the ability of the institutional arrangement to generate prosperity. Boettke et all give an example of a mismatch between formal and informal institutions citing Robert Blewett s (1995) study of the pastoral policy of the Maasai in Kenya: Pre-colonization, the Maasai followed a practice of communal ownership governed by tacit norms of restricted access. This practice evolved as a method to reduce the transaction costs associated with the collective action necessary for cooperation, including pastoral coordination and environmental risk management. British colonial rule, however, substituted explicit contracts for the tacit norms governing land usage in practice. Explicit contracts did not codify an existing IEX or IEN institution, but instead were created in direct conflict with existing underlying mētis about land usage. As a result, the 4/13

complex IEN institutional land structure of the Maasai was disrupted, and the long-term viability of the common land was destroyed. According to Blewett, this destruction undermined the existing Maasai social structure that enabled cooperative agriculture and created a situation of rampant conflict among formerly cooperative agents that manifested itself in the form of rent-seeking activities. This example suggests that tension between a set of formal institutions and the underlying informal institutions results in conflict and individual behavior that is not conducive to growth. As our example of the Hawala networks illustrates, institutional tension can even result in criminalizing behavior, which based solely on the informal norms and customs would not be considered divergent. Tension should accordingly result in an increase in observable criminal behavior. The literature on crime and development (Soares 2004) shows that crime decreases with economic development; we propose, extending on this observation, that crime is an indicator of institutional tension and that institutional tension is what prevents economic prosperity and the evolution of an efficient set of local formal institutions. 3 Data and Empirical Strategy Institutional Tension Data from the International Country Risk Guide (see for example Acemoglu et all 2002) is used in the development literature as a proxy for formal institutions. Glaeser et all (2004) argue however that it is merely a measure of short-term policy rather than formal institutions. They instead use constitutional constraints on the executive as a measure of formal institutions. More specifically they use electoral rules (Plurality and Proportional Representation 1 ) and judicial checks (judiciary independence and judicial review) to proxy formal institutions. 1 Plurality captures if a legislator is elected with a winner take all strategy, where as proportional representation measures if a legislator is elected to parliament in a proportional representative system. 5/13

We integrate these two approaches and measure formal institutions as an aggregate of a countries Political Risk score in the International Country Risk Guide (2002), its score in the Fraser Economic Freedom Index in the category of judicial independence, as well as the two measures of electoral rules (Plurality and Proportional Representation) as used by Glaeser et all, as proxies for constraints on the executive. For our measure of informal institutions we follow Tabellini (2005), who proxies for informal institutions using data on culture, and in constructing his measure of culture builds on an existing literature in sociology, which has identified four specific cultural traits that are especially conducive to economic development. More specifically his measure of culture is composed of scores from the World Value Survey for trust, respect, individual selfdetermination, and obedience within a country. Whereas trust, respect, and self-determination are interpreted as being conducive to market production and entrepreneurship, obedience is expected to have a negative effect on economic development because it encourages subordination to authority and parentalism. 2 We construct our measure of institutional tension, by subtracting each country s formal institutions score from its informal institutions score. The resulting measure of institutional tension is negative for countries in which the informal institutions, as rooted in the countries culture, are less conducive to development and prosperity than the countries set of formal institutions. The measure is positive for countries in which the informal institutions are more conducive to development and prosperity than the formal institutions. Our intuition suggests that in each case the less conducive of the two categories of institutions is binding, i.e. if informal institutions don t support individual property rights, cooperation, and trade, prosperity will not be achieved even if the formal institutions protect property rights and constrain the executive. Similarly where institutions are supportive of individual property 2 Buchanan defines parentalism as the demand for paternalistic policy by a population. 6/13

rights, cooperation, and trade, but constitutional constraints on the executive do not exist or the political system is very instable, prosperity will be hard to achieve as well. For our indirect measures of institutional tension we use data on crime, victimization, and corruption from the United Nations Interregional Crime and Justice Research Institute (UNICRI). Our prison population statistics were obtained from Centre of Prison Studies at King's College (London). We obtained GDP statistics from the United Nations Common Database. Empirical Set-up To test our hypothesis of institutional tension hampering economic prosperity we propose the following relationship: Y = F(I,X) Where Y is a measure of economic performance, I is our measure of informal institutions and X our measure of formal institutions. The interaction between I and X determines the degree of institutional tension, which in turn has an impact on economic performance. Furthermore we propose that the existence of institutional tension leads to directly observable behavior which is captured by corruption, crime and victimization statistics. This connection between institutional tension and these indirect measures of institutional tension can be represented as follows: F(I,X) = C, V, R Where F(I,X) is our measure of institutional tension between formal and informal institutions, C is the amount of reported crime, V is the percentage of the population which has been victimized, and R is a measure of perceived corruption within a society. 7/13

These indirect measures of institutional tension also have a direct effect on economic performance, which can be expressed as follows: Y = F(C,V,R) 4 Results The data used in this regression is a panel composed of 70 countries over the period from 1991-2007. Table 1 below, reports the estimated coefficients obtained in simple OLS regressions of our measure of tension, as well as the indirect measures of tension on per capita GDP. As can be seen all of the estimated coefficients are statistically significant. Our tension measure ranges from 1, indicating that formal institutions exceed formal institutions in their conduciveness to growth, to +1 indicating that informal institutions exceed formal institutions in their supportiveness of growth. Accordingly its impact on GDP per capita as estimated is positive, i.e. as institutional tension decreases or as the measure becomes less negative, per capita increases. This supports the assumption that negative institutional tension, i.e. informal institutions that are relatively unsupportive of growth, has a negative effect on prosperity. However, it does not support the hypothesis that formal institutional constraints are binding when informal institutions are relatively more supportive of growth. Instead what seems to be going on here is that informal institutions drive the result, i.e. they are more important for development than informal institutions. This can also be seen in Figure 1. 8/13

0 20000 40000 60000 80000 -.4 -.2 0.2.4 tension_total percap Fitted values Figure 1: Scatter plot of our tension measure and GDP per capita. The trend line indicates that as tension becomes positive GDP increases. At the first glance our indirect measures of tension seem to support our hypothesis only partially. While victimization statistic, prison population, and perceived corruption all have negative effects on prosperity, the coefficient on property crime is positive, suggesting that as property crime increases, GDP increases. However, Soares (2004) suggests that reporting behavior differs across countries, and more specifically, that reporting of crime is usually lower in less developed nations. Accounting for reporting behavior he finds that recorded crime decreases with development. Assuming that this is also the reason for our positive coefficient on reported property crime, we conclude that the result actually supports our theory of increased tension resulting in less prosperity. Soares theory is substantiated by our estimated effect of victimization on prosperity. The victimization percentage measures the percentage of a countries population, which has been a victim of a certain criminal act, irrespective of the crime being reported to the police (this statistic is based on survey data). The estimated coefficient of the victimization rate for car theft on GDP per capita is negative, which indicates that as car theft increases GDP per capita decreases (see appendix for scatter plot of car theft victimization and GDP). 9/13

Table 1: Tension Measure, Indicators of tension and their impact on GDP per capita Tension Measure Property Crime per Capita Car theft victimization Inmates per 100K population 20,168.28 (4.69) 36,2993.6 (15.19) -2,206.961 (-9.8) -16.25201 (-2.41) Perceived Corruption* 4,371.057 (34.99) *Perceived Corruption based on survey data, scale from 0-10, where 0 = totally corrupt and 10 = totally clean Similarly the coefficient of prison population per 100,000 citizens is also negative, indicating that GDP decreases with an increase in a countries prison population. More specifically an increase in the rate of inmates per 100,000 inhabitants by 1 prisoner leads to a decrease in per capita GDP of $16. Given the large differences in the rate of inmates per 100,000 inhabitants between the countries in our dataset, it seems that this variable can have a significant impact on GDP per capita. The difference between the countries with the highest and the lowest rate of inmates per 100,000 is fairly large with 729 inmates more per 100,000 inhabitants. This difference would, according to our results, imply a difference in per capita GDP of $11,646 per year. The coefficient on perceived corruption is positive. Since perceived corruption is measured on a scale from 0 to 10, 0 representing totally corrupt and 10 representing totally clean, this results also supports our hypothesis, i.e. as corruption decreases (increasing index score) GDP per capita increases (see appendix for scatter plot of perceived corruption index and GDP). None of our results establish a direction of causality between institutional tension and prosperity since we are using a simple OLS specification to test our hypothesis. However, we 10/13

believe that our results give a useful first impression of how important and wide-spread the effects of a divergence between the underlying cultural norms and values and a formal institutional framework can be. Further research should focus on establishing causality between institutional tension and economic development by using other empirical tools. 5 Conclusion As Boettke et al. (2008) suggest, imposing a set of formal institutions is not a panacea for the developing world and an evolutionary approach to institutions, while requiring patients and non-intervention, seems much more promising. Our results substantiate this theoretical insight, which can be traced back to Hayek (1962) and furthermore suggest that imposing exogenous formal institutions might actually hamper growth and divert development and economic activity into inefficient activities, such as rent seeking, corruption, and the general circumvention of obsolete formal constraints. While economic entrepreneurs might be able to find ways around these exogenous constraints, they certainly result in a sub-optimal level of economic development and prosperity. Development policy as prescribed by international institutions might actually harm developing nations. 11/13

References Acemoglu, Daron, Simon Johnson, and James Robinson (2001). The Colonial Origins of Comparative Development: An Empirical Investigation, American Economic Review, 91(5): 1369-1401 Acemoglu, Daron, Simon Johnson, and James Robinson (2002). Reversal of Fortune: Geography and Institutions in the Making of the Modern World Income Distribution, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117(4): 1231-1294 Blewett, Robert (1995). Property Rights as a Cause of the Tragedy of the Commons: Institutional Change and the Pastrol Maasai of Kenya, Eastern Economic Journal, 21(4): 477-490. Boettke, Peter, Christopher Coyne, Peter Leeson (2008). Institutional Stickiness and the New Development Economics, American Journal of Economics and Sociology, forthcoming Glaeser, Edward, Rafael La Porta, Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes, and Andrei Shleifer (2004). Do Institutions Cause Growth?, Journal of Economic Growth, 9(3): 271-303. Hayek, F.A. (1962). The Constitution of Liberty, Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Hayek, F.A. (1973). Law, Legislation, and Liberty Vol. 1, Chicago: University of Chicago. Knack, Steven and Philip Keefer (1997). Does Social Capital Have an Economic Payoff? A Cross-Country Investigation, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112(4): 1251-1288 Mises, Ludwig von. 1980 [1912]. The Theory of Money and Credit. Indianapolis: Liberty Fund. Schaeffer, Emily. Working paper. Hawala Networks: Self-Enforcing Exchange on an International Scale Soares, Rodrigo (2004). Development, Crime and Punishment: accounting for the international differences in crime rates. Journal of Development Economics. 73:155-184 Tabellini, Guido (2006). Culture and Institutions: Economic Development in the Regions of Europe, mimeo. http://www.princeton.edu/~pegrad/papers/tabellini.pdf Wagner, Richard E. (2007). Fiscal Sociology and the Theory of Public Finance. Edward Elgar. Williamson and Kerekes. Decomposing Private Property: Formal versus Informal Institutions. Working Paper. 12/13

Appendix 0 20000 40000 60000 80000 0 2 4 6 8 victim_car percap Fitted values Figure 2: Scatter plot of car theft victimization rate and GDP per capita. The trend line indicates that as the percentage of the population, which has been a victim of car theft increases, GDP per capita decreases. 0 20000 40000 60000 80000 2 4 6 8 10 corruption percap Fitted values Figure 3: Scatter plot of corruption and GDP per capita. The trend line indicates that as corruption decreases (increasing score) GDP increases. 13/13