THE ANTITRUST LEGALITY OF PHARMACEUTICAL PATENT LITIGATION SETTLEMENTS

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "THE ANTITRUST LEGALITY OF PHARMACEUTICAL PATENT LITIGATION SETTLEMENTS"

Transcription

1 THE ANTITRUST LEGALITY OF PHARMACEUTICAL PATENT LITIGATION SETTLEMENTS James F. Ponsoldt W. Hennen Ehrenclou I. INTRODUCTION Several federal courts of appeal have recently ruled on the issue of whether a pharmaceutical patent infringement settlement, pursuant to which a generic drug manufacturer agrees to forgo marketing a particular drug in return for monetary payments from a patent-holding pioneer drug manufacturer, is a violation of antitrust law. 1 These payments are termed reverse payments because, contrary to normal settlements, the plaintiff makes a lump sum payment to the defendant. 2 Reverse payments have sparked considerable academic comment and controversy. 3 Even more recently, the Federal Trade Commission Joseph Henry Lumpkin Professor of Law, University of Georgia School of Law; J.D. Harvard Law School. Associate, Weinstock & Scavo, P.C. in Atlanta, Ga. The authors express appreciation for the research assistance of Jason Fowler and Leah Akin-Acosta. 1. See Andrx Pharms., Inc. v. Elan Corp., 421 F.3d 1227 (11th Cir. 2005); Schering-Plough Corp. v. FTC, 402 F.3d 1056 (11th Cir. 2005); In re Tamoxifen Citrate Antitrust Litig., 429 F.3d 370 (2d Cir. 2005) petition for cert. filed, 2006 WL (U.S. Dec. 13, 2006) (No ); In re Cardizem CD Antitrust Litig., 332 F.3d 896 (6th Cir. 2003); Valley Drug Co. v. Geneva Pharms., Inc., 344 F.3d 1294 (11th Cir. 2003). 2. See, e.g., Schering-Plough Corp., 402 F.3d at See, e.g., Daniel A. Crane, Exit Payments in Settlement of Patent Infringement Lawsuits: Antitrust Rules and Economic Applications, 54 FLA. L. REV. 747 (2002); Herbert Hovenkamp et al., Balancing Ease and Accuracy in Assessing Pharmaceutical Exclusion Payments, 88 MINN. L. REV. 712 (2004); Keith Leffler & Cristofer Leffler, Efficiency Trade-Offs in Patent Litigation Settlements: Analysis Gone Astray?, 39 U.S.F. L. REV. 33, (2004); Carl Shapiro, Antitrust Limits to Patent Settlements, 34 RAND J. ECON. 391, 395 (2003). See also Joshua P. Davis & Steig Olson, Efforts to Delay Competition from Generic Drugs: Litigation Along a Seismic Fault Between Antitrust and Intellectual Property Law, 39 U.S.F. L. REV. 1 (2004); Stephen Roy Jenkins, Valley Drug Co. v. Geneva Pharmaceuticals, Inc.: Enlarging the Patent Exclusionary Right Through Hatch-Waxman Settlement Agreement Is Not Per Se Anticompetitive?, 6 TUL. J. TECH. & INTELL. PROP. 295, 297 (2004); Richard D. Chaves Mosier & Steven W. Ritcheson, In re Cardizem and Valley Drug: A View from the Faultline Between Patent and Antitrust in Pharmaceutical Settlements, 20 SANTA CLARA COMPUTER & HIGH TECH. L.J. 497, 500 (2004); Larissa Burford, Note, In re Cardizem & Valley Drug Co.: The Hatch-Waxman Act, Anticompetitive Actions, and Regulatory Reform, 19 BERKELEY TECH. L.J. 365 (2004). See also Editorial, Return of the Drug Company Payoffs, N.Y. TIMES, Jan. 24, 2007, at A22 (observing that the F.T.C. reported last week that after a five-year hiatus brand-name companies made 3 37

2 38 JOURNAL OF LAW, TECHNOLOGY & POLICY [Vol ( Commission ) and the Solicitor General have expressed views on the issue, in the context of the Schering-Plough litigation. 4 Patents, by definition, create a legal monopoly and an environment of exclusion in order to reward innovation. 5 However, when a patent extends beyond its scope or is used to dominate and abuse competitors, the result can be an antitrust violation. 6 The cases and academic commentary discussed in this Article necessarily raise questions about how courts should handle the intersection of patent and antitrust law and their conflicting underlying policies. These questions are important because drug manufacturers appear to use the suspect agreements in order to exclude competition and share monopoly profits, resulting in higher prices and harm to consumers. Courts have failed to develop a consistent and sensible approach to cases involving reverse payments. 7 While some courts apply traditional antitrust precedent in cases involving payments from pioneer drug manufacturers to generic drug manufacturers, other courts take a deferential, hands-off approach. 8 This deference leads to increasing manipulation of the legal system by drug manufacturers and less competition in the market. such do-not-compete settlements in fiscal year 2005 and 14 more last year... and speculating that the better approach for congress to take as it moves toward corrective legislation would be a bright line prohibition against making any payments to delay introduction of a generic drug. ). 4. The Supreme Court of the United States invited the Solicitor General to offer the views of the United States in the context of the petition for a writ of certiorari in FTC v. Schering-Plough Corp., 126 S. Ct. 544 (2005). In response, the Solicitor General advised the Court to deny certiorari, stating that although [t]he petition raises important and complex issues concerning the antitrust treatment of settlements in patent cases[,]... [it] does not present an appropriate opportunity for this Court to determine the proper standards for distinguishing legitimate patent settlements, which further the important goals of encouraging innovation and minimizing unnecessary litigation, from illegitimate settlements that impermissibly restrain trade in violation of the antitrust laws. Brief for the United States as Amicus Curiae, FTC v. Schering-Plough Corp., 126 S. Ct. 544 (2005) (No ), 2006 WL , at *8. In a separate but similar case involving reverse payments, the FTC submitted an amicus curiae brief to the Second Circuit, released on Nov. 30, 2005, urging a rehearing en banc, contending that the divided Second Circuit panel opinion, upholding the dismissal of an antitrust challenge, conflicts with basic principles of antitrust law. Brief of Amicus Curiae Federal Trade Commission in Support of Plaintiffs-Appellants Petition for Panel Rehearing and Rehearing En Banc, In re Tamoxifen Citrate Antitrust Litig., 429 F.3d 370 (2d Cir. 2005) (No ), 2005 WL See 35 U.S.C. 261 (2000); Valley Drug, 334 F.3d at 1304 ( A patent grants its owner the lawful right to exclude others. ). 6. See United States v. Singer Mfg. Co., 374 U.S. 174, 196 (1963) ( [B]eyond the limited monopoly which is granted, the arrangements by which the patent is utilized are subject to the general law. (quoting United States v. Masonite Corp., 316 U.S. 265, 277 (1942))); id. at ( [T]he possession of a valid patent or patents does not give the patentee any exemption from the provisions of the Sherman Act beyond the limits of the patent monopoly. (quoting United States v. Line Material Co., 333 U.S. 287, 308 (1948))). 7. Compare In re Cardizem CD Antitrust Litig., 332 F.3d 896, 908 (6th Cir. 2003), with Valley Drug, 344 F.3d at See, e.g., Valley Drug, 344 F.3d at ( [W]e do not think that a payment from the patentee to the alleged infringer should be automatically condemned under the antitrust laws... ).

3 No. 1] PHARMACEUTICAL PATENT LITIGATION SETTLEMENTS 39 Part II of this Article describes the regulatory framework underlying reverse payment settlement agreements and the patent infringement litigation from which they derive. Next, Part III examines cases that have addressed the antitrust issues created by reverse payments. Part IV compares academic commentary on the relevant antitrust issues. Finally, Part V assesses the most recent decisions by the Second and Eleventh Circuits. II. REGULATORY BACKGROUND The Drug Price Competition and Patent Term Restoration Act of 1984, commonly referred to as the Hatch-Waxman Act, provides a process by which generic drug manufacturers can enter the market for a particular drug without having to comply with the onerous safety and effectiveness studies normally required by law. 9 Under the Hatch- Waxman Act, a generic manufacturer may file an Abbreviated New Drug Application ( ANDA ), which incorporates the safety and effectiveness data developed and submitted by the original pioneer drug manufacturer in the relevant market. 10 If the ANDA establishes that the new drug is bioequivalent to the pioneer s drug, the Food and Drug Administration ( FDA ) may approve the drug. 11 The use of ANDAs often results in patent infringement accusations. Many times, the pioneer manufacturer, upon whose safety and effectiveness data the generic manufacturer relies, contends that the new drug infringes a valid patent held by the pioneer manufacturer. In order to protect the patent rights of the pioneer drug manufacturer, the Hatch- Waxman Act requires the ANDA to certify that: (1) no patent for the pioneer drug is listed in the records; (2) the patent listed in the records is expired; (3) the ANDA filer will seek FDA approval only after the listed patent expires; or (4) the listed patent is invalid or will not be infringed by the manufacture, use, or sale of the generic drug. 12 The most interesting cases arise when the generic manufacturer certifies that the listed patent is either invalid or will not be infringed by the generic drug (called a paragraph IV certification ). 13 An ANDA containing a paragraph IV certification has important legal ramifications. It automatically creates a cause of action for patent infringement. 14 When a generic manufacturer makes a paragraph IV certification, it must immediately notify the owner of the listed patent about its filing of 9. Drug Price Competition and Patent Term Restoration Act of 1984, Pub. L. No , 98 Stat (codified at 21 U.S.C. 355 (2000)). 10. See 21 U.S.C. 355(j)(2)(A). 11. See id. 355(j)(4). 12. Id. 355(j)(2)(A)(vii). 13. Mylan Pharms., Inc. v. Shalala, 81 F. Supp. 2d 30, 32 (D.D.C. 2000). 14. Id.

4 40 JOURNAL OF LAW, TECHNOLOGY & POLICY [Vol the ANDA and its paragraph IV assertions. 15 The pioneer manufacturer then has forty-five days to initiate a patent infringement suit. 16 If the pioneer manufacturer does not initiate suit within the allotted timeframe, the FDA is free to approve the ANDA. 17 If, however, a lawsuit is initiated, a thirty-month stay on FDA approval results. 18 The stay is lifted at the earlier of thirty months or a district court determination that the patent at issue is invalid or not infringed. 19 The court also has discretion to extend the thirty-month period if either party fails to reasonably cooperate in expediting the action. 20 The Hatch-Waxman Act further grants the first company to file a paragraph IV certification for a particular patent a 180-day period of exclusive rights to market a generic form of the pioneer drug in the event that the company either prevails in the patent infringement litigation or survives for forty-five days after notification of the pioneer manufacturer without challenge. 21 This exclusivity period gives the generic manufacturer an incentive to challenge listed patents for brand name drugs via the ANDA process in the face of potential infringement litigation costs. During the course of patent infringement actions based on paragraph IV certifications, parties sometimes decide to settle their lawsuits. The most controversial form of settlement from an antitrust perspective occurs when the pioneer manufacturer (the plaintiff in the infringement action) offers the generic manufacturer (the defendant and alleged infringer) a lump sum payment in return for an agreement by the generic manufacturer to exit the market for the drug at issue for the remaining life of the patent. 22 This form of settlement, referred to as a reverse payment or an exit payment, 23 seems anticompetitive because it results in an extension of a potentially invalid monopoly granted by the patent. The uncertainty inherent with regard to the scope and validity of patents has been termed the probabilistic nature of patent rights. 24 Keith and Cristofer Leffler, two of the many scholars who have weighed in on the reverse payment U.S.C. 355(j)(2)(B). 16. Id. 355(j)(5)(B)(iii). 17. Id. 18. Id. 19. See id. 20. See id. 21. See id. 355(j)(5)(B)(iv). 22. See generally Marc G. Schildkraut, Patent-Splitting Settlements and the Reverse Payment Fallacy, 71 ANTITRUST L.J (2004) (analyzing the reverse payment phenomenon). Problematically, in the event that the first filer settles without relinquishing its first filer status, no other drug companies can receive the 180-day exclusivity period. See Mova Pharms. Corp. v. Shalala, 140 F.3d 1060, (D.C. Cir. 1998) (eliminating the successful defense requirement). Accordingly, other generic manufacturers are deprived of the 180-day exclusivity incentive to further challenge the patent at issue. 23. See generally Crane, supra note 3 (terming such payments exit payments ). 24. Id. at 51.

5 No. 1] PHARMACEUTICAL PATENT LITIGATION SETTLEMENTS 41 issue, suggest that one should presume that Congress, by providing for this uncertainty, intended to strike an optimum balance between giving incentives for innovation ( dynamic efficiency ) and protecting consumers from monopolies ( static efficiency ): Prior to a final court resolution of the validity and scope of a patent, the uncertainty as to the exact rights possessed by a patent holder under the rules enacted by Congress implies that the expected profits from a patent are in practice necessarily less than the full monopoly profits with complete exclusion. This is because of the discount to the full monopoly profits for the likelihood that the patent is invalid or limited in scope. The presumption that Congress correctly balanced static and dynamic efficiency implies that it is this expected profit, which is less than the full monopoly profit that creates the proper and efficient innovation incentive. Similarly, the presumption that Congress correctly balanced static and dynamic efficiency implies that increases in the expected profit to a patent holder through private agreements with potential competitors creates inefficient innovation incentives. 25 Therefore, as a result of settlement, the monopoly granted by the patent (originally subject to challenge by the generic manufacturer s paragraph IV certification) extends beyond its intended scope. Rather than incur the risks of its probabilistic patent rights, the pioneer manufacturer may opt to pay the generic manufacturer to refrain from the challenge and to stay out of the market. 26 Consenting to the agreement makes economic sense to the generic manufacturer (absent the risk of antitrust penalties) if the pioneer is able to offer more money through reverse payments than the generic manufacturer would be able to earn if it manufactured and marketed the drug. 27 The pioneer manufacturer is capable of offering such a large sum of money due to the large profits it makes as a result of its monopoly on the relevant drug. 28 It makes economic sense for the pioneer manufacturer (absent the risk of antitrust penalties) to offer such a large sum of money if the money it pays by way of the settlement is less than the amount it anticipates to lose if the generic manufacturer entered the market. 29 Thus, the generic manufacturer receives a portion of the monopoly profits of the pioneer manufacturer Id. at See also Shapiro, supra note 3, at 395 (theorizing that a patent does not give the patentee the right to exclude but rather the more limited right to try to exclude by asserting its patent in court. ). 26. See Leffler & Leffler, supra note 3, at See id. 28. See id. 29. See id. 30. See id.

6 42 JOURNAL OF LAW, TECHNOLOGY & POLICY [Vol Judicial treatment of this type of settlement has ranged from per se condemnation to virtual per se legality. 31 Other courts take a middle-ofthe-road approach, applying a rule of reason analysis. 32 As explained infra in Part III.B, the Eleventh Circuit has taken the position that settlement agreements in situations involving the Hatch-Waxman Act are virtually per se legal. An examination of the various approaches to handling the patent and antitrust issues illustrates the important policy considerations that take place. III. CIRCUIT COURT DECISIONS Two federal courts of appeals, the Sixth and Eleventh Circuits, initially offered diametrically opposing views of allegedly anticompetitive reverse payment settlements of pharmaceutical patent infringement cases. A. The Sixth Circuit In In re Cardizem CD Antitrust Litigation, 33 brought before the Sixth Circuit Court of Appeals, Andrx, a generic manufacturer, filed an ANDA paragraph IV certification asserting that its formulation did not infringe a pioneer manufacturer s patent on Cardizem CD, a once-a-day release dose of the drug Cardizem. 34 In response, the pioneer manufacturer and patent holder, HMR, sued Andrx for patent infringement, triggering the thirty-month stay on FDA approval. 35 HMR and Andrx subsequently entered into an agreement under which Andrx agreed not to enter the market with its generic version of Cardizem until the earliest of: (1) Andrx obtaining a favorable, final, and unappealable determination in the patent infringement case; (2) HMR and Andrx entering into a licensing agreement; or (3) HMR entering into a licensing agreement with a third party. 36 Andrx further agreed to diligently prosecute its ANDA and to not relinquish or transfer the 180-day exclusivity period. 37 In return, HMR agreed to pay Andrx $10 million per quarter in the event that Andrx obtained FDA approval of its 31. Compare In re Cardizem CD Litig., 332 F.3d 896, 908 (6th Cir. 2003), with Valley Drug Co. v. Geneva Pharms., 344 F.3d 1294, 1310 (12th Cir. 2003) and Schering-Plough Corp. v. FTC, 402 F.3d 1056, (11th Cir. 2003). 32. In re Ciprofloxacin Hydrochloride Antitrust Litig., 261 F. Supp. 2d 188, (E.D.N.Y. 2003). Under the rule of reason, the factfinder must decide whether a challenged practice is an unreasonable restraint of trade, taking into account a variety of factors, including specific information about the relevant business, its condition before and after the restraint was imposed, and the restraint s history, nature, and effect. Id. at (quoting State Oil Co. v. Khan, 522 U.S. 3, 10 (1997)) F.3d Id. at Id. at Id. 37. See id.

7 No. 1] PHARMACEUTICAL PATENT LITIGATION SETTLEMENTS 43 generic drug. 38 The payments were scheduled to end when a final and unappealable order or judgment in the patent infringement case was rendered, or when Andrx obtained a license to market the drug. 39 As a result, Andrx agreed not to market its generic drug despite obtaining FDA approval, and HMR dropped its patent infringement action and began paying Andrx $10 million per quarter. 40 The Sixth Circuit held that the agreement between Andrx and HMR constituted a per se illegal market allocation agreement between competitors. 41 The court found that the agreement not only eliminated competition from Andrx in the market of Cardizem, but it also eliminated competition from all other potential competitors. 42 The court so held because Andrx s delayed entry into the market postponed the start of the 180-day exclusivity period, which Andrx agreed not to relinquish or transfer. 43 B. The Eleventh Circuit In contrast to the Sixth Circuit s approach, the Eleventh Circuit held similar agreements to be virtually per se lawful in Valley Drug Co. v. Geneva Pharmaceuticals, Inc. 44 and Schering-Plough v. FTC. 45 More recently, however, the Eleventh Circuit appears to have clarified its views, moving somewhat closer to the Sixth Circuit, in Andrx Pharmaceuticals, Inc. v. Elan Corp Valley Drug In Valley Drug, a consolidation of several antitrust lawsuits against Abbott Laboratories ( Abbott ), Geneva Pharmaceuticals ( Geneva ), and Zenith Goldline Pharmaceuticals ( Zenith ), the Eleventh Circuit ruled that agreements between Abbott, the pioneer manufacturer and holder of the patent for the drug Hytrin (made of the compound terazosin hydrochloride), and Zenith and Geneva, generic manufacturers, in the context of patent litigation, were not per se antitrust violations. 47 Valley Drug involved ANDA filings based on Hytrin by Zenith and Geneva and subsequent patent infringement suits by Abbott. 48 In the 38. See id. 39. See id. at 903 n Id. 41. Id. at Id. at Id F.3d 1294 (11th Cir. 2005) F.3d 1056 (11th Cir. 2005) F.3d 1227, 1236 (11th Cir. 2005). 47. Valley Drug, 344 F.3d at Id. at 1296.

8 44 JOURNAL OF LAW, TECHNOLOGY & POLICY [Vol course of the patent infringement litigation between Abbott and Geneva, Geneva admitted infringement [of the patent] but contested the patent s validity. 49 Under the allegedly anticompetitive settlement agreement, Geneva agreed to refrain from selling or distributing any form of terozosin hydrochloride until: (1) Abbott s patent expired; (2) another entity introduced a generic form of the drug; or (3) either Geneva obtained a final, unappealable judgment that its generic version for which it had filed an ANDA did not infringe Abbott s patent or a court found Abbott s patent invalid. 50 Geneva also agreed not to transfer or relinquish its rights as first ANDA filer to the 180-day exclusivity period. 51 In return, Abbot agreed to pay Geneva $4.5 million each month until either another generic manufacturer brought a terazosin hydrochloride drug into the market or Abbott won a favorable decision in the district court on its patent infringement claim against Geneva. 52 Thus, litigation of the patent validity issue continued in the interim, while Abbott paid Geneva $4.5 million per month. Ultimately, the district court held Abbott s patent invalid, the Eleventh Circuit affirmed, 53 and the Supreme Court denied certiorari. 54 The parties had by this time already terminated their agreement, however, as a result of an FTC investigation. 55 The agreement between Abbott and Zenith consisted of Zenith acknowledging the validity of Abbott s patent claims and agreeing not to sell or distribute any terazosin hydrochloride drug until Abbott s patent expired or another generic manufacturer entered the market. 56 In return, Abbott agreed to pay Zenith $3 million up front, $3 million after three months, and $6 million every three months thereafter for two years. 57 In the antitrust litigation, brought by wholesale and retail drug companies, the district court found that the agreements in question violated 1 of the Sherman Act, 58 characterizing the settlements as horizontal market allocation agreements. 59 The Eleventh Circuit reversed, permitting the settlement agreement because it was no broader than the potential exclusionary effects of the patent. 60 The court stated, [u]nlike some kinds of agreement that are per se illegal whether engaged in by patentees or anyone else, such as tying or price fixing, the 49. Id. at Id. at Id. 52. Id. 53. Abbott Labs. v. Geneva Pharms., Inc., 182 F.3d 1315, 1319 (Fed. Cir. 1999). 54. Abbott Labs. v. Geneva Pharms., Inc., 528 U.S (2000). 55. In re Abbott Labs., No. C-3925, 2000 WL (F.T.C. May 22, 2000). 56. Valley Drug, 344 F.3d at Id. 58. Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. 1 (2000). 59. See In re Terazosin Hydrochloride Antitrust Litig., 164 F. Supp. 2d 1340, 1354 (S.D. Fla. 2000). 60. Valley Drug, 344 F.3d at 1305.

9 No. 1] PHARMACEUTICAL PATENT LITIGATION SETTLEMENTS 45 exclusion of infringing competition is the essence of the patent grant. 61 According to the Eleventh Circuit, at the time the agreements were entered into, the patent had not been invalidated, so exclusion of competitors merely represented an exercise of the pioneer manufacturer s patent rights. 62 Consequently, the court held that the case would be remanded for appropriate antitrust analysis. 63 The court suggested that on remand the district court apply neither a rule of reason analysis nor a per se rule. 64 Rather, the court proposed a consideration of the scope of the exclusionary potential of the patent, the extent to which the provisions of the [a]greements exceed that scope, and the anticompetitive effects thereof. 65 Thus, the appropriate analysis on remand will likely require an identification of the protection afforded by the patents and the relevant law and consideration of the extent to which the [a]greements reflect a reasonable implementation of these. 66 On remand, the district court held that the component of the agreement that guaranteed that Geneva would not enter the Hytrin market even if the district court decided against Abbott in the patent litigation (i.e., when the district court found Abbott s patent to be invalid, but the settlement agreement provided that Geneva would stay out of the market until Geneva obtained a final, unappealable judgment), was not a reasonable implementation of the protection afforded by the patent. 67 The court applied the per se rule of illegality, concluding that there is simply no escaping the conclusion that the [a]greement... was, at its core, a horizontal agreement to eliminate competition in the domestic market for terazosin hydrochloride drugs, a classic example of an output-reducing, naked restraint on trade that qualifies for per se treatment. 68 In so holding, the court stressed the fact that the agreement also resulted in delaying the entry of other generic competitors, that, under the Hatch-Waxman Act, could not enter the market until 180 days after Geneva began marketing its generic drug Schering-Plough These issues came before the Eleventh Circuit more recently in Schering-Plough Corp. v. FTC. 70 The underlying facts of the case suggest 61. Id. at Id. 63. Id. 64. Id. at Id. at Id. (citation omitted). 67. See In re Terazosin Hydrochloride Antitrust Litig., 352 F. Supp. 2d 1279, 1319 (S.D. Fla. 2005). 68. Id. at 1315 (quoting In re Cardizem CD Antitrust Litig., 332 F.3d 896, 908 (6th Cir. 2003)). 69. Id F.3d 1056 (11th Cir. 2005), cert. denied, 126 S. Ct (2006).

10 46 JOURNAL OF LAW, TECHNOLOGY & POLICY [Vol that pharmaceutical companies may be adapting their settlement practices in an attempt to avoid potential antitrust violations. In Schering-Plough, the Federal Trade Commission challenged payments in the context of patent litigation settlements from Schering-Plough, Inc. ( Schering ) to Upsher-Smith Laboratories ( Upsher ) and ESI Lederle, Inc. ( ESI ). 71 Upsher and ESI sought FDA approval under paragraph IV ANDA certifications to market generic versions of K-Dur 20, a potassium chloride drug. 72 Schering sued for patent infringement and, before trial, the parties settled. 73 Pursuant to the settlement, Schering agreed to make payments to Upsher totaling over $60 million, and Upsher agreed not to enter the market for K-Dur 20 for over three years. 74 Upsher also granted Schering licensing rights for the global market outside of North America for Upsher s drug Niacor, a cholesterol-reducing niacin product. 75 Schering made a similar agreement with ESI under which Schering paid $10 million to ESI, and ESI agreed not to enter the K-Dur 20 market for a period of time. 76 The Commission reversed the administrative law judge s initial decision to dismiss the complaint, finding that, while the reverse payments were not per se illegal, they constituted a quid pro quo for an agreement to delay entry in the market. 77 The Commission rejected the defense that the $60 million payment to Upsher was for licenses because the payment substantially exceeded Schering s reasonable expectation of the value of the licenses. 78 The Eleventh Circuit reversed the opinion of the Commission, holding that the evidence did not support the conclusion that the settlement agreements unreasonably restrained competition beyond the exclusionary scope of the patent. 79 Citing Valley Drug, the court ruled that the proper analysis of antitrust liability requires an examination of: (1) the scope of the exclusionary potential of the patent; (2) the extent to which the agreements exceed that scope; and (3) the resulting anticompetitive effects. 80 Relying heavily on the policies of protecting patent rights and encouraging settlements, the court vacated the Commission s ruling and found the agreements to be lawful. 81 The court concluded that: [g]iven the costs of lawsuits to the parties, the public problems associated with overcrowded court dockets, and the correlative 71. Id. at Id. at Id. at Id. 75. Id. at Id. at Id. at Id. 79. Id. at Id. at Id. at 1076.

11 No. 1] PHARMACEUTICAL PATENT LITIGATION SETTLEMENTS 47 public and private benefits of settlements, we fear and reject a rule of law that would automatically invalidate any agreement where a patent-holding pharmaceutical manufacturer settles an infringement case by negotiating the generic s entry date, and, in an ancillary transaction, pays for other products licensed by the generic. 82 On August 29, 2005, the Commission petitioned the Supreme Court of the United States for a writ of certiorari. 83 After receiving briefs from the Commission and Schering, the Supreme Court asked the Solicitor General to submit an amicus brief on behalf of the United States. 84 In response, the Solicitor General recommended that the Court deny certiorari. 85 This response sparked an unusual disagreement between the Commission and the Solicitor General. In fact, the Commission subsequently filed a supplemental brief stating the economic impact of the ruling below on consumers of prescription drugs including the states is staggering.... Billions of dollars in added prescription drug costs annually are at stake. The decision below has opened a Pandora s box of anticompetitive settlements between brands and generic competitors. 86 The FTC also indicated that: although there was a five-year lull in pay-offs to potential competitors after the Commission commenced enforcement actions aimed at exclusion-payment settlements, pharmaceutical companies have once again started entering into settlement agreements that include both compensation in various forms to generic challengers and restrictions on generic market entry. Harm is very likely ongoing each day that the decision below prevails. 87 On June 26, 2006, the Supreme Court denied the Commission s petition for certiorari. 88 Thereafter, on June 27, 2006, Senators Herb Kohl (D-WI), Patrick Leahy (D-VT), Chuck Grassley (R-IA), and Charles Schumer (D-NY) proposed legislation to prohibit brand name pharmaceutical drug manufacturers from paying generic drug manufacturers cash settlements to keep generic drugs off the market. 89 Senator Leahy commented: It is stunning that the U.S. Supreme Court would refuse a request by the Federal Trade Commission to hear a case so important to 82. Id. 83. Petition for a Writ of Certiorari at 1, FTC v. Schering-Plough Corp., 126 S. Ct (2006) (No ), 2005 WL Brief for the United States as Amicus Curiae at 1, Schering-Plough Corp., 126 S. Ct (No ), 2006 WL Id. 86. Supplemental Brief for the Petitioner at 2, Schering-Plough Corp., 126 S. Ct (No ), 2006 WL Id. at Schering-Plough Corp., 126 S. Ct S. 3582, 109th Cong. (2006).

12 48 JOURNAL OF LAW, TECHNOLOGY & POLICY [Vol senior citizens and others needing lower-cost generic medicines. It is also regrettable that the Administration has sided with big drug companies over seniors and the FTC in pushing for this outcome. 90 Schering-Plough and its fallout demonstrate that lawmakers and courts continue to grapple with the concerns that arise in connection with reverse settlement payments. Accordingly, the debate over the proper judicial and congressional action with regard to pharmaceutical drug patent issues and the appropriate reach of antitrust enforcement has increased in significance. 3. Andrx Pharmaceuticals In Andrx Pharmaceuticals, Inc. v. Elan Corp., 91 the Eleventh Circuit reviewed the dismissal of claims brought by a generic manufacturer, Andrx Pharmaceuticals, Inc. ( Andrx ), alleging antitrust violations by Elan Corp. ( Elan ) in Elan s prior patent litigation settlement agreement with another potential generic competitor, SkyePharma. 92 Elan owned a patent that gave it the exclusive right to manufacture and sell in the United States a controlled-release naproxen medication. 93 When SkyePharma filed its ANDA application to manufacture and sell a generic version, it also made a paragraph IV certification, leading to Elan s initiation of patent infringement litigation against it, thereby triggering a 30-month stay on FDA approval. 94 This litigation was settled by entering into an agreement in which SkyePharma admitted to infringing the patent in exchange for a license from Elan to manufacture the generic version. 95 Because SkyePharma was the first ANDA applicant, the license agreement gave it the 180-day exclusive marketing period. 96 Andrx also sought to introduce a generic naproxen to the market, and Elan, in turn, initiated patent infringement proceedings against it. 97 As a result, Andrx brought a complaint against Elan, making two claims against it: (1) the settlement agreement between Elan and SkyePharma had the effect of preventing any generic competition in the controlled release naproxen market and constituted a conspiracy to restrain trade, in violation of 1 2 of the Sherman Act; 98 and (2) Elan s patent infringement proceedings were really sham litigation[s] with the true 90. Press Release, Kohl, Leahy, Grassley, and Schumer Introduce Bill to Stop Payoffs that Delay Generic Drugs (June 26, 2006), F.3d 1227 (11th Cir. 2005). 92. Id. at Id. at Id; 21 U.S.C. 355(j)(5)(B)(iii) (2000). 95. Andrx Pharmaceuticals, Inc., 421 F.3d at Id. 97. Id. 98. Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. 1 2 (2000).

13 No. 1] PHARMACEUTICAL PATENT LITIGATION SETTLEMENTS 49 intent of invoking the thirty-month rule and preventing Andrx s entrance into the market for a potential of two and a half more years. 99 The Eleventh Circuit found that the district court had properly dismissed the sham litigation claim for several reasons. 100 First, it held that Elan s initiation of patent infringement proceedings was not objectively baseless. 101 The court held that Elan was afforded immunity from antitrust liability by virtue of the Noerr-Pennington doctrine, which immunizes such First Amendment activities as petitioning the government for redress of grievances. 102 Next, the court reversed the district court s finding that Andrx had not sufficiently pled an antitrust violation in relation to the licensing agreement that Elan signed with SkyePharma to settle the patent infringement litigation. 103 The court concluded that the notice pleading standard of Federal Rule of Civil Procedure 8(a) 104 applied, and that given the fact-intensive nature of antitrust cases, dismissals on the pleadings were particularly disfavored, absent some doctrine immunizing the conduct from antitrust liability. 105 In citing the analysis established by Valley Drug, the court first found that, based on its complaint, Andrx s allegations established the scope of the patent. 106 Second, the court determined that Andrx s allegation that SkyePharma agreed to refrain from ever marketing a generic controlled release naproxen, after having been granted the license, would, if proven, exceed the scope of exclusion intended by the Elan patent by preventing any generic competitors from entering the market. 107 Finally, Andrx s allegations that depriving the public of a less expensive generic product and foreclosing entry by competitors into the controlled-release naproxen market, if proven, could demonstrate anticompetitive effects. 108 The court thus concluded that Andrx sufficiently pled facts for a claim based on 1 of the Sherman Act. 109 Finally, with regard to Andrx s claim based on 2 of the Sherman Act, the court concluded that Andrx had stated a claim, showing specific intent to bring about a monopoly and, given Elan s market power, a dangerous probability of success. 110 The court then remanded the case back to the district court for further proceedings Andrx Pharmaceuticals, Inc., 421 F.3d at Id. at Id Id Id Fed. R. Civ. P. 8(a) Andrx Pharmaceuticals, Inc., 421 F.3d at (quoting Covad Commc ns Co. v. BellSouth Corp., 299 F.3d 1272, 1279 (11th Cir. 2002), vacated on other grounds, 540 U.S (2004)) Id. at Id Id Id Id. at Id. at 1237.

14 50 JOURNAL OF LAW, TECHNOLOGY & POLICY [Vol IV. RECONCILING POLICY CONFLICTS A. Policy Considerations The important antitrust and patent issues in the cases described supra have given rise to much scholarly and judicial debate. 112 At least three policies come into conflict when one analyzes these cases. First, the law encourages innovation through the patent laws. 113 Some scholars suggest that if courts become overly zealous when enforcing antitrust laws and protecting consumer welfare, those courts could discourage innovation and product research and development because companies will be unable to fully realize the profits they could gain under a system that allows reverse payments. 114 Second, the law also encourages settlement of lawsuits in order to promote judicial economy. 115 If courts regularly permit reverse payments, judicial economy may be fostered because no infringement case will occur, thereby conserving judicial resources. 116 Third, however, the law also encourages efficiency in the marketplace by prohibiting market allocation and price fixing. 117 When a patentee, who bears the burden of proving that an alleged infringer is in violation of its patent, pays the alleged infringer not to market the product, potential consumer benefits are denied. 118 These policies must be considered within the framework of traditional antitrust analysis, which allows courts to further the policies of market efficiency and consumer welfare without ignoring competing policies. Section 1 of the Sherman Act provides that [e]very contract, combination in the form of trust or otherwise, or conspiracy, in restraint of trade or commerce among the several states, or with foreign nations, is declared to be illegal. 119 Most restraints are evaluated using the rule of reason. 120 Sometimes, however, restraints of trade are deemed unlawful per se because they have such predictable and pernicious anticompetitive effect, and such limited potential for procompetitive benefit. 121 For example, when competitors agree to geographically divide a market, the agreement is per se illegal. 122 Scholarly debate has centered around whether reverse payments should be considered per se 112. See, e.g., Crane, supra note 3, at See id. at Id. at Id. at Id. at Id. at See id. at Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. 1 (2000) See supra note Id. (citing N. Pac. R.R. v. United States, 356 U.S. 1, 5 (1958)) See Palmer v. BRG of Ga., Inc., 498 U.S. 46, 49 (1990). The lead author of this Article was co-counsel for plaintiffs/petitioners in Palmer.

15 No. 1] PHARMACEUTICAL PATENT LITIGATION SETTLEMENTS 51 illegal under antitrust laws, and, if not, what sort of analysis should take place. B. The Antitrust-Defendant-Friendly Approach Some scholars and judges advocate an approach that would generally permit reverse payments in patent litigation. 123 This is the approach generally accepted by the Eleventh Circuit. 124 Under this theory, payments from pioneer manufacturers to generic manufacturers are justified as ancillary to the procompetitive act of settling a patent dispute. 125 Thus, proponents of this approach argue that [t]oo great a willingness to find antitrust violations in settlement arrangements would significantly inhibit settlements of many types of cases at real cost to the administration of justice, with little likelihood of any countervailing benefit to the public interest. 126 In addition, if pioneer and generic manufacturers are not allowed to settle patent cases in this context, the incentives to innovate might be reduced as a result of the lower expected payoff from invention. However, with regard to the rationale that this will promote settlements, in many cases, at least under the analysis suggested by the Eleventh Circuit, the merits of the patent litigation suits are litigated when the agreement is challenged on antitrust grounds anyway, even if by the wrong plaintiff (i.e., the antitrust plaintiff rather than the more knowledgeable patent infringement plaintiff). 127 Accordingly, the benefit to society resulting from the settlement may be outweighed by the cost of protracted antitrust litigation, during which the validity of the patent represents part of a court s analysis. Furthermore, in the event that a patent settlement agreement is found to be anticompetitive after an antitrust challenge and appeal, the harm suffered by the consumer has already occurred and cannot be rectified by payment of damages to the antitrust plaintiff. 128 This factor is especially significant given the importance of affordable drugs for many consumers See, e.g., Schildkraut, supra note 22 at ; Robert D. Willig & John P. Bigelow, Antitrust Policy Towards Agreements That Settle Patent Litigation, 2004 ANTITRUST BULL. 655, Schering-Plough Corp. v. FTC, 402 F.3d 1056, (11th Cir. 2005) See id. at Harry M. Reasoner & Scott J. Atlas, The Settlement of Litigation As a Ground for Antitrust Liability, 50 ANTITRUST L.J. 115, 126 (1981) See Leffler & Leffler, supra note 3, at ( [A]ntitrust plaintiffs taking on the burden of demonstrating invalidity have to start from scratch and re-learn much of what the generic challenger likely knew before accepting the settlement. In addition, as antitrust plaintiffs, purchasers are likely to be at an information disadvantage compared to the generic challenger because the generic challenger is in the business of researching pharmaceuticals, understanding pharmaceutical patents, and assessing patent validity. ) See id. at 55. See, e.g., Schering-Plough, 402 F.3d at 1059 (regarding an allegedly anticompetitive agreement that was entered into in 1997, the final adjudication for which occurred in 2005).

16 52 JOURNAL OF LAW, TECHNOLOGY & POLICY [Vol With regard to the policy of promoting innovation through patent rights, it is clear that patent rights only extend so far as a court finds them valid and encompassing. While the possibility of monopoly profits flowing from a valid patent encourages innovation, companies and individuals engaging in research, development, and other innovative activities should keep in mind ex ante that patent laws do not give them absolute monopolies. To the extent that the scope of a patent is enlarged to cover more than a court would determine, it extends beyond the reach that Congress intended. 129 C. The Antitrust-Plaintiff-Friendly Approach A more antitrust-plaintiff-friendly position is held by judges and scholars who suggest that a per se rule of presumptive illegality is a better approach. 130 They argue that because the pioneer manufacturer is willing to pay a large sum of money for the generic manufacturer to stay out of the market, there is some uncertainty as to the scope or validity of the patent. 131 Although the patentee might offer a settlement in order to avoid high litigation costs, the settlements at issue in Valley Drug and other cases far exceed those costs. 132 The inflated value of payments can be attributed to the probability that the patent will be held invalid and a generic product will be allowed to enter the market. 133 Thus, if the patentee is certain to win its infringement suit, it will not pay the generic manufacturer more than the cost of litigation to stay out of the market. 134 However, if the patentee is only 75% sure that it will win the case, it will be willing to pay the generic manufacturer up to 25% of the value of its monopoly, because the result of the settlement would preserve its monopoly. 135 While this seems facially anticompetitive, antitrust defendants regularly assert procompetitive justifications for reverse payments. 136 That being the case, do reverse settlement payments constitute restraints of trade that have such predictable and pernicious anticompetitive effects warranting application of the per se rule of illegality? 129. See Leffler & Leffler, supra note 3, at See, e.g., id. at See Symposium, Anticompetitive Settlement of Intellectual Property Disputes, 87 MINN. L. REV. 1719, (2003) See In re Cardizem CD Antitrust Litig., 332 F.3d 896, 904 (6th Cir. 2003); Valley Drug Co. v. Geneva Pharms., 344 F.3d 1294, 1300 (11th Cir. 2003). See generally, Schering-Plough, 402 F.3d See In re Cardizem, 332 F.3d at See Symposium., supra note 131, at Id Thomas F. Cotter, Refining the Presumptive Illegality Approach to Settlements of Patent Disputes Involving Reverse Payments: A Commentary on Hovenkap, Janis & Lemley, 87 MINN. L. REV. 1789, (2003) [hereinafter Cotter, Refining].

17 No. 1] PHARMACEUTICAL PATENT LITIGATION SETTLEMENTS 53 D. Per Se Rule Applicability to Reverse Payments Courts have generally been willing to apply a per se rule of illegality when certain factors are present. 137 The practice in question must facially appear to be a practice that would always or almost always tend to restrict competition and decrease output. 138 These practices include, for example, price fixing, horizontal output restraints, and market-allocation agreements. 139 A per se rule of illegality is the appropriate mode of analysis when experience with a particular kind of restraint enables the court to predict with confidence that the rule of reason will condemn it. 140 It appears that reverse-payment settlements probably should not categorically fall under the per se rule. Although some courts have categorized reverse payments as market-allocation agreements (i.e., the pioneer manufacturer and the generic manufacturer agree that the product market will be allocated to the pioneer manufacturer in exchange for money), 141 sometimes the agreements are justified and could even result in an increase in overall competition. 142 This is the case if the plaintiff takes the increased monopoly profits resulting from the settlement, the defendant takes the settlement proceeds, and they each invest these funds in research and development. In this event, society benefits because, theoretically, each company will develop new drugs and medicines. The result would be more drugs and more competition, resulting in lower costs to consumers. 143 Notwithstanding the potential benefits that reverse payments may provide to society, the Hatch-Waxman Act includes provisions that encourage anticompetitive activity in patent litigation. 144 For example, 137. See In re Cardizem, 332 F.3d at Broad. Music, Inc. v. Columbia Broad. Sys. Inc., 441 U.S. 1, (1979) See id Arizona v. Maricopa County Med. Soc y, 457 U.S. 332, 344 (1982) (holding that it is the court s experience with the type of restraint (e.g., market-allocation) that is relevant in applying the per se rule, not the particular industry at issue or the specific facts of the case). As a result, antitrust defendants may not rely on the defense that courts have insufficient experience in the pharmaceutical industry or in cases involving alleged Hatch-Waxman Act infringements to apply the per se rule See Schering-Plough v. FTC, 402 F.3d 1056, 1068 (11th Cir. 2003); In re Ciprofloxacin Hydrochloride Antitrust Litig., 261 F. Supp. 2d 188, (E.D.N.Y. 2003) See generally Thomas F. Cotter, Antitrust Implications of Patent Settlements Involving Reverse Payments: Defending a Rebuttable Presumption of Illegality in Light of Some Recent Scholarship, 71 ANTITRUST L.J (2004) [hereinafter Cotter, Antitrust] This conclusion depends on some assumptions. One concerns the extent to which drug companies actually invest money gained as a result of settling Hatch-Waxman Act patent infringement lawsuits in research and development. This is an empirical question, for which no data exist. Another assumption here concerns one s views on the importance and legitimacy of patent incentives and the need to preserve the integrity of the patent system. See Josh Lerner, 150 Years of Patent Protection, 92 AM. ECON. REV. 221 (2002) (finding that strengthening a patent system did not significantly impact inventions); Mariko Sakakibara & Lee Branstetter, Do Stronger Patents Induce More Innovation? Evidence from the 1988 Japanese Patent Reform Laws, 32 RAND J. ECON. 77 (2001) (finding only a very small effect on research and development activity from expanding the scope of Japanese patents) See 21 U.S.C. 355 (2006).

18 54 JOURNAL OF LAW, TECHNOLOGY & POLICY [Vol the ANDA filer must certify that its product either will not infringe the patent on which it relies for safety and efficiency data or that the patent holder s patent is invalid. 145 This suggests that the patent infringement case might not be as meritorious as patent infringement cases in other contexts. In addition, the patent holder is encouraged to sue within the forty-five-day period because doing so automatically stays any entry into the market for thirty months. 146 This thirty-month period gives the patent holder time to evaluate the strength of its patent in the face of the ANDA s challenge and weigh the costs and benefits of continuing the infringement litigation. Given the high costs of patent litigation and the uncertainty involved, the result of this analysis might often be a decision to offer settlement. 147 Therefore, the scheme presented by the Hatch- Waxman Act gives special incentives for parties to collude in order to share monopoly rents. 148 Because of the incentives for drug manufacturers engaged in a patent infringement suit to agree to an anticompetitive reverse-payment settlement, some scholars argue that these types of agreements should almost never be upheld when subject to antitrust challenge. 149 For example, one group of analysts suggests that reverse-payment settlements should only be permitted to the extent that they reflect the parties actual avoided litigation costs. 150 This group reasons that payments in excess of avoided litigation costs indicate that the patent owner enjoys a better outcome by sharing monopoly profits than it would get through litigation. 151 However, this approach fails to adequately consider other factors that are relevant when negotiating settlements, such as risk aversion and informational asymmetries. 152 The best argument against application of the per se rule is spelled out in In re Ciprofloxacin Hydrochloride Antitrust Litig. ( In re Cirpo ), 153 a case in which purchasers of an antibiotic drug and advocacy groups sued pioneer and generic drug manufacturers for violation of antitrust laws. 154 Pioneer drug manufacturer Bayer held a patent for a particular drug, and generic drug manufacturer Barr filed an ANDA and accompanying paragraph IV certification alleging that Bayer s patent was invalid and unenforceable. 155 Bayer subsequently commenced a 145. See generally id See generally id This is especially true to the extent that the patent holder is risk averse It has been suggested that these perverse [statutory] incentives should be removed from patent laws in order to reduce the likelihood that drug manufacturers will come to anticompetitive settlement agreements. See, e.g., Cotter, Antitrust, supra note 142, at See Symposium, supra note 131, at Id. at Id. at Id. at F. Supp. 2d 188 (E.D.N.Y 2003) Id. at Id. at 194.

Pharmaceutical Patent Settlement Cases: Mixed Signals for Settling Patent Litigation

Pharmaceutical Patent Settlement Cases: Mixed Signals for Settling Patent Litigation By Margaret J. Simpson Tel: 312 923-2857 Fax: 312 840-7257 E-mail: msimpson@jenner.com The following article originally appeared in the Spring 2004 issue of the Illinois State Bar Association s Antitrust

More information

Pay-for-Delay Settlements: Antitrust Violation or Proper Exercise of Pharmaceutical Patent Rights?

Pay-for-Delay Settlements: Antitrust Violation or Proper Exercise of Pharmaceutical Patent Rights? Pay-for-Delay Settlements: Antitrust Violation or Proper Exercise of Pharmaceutical Patent Rights? By Kendyl Hanks, Sarah Jacobson, Kyle Musgrove, and Michael Shen In recent years, there has been a surge

More information

PENDING LEGISLATION REGULATING PATENT INFRINGEMENT SETTLEMENTS

PENDING LEGISLATION REGULATING PATENT INFRINGEMENT SETTLEMENTS PENDING LEGISLATION REGULATING PATENT INFRINGEMENT SETTLEMENTS By Edward W. Correia* A number of bills have been introduced in the United States Congress this year that are intended to eliminate perceived

More information

Stuck in Neutral: The Future of Reverse Payments Agreements in Hatch-Waxman Litigation

Stuck in Neutral: The Future of Reverse Payments Agreements in Hatch-Waxman Litigation Stuck in Neutral: The Future of Reverse Payments Agreements in Hatch-Waxman Litigation Alex E. Korona I. Introduction... 202 II. The Hatch-Waxman Act... 203 III. Settlement Agreements and Reverse Payments...

More information

Increased Scrutiny of Reverse Payment Settlements: Recent Cases in E.D. of PA and 2nd Circuit Suggest Change May Be Ahead for Pharma Clients

Increased Scrutiny of Reverse Payment Settlements: Recent Cases in E.D. of PA and 2nd Circuit Suggest Change May Be Ahead for Pharma Clients Increased Scrutiny of Reverse Payment Settlements: Recent Cases in E.D. of PA and 2nd Circuit Suggest Change May Be Ahead for Pharma Clients By Francis P. Newell and Jonathan M. Grossman Special to the

More information

Reverse Payment Settlements In Pharma Industry: Revisited

Reverse Payment Settlements In Pharma Industry: Revisited Portfolio Media. Inc. 860 Broadway, 6th Floor New York, NY 10003 www.law360.com Phone: +1 646 783 7100 Fax: +1 646 783 7161 customerservice@law360.com Reverse Payment Settlements In Pharma Industry: Revisited

More information

In Re Cardizem and Valley Drug: A View from the Faultline between Patent and Antitrust in Pharmaceutical Settlements

In Re Cardizem and Valley Drug: A View from the Faultline between Patent and Antitrust in Pharmaceutical Settlements Santa Clara High Technology Law Journal Volume 20 Issue 2 Article 8 January 2004 In Re Cardizem and Valley Drug: A View from the Faultline between Patent and Antitrust in Pharmaceutical Settlements Richard

More information

In The Supreme Court of the United States

In The Supreme Court of the United States No. 10-762 ================================================================ In The Supreme Court of the United States --------------------------------- --------------------------------- LOUISIANA WHOLESALE

More information

THE JOHN MARSHALL REVIEW OF INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY LAW

THE JOHN MARSHALL REVIEW OF INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY LAW THE JOHN MARSHALL REVIEW OF INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY LAW THE PRESERVE ACCESS TO AFFORDABLE GENERICS ACT: WILL CONGRESS'S RESPONSE TO REVERSE PAYMENT PATENT SETTLEMENTS ENHANCE COMPETITION IN THE PHARMACEUTICAL

More information

LOUISIANA WHOLESALE DRUG CO., INC., et al., Respondents. UPSHER-SMITH LABORATORIES, INC., Petitioner, v.

LOUISIANA WHOLESALE DRUG CO., INC., et al., Respondents. UPSHER-SMITH LABORATORIES, INC., Petitioner, v. Nos. 12-245, 12-265 In the Supreme Court of the United States MERCK & CO., INC., v. Petitioner, LOUISIANA WHOLESALE DRUG CO., INC., et al., Respondents. UPSHER-SMITH LABORATORIES, INC., Petitioner, v.

More information

From PLI s Program New Strategies Arising from the Hatch-Waxman Amendments #4888

From PLI s Program New Strategies Arising from the Hatch-Waxman Amendments #4888 From PLI s Program New Strategies Arising from the Hatch-Waxman Amendments #4888 New Strategies Arising From the Hatch-Waxman Amendments Practicing Law Institute Telephone Briefing May 12, 2004 I. INTRODUCTION

More information

Pharmaceutical Patent Litigation Settlements: Implications for Competition and Innovation

Pharmaceutical Patent Litigation Settlements: Implications for Competition and Innovation : Implications for Competition and Innovation John R. Thomas Visiting Scholar January 27, 2012 CRS Report for Congress Prepared for Members and Committees of Congress Congressional Research Service 7-5700

More information

In re Cardizem & Valley Drug Co.: The Hatch- Waxman Act, Anticompetitive Action, and Regulatory Reform

In re Cardizem & Valley Drug Co.: The Hatch- Waxman Act, Anticompetitive Action, and Regulatory Reform Berkeley Technology Law Journal Volume 19 Issue 1 Article 20 January 2004 In re Cardizem & Valley Drug Co.: The Hatch- Waxman Act, Anticompetitive Action, and Regulatory Reform Larissa Burford Follow this

More information

15 Hous. J. Health L. & Policy 281 Copyright 2015 Tracey Toll Houston Journal of Health Law & Policy

15 Hous. J. Health L. & Policy 281 Copyright 2015 Tracey Toll Houston Journal of Health Law & Policy 15 Hous. J. Health L. & Policy 281 Copyright 2015 Tracey Toll Houston Journal of Health Law & Policy PHARMACEUTICAL REVERSE PAYMENT SETTLEMENT AGREEMENTS AND A PROPOSAL FOR CLARIFYING THE APPLICATION OF

More information

Schering-Plough and in Re Tamoxifen: Lawful Reverse Payments in the Hatch-Waxman Context

Schering-Plough and in Re Tamoxifen: Lawful Reverse Payments in the Hatch-Waxman Context Berkeley Technology Law Journal Volume 22 Issue 1 Article 3 January 2007 Schering-Plough and in Re Tamoxifen: Lawful Reverse Payments in the Hatch-Waxman Context Jeff Thomas Follow this and additional

More information

Pharmaceutical Product Improvements and Life Cycle Management Antitrust Pitfalls 1

Pharmaceutical Product Improvements and Life Cycle Management Antitrust Pitfalls 1 Pharmaceutical Product Improvements and Life Cycle Management Antitrust Pitfalls 1 The terms product switching, product hopping and line extension are often used to describe the strategy of protecting

More information

REVERSE PAYMENTS: WHEN THE FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION CAN ATTACK THE VALIDITY OF UNDERLYING PATENTS

REVERSE PAYMENTS: WHEN THE FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION CAN ATTACK THE VALIDITY OF UNDERLYING PATENTS REVERSE PAYMENTS: WHEN THE FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION CAN ATTACK THE VALIDITY OF UNDERLYING PATENTS INTRODUCTION Settlements between brand-name and generic pharmaceutical companies that delay generic entry

More information

Antitrust and Intellectual Property: Recent Developments in the Pharmaceuticals Sector

Antitrust and Intellectual Property: Recent Developments in the Pharmaceuticals Sector September 2009 (Release 2) Antitrust and Intellectual Property: Recent Developments in the Pharmaceuticals Sector Aidan Synnott & William Michael Paul, Weiss, Rifkind, Wharton & Garrison LLP www.competitionpolicyinternational.com

More information

15.3a1. Entry-restrictive Agreements; Exclusion or Reverse Payments

15.3a1. Entry-restrictive Agreements; Exclusion or Reverse Payments Excerpted from Herbert Hovenkamp et al., IP and Antitrust (2013 Supplement) (forthcoming) 15.3a1. Entry-restrictive Agreements; Exclusion or Reverse Payments Insofar as antitrust is concerned, among the

More information

In re K-Dur Antitrust Litigation: Reopening the Door for Pharmaceutical Competition

In re K-Dur Antitrust Litigation: Reopening the Door for Pharmaceutical Competition Northwestern Journal of Technology and Intellectual Property Volume 12 Issue 1 Article 3 2014 In re K-Dur Antitrust Litigation: Reopening the Door for Pharmaceutical Competition Ahalya Sriskandarajah Northwestern

More information

Health Care Law Monthly

Health Care Law Monthly Health Care Law Monthly February 2013 Volume 2013 * Issue No. 2 Contents: Copyright ß 2013 Matthew Bender & Company, Inc., a member of the Lexis- Nexis group of companies. All rights reserved. HEALTH CARE

More information

PAYING FOR DELAY AND THE RULE OF REASON FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION V ACTAVIS INC ET AL 1

PAYING FOR DELAY AND THE RULE OF REASON FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION V ACTAVIS INC ET AL 1 COMPETITION LAW PAYING FOR DELAY AND THE RULE OF REASON FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION V ACTAVIS INC ET AL 1 LIGIA OSEPCIU 2 JUNE 2013 On 17 June 2013, the Supreme Court of the United States handed down its

More information

Intersection of Patent Infringement and Antitrust Liability in Abbreviated New Drug Application Litigation, The

Intersection of Patent Infringement and Antitrust Liability in Abbreviated New Drug Application Litigation, The Journal of Dispute Resolution Volume 2014 Issue 1 Article 5 2014 Intersection of Patent Infringement and Antitrust Liability in Abbreviated New Drug Application Litigation, The Kevin E. Noonan Follow this

More information

No. IN THE Supreme Court of the United States. Petitioner, v. SCHERING-PLOUGH CORPORATION, et al.

No. IN THE Supreme Court of the United States. Petitioner, v. SCHERING-PLOUGH CORPORATION, et al. No. IN THE Supreme Court of the United States FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION, Petitioner, v. SCHERING-PLOUGH CORPORATION, et al. On Petition for a Writ of Certiorari to the United States Court of Appeals for

More information

Pharmaceutical Pay for Delay Settlements

Pharmaceutical Pay for Delay Settlements Pharmaceutical Pay for Delay Settlements UCIP Seminar 12 November 2012 www.morganlewis.com Outline Background Goals of the Hatch-Waxman Act Price Effects of Generic Entry Pay-for-Delay Patent Settlements

More information

A Response to Chief Justice Roberts: Why Antitrust Must Play a Role in the Analysis of Drug Patent Settlements

A Response to Chief Justice Roberts: Why Antitrust Must Play a Role in the Analysis of Drug Patent Settlements A Response to Chief Justice Roberts: Why Antitrust Must Play a Role in the Analysis of Drug Patent Settlements Michael A. Carrier* The Supreme Court s decision in FTC v. Actavis, Inc. 1 has justly received

More information

WE V E A L L B E E N T H E R E.

WE V E A L L B E E N T H E R E. Antitrust, Vol. 23, No. 2, Spring 2009. 2009 by the American Bar Association. Reproduced with permission. All rights reserved. This information or any portion thereof may not be copied or disseminated

More information

Competition Ahead? The Legal Landscape for Reverse Payment Settlements After Federal Trade Commission v. Actavis, Inc.

Competition Ahead? The Legal Landscape for Reverse Payment Settlements After Federal Trade Commission v. Actavis, Inc. Berkeley Technology Law Journal Volume 29 Issue 4 Annual Review 2014 Article 6 8-1-2014 Competition Ahead? The Legal Landscape for Reverse Payment Settlements After Federal Trade Commission v. Actavis,

More information

ON NOVEMBER 6, 2001, the U.S. Court of Appeals

ON NOVEMBER 6, 2001, the U.S. Court of Appeals 21 Biotechnology Law Report 13 Number 1 (February 2002) Mary Ann Liebert, Inc. Brief Analysis of Recent Pharmaceutical/IP Decisions DAVID A. BALTO AMERICAN BIOSCIENCE, INC. V. THOMPSON 269 F.3D1077, 2001

More information

No.,, LOUISIANA WHOLESALE DRUG CO., AG, et al., BAYER AG AND BAYER CORP., et al.,

No.,, LOUISIANA WHOLESALE DRUG CO., AG, et al., BAYER AG AND BAYER CORP., et al., No.,, 10-762 IN TIlE ( urt fll Nnit h LOUISIANA WHOLESALE DRUG CO., AG, et al., Petitioners, V. BAYER AG AND BAYER CORP., et al., Respondents. ON PETITION FOR A WRIT OF CERTIORARI TO TIlE UNITED STATES

More information

PATENT TERM LIMITS, ANTI-TRUST LAW, AND THE HATCH-WAXMAN ACT: WHY DEFENSE OF A LEGALLY GRANTED PATENT MONOPOLY DOES NOT VIOLATE ANTI- TRUST LAWS.

PATENT TERM LIMITS, ANTI-TRUST LAW, AND THE HATCH-WAXMAN ACT: WHY DEFENSE OF A LEGALLY GRANTED PATENT MONOPOLY DOES NOT VIOLATE ANTI- TRUST LAWS. PATENT TERM LIMITS, ANTI-TRUST LAW, AND THE HATCH-WAXMAN ACT: WHY DEFENSE OF A LEGALLY GRANTED PATENT MONOPOLY DOES NOT VIOLATE ANTI- TRUST LAWS. Christopher Fasel I. INTRODUCTION In the interest of increasing

More information

Pharmaceutical Patent Settlements: Issues in Innovation and Competitiveness

Pharmaceutical Patent Settlements: Issues in Innovation and Competitiveness Pharmaceutical Patent Settlements: Issues in Innovation and Competitiveness John R. Thomas Visiting Scholar February 15, 2013 CRS Report for Congress Prepared for Members and Committees of Congress Congressional

More information

In Re: Tamoxifen Citrate Antitrust Litigation UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE SECOND CIRCUIT. 466 F.3d 187 August 10, 2006, Decided

In Re: Tamoxifen Citrate Antitrust Litigation UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE SECOND CIRCUIT. 466 F.3d 187 August 10, 2006, Decided In Re: Tamoxifen Citrate Antitrust Litigation UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE SECOND CIRCUIT 466 F.3d 187 August 10, 2006, Decided [*190] SACK, Circuit Judge: This appeal, arising [**3] out of circumstances

More information

FTC v. Actavis, Inc.: When Is the Rule of Reason Not the Rule of Reason?

FTC v. Actavis, Inc.: When Is the Rule of Reason Not the Rule of Reason? Minnesota Journal of Law, Science & Technology Volume 15 Issue 1 Article 6 2014 FTC v. Actavis, Inc.: When Is the Rule of Reason Not the Rule of Reason? Thomas F. Cotter Follow this and additional works

More information

In the Supreme Court of the United States

In the Supreme Court of the United States No. 12-416 In the Supreme Court of the United States FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION, PETITIONER v. WATSON PHARMACEUTICALS, INC., ET AL. ON PETITION FOR A WRIT OF CERTIORARI TO THE UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS

More information

Pay-to-Delay Settlements: The Circuit-Splitting Headache Plaguing Big Pharma

Pay-to-Delay Settlements: The Circuit-Splitting Headache Plaguing Big Pharma Pay-to-Delay Settlements: The Circuit-Splitting Headache Plaguing Big Pharma ABSTRACT At its passage, the Hatch-Waxman Act was hailed as a much-needed step in making generic drugs more readily available

More information

SETTLEMENTS BETWEEN BRAND AND GENERIC PHARMACEUTICAL COMPANIES: A REASONABLE ANTITRUST ANALYSIS OF REVERSE PAYMENTS

SETTLEMENTS BETWEEN BRAND AND GENERIC PHARMACEUTICAL COMPANIES: A REASONABLE ANTITRUST ANALYSIS OF REVERSE PAYMENTS SETTLEMENTS BETWEEN BRAND AND GENERIC PHARMACEUTICAL COMPANIES: A REASONABLE ANTITRUST ANALYSIS OF REVERSE PAYMENTS Anne-Marie C. Yvon, Ph.D.* INTRODUCTION Imagine that CureCo, Inc., is the exclusive seller

More information

REVERSE PAYMENT AGREEMENTS: WHY A QUICK LOOK PROPERLY PROTECTS PATENTS AND PATIENTS

REVERSE PAYMENT AGREEMENTS: WHY A QUICK LOOK PROPERLY PROTECTS PATENTS AND PATIENTS REVERSE PAYMENT AGREEMENTS: WHY A QUICK LOOK PROPERLY PROTECTS PATENTS AND PATIENTS INTRODUCTION Regulating the pharmaceutical industry has proven to be precarious because of the unique landscape of the

More information

No DD IN THE UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE ELEVENTH CIRCUIT

No DD IN THE UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE ELEVENTH CIRCUIT No. 10-12729-DD IN THE UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE ELEVENTH CIRCUIT FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION, Plaintiff-Appellant, v. WATSON PHARMACEUTICALS, INC., et al., Defendants-Appellees. ON APPEAL FROM

More information

THE HATCH-WAXMAN ACT AND THE CONFLICT BETWEEN ANTITRUST LAW & PATENT LAW

THE HATCH-WAXMAN ACT AND THE CONFLICT BETWEEN ANTITRUST LAW & PATENT LAW 381 THE HATCH-WAXMAN ACT AND THE CONFLICT BETWEEN ANTITRUST LAW & PATENT LAW I. INTRODUCTION PAMELA J. CLEMENTS * On September 12, 2006, the chief executive officer of Bristol-Myers Squibb, Peter Dolan,

More information

Product Improvements and Life Cycle Management Antitrust Pitfalls

Product Improvements and Life Cycle Management Antitrust Pitfalls Product Improvements and Life Cycle Management Antitrust Pitfalls NJ IP Law Association's 26th Annual Pharmaceutical/Chemical Patent Practice Update Paul Ragusa December 5, 2012 2012 Product Improvements

More information

In the Supreme Court of the United States

In the Supreme Court of the United States No. 12-416 In the Supreme Court of the United States FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION, PETITIONER v. WATSON PHARMACEUTICALS, INC., ET AL. ON WRIT OF CERTIORARI TO THE UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE ELEVENTH

More information

Actavis, the Reverse Payment Fallacy, and the Continuing Need for Regulatory Solutions

Actavis, the Reverse Payment Fallacy, and the Continuing Need for Regulatory Solutions Minnesota Journal of Law, Science & Technology Volume 15 Issue 1 Article 7 2014 Actavis, the Reverse Payment Fallacy, and the Continuing Need for Regulatory Solutions Daniel A. Crane Follow this and additional

More information

Looking Within the Scope of the Patent

Looking Within the Scope of the Patent Latham & Watkins Antitrust and Competition Practice Number 1540 June 25, 2013 Looking Within the Scope of the Patent The Supreme Court Holds That Settlements of Paragraph IV Litigation Are Subject to the

More information

SUPREME COURT OF THE UNITED STATES

SUPREME COURT OF THE UNITED STATES (Slip Opinion) OCTOBER TERM, 2012 1 Syllabus NOTE: Where it is feasible, a syllabus (headnote) will be released, as is being done in connection with this case, at the time the opinion is issued. The syllabus

More information

Issue Brief for Congress Received through the CRS Web

Issue Brief for Congress Received through the CRS Web Order Code IB10105 Issue Brief for Congress Received through the CRS Web The Hatch-Waxman Act: Proposed Legislative Changes Affecting Pharmaceutical Patents Updated November 25, 2002 Wendy H. Schacht and

More information

The Role of Antitrust Principles in Patent Monopolies: The Third Circuit Applies Antitrust Scrutiny to No-AG Patent Settlements in Smithkline

The Role of Antitrust Principles in Patent Monopolies: The Third Circuit Applies Antitrust Scrutiny to No-AG Patent Settlements in Smithkline Boston College Law Review Volume 58 Issue 6 Electronic Supplement Article 11 4-13-2017 The Role of Antitrust Principles in Patent Monopolies: The Third Circuit Applies Antitrust Scrutiny to No-AG Patent

More information

No IN THE ( ourt of the: Petitioners, v. BAYER AG ~ ~D BAYER CORP., ETAL., Respondents.

No IN THE ( ourt of the: Petitioners, v. BAYER AG ~ ~D BAYER CORP., ETAL., Respondents. No. 08-1194 OFFIUE OF 1HE CLEFI~ IN THE ( ourt of the: o I ARKANSAS CARPENTERS HEALTH AND WELFARE FUND, PAPER, A.E OF L., ETAL., Petitioners, v. BAYER AG ~ ~D BAYER CORP., ETAL., Respondents. ON PETITION

More information

No. IN THE Supreme Court of the United States. Petitioner, v. SCHERING-PLOUGH CORPORATION, et al.

No. IN THE Supreme Court of the United States. Petitioner, v. SCHERING-PLOUGH CORPORATION, et al. No. IN THE Supreme Court of the United States FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION, Petitioner, v. SCHERING-PLOUGH CORPORATION, et al. On Petition for a Writ of Certiorari to the United States Court of Appeals for

More information

In Re K-Dur Antitrust Litigation: Pharmaceutical Reverse Payment Settlements Go beyond the Scope of the Patent

In Re K-Dur Antitrust Litigation: Pharmaceutical Reverse Payment Settlements Go beyond the Scope of the Patent NORTH CAROLINA JOURNAL OF LAW & TECHNOLOGY Volume 14 Issue 1 Fall 2012 Article 9 10-1-2012 In Re K-Dur Antitrust Litigation: Pharmaceutical Reverse Payment Settlements Go beyond the Scope of the Patent

More information

Reverse Payment Settlements: A Patent Approach to Defending the Argument for Illegality

Reverse Payment Settlements: A Patent Approach to Defending the Argument for Illegality Reverse Payment Settlements: A Patent Approach to Defending the Argument for Illegality CORY J. INGLE* Abstract: This note proposes a new strategy to address the challenges of reverse payment settlements

More information

Payment After Actavis 100 Iowa Law Review 1 (forthcoming 2014) Michael A. Carrier *

Payment After Actavis 100 Iowa Law Review 1 (forthcoming 2014) Michael A. Carrier * Payment After Actavis 100 Iowa Law Review 1 (forthcoming 2014) Michael A. Carrier * One of the most pressing issues in patent and antitrust law involves agreements by which brand-name drug companies pay

More information

Antitrust and Intellectual Property

Antitrust and Intellectual Property and Intellectual Property July 22, 2016 Rob Kidwell, Member Antitrust Prohibitions vs IP Protections The Challenge Harmonizing U.S. antitrust laws that sanction the illegal use of monopoly/market power

More information

Rachel A. Lewis * * J.D. Candidate, Seattle University School of Law, I want to dedicate this Comment to my

Rachel A. Lewis * * J.D. Candidate, Seattle University School of Law, I want to dedicate this Comment to my Inevitable Imbalance: Why FTC v. Actavis Was Inadequate to Solve the Reverse Payment Settlement Problem and Proposing a New Amendment to the Hatch Waxman Act Rachel A. Lewis * The law regarding reverse

More information

Antitrust Issues in the Settlement of Pharmaceutical Patent Disputes, Part III

Antitrust Issues in the Settlement of Pharmaceutical Patent Disputes, Part III Antitrust Issues in the Settlement of Pharmaceutical Patent Disputes, Part III Thomas B. Leary t I. INTRODUCTION Once again, I will address the issue of litigation settlements between companies that hold

More information

1 Bret Dickey, Jonathan Orszag & Laura Tyson, An Economic Assessment of Patent Settlements

1 Bret Dickey, Jonathan Orszag & Laura Tyson, An Economic Assessment of Patent Settlements Hatch-Waxman Act Reverse-Payment Settlements FTC v. Actavis, Inc. Pharmaceutical development is an uncertain business. The process is long and laborious, resulting in research costs that are substantially

More information

In the Supreme Court of the United States

In the Supreme Court of the United States No. 12-416 In the Supreme Court of the United States FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION, Petitioner, v. WATSON PHARMACEUTICALS, INC., ET AL., Respondents. On Petition for a Writ of Certiorari to the United States

More information

FTC v. ACTAVIS: The Patent-Antitrust Intersection Revisited

FTC v. ACTAVIS: The Patent-Antitrust Intersection Revisited Texas A&M University School of Law Texas A&M Law Scholarship Faculty Scholarship 2015 FTC v. ACTAVIS: The Patent-Antitrust Intersection Revisited Glynn S. Lunney Jr Texas A&M University School of Law,

More information

Caraco V. Novo Nordisk: Antitrust Implications

Caraco V. Novo Nordisk: Antitrust Implications Portfolio Media. Inc. 860 Broadway, 6th Floor New York, NY 10003 www.law360.com Phone: +1 646 783 7100 Fax: +1 646 783 7161 customerservice@law360.com Caraco V. Novo Nordisk: Antitrust Implications Law360,

More information

Pharmaceutical Patent Settlements A Presumption in Reverse

Pharmaceutical Patent Settlements A Presumption in Reverse AUGUST 2009, RELEASE ONE Pharmaceutical Patent Settlements A Presumption in Reverse Kristina Nordlander & Patrick Harrison Sidley Austin LLP Pharmaceutical Patent Settlements A Presumption in Reverse Kristina

More information

Payment After Actavis

Payment After Actavis Payment After Actavis Michael A. Carrier ABSTRACT: One of the most pressing issues in patent and antitrust law involves agreements by which brand-name drug companies pay generic firms to delay entering

More information

Harvard Journal of Law & Technology Volume 24, Number 2 Spring Gregory Dolin, M.D.*

Harvard Journal of Law & Technology Volume 24, Number 2 Spring Gregory Dolin, M.D.* Harvard Journal of Law & Technology Volume 24, Number 2 Spring 2011 REVERSE SETTLEMENTS AS PATENT INVALIDITY SIGNALS Gregory Dolin, M.D.* TABLE OF CONTENTS I. INTRODUCTION...282 II. THE HATCH-WAXMAN ACT...286

More information

A Pharmaceutical Park Place: Why the Supreme Court Should Modify the Scope of the Patent Test for Reverse Payment Deals

A Pharmaceutical Park Place: Why the Supreme Court Should Modify the Scope of the Patent Test for Reverse Payment Deals Journal of Intellectual Property Law Volume 20 Issue 2 Article 3 April 2013 A Pharmaceutical Park Place: Why the Supreme Court Should Modify the Scope of the Patent Test for Reverse Payment Deals David

More information

Case 1:10-mc CKK -AK Document 31 Filed 07/13/10 Page 1 of 12 UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE DISTRICT OF COLUMBIA

Case 1:10-mc CKK -AK Document 31 Filed 07/13/10 Page 1 of 12 UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE DISTRICT OF COLUMBIA Case 1:10-mc-00289-CKK -AK Document 31 Filed 07/13/10 Page 1 of 12 UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE DISTRICT OF COLUMBIA FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION, Petitioner, v. PAUL M. BISARO, Misc. No. 10-289 (CKK)(AK)

More information

The Hatch-Waxman Act and Market Exclusivity for Generic Manufacturers: An Entitlement or an Incentive

The Hatch-Waxman Act and Market Exclusivity for Generic Manufacturers: An Entitlement or an Incentive Chicago-Kent Law Review Volume 81 Issue 2 Symposium: Secrecy in Litigation Article 13 April 2006 The Hatch-Waxman Act and Market Exclusivity for Generic Manufacturers: An Entitlement or an Incentive Ashlee

More information

Nos , & UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE THIRD CIRCUIT IN RE K-DUR ANTITRUST LITIGATION

Nos , & UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE THIRD CIRCUIT IN RE K-DUR ANTITRUST LITIGATION Case: 10-2077 Document: 003110535427 Page: 1 Date Filed: 05/18/2011 Nos. 10-2077, 10-2078 & 10-2079 UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE THIRD CIRCUIT IN RE K-DUR ANTITRUST LITIGATION On Appeal from

More information

ANDRX PHARMACEUTICALS, INC.

ANDRX PHARMACEUTICALS, INC. ANDRX PHARMACEUTICALS, INC. v. ELAN CORP., PLC Cite as 421 F.3d 1227 (11th Cir. 2005) 1227 rence admits in his appellate brief that medical reports state that his full scale IQ is 81, and he admits that

More information

Editor s Note. US Antitrust Modernization Commission. By A. Noboa Pagán.

Editor s Note. US Antitrust Modernization Commission. By A. Noboa Pagán. Editor s Note. US Antitrust Modernization Commission. By A. Noboa Pagán. Since 2002, the United States Congress designated an Antitrust Modernization Commission with the task of examining whether or not

More information

Case: 1:16-cv Document #: 1 Filed: 03/09/16 Page 1 of 13 PageID #:1 UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT NORTHERN DISTRICT OF ILLINOIS EASTERN DIVISION

Case: 1:16-cv Document #: 1 Filed: 03/09/16 Page 1 of 13 PageID #:1 UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT NORTHERN DISTRICT OF ILLINOIS EASTERN DIVISION Case: 1:16-cv-02988 Document #: 1 Filed: 03/09/16 Page 1 of 13 PageID #:1 UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT NORTHERN DISTRICT OF ILLINOIS EASTERN DIVISION TORRENT PHARMACEUTICALS LIMITED, and TORRENT PHARMA

More information

Supreme Court of the United States

Supreme Court of the United States No. 15-1055 IN THE Supreme Court of the United States SMITHKLINE BEECHAM CORPORATION, D/B/A GLAXOSMITHKLINE; TEVA PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRIES LTD.; TEVA PHARMACEUTICALS, USA, Petitioners, v. KING DRUG COMPANY

More information

Supreme Court of the United States

Supreme Court of the United States No. 12-416 IN THE Supreme Court of the United States FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION, v. Petitioner, ACTAVIS, INC., ET AL. Respondents. On Writ Of Certiorari To The United States Court Of Appeals For The Eleventh

More information

A Prescription for the Future: Reverse-Payment Settlements in the Wake of FTC v. Actavis Pharmaceuticals

A Prescription for the Future: Reverse-Payment Settlements in the Wake of FTC v. Actavis Pharmaceuticals Notre Dame Journal of Law, Ethics & Public Policy Volume 29 Issue 2 Symposium: Regulating Life, Disease, and Death Article 9 2015 A Prescription for the Future: Reverse-Payment Settlements in the Wake

More information

In the Supreme Court of the United States

In the Supreme Court of the United States No. 15-1055 In the Supreme Court of the United States SMITHKLINE BEECHAM CORPORATION, D/B/A GLAXOSMITHKLINE, ET AL., PETITIONERS v. KING DRUG COMPANY OF FLORENCE, INC., ET AL. ON PETITION FOR A WRIT OF

More information

Antitrust/Intellectual Property Interface Under U.S. Law

Antitrust/Intellectual Property Interface Under U.S. Law BEIJING BRUSSELS CHICAGO DALLAS FRANKFURT GENEVA HONG KONG LONDON LOS ANGELES NEW YORK SAN FRANCISCO SHANGHAI SINGAPORE SYDNEY TOKYO WASHINGTON, D.C. Antitrust/Intellectual Property Interface Under U.S.

More information

Recent developments in US law: Remedies and damages for improper patent listings in the FDA s Orange Book

Recent developments in US law: Remedies and damages for improper patent listings in the FDA s Orange Book Daniel G. Brown is a partner in the New York law firm Frommer Lawrence & Haug, LLP, and practises extensively in the Hatch Waxman area. He has been practising in New York since 1993 in the patent and intellectual

More information

RAMBUS, INC. v. FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION Impact on Standards and Antitrust

RAMBUS, INC. v. FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION Impact on Standards and Antitrust RAMBUS, INC. v. FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION Impact on Standards and Antitrust American Intellectual Property Law Association IP Practice in Japan Committee October 2009, Washington, DC JOHN A. O BRIEN LAW

More information

Injunctive and Reverse Settlements in Competition-Blocking Litigation (with Keith N. Hylton)

Injunctive and Reverse Settlements in Competition-Blocking Litigation (with Keith N. Hylton) Chicago-Kent College of Law Scholarly Commons @ IIT Chicago-Kent College of Law All Faculty Scholarship Faculty Scholarship 1-1-2013 Injunctive and Reverse Settlements in Competition-Blocking Litigation

More information

In the Supreme Court of the United States

In the Supreme Court of the United States No.06-937 In the Supreme Court of the United States QUANTA COMPUTER, INC., ET AL., v. Petitioners, LG ELECTRONICS, INC., Respondent. ON WRIT OF CERTIORARI TO THE UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE

More information

No IN THE EISAI CO. LTD AND EISAI MEDICAL RESEARCH, INC., TEVA PHARMACEUTICALS USA, INC., through its GATE PHARMACEUTICALS Division,

No IN THE EISAI CO. LTD AND EISAI MEDICAL RESEARCH, INC., TEVA PHARMACEUTICALS USA, INC., through its GATE PHARMACEUTICALS Division, No. 10-1070 ~[~ 2 7 7.i~[ IN THE EISAI CO. LTD AND EISAI MEDICAL RESEARCH, INC., Petitioners, TEVA PHARMACEUTICALS USA, INC., through its GATE PHARMACEUTICALS Division, Respondent. ON PETITION FOR A WRIT

More information

A Framework to Evaluate Pharmaceutical Pay-for- Delays: A Balancing Test Based Upon Reasonableness

A Framework to Evaluate Pharmaceutical Pay-for- Delays: A Balancing Test Based Upon Reasonableness Kentucky Law Journal Volume 102 Issue 2 Special Feature: Medicaid Matters Article 10 2013 A Framework to Evaluate Pharmaceutical Pay-for- Delays: A Balancing Test Based Upon Reasonableness Jessica Hudson

More information

FEDERAL REPORTER, 3d SERIES

FEDERAL REPORTER, 3d SERIES 1294 344 FEDERAL REPORTER, 3d SERIES in this court in active service having voted in favor of granting a rehearing en banc, IT IS ORDERED that the above cause shall be reheard by this court en banc. The

More information

The EU Sector Inquiry: Implications for Patent Litigation and Settlements

The EU Sector Inquiry: Implications for Patent Litigation and Settlements The EU Sector Inquiry: Implications for Patent Litigation and Settlements Sean-Paul Brankin Crowell & Moring February 17, 2009 1 Issues from the Preliminary Report Market definition Vexatious litigation

More information

Case 2:08-cv MSG Document 43 Filed 08/31/2009 Page 1 of 59 IN THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE EASTERN DISTRICT OF PENNSYLVANIA

Case 2:08-cv MSG Document 43 Filed 08/31/2009 Page 1 of 59 IN THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE EASTERN DISTRICT OF PENNSYLVANIA Case 2:08-cv-02141-MSG Document 43 Filed 08/31/2009 Page 1 of 59 IN THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE EASTERN DISTRICT OF PENNSYLVANIA FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION, Plaintiff, v. CEPHALON INC., Defendant.

More information

No IN THE Supreme Court of the United States. On Writ of Certiorari to the United States Court of Appeals for the Eleventh Circuit

No IN THE Supreme Court of the United States. On Writ of Certiorari to the United States Court of Appeals for the Eleventh Circuit No. 12-416 IN THE Supreme Court of the United States FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION, v. Petitioner, ACTAVIS, INC. ET AL., Respondents. On Writ of Certiorari to the United States Court of Appeals for the Eleventh

More information

Case 1:18-cv AKH Document 101 Filed 10/24/18 Page 1 of 26 UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE SOUTHERN DISTRICT OF NEW YORK

Case 1:18-cv AKH Document 101 Filed 10/24/18 Page 1 of 26 UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE SOUTHERN DISTRICT OF NEW YORK Case 1:18-cv-04361-AKH Document 101 Filed 10/24/18 Page 1 of 26 UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE SOUTHERN DISTRICT OF NEW YORK In re Novartis and Par Antitrust Litigation 1:18-cv-04361-AKH This Document

More information

IN THE PAST THREE YEARS, A NUMBER

IN THE PAST THREE YEARS, A NUMBER C O V E R S T O R I E S Antitrust, Vol. 22, No. 2, Spring 2008. 2008 by the American Bar Association. Reproduced with permission. All rights reserved. This information or any portion thereof may not be

More information

HOGAN & HARTSON APR -9 P4 :18 BY HAND DELIVERY

HOGAN & HARTSON APR -9 P4 :18 BY HAND DELIVERY HOGAN & HARTSON 2741 10 APR -9 P4 :18 Hogan & Hartson up Columbia Square 555 Thirteenth Street, NW Washington, DC 20004 +1.202.637.5600 Tel +1.202.637.5910 Fax www.hhlaw.com Philip Katz Partner 202.637.5632

More information

Hatch-Waxman Patent Case Settlements The Supreme Court Churns the Swamp

Hatch-Waxman Patent Case Settlements The Supreme Court Churns the Swamp Hatch-Waxman Patent Case Settlements The Supreme Court Churns the Swamp Kent Bernard* I. INTRODUCTION To lusty cheers of consulting economists and litigating lawyers everywhere, and the heartfelt groans

More information

FTC v. Watson Pharmaceuticals: 677 F.3D 1298 (11th Cir. 2012)

FTC v. Watson Pharmaceuticals: 677 F.3D 1298 (11th Cir. 2012) DePaul Journal of Art, Technology & Intellectual Property Law Volume 23 Issue 2 Spring 2013 Article 8 FTC v. Watson Pharmaceuticals: 677 F.3D 1298 (11th Cir. 2012) Christopher Bingham Galligan Follow this

More information

United States Court of Appeals for the Federal Circuit

United States Court of Appeals for the Federal Circuit United States Court of Appeals for the Federal Circuit 2009-1071 ELI LILLY AND COMPANY, Plaintiff-Appellee, v. TEVA PHARMACEUTICALS USA, INC., Defendant-Appellant. Charles E. Lipsey, Finnegan, Henderson,

More information

FDA, PATENT TERM EXTENSIONS AND THE HATCH WAXMAN ACT. Dr.Sumesh Reddy- Dr. Reddys Lab Hyderabad-

FDA, PATENT TERM EXTENSIONS AND THE HATCH WAXMAN ACT. Dr.Sumesh Reddy- Dr. Reddys Lab Hyderabad- FDA, PATENT TERM EXTENSIONS AND THE HATCH WAXMAN ACT Dr.Sumesh Reddy- Dr. Reddys Lab Hyderabad- FDA Regulatory approval-time and cost Focus of FDA approval process-safety and efficacy Difference between

More information

No IN THE Supreme Court of the United States. FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION, Petitioner, v. WATSON PHARMACEUTICALS, INC., et al., Respondents.

No IN THE Supreme Court of the United States. FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION, Petitioner, v. WATSON PHARMACEUTICALS, INC., et al., Respondents. No. 12-416 IN THE Supreme Court of the United States FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION, Petitioner, v. WATSON PHARMACEUTICALS, INC., et al., Respondents. ON WRIT OF CERTIORARI TO THE UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS

More information

FTC AND DOJ ISSUE JOINT REPORT REGARDING ANTITRUST ENFORCEMENT AND INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY RIGHTS

FTC AND DOJ ISSUE JOINT REPORT REGARDING ANTITRUST ENFORCEMENT AND INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY RIGHTS OF INTEREST FTC AND DOJ ISSUE JOINT REPORT REGARDING ANTITRUST ENFORCEMENT AND INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY RIGHTS Interesting and difficult questions lie at the intersection of intellectual property rights and

More information

WHY THE SUPREME COURT WAS CORRECT TO DENY CERTIORARI IN FTC V. RAMBUS

WHY THE SUPREME COURT WAS CORRECT TO DENY CERTIORARI IN FTC V. RAMBUS WHY THE SUPREME COURT WAS CORRECT TO DENY CERTIORARI IN FTC V. RAMBUS Joshua D. Wright, George Mason University School of Law George Mason University Law and Economics Research Paper Series 09-14 This

More information

An ANDA Update. June 2004 Bulletin 04-50

An ANDA Update. June 2004 Bulletin 04-50 June 2004 Bulletin 04-50 If you have questions or would like additional information on the material covered in this Bulletin, please contact one of the authors: Mark R. Shanks 202.414.9201 mshanks@reedsmith.com

More information

United States Court of Appeals for the Federal Circuit

United States Court of Appeals for the Federal Circuit United States Court of Appeals for the Federal Circuit TEVA PHARMACEUTICALS USA, INC., THROUGH ITS GATE PHARMACEUTICALS DIVISION, Plaintiff-Appellant, v. EISAI CO., LTD. AND EISAI MEDICAL RESEARCH, INC.,

More information

DIRECT PURCHASERS STANDING TO SUE FOR WALKER PROCESS FRAUD IN RE: DDAVP DIRECT PURCHASER ANTITRUST LITIGATION

DIRECT PURCHASERS STANDING TO SUE FOR WALKER PROCESS FRAUD IN RE: DDAVP DIRECT PURCHASER ANTITRUST LITIGATION DIRECT PURCHASERS STANDING TO SUE FOR WALKER PROCESS FRAUD IN RE: DDAVP DIRECT PURCHASER ANTITRUST LITIGATION Rick Duncan Denise Kettleberger Melina Williams Faegre & Benson, LLP Minneapolis, Minnesota

More information

ORDER GRANTING IN PART AND DENYING IN PART MOTION TO TRANSFER OR STAY

ORDER GRANTING IN PART AND DENYING IN PART MOTION TO TRANSFER OR STAY Pfizer Inc. et al v. Sandoz Inc. Doc. 50 Civil Action No. 09-cv-02392-CMA-MJW IN THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE DISTRICT OF COLORADO Judge Christine M. Arguello PFIZER, INC., PFIZER PHARMACEUTICALS,

More information

Case 3:14-cv MLC-TJB Document Filed 07/24/15 Page 2 of 16 PageID: 1111 TABLE OF CONTENTS INTRODUCTION... 1 BACKGROUND...

Case 3:14-cv MLC-TJB Document Filed 07/24/15 Page 2 of 16 PageID: 1111 TABLE OF CONTENTS INTRODUCTION... 1 BACKGROUND... Case 3:14-cv-02550-MLC-TJB Document 100-1 Filed 07/24/15 Page 1 of 16 PageID: 1110 Keith J. Miller Michael J. Gesualdo ROBINSON MILLER LLC One Newark Center, 19th Floor Newark, New Jersey 07102 Telephone:

More information

Supreme Court Invites Solicitor General s View on Safe Harbor of the Hatch-Waxman Act

Supreme Court Invites Solicitor General s View on Safe Harbor of the Hatch-Waxman Act Supreme Court Invites Solicitor General s View on Safe Harbor of the Hatch-Waxman Act Prepared By: The Intellectual Property Group On June 25, 2012, the United States Supreme Court invited the Solicitor

More information