Who s Turn to Eat? The Political Economy of Roads in Kenya

Similar documents
Our Turn To Eat: The Political Economy of Roads in Kenya

Issues in African Economic Development. Economics 172. University of California, Berkeley. Department of Economics. Professor Ted Miguel

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE VALUE OF DEMOCRACY: EVIDENCE FROM ROAD BUILDING IN KENYA

The Ethnic Logic of Campaign Strategy in Diverse Societies: Theory and Evidence from Kenya

Does Aid Target Votes? How Electoral Strategies Shape the Distribution of Aid 1

Decentralized Despotism: How Indirect Colonial Rule Undermines Contemporary Democratic Attitudes

Course Overview. Requirements: PSC/IR 286: Political Economy of Developing Countries. Fall 2015 MW 10:25 am 11:40 pm B&L 270

Intergovernmental Fiscal Transfers and Tactical Political Maneuverings: Evidence from Ghana s District Assemblies Common Fund ABEL FUMEY

The efficient provision of public goods relies on a well-functioning public

Research Report. How Does Trade Liberalization Affect Racial and Gender Identity in Employment? Evidence from PostApartheid South Africa

Trickle-Down Ethnic Politics: Drunk and Absent in the Kenya Police Force ( )

Economics 270c. Development Economics. Lecture 6 February 20, 2007

Vote Buying and Clientelism

Women as Policy Makers: Evidence from a Randomized Policy Experiment in India

A short note on Kenya and early warning signals

The Distortionary Effects of Power Sharing on Political Corruption and Accountability: Evidence from Kenya

Remittances and the Brain Drain: Evidence from Microdata for Sub-Saharan Africa

UCLA DEPARTMENT OF POLITICAL SCIENCE POLITICAL SCIENCE 241: AFRICAN POLITICS FIELD SEMINAR

What Democracy Does (and Doesn t do) for Basic Services

Natural Resources & Income Inequality: The Role of Ethnic Divisions

Friend, Our 1618 Plan contains three fundamental strategies:

The Decision to Privatize: Finance and Politics. I. Serdar Dinç and Nandini Gupta * ABSTRACT

Why are Immigrants Underrepresented in Politics? Evidence From Sweden

Distributive politics depend on powerful actors. This study tries to identify in

Publicizing malfeasance:

The road to power: partisan loyalty and the centralized provision of local infrastructure

Determinants of Return Migration to Mexico Among Mexicans in the United States

Political Economy of Institutions and Development. Lecture 1: Introduction and Overview

Why Does Ethnic Diversity Affect Public Good Provision? An Empirical Analysis of Water Provision in Africa

Using Satellite Imagery of Night Lights to Study Patronage and Politics in Africa: A Research Proposal

Pork Barrel as a Signaling Tool: The Case of US Environmental Policy

Voting Technology, Political Responsiveness, and Infant Health: Evidence from Brazil

Presented at the General Conference of the International Union for the Scientific Study of Population (IUSSP), August 18-24, 2001, Bahia, Brazil.

Relationship between Objective and Subjective Horizontal Inequalities: Evidence from Five African Countries

Politics Before Pupils? Electoral Cycles and School Resources in India

350,000 Internally Displaced People reported in Kenya (updated October 2003)

Risk Sharing and Transaction Costs: Evidence from Kenya s Mobile Money Revolution. William Jack and Tavneet Suri

Ethnic Diversity and Perceptions of Government Performance

Case Evidence: Blacks, Hispanics, and Immigrants

The Return of the Prodigy Son: Do Return Migrants make Better Leaders?

Policy Deliberation and Electoral Returns: Experimental Evidence from Benin and the Philippines

Economic Costs of Conflict

Fertilizer subsidies & voting behavior: Political economy dimensions of input subsidy programs

Remittance and Household Expenditures in Kenya

From Violence to Peace: The Daily Nation and the change in how ethnicity is reported from the 2007 to the 2013 presidential elections

The Ethnicity Distraction?

Subhasish Dey, University of York Kunal Sen,University of Manchester & UNU-WIDER NDCDE, 2018, UNU-WIDER, Helsinki 12 th June 2018

Corruption along ethnic lines:

Education Benefits of Universal Primary Education Program: Evidence from Tanzania

Prologue Djankov et al. (2002) Reinikka & Svensson (2004) Besley & Burgess (2002) Epilogue. Media and Policy

Quality of Institutions : Does Intelligence Matter?

Settlers and missionaries: a sub-national comparison of the consequences of colonial institutions and historical school investments

Do formula-based intergovernmental transfer mechanisms eliminate politically motivated targeting? Evidence from Ghana

When does ethnic diversity lead to violence? Evidence from the 2007 elections in Kenya. July Thomas Markussen

Women and Power: Unpopular, Unwilling, or Held Back? Comment

THE WAR ON CRIME VS THE WAR ON DRUGS AN OVERVIEW OF RESEARCH ON INTERGOVERNMENTAL GRANT PROGRAMS TO FIGHT CRIME

Democracy and Primary School Attendance. Aggregate and Individual Level Evidence from Africa

MINISTRY OF INTERIOR AND COORDINATION OF NATIONAL GOVERNMENT Department of Immigration Services. East African Community e-passport: Kenyan Journey

Kenya after the Elections

Rainfall, Economic Shocks and Civil Conflicts in the Agrarian Countries of the World

District Creation in Kenya Under President Moi

Efficiency Consequences of Affirmative Action in Politics Evidence from India

Democracy and Primary School Attendance in Africa

Essays on the Single-mindedness Theory. Emanuele Canegrati Catholic University, Milan

Journal of Public Economics

FEMALE AND MALE MIGRATION PATTERNS INTO THE URBAN SLUMS OF NAIROBI, : EVIDENCE OF FEMINISATION OF MIGRATION?

Unit 1 Introduction to Comparative Politics Test Multiple Choice 2 pts each

Prologue Djankov et al. (2002) Reinikka & Svensson (2004) Besley & Burgess (2002) Epilogue. Media and Policy. Dr. Kumar Aniket

100. In a unitary government system who holds most of the power? C the central government

Does Local Ethnic Segregation Lead to Violence?: Evidence from Kenya

Does Political Competition Reduce Ethnic Discrimination?

Columbia University. Department of Economics Discussion Paper Series

Being a Good Samaritan or just a politician? Empirical evidence of disaster assistance. Jeroen Klomp

Table A.2 reports the complete set of estimates of equation (1). We distinguish between personal

Ethnic Politics, Group Size, and the Under-Supply of Local Public Goods

Groupe de Recherche en Économie et Développement International. Cahier de recherche / Working Paper 08-15

Does Elite Capture Matter? Local Elites and Targeted Welfare Programs in Indonesia

Surviving Elections: Election Violence, Incumbent Victory, and Post-Election Repercussions January 11, 2016

UGANDA DEFENCE REFORM PROGRAMME. Issues around UK engagement

Summary version. ACORD Strategic Plan

Is Corruption Anti Labor?

1. Global Disparities Overview

A Tale of Two Villages

Personnel Politics: Elections, Clientelistic Competition, and Teacher Hiring in Indonesia

Ethnic Favoritism: Winner Takes All or Power Sharing? Evidence from school constructions in Benin

Measuring Institutional Strength: The Correlates of Growth

The Experience of the National Rainbow Coalition (NARC): Political Parties in Kenya from 1991 to 2007

Legislatures and Growth

ECON 450 Development Economics

Determinants and Effects of Negative Advertising in Politics

INFOTRAK PUBLIC POLICY AND GOVERNANCE RESEARCH DIVISION

Differences Lead to Differences: Diversity and Income Inequality Across Countries

The Urban Wage Premium in Africa

Contemporary African Politics Political Science 246, Fall 2009 Tuesdays: pm

You Reap What You Sow

Supporting Information for Representation and Redistribution in Comparative Perspective. Tiberiu Dragu and Jonathan Rodden

Fertility Differentials in Kenya: The Effect of Female Migration

Corruption in Kenya, 2005: Is NARC Fulfilling Its Campaign Promise?

The Privatization Origins of Political Corporations. Felipe González Mounu Prem Francisco Urzúa PUC-Chile U del Rosario Erasmus U

Election Outcomes and Food Security: Evidence from the. Consumption of Scheduled Castes and Tribes in India. Sharad Tandon.

Transcription:

Who s Turn to Eat? The Political Economy of Roads in Kenya Robin Burgess (LSE), Remi Jedwab (PSE/LSE), Edward Miguel (UC-Berkeley) and Ameet Morjaria (LSE) Infrastructure and Economic Development Conference World Bank/TSE 11 January 2009

Ministers Home Areas Get Lion s Share of Roads Cash. Daily Nation, 20 July 2006. Once Nairobi and the tourist hub represented by the Maasai Mara were excluded, [road] allocations to the home constituencies of vocal government critics were nearly 320 times less generous than those to constituencies of trusted presidential aides. It s Our Turn to Eat., Michela Wrong, 2009.

Research Question Do African leaders disproportionately favor specific ethnic groups in the provision of public investments? Why?

Motivation 1 African politics is widely claimed to be unrepresentative and unaccountable, whereby leaders disproportionately favor their own ethnicity when allocating public investments (Posner 2005, Bates 2008). A large cross-country literature has emphasized the role of ethnic diversity in Africa s growth tragedy (Easterly and Levine 1997, Montalvo and Reynal-Querol 2005). Yet, even in not fully democratic regimes, leaders must build multiethnic coalitions to retain power. They reward co-ethnics and non co-ethnics by investing in public infrastructure.

Motivation 2 Why Roads? Roads are the single largest development expenditure in the Kenyan budget (approx. 15% between 1965 1999). Further, the WB spends nearly a quarter of its resources on infrastructure projects, more than on any other single category. Africa has been recognized as a continent with weak states and thus challenging for nation-building. Roads act as a mechanism to exert political power (Herbst 2000). Africa fares worse in terms of transportation infrastructure (WDR 2009). Mentioned as a main cause of African underdevelopment (WDR 1994, Buys, Deichmann and Wheeler 2006). Roads are modern, visible, targetable and recent works show large welfare gains (Michaels 2008, Banerjee, Duflo and Qian 2009).

This Paper s Approach We take an empirical micro approach which goes beyond the current limitations of the existing cross-country literature (Kasara 2007, Frank and Rainer 2009). We assemble an original and very detailed district dataset on roads in 1961-1992 Kenya, using GIS on historical maps. We combine this information with a rich political dataset on the ethnic composition of governing coalitions. This allows to test whether political changes impact the placement of roads.

Contribution Strengths: Empirical micro approach which goes beyond existing cross-country literature. Current literature has focused on education or health. Few studies on roads. Current literature has focused on the ethnicity of the leader. Limitations: We exploit two variations (independence, Kenyatta s death). Identification concerns. Case-study: one country.

Context Kenya became independent in 1963. Single-party democracy from 1966 to 1992. The President is chosen by the Central Committee of the ruling party (KANU). The executive seat is never contested during this period. Political competition takes place within the party and along ethnic lines. Three groups monopolize the political game: the Kikuyus, the Kalenjins and the Luos. The Ministry of Public Works is both the decision-maker and operator of road construction.

1964-1978: Kenyatta (Kikuyu) is president. Coalition with the Luos. 1979-1992: Moi(Kalenjin) is president. Coalition with the Kikuyus.

Preview of Findings Key Message: Targeting of roads is both narrower and broader than suggested by the often popularised ethnic patronage story. 1. Co-ethnic districts receive twice more paved roads than non co-ethnic districts (10.6%). 2. The President s home area gets five times more paved roads than the other co-ethnic districts (10.4%). 3. The district of the non co-ethnic coalition members obtain as much paved roads as the co-ethnic districts (10.5%). Around one-third of the construction of paved roads can be explained by political economy factors.

Conceptual Framework Autocrats face the threat of being evicted by coalitions within the ruling party. By distributing cabinet positions to the top men of the other ethnic groups and bringing public goods to their areas, they are able to build stable multi-ethnic coalitions and remain in power. Loyal Backer models: target co-ethnics, same sub-tribe. Core-supporter models (Cox and McCubbins 1986, Dixit and Londregan 1996): target co-ethnics, other subtribe. Swing-voter models (Lindbeck and Weibull 1987, Dixit and Londregan 1996, Groseclose and Snyder 1996): target pivotal voters, i.e. non co-ethnics.

Extended Probabilistic Model of Vote-Buying Democracy: Elections / Voters Autocracy: No eviction / Top men of the ruling party Public Expenditure Support- Buying Loyal Backers Core Supporters Swing Voters Co-ethnics, Same Subtribe Co-ethnics, Other Subtribe Non-Co-ethnics Prob.(vote): with 1 > p > q 1 p q

Empirical Evidence Empirical evidence on both African democracies and autocracies tends to support the patronage hypothesis: leaders favor loyal backers (Miguel and Zaidi 2003, Posner 2005, Frank and Rainer 2009). This fact is contradicted by Kasara 2007 (co-ethnics are more heavily taxed) and Moser 2008 (swing voters also receive public goods). Besides, no distinction between loyal backers and core supporters.

Political Data Variables: District of birth and ethnicity of all the appointed cabinet members between 1961 and 1992: the President, Vice-President and Ministers. Primary Sources: Government Publication: Organization of The Government of the Republic of Kenya, released after every cabinet shuffle and lists all the civil servants. We obtain the ethnicity and district of birth of the leaders: 1. Direct assistance from journalists from the top Kenyan dailies. 2. Work of political scientists (e.g. Hornsby 1995 and Ahluwalia 1996). 3. Weekly Review Magazine - highly active political magazine.

Political Data Table: Cabinet Share (%) of the Six Main Ethnic Groups, 1963-1992. Year Kikuyu Luhya Luo Kamba Kalenjin Kisii Other Cabinet Size 1963 35 6 24 6 0 6 24 17 1964 32 5 21 11 5 5 21 19 1966 30 9 13 9 4 9 26 23 1969 30 9 13 9 9 9 22 23 1974 30 9 13 9 9 9 22 23

Political Data Table: Cabinet Share (%) of the Six Main Ethnic Groups, 1963-1992. Year Kikuyu Luhya Luo Kamba Kalenjin Kisii Other Cabinet Size 1963 35 6 24 6 0 6 24 17 1964 32 5 21 11 5 5 21 19 1966 30 9 13 9 4 9 26 23 1969 30 9 13 9 9 9 22 23 1974 30 9 13 9 9 9 22 23 1979 30 11 11 7 15 7 19 27 1983 21 13 13 8 17 4 25 24 1988 26 12 15 12 12 6 18 34

Road Data Variables: R qdt is the total length of roads of quality q in district d at year t. Where: q = paved roads, improved roads, tracks t = 1961, 1964, 1967, 1969, 1972, 1974, 1979, 1981, 1984, 1987, 1989, 1992 Primary Sources: Time series of Michelin Road Map Series: Africa South and Central. These maps have a consistent legend which allows to classify roads into three different qualities.

Michelin map in 1961 Digitization and Standardization in GIS With district boundaries

PAVED IMPROVED TRACKS Paved(asphalt or cement concrete) Improved(laterite or gravel) Tracks(earthen and dirt roads)

The evolution of the road network, 1961-1992 1961 1964 1967

The evolution of the road network, 1961-1992 1969 1972 1974

The evolution of the road network, 1961-1992 1979 1981 1984

The evolution of the road network, 1961-1992 1987 1989 1992

Econometric Specification For district d and year t, we run: R qdt = α d + β t + ξr qdt 1 + δp dt 1 + φ t X d + ɛ dt (1) R qdt is the length in km of road type q in district d at time t. P dt 1 are our political economy variables of interest at time t-1: 1. Share of the President s co-ethnic group in district d. 2. Share of the coalition member s ethnic group in district d. 3. A dummy variable valuing 1 if district d is the district of birth of the President. 4. A dummy variable valuing 1 if district d is the district of birth of the Public Works Minister. α d and β t are district and year fixed effects, and X d is a vector of baseline demographic, economic and geographic variables whose effect φ t we allow to vary with time.

Econometric Concerns 1 Key Assumption: Changes in political leadership are exogenous. The timing of independence (1963) is exogenous, as the British Empire was granting independence to its African colonies around that time. The death of Kenyatta in 1978 was due to natural causes (similar exercise to Jones and Olken 2005). 1. We exploit the one change in president leadership. 2. Further, the vice-president Moi (Kalenjin) was not expected to succeed Kenyatta (Kikuyu) due to strong opposition from the Kikuyu elite.

Econometric Concerns 2 Concerns: Omitted variables: (a) political and economic powers go hand-in-hand, both driving road building, or (b) road building unrelated to political economy factors (e.g., Mombasa-Kampala road). Kalenjins are a pastoralist community and were not economically successful during the pre-1978 period. Control for economic geography, demography and economic activity characteristics by including interactions of baseline district variables with a time trend or time dummies.

Three Sets of Controls 1. Economic Geography: dummies for Mombasa-Kampala international road, border of Uganda and border of Tanzania, all interacted with a time trend. 2. Demography: 1962 population, having a city in 1962 and 1962 urbanization rate, all interacted with time dummies. 3. Economic activity: 1961 per capita earnings, 1961 employment rate in the formal sector and 1961 primary education completion rate, all interacted with time dummies.

Table 1: Ethnicity and District of Birth of Leaders and Road Investments Dependent Variable: Value (2007K$) Length (in km) of Value Paved Roads Lanes of Paved Roads All Roads (1) (2) (3) (4) Share of the President's Ethnic Group in the District 3,925** 10.44** 18.82* -3.44 [1,922] [4.86] [11.07] [8.45] Share of the Nearest Coalition Member in the District 4,410** 11.85** 35.05*** -8.71 [1,949] [4.88] [10.63] [9.62] District of Birth of the President 17,556*** 46.33*** 96.93*** -9.08 [2,933] [9.50] [14.49] [19.49] District of Birth of the Public Works Minister 2743 8.53* 14.02-7.5 [1,645] [4.41] [12.57] [8.79] Dependent Variable t-1 0.81*** 0.78*** 0.80*** 0.71*** [0.07] [0.08] [0.08] [0.06] Controls Y Y Y Y District FE Y Y Y Y Time FE Y Y Y Y Observations 451 451 451 451 R-squared 0.89 0.85 0.87 0.9 Notes: Robust standard errors clustered at the district level in parentheses. * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; ***significant at 1%.

Table 2: Ethnicity and District of Birth of Leaders and Paved Roads, Robustness and Specification Checks Dependent Variable: Length (in kms) of Paved Roads Change in the Length of Paved Roads Log of Length of Paved Roads Baseline No controls w/o Nairobi & Mombasa Time Dummies x Dist. Area Change (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) Log Share of the President's Ethnic Group in the Dist. 10.44** 7.81 10.05* 13.12** 11.69** 0.76** [4.86] [4.96] [5.14] [5.35] [4.41] [0.29] Share of the Nearest Coalition Member in the Dist. 11.85** 1.88 12.13** 13.98** 8.24** 0.56*** [4.88] [4.37] [5.25] [5.82] [3.95] [0.21] District of Birth of the President 46.33*** 15.10* 45.86*** 50.48*** 15.43** 0.23 [9.50] [8.73] [9.61] [12.48] [7.62] [0.32] District of Birth of the Public Works Minister 8.53* 9.27 8.11** 8.33* 18.57** 0.12 [4.41] [6.04] [3.92] [4.17] [7.28] [0.17] Dependent Variable t-1 0.78*** 0.80*** 0.79*** 0.78*** 0.54*** [0.08] [0.07] [0.08] [0.06] [0.06] Controls Y N Y Y Y Y District FE Y Y Y Y Y Y Time FE Y Y Y Y Y Y Observations 451 451 429 451 492 451 R-squared 0.85 0.81 0.85 0.86 0.31 0.77 Notes: Robust standard errors clustered at the district level in parentheses. * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; ***significant at 1%.

Table 3: Ethnicity and District of Birth of Leaders and Road Network Value, Robustness and Specification Checks Dependent Variable: Road Network Value (2007K$) Change in Road Network Value Log of Road Network Value Baseline No controls w/o Nairobi & Mombasa Time Dummies x Dist. Area Change (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) Log Share of the President's Ethnic Group in the Dist. 3,925** 2926 3,771* 4,860** 4,996*** 0.29*** [1,922] [1,784] [2,004] [2,036] [1,825] [0.10] Share of the Nearest Coalition Member in the Dist. 4,410** 962 4,538** 5,265** 3,922** 0.20** [1,949] [1,476] [2,062] [2,182] [1,636] [0.08] District of Birth of the President 17,556*** 6,982** 17,459*** 19,710*** 9,242*** 0.21 [2,933] [3,078] [2,917] [4,177] [2,690] [0.12] District of Birth of the Public Works Minister 2743 2,858.00 2531 2423 4660-0.01 [1,647] [2,314] [1,525] [1,620] [2,772] [0.06] Dependent Variable t-1 0.81*** 0.81*** 0.81*** 0.81*** 0.55*** [0.07] [0.07] [0.07] [0.08] [0.05] Controls Y N Y Y Y Y District FE Y Y Y Y Y Y Time FE Y Y Y Y Y Y Observations 451 451 429 451 451 451 R-squared 0.89 0.87 0.89 0.9 0.36 0.7 Notes: Robust standard errors clustered at the district level in parentheses. * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; ***significant at 1%.

Conclusion 1. In line with the political patronage literature, we find that presidents favor co-ethnics (10.6%). 2. We also find evidence for: - The president further favors his home area (10.5%). - The president rewards non co-ethnic allies (10.4%). - The Ministry of Public Works is a key position (1.9%). One third of the construction of paved roads can be explained by political economy factors. African politics is more complex than the sole political patronage story.

Future Work 1. Falsification exercise: using pre-independence road data (Blue Books), test that ethnicity is not driving road building. 2. District expenditure data: we will complement our road maps with district level road expenditure 1973-2000. 3. Subtribe analysis: do subtribes/clans of the same tribe experience more road building if they cooperate with the president? 4. Other public goods: do we find similar effects for other public goods? See possible district expenditure data 1973-2000 for schools, health centers, electrical infrastructure, water supply. 5. Long-term welfare implications of favoritism: district data for 1964-2007 on population, employment in the formal sector or per capita earnings.