DRAFT, WORK IN PROGRESS. A general equilibrium analysis of effects of undocumented workers in the United States

Similar documents
Labour Market Reform, Rural Migration and Income Inequality in China -- A Dynamic General Equilibrium Analysis

The Importance of Timing in the U.S. response to. Illegal Immigrants: A Recursive Dynamic Approach. Angel Aguiar. and.

Debapriya Bhattacharya Executive Director, CPD. Mustafizur Rahman Research Director, CPD. Ananya Raihan Research Fellow, CPD

The Impact of Foreign Workers on the Labour Market of Cyprus

WORKING PAPERS IN ECONOMICS & ECONOMETRICS. A Capital Mistake? The Neglected Effect of Immigration on Average Wages

International Migration

14.54 International Trade Lecture 23: Factor Mobility (I) Labor Migration

The North American Integration Model (NAIM): description and preliminary results

Volume 35, Issue 1. An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach

Do (naturalized) immigrants affect employment and wages of natives? Evidence from Germany

RESTRICTING EMPLOYMENT OF LOW-PAID IMMIGRANTS: A GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM ASSESSMENT OF THE SOCIAL WELFARE IMPLICATIONS FOR LEGAL U.S.

Unemployment and the Immigration Surplus

The Labor Market Impact of Immigration: Recent Research. George J. Borjas Harvard University April 2010

Access to Israeli Labor Markets: Effects on the West Bank Economy

Relaxing the Restrictions on the Temporary Movement of Natural Persons: A Simulation Analysis

Online Appendices for Moving to Opportunity

Discussion comments on Immigration: trends and macroeconomic implications

The Analytics of the Wage Effect of Immigration. George J. Borjas Harvard University September 2009

Potential Economic Impacts in Oregon of Implementing Proposed Department of Homeland Security No Match Immigration Rules

Crossing Boarders Labor Movement in an Enlarged EU

IMPLICATIONS OF THE GLOBAL ECONOMIC CRISIS FOR THE BANGLADESH ECONOMY

Professor Christina Romer. LECTURE 13 LABOR AND WAGES March 1, 2018

Professor Christina Romer. LECTURE 13 LABOR AND WAGES March 2, 2017

Immigration and property prices: Evidence from England and Wales

THE ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF ADMINISTRATIVE ACTION ON IMMIGRATION

Lecture Note: The Economics of Immigration. David H. Autor MIT Fall 2003 December 9, 2003

Immigration and the U.S. Economy

Bilateral Migration Model and Data Base. Terrie L. Walmsley

Agricultural Trade Reform and Poverty in Thailand: A General Equilibrium Analysis

Migration and Education Decisions in a Dynamic General Equilibrium Framework

The Labor Market Impact of Immigration. George J. Borjas Harvard University October 2006

Migration and FDI Facts

Immigration is a contentious issue in the industrialized nations of the

Does Immigration Reduce Wages?

The labour market impact of immigration

Immigrants strengthen Colorado s economy, generating $42 billion of activity in 2011

Trading Goods or Human Capital

IMPLICATIONS OF U.S. FREE TRADE AGREEMENT WITH SOUTH KOREA

The Wage Effects of Immigration and Emigration

Professor Christina Romer. LECTURE 11 LABOR AND WAGES February 28, 2019

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE ANALYTICS OF THE WAGE EFFECT OF IMMIGRATION. George J. Borjas. Working Paper

Immigrant-native wage gaps in time series: Complementarities or composition effects?

Japanese External Policies and the Asian Economic Developments

Semih Tumen Central Bank of the Republic of Turkey, and IZA, Germany. Cons. Pros

Migration, Wages and Unemployment in Thailand *

2. Labor Mobility in the Enlarged EU: Who Wins, Who Loses?

Regional benefits from international trade

GLOBALISATION AND WAGE INEQUALITIES,

Complementarities between native and immigrant workers in Italy by sector.

THESIS THE EFFECTS OF UNDOCUMENTED IMMIGRATION ON THE EMPLOYMENT OPPORTUNITIES OF LOW SKILL NATIVES IN THE UNITED STATES.

The Integration of Palestinian-Israeli Labour Markets: A CGE Approach

Labor Market Integration: as a response to goods market failure to adjust

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE LABOR MARKET IMPACT OF HIGH-SKILL IMMIGRATION. George J. Borjas. Working Paper

Enforcing Israeli Labour Market Laws against Non-Israelis: Who Pays the Price?

TURKEY S ACCESSION TO THE EUROPEAN UNION: IMPLICATIONS FOR AGRICULTURAL SECTORS. Orhan Karaca and George Philippidis

The Impact of Immigration on Wages of Unskilled Workers

Labor Market Policy Core Course: Creating Jobs in a Post- Crisis World. March 28- April 8, 2011 Washington, D.C. -- World Bank HQ- Room I2-250

Empirical Estimates of the Long-Run Labor Market Adjustments to Immigration

WhyHasUrbanInequalityIncreased?

Wage Trends among Disadvantaged Minorities

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES SCHOOLING SUPPLY AND THE STRUCTURE OF PRODUCTION: EVIDENCE FROM US STATES Antonio Ciccone Giovanni Peri

U.S. immigrant population continues to grow

EPI BRIEFING PAPER. Immigration and Wages Methodological advancements confirm modest gains for native workers. Executive summary

Impact of Japan s ODA Loan on Asian Economic Developments

Mexican Migrant Labor and Southern Plains Labor: Compatible or Exclusive

George J. Borjas Harvard University. September 2008

Abstract/Policy Abstract

Economic Effects of the Syrian War and the Spread of the Islamic State on the Levant

International Remittances and Brain Drain in Ghana

How Should Immigration Affect the Economy? A D A M M. Z A R E T S K Y

Computational Analysis of the Menu of U.S. Japan Trade Policies

Economic repercussions of opening the border to labour movements between North and South Cyprus

IMMIGRATION ECONOMICS ECONOMICS 980u, Fall 2012 Department of Economics Harvard University

Services Trade Liberalization between the European Union and Africa Caribbean and Pacific Countries: A Dynamic Approach

SUP-311 The Economic Impact of Immigration

Immigrants are playing an increasingly

Immigrants Inflows, Native outflows, and the Local Labor Market Impact of Higher Immigration David Card

A Multivariate Analysis of the Factors that Correlate to the Unemployment Rate. Amit Naik, Tarah Reiter, Amanda Stype

Understanding Immigration:

Rural-urban Migration and Minimum Wage A Case Study in China

Immigration and Wages: Decoding the Economics

Immigration and Poverty in the United States

Chapter 4 Specific Factors and Income Distribution

The Causes of Wage Differentials between Immigrant and Native Physicians

Computerization and Immigration: Theory and Evidence from the United States 1

Immigration Policy and Its Possible Effects on U.S. Agriculture

(V) Migration Flows and Policies. Bocconi University,

Changing Dynamics and. to the United States

The Impact of Trade Liberalisation on Poverty and Welfare in South Asia: A Special Reference to Sri Lanka

Chapter 5. Labour Market Equilibrium. McGraw-Hill/Irwin Labor Economics, 4 th edition

Illegal Immigration. When a Mexican worker leaves Mexico and moves to the US he is emigrating from Mexico and immigrating to the US.

AEC Integration and Internal Migration: A Dynamic CGE Model Approach

Migration and Employment Interactions in a Crisis Context

Skilled Immigration and the Employment Structures of US Firms

The Effect of Economic Sanctions on Domestic Production, Trade and Transportation of Sanctioned Goods

Characteristics of the Ethnographic Sample of First- and Second-Generation Latin American Immigrants in the New York to Philadelphia Urban Corridor

The Costs of Remoteness, Evidence From German Division and Reunification by Redding and Sturm (AER, 2008)

LABOR MARKET DISTORTIONS, RURAL-URBAN INEQUALITY AND THE OPENING OF CHINA S ECONOMY *

Free Trade in the Americas FTAA

Advancing Computable General Equilibrium Analysis (CGE) of the Economic Consequences of Terrorism

Transcription:

DRAFT, WORK IN PROGRESS A general equilibrium analysis of effects of undocumented workers in the United States Marinos Tsigas and Hugh M. Arce U.S. International Trade Commission, Washington, DC, USA 14 April 2008 Abstract We examine some of the economic impacts of the 7.2 million undocumented workers in the United States. We use the USAGE-ITC model, an applied general equilibrium model of the United States. Our simulation suggests that the immigration surplus due to undocumented workers is about $20 billion, which is about 0.19 percent of GDP. Additional calculations with the GTAP model of global trade suggest that ignoring the international implications of immigration and remittances might underestimate the immigration surplus due to undocumented workers. Research report submitted to the Eleventh Annual Conference on Global Economic Analysis, Helsinki, Finland, June 12-14, 2008. The authors thank Jeffrey Passel for sharing statistics about undocumented workers in the United States. This research report represents solely the views of the authors and does not represent the views of the U.S. International Trade Commission or any of its Commissioners. E-mails: Marinos.Tsigas@usitc.gov, Hugh.Arce@usitc.gov.

A general equilibrium analysis of effects of undocumented workers in the United States Introduction In 2005 the number of undocumented workers in the United States was about 7.2 million, which is equal to about 5 percent of the U.S. workforce (Passel, 2006). About 3 million of the 7.2 million workers were in occupations in which undocumented workers account for at least 15 percent of total employment in that occupation. These included construction labor (25 percent), cooks (20 percent), maids and housecleaners (22 percent), and grounds maintenance (25 percent). Among roofers, 29 percent of the total workforce was estimated to be undocumented workers. Economic theory predicts that, when the supply of productive factor increases, its rental rate will fall. So will the rental rates of factors that are close substitutes. On the other hand, there will be an increase in the rental rate of factors that are used in combination with it, i.e., complements. So for example, if the supply of fruit pickers in the United States increases through immigration, theory predicts that the wages of fruit pickers in the United States will fall. So will the wages of workers with similar skills. But there will be an increase in the earnings of fruit growers, transportation workers and others who work with fruit pickers to bring fruits to markets. Finally, because immigrants not only work, but also spend their income, the increased demand for goods and services will create jobs and raise wages throughout the economy. Thus immigration generates extra income for the U.S. economy, even as it pushes down wages for some workers. The gain in productivity yields extra income for U.S. natives, which is termed the immigration surplus. 1

Several studies have quantified the effects of immigrants on the U.S. economy. 1 At the national level, George Borjas used a partial equilibrium economic framework to describe how natives benefit from immigration (Borjas, 1995). Borjas concluded that the annual increase in national income accruing to natives, or the immigration surplus due to all immigrants was about 0.1 percent of GDP in 1995. Borjas (1995) shows that the immigration surplus, as a fraction of national income, equals ½SεM, where S is labor s share of national income; ε is the elasticity of factor price for labor (i.e., the percentage change in the wage resulting from 1 percent change in the size of the work force); and M is the fraction of the workforce that are immigrants. 2 Gordon Hanson (2007) estimated that the annual immigration surplus due to all immigrants in the United States was about 0.2 percent of GDP in 2004. Hanson s estimate of the immigration surplus is higher than Borjas because the fraction of immigrants in the workforce had grown from less than 10 percent in 1995 to slightly over 14 percent in 2004. Peter Dixon, Martin Johnson, and Maureen Rimmer (2008) used a dynamic applied general equilibrium model to simulate the effects of potential government programs aiming to restrict the employment of illegal immigrants in the United States. Their economic framework, USAGE-M, is labor-market-extended version of USAGE-ITC, the model that we use in this paper. Dixon et al. estimated that U.S. GDP would decline by 1.6 percent due to a policy that brings about a 28.6 percent reduction in the employment of undocumented workers. 3 1 For surveys of this literature, see Gordon Hanson (2005), James Smith and Barry Edmonston (1997) and George Borjas (1999a, 1999b). 2 The empirical literature suggests that the price elasticity of factor demand for labor is about -0.3 (Hamermesh, 1993). The share of labor in national income is about 0.7. 3 Among studies which focus at the effects of immigration at the local level, David Card (1990) studied the 1980 Mariel boat lift, during which 125,000 Cubans arrived in South Florida with approximately half remaining in the Miami area, and increasing the city's labor force by 7 percent. Card concluded that the Mariel 2

In this paper, we apply a large-scale applied general equilibrium model, the USAGE- ITC 4 model, to simulate the effects of undocumented workers on the U.S. economy. Overview of the USAGE-ITC Framework The USAGE-ITC framework has been developed by the Centre of Policy Studies (CoPS), Monash University, Australia and the U.S. International Trade Commission. The theory of the USAGE-ITC model is described in Dixon and Rimmer (2002). The USAGE- ITC model is specified at the 498 industries contained in the published input-output accounts for the United States (Lawson, 1997). The USAGE-ITC data in this paper reflect economic conditions in 2002 (Dixon and Rimmer, 2001 and 2003, Dixon et al., 2004, and US ITC, 2004). The USAGE-ITC framework has three components: (i) I-O accounts, (ii) behavioral parameters, and (iii) a system of economy-wide conditions. While the I-O accounts specify the initial equilibrium for the U.S. economy, behavioral equations and parameters determine how economic agents would respond to an exogenous change. The following parameters are used by USAGE-ITC: 1. Elasticities of substitution between imported and domestic goods; 2. Elasticities of import supply and export demand; 3. Elasticities of input substitution for U.S. producers; and 4. Income and price elasticities for U.S. households. Where possible, parameters have been estimated. In other cases, parameter specification relied on published studies. The elasticities of substitution between imported influx appears to have had virtually no effect on the wages or unemployment rates of less-skilled workers. Jennifer Hunt (1992) and Rachel Friedberg (2001) have reached similar conclusions for the return migration of ethnic French from Algeria to France in 1962 and the exodus of 600,000 Russian Jews to Israel in the early 1990's. 4 USAGE-ITC stands for U.S. applied general equilibrium-international Trade Commission. 3

and domestic goods (i.e., the Armington elasticities) are documented in Donnelly et al. and Hertel et al. The final component of the USAGE-ITC framework is a system of three general conditions which ensure a competitive general equilibrium. First, all constant returns activities must earn zero profits. Second, the market for each product must clear such that supply equals demand. The third general condition is that income is exhausted on final demand and savings. In addition, the following nine assumptions underlie the simulations in this paper: 1. The simulation has no effect on real national savings. Thus, the quantity of capital owned by U.S. residents is unaffected in the simulation. 2. Real government expenditures are not affected by the simulation. 3. The ratio of real public consumption to real private consumption is held constant. 4. Real private consumption is related to real disposable income. The government adjusts the tax rate on labor income to ensure that the simulation-induced movement in real private consumption is consistent with maintenance of real national savings. 5. The ratio of investment to capital (I/K) in each industry is held constant. Because the ratio I/K is a reflection of business confidence, this assumption implies that the simulation has no long-run effect on business confidence. 6. The average rate of return on capital across industries adjusts while capital stocks do not change, i.e., our simulations depict short-run effects. 7. Real wage rates adjust so that the simulation has no effect on aggregate employment of U.S. residents. 8. The simulation has no effect on technology or consumer preferences. 4

9. The simulation has no effect on the aggregate price index for private consumption; that is, this aggregate price index is the numeraire price. Specification of the USAGE-ITC Model The following sections describe briefly the three key components of the USAGE- ITC model: final demand behavior, production technology, and the trade equilibrium. The USAGE-ITC model considers three separate components of domestic final demand: household consumption, government demand, and investment demand. Household consumption is derived from a linear expenditure system (LES) of commodity demands. The assumption of fixed real government spending is satisfied by endogenously adjusting government transfers to households. This adjustment assumes that changes in government revenues are compensated through a tax. For investment demand, capital creators in an industry are assumed to choose their input mixes to minimize the costs of producing new capital subject to a constant-returns-to-scale capital-creation function. The only prices affecting the demand for domestic and imported inputs to capital creation are the prices of these inputs. Input-output technologies are modeled with nested substitution/transformation functions. Value-added and intermediate inputs are combined to produce a composite industry output. Intermediate inputs do not substitute for one another and for value added. Land, capital and labor are combined to produce value-added. Substitution possibilities between land, labor and capital are based on the CRESH (i.e., constant ratios of elasticities of substitution, homothetic) specification. For each commodity in USAGE-ITC there is a distinction between two varieties. A domestic variety is destined for domestic consumption and exports and a foreign variety is 5

destined for domestic consumption. The substitution possibilities between the two varieties (i.e., the degree of product differentiation) are specified with a CES (constant elasticity of substitution) substitution parameter which is often referred to as the "Armington" elasticity (Armington, 1969). The modeling of trade equilibrium is completed by defining constant elasticity export demand and import supply functions. Effects of Undocumented Workers on the U.S. Economy To quantify the effects of undocumented workers on the U.S. economy we simulate the absence of those workers. Table 1 shows the share of undocumented workers for nine broad economic sectors. 5 There is a wide variation in the share of undocumented workers in each sector s labor force. Undocumented workers are more than 12 percent of the labor force in the two sectors representing farming, fisheries, and forestry and construction. For the rest of the economy, undocumented workers account from two to six percent of the labor force. For the U.S. economy as a whole, undocumented workers account for 4.9 percent of the labor force. Table 2 shows some macro effects from the simulation. The labor wage rate increases by 1.8 percent. 6 The average capital rental rate declines by 3.1 percent. Real GDP declines by 3.5 percent (or $351.7 billion) which is roughly equal to the product of the share of labor (0.7) and the percentage decline in labor (4.9 percent). The immigration surplus, or the decline in income for natives, is about $20 billion (i.e., the GDP effect less the undocumented worker wage bill), which is about 0.19 percent of GDP. As a result of this simulation, the cost of producing U.S. commodities increases on average and thus the volume of total U.S. exports declines by 7.9 percent. Despite the 5 The USAGE-ITC simulation in this paper is run at the 498-industry specification. We report effects for nine broad industry aggregates. 6 The USAGE-ITC model has been calibrated to about a -0.37 price elasticity for labor demand. 6

increase in average U.S. costs of production, the volume of total U.S. imports declines by 4.3. Real consumption or welfare declines by 4.6 percent (or $333.7 billion). Table 3 shows some of the sector-level effects from the simulation. Farming, fisheries, and forestry are affected the most by this simulation. About 12 percent of the labor in this sector is undocumented so its absence causes a decline of 8.5 percent in the sector s output. The share of undocumented labor in construction is about 12 percent too. This sector however is not affected much by the absence of undocumented labor because investment, the major market for construction, does not change much in this simulation. The immigration surplus Most of the undocumented workers in the United States are from Mexico, an economy with close trade linkages to the U.S. economy. Estimating the immigration surplus in partial or general equilibrium frameworks that do not consider the international trade consequences of immigration and remittances might lead to biased estimates. To assess the extent of bias we apply a global trade framework, the GTAP model of global trade (Hertel, 1997). We assume that all undocumented workers come to the United States from Mexico and that 80 percent of their labor wages are remitted to Mexico. The GTAP simulation consists of three shocks: a migration of undocumented unskilled labor from Mexico to the United States; the implied change in the populations of the two economies; and remittances from the United States to Mexico. 7 The GTAP simulation suggests that the arrival of undocumented workers in the United States would increase U.S. real income by $63 billion or 0.69 percent of GDP. This estimate of the immigration surplus due to undocumented 7 We note that we use the GTAP model to simulate the effects of the arrival of the 7.2 million undocumented workers in the U.S. economy whereas we simulated the departure of those workers with the USAGE-ITC model. 7

workers is much higher than that obtained when ignoring the international consequences of remittances. Summary and conclusions We examined some of the economic impacts of the 7.2 million of undocumented workers in the United States. We used an applied general equilibrium model of the United States. Our simulation suggests that the immigration surplus is about $20 billion which is about 0.19 percent of GDP. To put this figure in perspective, we note that Anderson and Martin (2005) estimate that U.S. real income gains from full liberalization of global trade amount to 0.1 percent of GDP. Similarly, simulation estimates of the potential effects of NAFTA prior to entering into force suggested increases of U.S. real income of approximately 0.07 percent (U.S. ITC, 1992). Additional calculations with the GTAP model suggest that ignoring the international implications of immigration and remittances might underestimate the immigration surplus. 8

References Anderson, K. and Martin, W. (2005). Agricultural Trade Reform and the Doha Development Agenda. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 3607. May. Armington, P.S. (1969), "A Theory of Demand for Products Distinguished by Place of Production," IMF Staff Papers, 16, Mar., pp. 159-76. Borjas, G.J. (1995). The Economic Benefits from immigration. Journal of Economic Perspectives. 9(2), Spring, pp. 3-22. Borjas, G. J. (1999a). The Economic Analysis of Immigration. In Ashenfelter, O.C., and Card, D., eds., Handbook of Labor Economics, Amsterdam: North-Holland, pp. 1697-1760. Borjas, G. J. (1999b). Heaven s Door: Immigration Policy and the American Economy. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press. Card, D. (1990). The Impact of the Mariel Boatlift on the Miami Labor Market. Industrial and Labor Relations Review. 43(2), Jan., pp. 245-257. Donnelly, W.A., Johnson, K., Tsigas, M., Ingersoll, D. (2004). "Revised Armington Elasticities of Substitution for the USITC Model and the Concordance for Constructing a Consistent Set for the GTAP Model, Office of Economics Research Note, No. 2004-01-A, U.S. International Trade Commission, January. Dixon, P.B., Johnson, M., and Rimmer, M.T. (2008). Reducing illegal migrants in the U.S.: a dynamic CGE analysis. Centre of Policy Studies, Monash University. February 20. Dixon, P.B., and Rimmer, M.T. (2001). MONASH-USA: Creating a 1992 Benchmark Input-Output database. Clayton: Centre of Policy Studies, Monash University. Dixon, P.B., and Rimmer, M.T. (2002). USAGE-ITC: Theoretical Structure. Clayton: Centre of Policy Studies, Monash University. Dixon, P.B., and Rimmer, M.T. (2003). USAGE-ITC: Creating historical shocks for 1992 to 1998. Clayton: Centre of Policy Studies, Monash University. Dixon, P.B., Rimmer, M.T., and Tsigas, M. (2004). Creating a USAGE-ITC database for 2002. Clayton: Centre of Policy Studies, Monash University. Friedberg, R. M. (2001). The Impact of Mass Migration on the Israeli Labor Market. The Quarterly Journal of Economics. 116 (4), Nov., pp. 1373-1408. Hamermesh, D.S. (1993). Labor Demand. Princeton University Press, Princeton, N.J. 9

Hanson, G.H. (2006). Illegal Migration from Mexico to the United States. Journal of Economic Literature. 44:869-924, December. Hanson, G.H. (2007). The Economic Logic of Illegal Immigration. CSR No. 26, Council on Foreign Relations. New York. April. Hertel, T.W. editor (1997), Global Trade Analysis: Modeling and Applications, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, U.K. Hertel, T.W., Hummels, D., Ivanic, M., and Roman, K.. (2003). How Confident Can We Be in CGE-Based Assessments of Free Trade Agreements? GTAP Working Paper No.26, Center for Global Trade Analysis, Purdue University, West Lafayette, Indiana, May. Hunt, J. (1992). The Impact of the 1962 Repatriates from Algeria on the French Labor Market. Industrial and Labor Relations Review. 45, April, pp. 556-572. Lawson, A.M. (1997). Benchmark Input-Output Accounts for the U.S. Economy, 1992: Make, Use, and Supplementary Tables. Survey of Current Business. 77, 36-82. Washington DC: Bureau of Economic Analysis, U.S. Dept. of Commerce. Passel, J. S. (2006). The Size and Characteristics of the Unauthorized Migrant Population in the U.S. Pew Hispanic Center. Washington, DC. March. Smith, J. P., and Edmonston, B., eds. (1998). The Immigration Debate. National Academy Press: Washington, D.C. U. S. International Trade Commission. (1992). Economy-wide Modeling of the Economic Implications of a FTA with Mexico and a NAFTA with Canada and Mexico. Report on Inv. No. 332-317. Pub. 2516. Washington DC. May. U. S. International Trade Commission. (2004). The Economic Effects of Significant U.S. Import Restraints: Fourth Update 2004. Inv. No. 332-325. Pub. 3701. Washington DC. 10

Table 1. Employment share of undocumented workers in the United States, by sector Sector Share of undocumented workers percent Farming, fisheries, and forestry 12.2 Mining 2.4 Construction 12.2 Durable manufacturing 6.0 Non-durable manufacturing 5.7 Transportation and utilities 2.8 Wholesale and retail trade 3.7 Finance, insurance, and real estate 2.2 Other services 4.4 U.S. economy as a whole 4.9 Sources: Passel (2006) and USAGE-ITC database. Table 2.Simulating the absence of undocumented workers in the United States, selected macro effects percent change Real consumption -4.6 Real GDP -3.5 Exports -7.9 Imports -4.3 Wage rate 1.8 Capital rental rate -3.1 Source: USAGE-ITC model simulation. Table 3.Simulating the absence of undocumented workers in the United States, selected sectoral effects Sector Labor employment Supply Exports Imports ----------------- percent change --------------- Farming, fisheries, and forestry -19.5-8.5-17.6-3.3 Mining 3.7 1.5 38.8-4.1 Construction -2.7-1.0-98.8 0.0 Durable manufacturing -9.2-7.4-20.3-3.7 Non-durable manufacturing -7.9-5.2-8.1-4.0 Transportation and utilities -7.5-4.2 40.7-6.4 Wholesale and retail trade -5.9-5.3 26.2 0.0 Finance, insurance, and real estate 3.7 0.8 166.6-5.4 Other services -5.1-4.4-12.3-4.5 Source: USAGE-ITC model simulation. 11