Antitrust and Intellectual Property: Recent Developments in the Pharmaceuticals Sector

Similar documents
Pay-for-Delay Settlements: Antitrust Violation or Proper Exercise of Pharmaceutical Patent Rights?

Increased Scrutiny of Reverse Payment Settlements: Recent Cases in E.D. of PA and 2nd Circuit Suggest Change May Be Ahead for Pharma Clients

From Walker Process to In re DDAVP: Should Direct Purchasers Have Antitrust Standing in Walker Process Claims?

A ((800) (800) Supreme Court of the United States REPLY BRIEF. No IN THE

Pharmaceutical Patent Settlement Cases: Mixed Signals for Settling Patent Litigation

Pharmaceutical Product Improvements and Life Cycle Management Antitrust Pitfalls 1

Case4:07-cv CW Document133 Filed01/12/10 Page1 of 18 IN THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE NORTHERN DISTRICT OF CALIFORNIA

In The Supreme Court of the United States

LOUISIANA WHOLESALE DRUG CO., INC., et al., Respondents. UPSHER-SMITH LABORATORIES, INC., Petitioner, v.

Reverse Payment Settlements In Pharma Industry: Revisited

PENDING LEGISLATION REGULATING PATENT INFRINGEMENT SETTLEMENTS

Stuck in Neutral: The Future of Reverse Payments Agreements in Hatch-Waxman Litigation

Health Care Law Monthly

Whither Price Squeeze Antitrust?

Looking Within the Scope of the Patent

WE V E A L L B E E N T H E R E.

Editor s Note. US Antitrust Modernization Commission. By A. Noboa Pagán.

Pharmaceutical Pay for Delay Settlements

Product Improvements and Life Cycle Management Antitrust Pitfalls

PAYING FOR DELAY AND THE RULE OF REASON FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION V ACTAVIS INC ET AL 1

Antitrust/Intellectual Property Interface Under U.S. Law

In the Supreme Court of the United States

Intellectual Property E-Bulletin

In re K-Dur Antitrust Litigation: Reopening the Door for Pharmaceutical Competition

Pay-to-Delay Settlements: The Circuit-Splitting Headache Plaguing Big Pharma

SUPREME COURT OF THE UNITED STATES

FTC AND DOJ ISSUE JOINT REPORT REGARDING ANTITRUST ENFORCEMENT AND INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY RIGHTS

Antitrust and Intellectual Property

Case 1:10-mc CKK -AK Document 31 Filed 07/13/10 Page 1 of 12 UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE DISTRICT OF COLUMBIA

SUPREME COURT OF THE UNITED STATES

From PLI s Program New Strategies Arising from the Hatch-Waxman Amendments #4888

THE ANTITRUST LEGALITY OF PHARMACEUTICAL PATENT LITIGATION SETTLEMENTS

Competition Ahead? The Legal Landscape for Reverse Payment Settlements After Federal Trade Commission v. Actavis, Inc.

Pharmaceutical Patent Settlements A Presumption in Reverse

The EU Sector Inquiry: Implications for Patent Litigation and Settlements

1 Bret Dickey, Jonathan Orszag & Laura Tyson, An Economic Assessment of Patent Settlements

5 Red Flags In Pharmaceutical Settlements

DIRECT PURCHASERS STANDING TO SUE FOR WALKER PROCESS FRAUD IN RE: DDAVP DIRECT PURCHASER ANTITRUST LITIGATION

Intersection of Patent Infringement and Antitrust Liability in Abbreviated New Drug Application Litigation, The

CRS Report for Congress

Intellectual Ventures Wins Summary Judgment to Defeat Capital One s Antitrust Counterclaims

FTC v. Actavis, Inc.: When Is the Rule of Reason Not the Rule of Reason?

by Harvey M. Applebaum and Thomas O. Barnett

A Response to Chief Justice Roberts: Why Antitrust Must Play a Role in the Analysis of Drug Patent Settlements

REVERSE PAYMENT AGREEMENTS: WHY A QUICK LOOK PROPERLY PROTECTS PATENTS AND PATIENTS

Pharmaceutical Patent Settlements: Issues in Innovation and Competitiveness

Case 1:06-cv RWR Document 53 Filed 02/25/2008 Page 1 of 15 UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE DISTRICT OF COLUMBIA

Reverse Payment Settlements: A Patent Approach to Defending the Argument for Illegality

In the Supreme Court of the United States

No IN THE ( ourt of the: Petitioners, v. BAYER AG ~ ~D BAYER CORP., ETAL., Respondents.

Does a Civil Protective Order Protect a Company s Foreign Based Documents from Being Produced in a Related Criminal Investigation?

RAMBUS, INC. v. FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION Impact on Standards and Antitrust

Patent Portfolio Management and Technical Standard Setting: How to Avoid Loss of Patent Rights. Bruce D. Sunstein 1 Bromberg & Sunstein LLP

2 Noerr-Pennington Rulings Affirm Narrow Scope Of Immunity

In Re: Tamoxifen Citrate Antitrust Litigation UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE SECOND CIRCUIT. 466 F.3d 187 August 10, 2006, Decided

THE JOHN MARSHALL REVIEW OF INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY LAW

No DD IN THE UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE ELEVENTH CIRCUIT

A Framework to Evaluate Pharmaceutical Pay-for- Delays: A Balancing Test Based Upon Reasonableness

Schering-Plough and in Re Tamoxifen: Lawful Reverse Payments in the Hatch-Waxman Context

Supreme Court of the United States

A Different Approach to Antimonopolization Enforcement for the Obama Admininstration

15.3a1. Entry-restrictive Agreements; Exclusion or Reverse Payments

The Supreme Court Decision in Empagran

Caraco V. Novo Nordisk: Antitrust Implications

No.,, LOUISIANA WHOLESALE DRUG CO., AG, et al., BAYER AG AND BAYER CORP., et al.,

No IN THE Supreme Court of the United States. On Writ of Certiorari to the United States Court of Appeals for the Eleventh Circuit

Payment After Actavis

A Pharmaceutical Park Place: Why the Supreme Court Should Modify the Scope of the Patent Test for Reverse Payment Deals

REVERSE PAYMENTS: WHEN THE FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION CAN ATTACK THE VALIDITY OF UNDERLYING PATENTS

The Implications Of Twombly And PeaceHealth

Towards a Consistent Antitrust Policy for Unilateral Conduct

Supreme Court of the United States

STATEMENT OF CHARLES P. BAKER CHAIR ABA SECTION OF INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY LAW. on behalf of the AMERICAN BAR ASSOCIATION. before the SUBCOMMITTEE

Tenth Circuit Affirms Dismissal of Antitrust Tying and Bundling Claims

Antitrust and Refusals To Deal after Nynex v. Discon

Antitrust Enforcement Under President Obama: Where Have We Been and Where Are We Going? Stacey Anne Mahoney *

CUSTOMERS MAY BE ABLE TO SUE PATENT OWNERS FOR ANTITRUST DAMAGES IN CASES OF FRAUD ON THE USPTO

ORDER GRANTING IN PART AND DENYING IN PART MOTION TO TRANSFER OR STAY

Graduate Industrial Organization Some Notes on Antitrust.

Rachel A. Lewis * * J.D. Candidate, Seattle University School of Law, I want to dedicate this Comment to my

International Competition Network Unilateral Conduct Working Group Questionnaire

FTC v. ACTAVIS: The Patent-Antitrust Intersection Revisited

PCI SSC Antitrust Compliance Guidelines

SOME PREDICTIONS ABOUT FUTURE ANTITRUST ENFORCEMENT

Can You Hear Me Now? Bell Atlantic v. Twombly and the Pleading Standards for Antitrust Conspiracy Claims

Payment After Actavis 100 Iowa Law Review 1 (forthcoming 2014) Michael A. Carrier *

Side Effects The Evolving Law of Reverse Payments and Its Impact on Drug Litigation

PATENT HOLDUP, ANTITRUST, AND INNOVATION: HARNESS

WHY THE SUPREME COURT WAS CORRECT TO DENY CERTIORARI IN FTC V. RAMBUS

Case 2:08-cv MSG Document 43 Filed 08/31/2009 Page 1 of 59 IN THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE EASTERN DISTRICT OF PENNSYLVANIA

UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT DISTRICT OF MASSACHUSETTS

UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT SOUTHERN DISTRICT OF CALIFORNIA. Plaintiffs,

15 Hous. J. Health L. & Policy 281 Copyright 2015 Tracey Toll Houston Journal of Health Law & Policy

No. IN THE Supreme Court of the United States. Petitioner, v. SCHERING-PLOUGH CORPORATION, et al.

FTC Orders Compulsory IP Licensing to Remedy Competitive Concerns in Honeywell/Intermec Transaction

Case 1:05-cv JDT-TAB Document 30 Filed 11/28/2005 Page 1 of 12 UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT SOUTHERN DISTRICT OF INDIANA INDIANAPOLIS DIVISION

BANKRUPTCY JUDGE FINDS NO COLLUSION IN GRAND UNION AUCTION

In Re K-Dur Antitrust Litigation: Pharmaceutical Reverse Payment Settlements Go beyond the Scope of the Patent

An ANDA Update. June 2004 Bulletin 04-50

ON NOVEMBER 6, 2001, the U.S. Court of Appeals

Transcription:

September 2009 (Release 2) Antitrust and Intellectual Property: Recent Developments in the Pharmaceuticals Sector Aidan Synnott & William Michael Paul, Weiss, Rifkind, Wharton & Garrison LLP www.competitionpolicyinternational.com Competition Policy International, Inc.

Antitrust and Intellectual Property: Recent Developments in the Pharmaceuticals Sector Aidan Synnott & William Michael 1 I. INTRODUCTION uring his campaign for the Presidency, then Senator Barack Obama promised that he would direct his administration to reinvigorate antitrust enforcement, placing special emphasis on competition in health care and pharmaceuticals. 2 Among other things, he promised to ensure that the law effectively prevents anticompetitive agreements that artificially retard the entry of generic pharmaceuticals onto the market.... 3 That promise has been echoed by President Obama s choice to head the Federal Trade Commission ( FTC ), Jon Leibowitz, long an outspoken critic of so called reverse settlement or pay for delay agreements between manufacturers of branded and generic pharmaceuticals. More recently, the Antitrust Division of the Department of Justice ( DOJ ), under new Assistant Attorney General Christine Varney, has taken a significantly more aggressive stance toward such agreements than the DOJ has taken before. As yet, however, the policy position advanced by the FTC, and now adopted by the DOJ, has not gained acceptance in any federal court of appeals. And recent Supreme Court and Courts of Appeals decisions have had the effect of limiting, rather than expanding, the range of antitrust claims that may be brought against holders of pharmaceutical patents for their conduct in the marketplace especially when such conduct is unilateral. The practical effect of the agencies stated commitment to heightened enforcement in the pharmaceutical sector, therefore, may be limited by their ability to articulate theories of anticompetitive harm that the federal courts deem viable. 1 Aidan Synnott is a partner in the Litigation Department of Paul, Weiss, Paul, Rifkind, Wharton & Garrison LLP where he focuses on antitrust litigation and compliance, intellectual property litigation, securities litigation and complex commercial litigation. William Michael is an associate in the same department. Prior to joining Paul, Weiss, Mr. Michael served as a trial attorney in the Antitrust Division of the United States Department of Justice. 2 Statement of Senator Barack Obama for the American Antitrust Institute (Sept. 27, 2007) ( AAI Statement ), available at http://www.antitrustinstitute.org/archives/files/aai %20Presidential%20campaign%20 %20Obama%209 07_092720071759.pdf. 3 Id. 2

II. THE DOJ S REVERSAL OF ITS POSITION ON REVERSE SETTLEMENTS Reverse settlement agreements arise in pharmaceutical patent disputes in which the manufacturer of a branded drug sues a would be competitor for patent infringement when it seeks federal regulatory approval to market a generic version of the drug. If litigated to a judgment, such disputes typically require a court to address the validity of the patent at issue. Given the risks associated with invalidation of a patent on a successful pharmaceutical product, branded manufacturers arguably have an incentive to settle such claims by paying the generic competitor to delay its entry into the market. While the FTC has long taken the view that such agreements are anticompetitive and harmful to consumers, the Antitrust Division s response to reverse settlements has been considerably more tolerant. In 2006, the FTC and DOJ took conflicting positions on a petition for certiorari in FTC v. Schering Plough, 4 a case in which the Eleventh Circuit Court of Appeals had rejected the FTC s allegations that a reverse settlement agreement concerning the drug K Dur 20 unreasonably restrained competition by delaying entry of a generic competitor. The FTC sought certiorari from the Supreme Court to correct what it characterized as fundamental legal errors by the court of appeals that not only depart from settled antitrust and administrative law principles, but also dramatically alter Congress s intended balance between the patent and antitrust laws as applied to generic drugs. 5 In a separate amicus brief, filed at the invitation of the Supreme Court, DOJ argued that certiorari should be denied because the case did not present an appropriate opportunity for this Court to determine the proper standards for distinguishing legitimate patent settlements, which further the important goals of encouraging innovation and minimizing unnecessary litigation, from illegitimate settlements that impermissibly restrain trade in violation of the antitrust laws. 6 Throughout the previous administration, the FTC and DOJ remained split on how reverse settlements were to be treated under the antitrust laws. That split has narrowed, if not disappeared. Departing from its previous positions in cases like Schering Plough, DOJ recently argued in an amicus brief filed at the invitation of the United States Court of Appeals for the Second Circuit in In re Ciprofloxacin Hydrochloride Antitrust Litigation that reverse settlement agreements in the pharmaceutical industry should be treated as presumptively unlawful under the antitrust laws. 7 To the extent adopted by the Court, DOJ s newly articulated position would mark a departure from existing precedent in the Second Circuit and other federal courts involving challenges to such agreements. 4 402 F.3d 1056 (11th Cir. 2005). 5 FTC v. Schering Plough, No. 05 273, Petition for a Writ of Certiorari (Aug. 2005), available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/2005/08/050829scheringploughpet.pdf. 6 Id., Brief of the United States as Amicus Curiae (May 17, 2006), available at http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/cases/f216300/216358.pdf. 7 Brief for the United States in Response to the Court s Invitation, In re Ciprofloxacin Hydrochloride Antitrust Litig., No. 05 2851 cv (2d Cir. July 6, 2009) ( Cipro Brief ), available at http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/cases/f247700/247708.pdf. 3

Ciprofloxacin, still pending before the Court of Appeals, was brought by purchasers of the antibiotic Cipro. They sued Bayer, the manufacturer of Cipro, and Barr Laboratories, the manufacturer of a generic alternative, for allegedly violating the antitrust laws by entering into a reverse settlement of a prior patent infringement suit brought by Bayer against Barr. Under the settlement agreement, Bayer allegedly made a series of payments to Barr in return for an agreement to delay the generic version of Cipro until six months before the Cipro patent would expire. In 2005, the District Court for the Eastern District of New York granted defendants motion for summary judgment, holding that plaintiffs had failed to prove that the challenged settlement agreement had an actual adverse effect on competition. 8 The District Court concluded that it would be inappropriate to engage in an after the fact analysis of the patent s validity; rather, an existing patent should be treated as presumptively valid. 9 The proper test for determining the validity of a reverse settlement agreement, the court held, is whether the agreement would constrain competition beyond the scope of the underlying patent. 10 Applying this test to Bayer s settlement agreement with Barr, the court determined that plaintiffs had not shown any restraint of competition beyond that achieved by the Cipro patent itself. In response to the Second Circuit s invitation to submit a brief on the reverse settlement issue, DOJ maintained, as in prior cases, that such agreements do not constitute per se antitrust violations. For the first time, however, DOJ argued that reverse settlement agreements in the pharmaceutical context should be treated as presumptively unlawful under Section 1 of the Sherman Act. 11 Defendants may rebut that presumption, it contended, by offering evidence that the challenged payments did not purchase a reduction in competition. 12 For example, where defendant can show that the payment to an alleged infringer was no more than an amount commensurate with the patent holder s avoided litigation costs, the agreement is likely to be upheld. 13 By contrast, where the challenged payment is greatly in excess of avoided litigation costs, and the agreement precludes generic competition throughout the term of the underlying patent, the agreement is likely to violate the Sherman Act. 14 In addition to advocating the adoption of a presumptively unlawful standard, the Division urged the Second Circuit to revisit its own 2006 decision in In re Tamoxifen Citrate Antitrust Litigation. 15 In Tamoxifen, on which the District Court relied in Ciprofloxacin, the Court of Appeals had held absent an extension of the monopoly beyond the patent s scope,... and absent fraud,... the question is whether the underlying infringement lawsuit was objectively baseless in the sense that no reasonable litigant could realistically expect success on the merits. 16 This holding, DOJ asserted, was incorrect. 17 In particular, the Division maintained 8 In re Ciprofloxacin Hydrochloride Antitrust Litig., 363 F. Supp. 2d 514 (E.D.N.Y. 2005). 9 Id. at 539. 10 Id. at 540. 11 Cipro Brief at 10. 12 Id. at 27 32. 13 Id. at 28. 14 Id. at 29. 15 466 F.3d 187 (2d Cir. 2006). 16 Id. at 213 (internal quotation marks omitted). 4

that Tamoxifen s objectively baseless standard effectively barred antitrust scrutiny of reverse settlement agreements and offered no protection to the public interest in eliminating undeserved patents. 18 Finally, DOJ directly reversed a position it had advanced in Schering Plough that courts weighing the anticompetitive effects of a reverse settlement payment, at a minimum should take into account the relative likelihood of success of the parties claims in the underlying infringement lawsuit. 19 In its Ciprofloxacin brief, DOJ maintained that [i]f the settlement involves a payment in exchange for the generic manufacturer s agreement to withdraw its challenge to the patent and to delay entry, there is no need to determine whether the patent would in fact have been held invalid in order to conclude that the settlement likely disadvantaged consumers. 20 Aligning itself with the FTC s opinion in another case where the two agencies had previously been at odds, 21 DOJ argued that a reverse settlement payment is itself enough to raise a red flag, mandating further inquiry by the court, without examination of whether the underlying infringement suit had merit. Whether ultimately endorsed by the Second Circuit in Ciprofloxacin, DOJ s brief reflects an important shift in its views of reverse settlement agreements in the pharmaceutical context. This issue is likely to continue to garner attention from both the FTC and the DOJ in the form of amicus briefs and also legislative efforts under the new administration. FTC Chairman Jon Leibowitz has repeatedly called on Congress to pass legislation restricting the ability of pharmaceutical companies to make such agreements. 22 And, last March, Representative Bobby Rush of Illinois re introduced a bill, the Protecting Consumer Access to Generic Drugs Act of 1999, that would ban reverse settlement payments in pharmaceutical patent disputes. The extent to which the FTC and DOJ increase their own enforcement activities with respect to reverse settlements and other practices surrounding pharmaceutical patents as well as the involvement of private plaintiffs in this type of litigation may depend on how quickly such legislation moves through the Congress, as well as on the outcome of cases such as Ciprofloxacin. III. DOE V. ABBOTT LABORATORIES: A HIGHER STANDARD FOR PLAINTIFFS IN THE NINTH CIRCUIT AND BEYOND The Ninth Circuit s recent decision in Doe v. Abbott Laboratories represents a significant development in case law concerning unilateral conduct by holders of pharmaceutical (and 17 Cipro Brief at 6, 15. 18 Id. at 15. 19 Brief for the United States as Amicus Curiae, Joblove v. Barr Labs., Inc., No. 06 830 (May 2007), available at http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/cases/f223500/223525.htm. 20 Cipro Brief at 26. 21 Schering Plough Corp. v. FTC, 402 F.3d 1056 (11th Cir. 2005). 22 See Jon Leibowitz, Pay for Delay Settlements in the Pharmaceutical Industry: How Congress Can Stop Anticompetitive Conduct, Protect Consumers Wallets, and Help Pay for Health Care Reform (The $35 Billion Solution) (June 23, 2009), available at http://www.ftc.gov/speeches/leibowitz/090623payfordelayspeech.pdf; Jon Leibowitz, The Pill Not To Be Taken With Competition: How Collusion Is Keeping Generic Drugs Off the Shelves, Washington Post (Feb. 28, 2008), available at http://www.ftc.gov/speeches/leibowitz/080225cephalonoped.pdf. 5

other) patents. 23 Doe involved sales by Abbott of the branded drug Norvir, which is used to boost the effectiveness of protease inhibitors in treating HIV. According to plaintiffs complaint, Abbott allegedly has a monopoly in the protease inhibitor booster market by virtue of its patent on Norvir. Abbott sells Norvir to other drug manufacturers, who sell it in combination with their own, standalone protease inhibitors. In addition, Abbott markets its own protease inhibitor compound, which incorporates Norvir, in a single pill called Kaletra. The Doe plaintiffs alleged that Abbott leveraged its booster monopoly to attempt to monopolize the market in boosted protease inhibitors. Abbott allegedly did so by raising the price of Norvir from $1.71 to $8.57 per 100 mg, while keeping the price of Kaletra the same. Abbott moved to dismiss the Complaint, arguing that plaintiffs had failed to state a claim under Section 2 of the Sherman Act. On appeal, the Ninth Circuit reversed the District Court s holding that plaintiffs had articulated a valid theory of monopoly leveraging based on the prior decision of the Court of Appeals in Image Technical Services, Inc v. Eastman Kodak Co. 24 Time, and the United States Supreme Court, the Court of Appeals observed, had overtaken this case. In particular, the Court held that plaintiffs claim of monopoly leveraging was barred by the Supreme Court s recent decision in Pacific Bell Telephone Co. v. linkline Communications, Inc. 25 a case decided after the District Court s decision in Doe v. Abbott. linkline involved allegations of a price squeeze by an alleged monopolist, AT&T, in the market for high speed Internet ( DSL ) services. Plaintiffs in linkline alleged that AT&T was selling wholesale DSL transport service to competing providers at a price so high, and retail DSL service to consumers at a price so low, that AT&T s retail competitors (and wholesale customers) were unable to turn a profit. Such conduct, the Court held, is lawful where defendant has no antitrust duty to deal i.e., no independent obligation to sell to rivals and has not engaged in predatory pricing i.e., selling its products at a price that is below an appropriate measure of cost. After Trinko, the Court emphasized, it is clear that if a firm has no antitrust duty to deal with its competitors at wholesale, it certainly has no duty to deal under terms and conditions that the rivals find commercially advantageous. 26 Although plaintiffs claim in linkline had been styled as a price squeeze, rather than as an attempt at monopoly leveraging, the Ninth Circuit concluded that the conduct at issue in Doe v. Abbott was the functional equivalent. Furthermore, the Court of Appeals interpreted linkline to require separate analysis of each relevant market at issue in plaintiffs claim that Abbott had leveraged its monopoly power in standalone boosters in order to gain monopoly power in boosted protease inhibitors. Applying this analysis, the Court determined that plaintiffs failed to allege that Abbott had engaged in an anticompetitive refusal to deal in the standalone booster market (with Norvir) and also failed to allege that Abbott had engaged in 23 Doe v. Abbott Labs., 571 F.3d 930 (9th Cir. 2009). 24 125 F.3d 1195 (9th Cir. 1997). 25 129 S. Ct. 1109 (2009). 26 Id. at 1119 (citing Verizon Commc ns Inc. v. Law Offices of Curtis V. Trinko, LLP, 540 U.S. 398 (2004)). 6

below cost pricing in the boosted inhibitor market (with Kaletra). Absent such allegations, the mere fact that Abbott charged a high price for Norvir where it already had a monopoly by virtue of its patent and a low price for Kaletra where it competed with other protease inhibitors failed to state a claim under Section 2. As the Supreme Court observed in linkline, [c]utting price in order to increase business is often the very essence of competition. 27 In holding that plaintiffs claim was foreclosed by linkline, the Court of Appeals rejected the argument that its own prior decision in Image Technical had made standalone monopoly leveraging claims cognizable under Section 2. Image Technical, the Court explained, involved a refusal to deal whereas no such refusal had been alleged in Doe: Read in that context and in light of linkline, Image Technical does not save Does claim. 28 Although the Court stopped short of overruling Image Technical, the holding in Doe significantly limited the reach of that decision with respect to monopoly leveraging claims. Not only did the Court make clear that after linkline a claim of monopoly leveraging would not be recognized outside the context of a refusal to deal, but after Trinko (as reaffirmed in linkline) plaintiffs face significant hurdles in demonstrating that a monopolist s unilateral refusal to deal is actually anticompetitive. The tenuousness of monopoly leveraging theory is underscored by the Seventh Circuit s 2006 decision in Schor v. Abbott Laboratories. 29 In that case, decided prior to linkline, plaintiff had leveled virtually identical allegations of monopoly leveraging against Abbott in the same product markets at issue in Doe. Observing that Schor had alleged neither a refusal to deal nor predatory pricing, Judge Easterbrook s opinion rejected the argument that a free standing theory of monopoly leveraging was sufficient to state a claim under Section 2. The problem with monopoly leveraging as an antitrust theory, the Court held, is that the practice cannot increase a monopolist s profits. 30 The Court went on to note that in Image Technical, the Ninth Circuit had adopted just such an undisciplined monopoly leveraging principle. 31 Furthermore, the Court indicated that although it would be possible to cabin Image Technical by observing that, despite the opinion s language, the case arose from a refusal to deal as the Ninth Circuit did in Doe the Seventh Circuit s opinion was that Image Technical just got it wrong. 32 By limiting its holding in Image Technical, the Ninth Circuit avoided a direct split with the Seventh Circuit s holding in Schor and also kept the theory of monopoly leveraging alive to some extent. Nevertheless, the circumstances in which such a theory might be supported, after Doe and linkline, are extremely narrow. As a result, plaintiffs including government agencies and private parties alike who seek to challenge the unilateral pricing practices of pharmaceutical patent holders in the Ninth Circuit and elsewhere will face significantly higher standards going forward. 27 Id. at 1120. 28 571 F.3d at 935. 29 457 F.3d 608 (7th Cir. 2006). 30 Id. at 611. 31 Id. at 613. 32 Id. 7