Migration and the Cultural Transmission of Knowledge: An. Examination of Diamond s Axis Orientation Hypothesis

Similar documents
The Cultural Transmission of Knowledge: The Historical Origins and. Deep Economic Consequences of Diversity

Europe and the US: Preferences for Redistribution

The Economic and Political Effects of Black Outmigration from the US South. October, 2017

Decentralized Despotism: How Indirect Colonial Rule Undermines Contemporary Democratic Attitudes

Choosing Ungoverned Space: Pakistan s Frontier Crimes Regulation. Michael Callen Saad Gulzar Arman Rezaee Jacob N. Shapiro

John Parman Introduction. Trevon Logan. William & Mary. Ohio State University. Measuring Historical Residential Segregation. Trevon Logan.

Understanding permanent migration response to natural disasters: evidence from Indonesia

IMMIGRATION AND LABOR PRODUCTIVITY. Giovanni Peri UC Davis Jan 22-23, 2015

The transition of corruption: From poverty to honesty

Openness and Poverty Reduction in the Long and Short Run. Mark R. Rosenzweig. Harvard University. October 2003

Do Individual Heterogeneity and Spatial Correlation Matter?

Honors General Exam Part 1: Microeconomics (33 points) Harvard University

Economics 270c. Development Economics. Lecture 6 February 20, 2007

Do People Pay More Attention to Earthquakes in Western Countries?

Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE TRANSMISSION OF DEMOCRACY: FROM THE VILLAGE TO THE NATION-STATE. Paola Giuliano Nathan Nunn

LECTURE 10 Labor Markets. April 1, 2015

Determinants and Effects of Negative Advertising in Politics

Persistence of Relative Income for Countries and Populations

The Long-run Effects of Land Productivity on Democracy 1

Publicizing malfeasance:

Honors General Exam PART 3: ECONOMETRICS. Solutions. Harvard University April 2014

The Transmission of Democracy: From the Village to the Nation-State

Ohio State University

Ethnic Diversity and Perceptions of Government Performance

DETERMINANTS OF IMMIGRANTS EARNINGS IN THE ITALIAN LABOUR MARKET: THE ROLE OF HUMAN CAPITAL AND COUNTRY OF ORIGIN

Intra-Rural Migration and Pathways to Greater Well-Being: Evidence from Tanzania

Migration and Consumption Insurance in Bangladesh

Is Corruption Anti Labor?

Online Appendix. Forced Migration and Human Capital Accumulation: Evidence from Post-WWII Population Transfers. Paris School of Economics

Property rights reform, migration, and structural transformation in Mexico

The Costs of Remoteness, Evidence From German Division and Reunification by Redding and Sturm (AER, 2008)

Brain drain and Human Capital Formation in Developing Countries. Are there Really Winners?

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr

Networks and Mobility

ONLINE APPENDIX. David D. Laitin and Rajesh Ramachandran. Organization of the online appendix. August 2015

Human capital transmission and the earnings of second-generation immigrants in Sweden

What does the U.K. Want for a Post-Brexit Economic. Future?

Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation

Immigration and Internal Mobility in Canada Appendices A and B. Appendix A: Two-step Instrumentation strategy: Procedure and detailed results

Trading Goods or Human Capital

ECON 450 Development Economics

SIERRA LEONE 2012 ELECTIONS PROJECT PRE-ANALYSIS PLAN: INDIVIDUAL LEVEL INTERVENTIONS

Intra-Rural Migration and Pathways to Greater Well-Being: Evidence from Tanzania

How migrants choose their destination in Burkina Faso? A place-utility approach

Heterogeneous Friends-and-Neighbors Voting

THE IMPACT OF TAXES ON MIGRATION IN NEW HAMPSHIRE

The Impact of Having a Job at Migration on Settlement Decisions: Ethnic Enclaves as Job Search Networks

Who s Turn to Eat? The Political Economy of Roads in Kenya

Africa s Growth Tragedy, 20 Years On

A climate and resource security dialogue for the 21 st century

Campaign finance regulations and policy convergence: The role of interest groups and valence

Regional Income Trends and Convergence

Uncertainty and international return migration: some evidence from linked register data

Population Change and Economic Development in Albania

From Banerjee and Iyer (2005)

Pork Barrel as a Signaling Tool: The Case of US Environmental Policy

Supplementary Tables for Online Publication: Impact of Judicial Elections in the Sentencing of Black Crime

Benefit levels and US immigrants welfare receipts

A REPLICATION OF THE POLITICAL DETERMINANTS OF FEDERAL EXPENDITURE AT THE STATE LEVEL (PUBLIC CHOICE, 2005) Stratford Douglas* and W.

Natural Disasters and Poverty Reduction:Do Remittances matter?

I ll marry you if you get me a job Marital assimilation and immigrant employment rates

Wage Trends among Disadvantaged Minorities

Born to be an Entrepreneur? How Cultural Origin Affects Entrepreneurship

Neighborhood Segregation and Black Entrepreneurship

on Interstate 19 in Southern Arizona

Drug Trafficking Organizations and Local Economic Activity in Mexico

The impact of low-skilled labor migration boom on education investment in Nepal

SocialSecurityEligibilityandtheLaborSuplyofOlderImigrants. George J. Borjas Harvard University

Impacts of International Migration on the Labor Market in Japan

Roles of children and elderly in migration decision of adults: case from rural China

UCD CENTRE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH WORKING PAPER SERIES. Open For Business? Institutions, Business Environment and Economic Development

Migration, Bureaucratic Reform and Institutional Persistence: Evidence from U.S. Municipalities

Supplementary Materials A: Figures for All 7 Surveys Figure S1-A: Distribution of Predicted Probabilities of Voting in Primary Elections

Women as Policy Makers: Evidence from a Randomized Policy Experiment in India

Trade Liberalization and the Allocation of Labor between Households and Markets in a Poor Country *

Efficiency Consequences of Affirmative Action in Politics Evidence from India

Political Decentralization and Legitimacy: Cross-Country Analysis of the Probable Influence

CHAPTER 5 SOCIAL INCLUSION LEVEL

Student accountability for these content standards will be available in for social science CIM endorsement.

Chapter 3 Notes Earth s Human and Cultural Geography

Immigrants Inflows, Native outflows, and the Local Labor Market Impact of Higher Immigration David Card

World of Labor. John V. Winters Oklahoma State University, USA, and IZA, Germany. Cons. Pros

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE EFFECT OF IMMIGRATION ON PRODUCTIVITY: EVIDENCE FROM US STATES. Giovanni Peri

On the dynamics of segregation

Explaining the two-way causality between inequality and democratization through corruption and concentration of power

Cultural vs. Economic Legacies of Empires: Evidence from the Partition of Poland

The impact of Chinese import competition on the local structure of employment and wages in France

Immigration and Economic Growth: Further. Evidence for Greece

Computerization and Immigration: Theory and Evidence from the United States 1

I'll Marry You If You Get Me a Job: Marital Assimilation and Immigrant Employment Rates

IMMIGRATION REFORM, JOB SELECTION AND WAGES IN THE U.S. FARM LABOR MARKET

Support for Peaceable Franchise Extension: Evidence from Japanese Attitude to Demeny Voting. August Very Preliminary

Does Residential Sorting Explain Geographic Polarization?

In this activity, you will use thematic maps, as well as your mental maps, to expand your knowledge of your hometown as a specific place on Earth.

Access to agricultural land, youth migration and livelihoods in Tanzania

Network effects in Hungarian internal migration

Skill Wage Gap in Brazil:

Geographers generally divide the reasons for migration into push and pull factors.

Do natives beliefs about refugees education level affect attitudes toward refugees? Evidence from randomized survey experiments

Transcription:

Migration and the Cultural Transmission of Knowledge: An Examination of Diamond s Axis Orientation Hypothesis Arthur Blouin Abstract This paper asks whether Africa s long-run history plays a role in current crop production. Plausibly exogenous differences in migration routes are exploited to test Jared Diamond s axis orientation hypothesis. The findings suggest that axis-orientation does matter, but that there is no evidence for Diamond s head-start theory of persistence; instead an equilibrium based theory implying permanent persistence gets more support. The paper identifies a causal relationship between technology transfer and agro-climactic discontinuities, and offers evidence suggesting that cultural isolation plays a prominent role in persistence. History s reach goes beyond institutional outcomes, directly into production decisions. 1 Introduction Recent work in economic history has reinforced the importance of history in explaining economic outcomes. Colonialism and the slave trade are the primary examples, and studies of these events have shown that modern institutions, whether formal or informal, are highly dependent on history. It has been suggested that informal institutions depend on historic context due to the presence of multiple equilibria, while it has also been suggested that extremely slow convergence of historic shocks to new equilibria could explain these findings. This paper demonstrates that the persistence finding can extend beyond the institutional setting, and that at least in this context, out-of-equilibrium dynamics can not explain persistence. The idea is motivated by Jared Diamond s heavily cited theory of technology adoption (Diamond (1998)) and the results presented are the first economic test of his theory. According to Diamond, because there is greater heterogeneity along a north-south axis than an east-west axis, technological advances have historically more easily diffused east-west. He argues that this effect has persisted into the present because axis-orientation gave some regions a head-start on development. 1

The Bantu expansion provides a natural experiment for testing these hypotheses. The Bantu expansion refers to a migration in which Bantu people populated the previously unsettled regions south of the Sahel. The bulk of the expansion occurred after 1C.E., which serves as the baseline for this study. One group migrated south through the rainforest where they had to abandon production of dry-traditional crops, while the other group migrated east and were able to continue producing every traditional crop (1). The history literature argues that migration routes were near-random, based almost entirely on the arrival of ironworking, which was required to cut through the forest (Vansina (1990)). Figure 1: Migration routes during the settlement of Africa. (1) denotes the two branches of the Bantu expansion The evidence demonstrates that Diamond was correct that the axis-orientation effect has persisted until today, but his head-start explanation is unlikely to be causing persistence. While southern migrants do underproduce traditional dry-crops relative to eastern migrants they surprisingly also underproduce all recently introduced crops, a fact inconsistent with the head-start explanation. 2 Data Data on contemporary production of the major crops grown in Africa is required 1. The continent is divided into 0.5 by 0.5 cells and the production data provides, for each cell and each major crop, the 1 Leff et al. (2004) 2

percentage of the cell devoted to the production of that crop. These 0.5 by 0.5 cells are used as the unit of observation throughout the paper. McEvedy (1978) was used to determine historic population density. This data was geocoded for each period from 1C.E. to 1500C.E. (figure 2) (a) 1 C.E. (b) 200 C.E. (c) 400 C.E. (d) 600 C.E. (e) 800 C.E. (f) 1000 C.E. (g) 1100 C.E. (h) 1200 C.E. (i) 1300 C.E. (j) 1400 C.E. (k) 1500 C.E. Figure 2: Population data at each period. Darker regions are more populated Crop suitability data was acquired to control for selection on land characteristics 2 (figure 3). The data provides a suitability measure ranging from 1-8 for each major crop of Africa. Assigning migration routes to cells was accomplished using the ethnolinguistic map of Murdock (1959). For each group on the map, the associated language was identified and matched to the Ethnologue (Lewis (2009)). Each group is traced back along the Ethnologue language trees, which at one level provides a language split analogous to the migration split. This split is used to assign migration routes. 3 Empirical Strategy and Framework The main results section makes three related but separate claims, so three hypotheses are tested. Each hypothesis and its test is described briefly. Hypothesis 1: Technology travelled equally well through the rainforest as around it. Test 1a: Rejection of hypothesis 1 faces a triple burden of proof. First, there must have been an immediate decline in economic wellbeing as the migrants learnt how to produce in their new environment. 2 FAO crop suitability data 3

Figure 3: FAO Suitability Data (a) Sorghum (b) Cotton (c) Rice (d) Oilpalm (e) Maize (f) Soy (g) Sunflower (h) Cassava (i) Groundnut (j) Sugarcane (k) Legend Second, this immediate decline must not have been permanent if the initial effect was knowledge driven. Third, there should be a second decline in welfare upon emergence into the southern region which was more suitable for dry-crops. The following specification is used: SpeedOfF rontier ct = β 0 + β 1 SouthRoute c P ost t + β 3 P ost t + ΓcellF E c + ɛ ct (1) Where c represents a cell and t a 200-year time period. The difference-in-differences estimates can be interpreted as the speed of the migration frontier in kilometres per 200 years. Test 1b: Test 1b will examine whether southern migrants chose to settle in regions that were similar to the rainforest region of Africa. If both groups had similar levels of knowledge after migration, they would settle in similar agricultural environments. An index measures the agricultural similarity of a settlement to the rainforest: 8 Index c = 64 (suit ic suit ir ) (2) i Where ic represents suitability of crop i in cell c, whereas ir denotes the suitability of crop i in the rainforest. Two specifications are presented. The first looks only at the locations settled. This specification is: South i = β 0 + β 1 Index i + θcoordinatecontrols + ΥSuitabilityF E + ɛ i (3) 4

The specification above can be interpreted as selection on the extensive margin. To examine the intensive margin, the following difference-in-differences design is analyzed: P opulation =β 0 + β 1 SouthRoute Index + β 2 SouthRoute + β 3 Index (4) + ΓLanguageGroupF E + ΥSuitabilityF E + θcoordinates + ɛ In both cases β 1 is the variable of interest, and β 1 > 0 is required to reject hypothesis 1. Hypothesis 2: Migrants eventually adopted the efficient crop for their region. Test 2: To reject hypothesis 2 the current production of dry-traditional crops should be lower for areas settled by southern migrants. The current production of wet-traditional crops should not be lower for areas settled by southern migrants, since wet crops were not lost throughout either migration route. Wet crops therefore serve as a falsification test, ruling out competing explanations such as selection on agricultural ability. The model used to test hypotheses 2: CropP roduction ij =β 0 + β 1 SouthRoute ij + β 2 LandQuality ij (5) + ΓSuitabilityF E + τregionf E + θcoordinates ij + ɛ ij Where j denotes crop-type and i denotes cells. Hypothesis 3: Underproduction of dry-crops persists because of the head-start in knowledge of drytraditional crops by eastern migrants. Test 3: The model used to test hypothesis 2 is the same as that for hypothesis 3. The difference is that instead of examining traditional crops, new world crops introduced much later are considered. Where previously the expectation was that dry-crops are under-produced and wet crops act as a falsification test, here both wet and dry crops must be underproduced to reject the head-start theory. That is because both required adoption after migration and both were introduced to all migrants at the same time. 3.1 Mechanism It will be shown that cultural isolation lowered the equilibrium rate of adoption for southern migrants. To test this, an IV framework is employed. A cultural connectedness measure is developed, and instrumented for with migration route. It must be that in the first stage, those who migrated south ended up more isolated than those who migrated around the rainforest. The second stage examines the 5

correlation between predicted cultural connectedness and modern crop production: CropP roduction = β 0 + β 1 CulturalConnectedness ˆ + β 2 LandQuality ij (6) + ΓSuitabilityF E + τregionf E + θcoordinates ij + ɛ ij Here the expectation is that those that are more culturally connected (β 1 ) are more likely to produce any crops that required adoption after migration. 4 Results 4.1 Hypotheses 1 - Imperfect Technology Transmission 4.1.1 Test 1a - Speed of Migration Frontier Consider the results of the regression from test 1a, found in Table 1. Table 1: Differences in the Speed of the Migration Frontier by Route (in km/200 years) (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) 2 century period ending in: VARIABLES 200 400 600 800 1000 1200 1400 Year x South -49.46-873.7*** -68.47*** -2.11-2.33-37.64** -42.50*** (47.69) (178.7) (22.38) (13.74) (75.81) (16.63) (15.09) Observations 3926 3926 3926 3926 3926 3926 3926 R-squared 0.065 0.247 0.030 0.011 0.043 0.017 0.012 Standard errors are clustered by region. Migration partition as described in Flight (1980) is used ({ABCHKLR:DEFGMNPS.}). Year dummies and cellfe are also included as controls.***p<0.01,**p<0.05,*p<0.1 In order to reject hypothesis 1 it must be true that β t=400 < β t=200 to demonstrate that the crops used in the Bantu homeland were not as productive in the rainforest. It must also be true that β t=800 = 0 to ensure that it is crop knowledge and not harsh conditions that caused slower migration (crop knowledge changes substantially, but conditions do not), and that β t=1200 < 0 to demonstrate that knowledge of unused crops was not diffused to subsequent generations. Table 1 and figure 4 shows these conditions are met, so hypothesis 1 is rejected. 6

Figure 4: Speed of Migration Frontier Entering (left) and Exiting (right) the Rainforest 4.1.2 Test 1b - Selection of Land Test 1b further examines hypothesis 1 by examining settlement locations by migration route upon emergence into the southern dry-crop suitable region. Table 2: Sorting into Regions Similar to Rainforest (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) Dep. Var.: Dependent Variable: Population per 110 x 110km cell South Route VARIABLES 1000 1100 1200 1300 1400 1500 Bantu South x Similarity 196.1 351.6 474.5* 608.6* 776.0* 937.8** (171.7) (229.6) (278.3) (330.7) (392.8) (453.4) Similarity Index 0.0915*** 167.9 181.0 185.2 191.0 202.5 212.4 (0.0223) (108.9) (140.2) (172.2) (204.8) (237.8) (271.1) Observations 12155 935 935 935 935 935 935 R-squared 0.763 0.126 0.138 0.156 0.170 0.175 0.181 Standard errors are clustered by region. Migration partition as described in Flight (1980) is used ({ABCHKLR:DEFGMNPS.}). Controls include language subgroup FE, land characteristics controls and coordinate polynomials.***p<0.01,**p<0.05,*p<0.1 Table 2 column 1 shows the results of the extensive margin model. It shows evidence rejecting hypothesis 2, as southern migrants were about 9% more likely than eastern migrants to settle on land that was higher than the mean similarity to the rainforest. Table 2 columns 2-7 examine the intensive margin. The relative populations within settlements strengthen as groups have more time to sort. By 1500C.E. the estimate of the extent of sorting at the intensive margin becomes highly significant with a density of over 5% above the average population 7

density. Both the intensive and extensive margin evidence demonstrate sorting on land quality did take place which is sufficient to reject hypothesis 1. 4.2 Hypothesis 2 - Persistence Table 3 considers modern crop production to test whether southern migrants fully adopted dry-traditional crops. It compares wet crops that are traditional to the Bantu people with dry crops, also traditional to the Bantu people. To show persistence, there should be evidence that dry crops are significantly underproduced by southern migrants compared to eastern migrants. Table 3: Modern Crop Production by Migration Route Traditional African Crops Dry Crops Wet Crops VARIABLES Sorghum&Millet Cotton Rice Pulses Oil Palm Bantu x South -0.504** -0.130** 0.00763 0.0402 0.0319** (0.254) (0.0529) (0.0301) (0.0378) (0.0126) Observations 4524 4524 4524 4524 4524 R-squared 0.335 0.547 0.526 0.449 0.336 Standard errors are clustered by region. Migration partition as described in Flight (1980) is used ({ABCHKLR:DEFGMNPS.}). Controls include regionfe, crop suitabilityfe, land quality, coordinate polynomials, similarity to the rainforest, desert and distance to market.***p<0.01,**p<0.05,*p<0.1 The results are sufficient to reject hypothesis 2. Each of the dry crops are more likely to be produced by those whose ancestors migrated east, while each of the wet crops are more likely to be produced by those whose ancestors migrated south. 4.3 Hypothesis 3 - Class of Mechanism Modern production of crops introduced to Africa after the end of the Bantu expansion are now considered to reject the head-start theory. If this theory is true, then there is no reason for newly introduced crops to be impacted, as both treatment and control groups were introduced to them at the same time. Table 4 shows all newly introduced crops are underproduced by southern migrants relative to eastern ones. Hypothesis 3 is rejected based on this evidence. 8

Table 4: Modern Crop Production by Migration Route New World crops introduced to Africa after settlement Dry Crops Wet Crops Soy Maize Sunflower Sugarcane Bantu x South -0.0365* -1.415*** -0.138*** -0.0583* (0.0191) (0.540) (0.0524) (0.0351) Observations 4524 4524 4524 4524 R-squared 0.517 0.564 0.492 0.389 Standard errors are clustered by region. Migration partition as described in Flight (1980) is used ({ABCHKLR:DEFGMNPS.}).Controls include regionfe, crop suitabilityfe, land quality, coordinate polynomials, similarity to the rainforest, desert and distance to market.***p<0.01,**p<0.05,*p<0.1 4.4 Culture as a Mechanism for Persistence One explanation for the results above is that each tribe developed different cultures, despite originating from a homogenous unit. The southern migrants faced greater geographic heterogeneity, may have become more isolated (Michalopoulos (2011)). The Ethnologue data includes language trees which are used to measure cultural connectedness. A fixed point is taken on the language tree, and the number of connections one group can make using this fixed point as a root is measured. Many connections implies a low level of isolation. Figure 5 shows an example for sub-group H. Denoted in brackets are the number of tribes that end if that branch of the tree is followed. There are 10 tribes in the data with H.10 as a root, so a connectedness score of 10 is assigned. While not presented, the first stage: migration route on cultural isolation, is significant at the 1% level. It demonstrates that those who migrated south are culturally more isolated than those who migrated east. The IV estimates (table 5) suggest that the main results operate through a cultural isolation mechanism. Each estimate is positive indicating that connectedness increases crop adoption. 5 Conclusion This study examined whether history had an impact on the adoption of agricultural products in Africa, and argued that culture should be considered a prominent mechanism for persistence. This contributes 9

Bantu South East D E F.... S A B.... H H40 (1) H10 (10) H20 (4) H30 (7) Figure 5: Bantu Language Tree. East and South refer to the initial migration split. Letters refer to subdivisions. The numbers in brackets denote the number of tribes in each subdivision. 10

Table 5: Two-Stage Least Squared Estimates for the Impact of Cultural Isolation on Crop Production (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) VARIABLES Soy Maize Sunflower Sugarcane Sorghum Cotton ˆ LinguisticConnectedness 0.0127* 0.492** 0.0480*** 0.0202* 0.175** 0.0450** (0.00769) (0.196) (0.0179) (0.0107) (0.0682) (0.0225) Observations 4524 4524 4524 4524 4524 4524 Cragg-Donald minimum eigenvalue 308.3 308.3 308.3 308.3 308.3 308.3 Standard errors are clustered by region. Migration partition as described in Flight (1980) is used ({ABCHKLR:DEFGMNPS.}).Controls include regionfe, crop suitabilityfe, land quality, coordinate polynomials, similarity to the rainforest, desert and distance to market.***p<0.01,**p<0.05,*p<0.1 to several literatures by showing that history s impact extends beyond institutions into production, by demonstrating importance of culture on actual production decisions. Diamond s theory regarding agricultural transmission was examined using the Bantu expansion as a natural experiment. Diamond s theory was tested against prominent alternatives, and while Diamond correctly asserted that axis-orientation matters, the mechanism for persistence is more complex than initially envisioned. 11

References Diamond, Jared, Guns, Germs and Steel: a short history of everybody for the last 13,000 years, Vintage, 1998. Flight, Colin, Malcolm Guthrie and the Reconstruction of Bantu Prehistory, History in Africa, 1980, 7, pp. 81 118. Leff, Billie, Navin Ramankutty, and Jonathan A. Foley, Geographic Distribution of Major Crops Across the World, Global Biochemical Cycles, 2004, 18 (GB1009). Lewis, Paul M., Ethnologue: Languages of the World, sixteenth ed., Dallas, Texas: SIL International, 2009. McEvedy, Colin, Atlas of world population history, Harmondsworth ;;New York [etc.]: Penguin, 1978. Michalopoulos, Stelios, The Origins of Technolinguistic Diversity, Economics Working Papers 0095, Institute for Advanced Study, School of Social Science May 2011. Murdock, George Peter, Africa : its peoples and their culture history, New York [u.a.]: McGraw-Hill, 1959. Vansina, Jan, Paths in the rainforests : toward a history of political tradition in equatorial Africa, Madison Wis.: University of Wisconsin Press, 1990. 12