Do Voters Appreciate Responsive Governments? Evidence from Indian Disaster Relief *

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Do Voters Appreciate Responsive Governments? Evidence from Indian Disaster Relief *"

Transcription

1 Do Voters Appreciate Responsive Governments? Evidence from Indian Disaster Relief * Shawn Cole Harvard Business School Andrew Healy Loyola Marymount University Eric Werker Harvard Business School December 18, 2008 * s: scole@hbs.edu; ahealy@lmu.edu; ewerker@hbs.edu. Data collection for this project began in 2004; first draft We are grateful to Alberto Alesina, Rafael di Tella, Allen Drazen, Ray Fisman, Michael Norton, Rohini Pande, Daniel Posner, Petia Topalova, Lou Wells, and seminar participants at the Harvard development faculty lunch, Harvard Business School Business Government and the International Economy seminar series, and the New England Universities Development Consortium for comments and discussions. We thank Robin Burgess and Stuti Khemani for providing data, and Byron Hussie, Gautam Bastian, Samantha Bastian, and Ritika D Souza for excellent research assistance. Cole and Werker acknowledge financial support from the Harvard Business School Division of Research and Faculty Development. The usual caveat applies.

2 ABSTRACT: Using rainfall, public relief, and election data from India, we examine how governments respond to adverse shocks and how voters react to these responses. The data show that voters punish the incumbent party for weather events beyond its control. However, we find evidence that fewer voters punish the ruling party when the party responds vigorously to the crisis. Moreover, severe crises are associated with increased voter sensitivity to disaster assistance. These results are consistent with models of government accountability, and provide an explanation for Amartya Sen s claim that democratic governments respond better to salient emergencies than to less conspicuous ones. Even so, the results suggest that even the most responsive government will fare worse in the subsequent election than had there been no disaster.

3 I. Introduction In a functioning democracy, politicians ability to win reelection declines when they perform poorly. This idea fits well with models of political accountability. Recent evidence suggests, however, that voters may punish politicians even for events outside their control. This behavior may violate standard models of democratic accountability, and has been advanced as evidence of voter irrationality. Yet, not all bad shocks are bad for politicians. Rudolph Giuliani s political career, wrote The New York Times Magazine in September 2007, is built atop the rubble of the twin towers. Giuliani s leadership following the terrorist attacks, according to most accounts, catapulted the former mayor into a presidential run. Similarly, the main source of [Russian President Vladimir] Putin s popularity, wrote Richard Haass in 2000, was the perception that the war against the Chechen rebels was going well. In this paper, we use weather crises to identify the relationship between government response and electoral decisions. Specifically, we look at the decisions that Indian voters make in provincial elections, using the quality of the monsoon rains as an exogenous shock to welfare. We find that voters do indeed punish politicians following adverse weather events, but that the degree of punishment depends critically on the quality of the ruling party s response: those distributing greater amounts of relief aid suffer smaller subsequent electoral losses. We motivate our analysis with a simple principal-agent view of political accountability, in which voters observe their own welfare, the public and exogenous welfare shock, as well as the government response. Rational voters can filter the observed shock from the government s performance, and do not punish politicians for bad luck. However, if the government s ability is more accurately revealed during a crisis, rational voters may correctly vote against incumbent politicians following adverse weather if they respond poorly. Finally, if voters are irrational or boundedly rational, they may punish politicians simply because a negative shock has occurred, either ignoring or insufficiently weighing the government s response. Our paper builds on recent work examining voters response to adverse shocks. Achen and Bartels (2004) find that leaders are punished for droughts, floods, and even

4 shark attacks that occur under their watch. Healy (2008) finds that American voters systematically punish the incumbent party for tornado damage in election years. In a similar vein, Wolfers (2006) and Leigh (2004) show that incumbent politicians are punished for movements in the economy outside their plausible sphere of influence. None of these papers, however, includes measures of government response in their descriptions of voter decisions. The determinants of crisis relief, on the other hand, have received some attention. Besley and Burgess (2002) show that state governments in India are responsive to agricultural and weather-induced catastrophes, but the degree of response depends on the sophistication of the voters. Specifically, they find that state governments increase public food distribution and calamity relief expenditures more when their electorates are characterized by higher literacy rates and greater newspaper circulation. This research is in the tradition of Amartya Sen and others who have sought to understand the prevention and resolution of food crises with a particular focus on India (Sen 1981, Drèze and Sen, 1989). Sen observed that democracies are better at responding to those disasters that are easy to understand and where sympathy can take a particularly immediate form than to less salient deprivations (1999, p. 154). Sen s argument suggests either that some governments have limited awareness of certain crises or that public accountability is crucial to creating the incentives that lead to vigorous government response. Some evidence from the United States suggests that the importance of electoral incentives may be the crucial factor; Garrett and Sobel (2003) found that half of federal emergency relief appears to be driven by a given state s importance in winning presidential elections. The fact that governments respond to electoral incentives suggests that voters reward at least some types of government response efforts. At the same time, the fact that governments may respond less well to less visible crises certainly suggests limitations to voters abilities to hold governments accountable. In this paper, we use electoral data from India to test hypotheses relating to how effectively voters hold governments accountable for crisis response. We note several advantages of our setting. India s size and history yield a large sample size: there have been over 21,000 elections in over 25 states, spanning nearly a quarter century. Agriculture is critically important to India s economy (employing over half the nation s population throughout our sample), and

5 rainfall shocks are measured accurately. This enables extraordinarily precise estimation, as well as the flexibility to explore heterogeneous shocks and treatment effects. Our results are consistent with both the electoral accountability literature as well as the voter irrationality literature. We establish that rainfall is an important determinant of agricultural output and that relief does flow to areas hardest hit by crisis events. We then confirm the basic findings of Achen and Bartels (2004) and Healy (2008) in the Indian context. We show that, on average, incumbent parties that run for re-election get punished for bad weather, losing more than 3 percent of the vote for each standard deviation rainfall in their district deviates from the optimum. We find suggestive evidence that this effect is stronger in farming districts, where rainfall has a larger impact on income, and weaker in districts with a higher literacy rate, where voters may be more sophisticated and less likely to blame politicians for events beyond their control. Next, we test whether voters reward governments that increase disaster spending in response to extreme rainfall. Our results are strong and significant: incumbents fare better when they respond to a crisis with emergency relief. However, we estimate that governments that respond to crises with an average increase in relief spending are able to make up votes equivalent to only one seventh the punishment from having presided during a crisis in the first place. We argue that these results are not driven by the omitted variable of government competence by controlling for observable characteristics of government competence as well as the government s response to crises earlier in the election cycle where voter recall is much weaker. Finally, we investigate nonlinear dynamics around voting and weather crises. When we restrict the analysis to extreme weather events (rainfall in the worst decile for crop production) we find that a 2.5-times average increase in relief spending can make up all the bad luck of presiding over a drought. Importantly, we find that governments are much more generous with relief spending to regions hit by the worst decile of weather shocks than they are to the second-worst decile even though there is substantial crop loss under both scenarios. We argue this is likely to be motivated by biases in voter response: votes are more than twice as sensitive to relief spending during these extreme weather events than they are to relief spending during the less salient crises.

6 Overall, these results tie together the findings of the literature on government accountability and voter irrationality. In democratic contexts, governments respond to crises with government-supplied relief, but the degree to which they do so depends on the likely electoral return. Indian voters, on average, punish their leaders for events beyond their control, a finding consistent with voter irrationality. However, the degree of this punishment is reduced for improved government responsiveness to those events. Moreover, the vote-increasing power of a competent response is strongest during conspicuous crises, supporting Sen s view that democracies are better at monitoring disasters than quiet deprivation. The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section II summarizes the context of the political system in India and related research. Section III describes our data set and empirical specifications. Section IV details the main results of our analysis on crop yields, relief spending, and voting outcomes. Section V examines whether government and voter behavior differs during especially severe climatic events. Section VI concludes. II. Politics in India Previous Research on Indian Elections Several studies have exploited the richness of Indian electoral data. Linden (2004) uses a regression-discontinuity design to test for incumbency advantage in Indian national elections, finding that candidates enjoyed an incumbency advantage prior to 1991, while suffering from an incumbency disadvantage in the subsequent period. Khemani (2001) examines voter behavior in state and national elections and finds that voters evaluate state politicians based on economic growth over their representative s five-year term; in contrast, when evaluating national elections, they are influenced primarily by recent economic growth. Perhaps the paper most closely related to the present draft is Afzal (2007), which studies rainfall and voting in South Asia. Afzal develops a model in which politicians who own land face a tradeoff between political effort and farm labor. When there is an incumbency disadvantage and good rainfall, politicians will not bother to govern well given the opportunity cost of agricultural production. She tests this model using

7 development fund spending in Pakistan, and variation in the profession of elected members of India s lower parliament, finding support for the model in other words, the rainfall/re-election link is sensitive to the incumbency (dis)advantage of the period. This paper differs from Afzal in several ways. We focus on state, rather than federal elections. Our time panel is substantially longer, and because state elections are staggered, we can control for national political trends by including state fixed-effects. Most importantly, drought and flood relief spending is organized at the state level. The goal of our paper is not to test whether voters act rationally or irrationally, but rather to better understand the incentives faced by electoral officials, how politicians react to these incentives, and how voters in turn respond. Political Context In this paper we focus on state-level elections. State governments are responsible for most public goods in India, including agricultural infrastructure, health, and education. Importantly, they are also responsible for spending on disaster relief and distributing food grains (Khemani 2007). India has a federal system of government, with a bicameral national legislature, but typically unicameral state legislatures. 1 The chief executive of the state is the Chief Minister, who is chosen by the parliament. States also have titular governors, whose powers are mainly ceremonial. Our main measure of state responsiveness is state spending on disaster relief these amounts are reported in state budgets, and include both planned and unplanned expenditure. The former is either allocated ex-ante into the budget as a contingency, or included to pay for ongoing disaster relief. Elections in India function on a first-past-the-post system, with a seat going to the candidate who gets a plurality of votes. The number of seats per state ranges from 19 to 406, with an average of 136. Following the election, the governor of the state invites the party with the largest number of seats to form a government. If the party manages to form a majority, it becomes the ruling party. If not, the governor invites the next-largest party to form a ruling coalition. 1 A few states have upper houses, with indirect elections; for those states, we study the more important chamber, the popularly elected lower house.

8 The first state and federal elections were held in 1951, shortly after the promulgation of India s constitution. Parliamentary elections are scheduled to occur at five-year intervals. While state and federal elections were once generally synchronized, over time they have become less so as states hold early elections. As in other parliamentary systems, elections may be called if the government loses a no-confidence vote. Alternatively, under article 356 of the constitution, the central government can declare President s Rule, dismiss the state legislature and executive, and appoint a governor. This is meant to occur when the Government of the State cannot be carried on in accordance with the provisions of this Constitution. 2 Campaign finance is relatively restricted in India, as compared to the United States. The nominal limits on spending are very low, less than US$1,000 for the period covered in our data (Sridharan, 1999). While certainly candidates and parties often spend more than the legal limit, in general, hard-dollar spending is of limited importance. In contrast, politically-motivated budget manipulation, and government-owned bank lending are important features of Indian elections that may aid incumbents seeking re-election. (See Khemani, 2004, and Cole, 2008, for examples.) In Russia, such manilupations have been shown to aid re-election (Akhmedov and Zhuravskaya, 2004). Politics and parties The Indian National Congress Party, which led the independence movement, initially dominated Indian politics. It won a majority in every federal election until 1977, and captured many state assemblies as well. In addition to Congress, there are several other major national parties (including the Communist Party of India and the Hindunationalist Bharatiya Janata Party) and a host of recognized state parties. There are limited barriers to entry in Indian electoral contests, and the number of candidates running for office ranges from 1 to over During the period covered by our 2 While this clause has been invoked over 100 times, a federal government report argued that the vast majority of cases were warranted, either because of state reorganization or the collapse of the state ruling coalition (National Commission to Review the Working of the Constitution, 2002). Eighteen of these cases, occurring in 1977 and 1980, were deemed clearly abusive, with the central government dismissing hostile state governments, while 13 were viewed as possibly abusive (Section 8.16). 3 The constitution mandates that each state reserve a share of seats for scheduled tribes and scheduled castes (the dalits, or untouchables).

9 data, constituency boundaries were stable, allowing us to match constituencies over time and thus identify the political affiliation of the incumbent. 4 Chhiber and Kollman (1998) find that while the number of state and national parties fluctuates, in any given electoral district there are usually two effective parties. State parties may form (informal) coalitions prior to elections, dividing up the constituencies in which they run candidates so as not to compete with other members of the presumed post-election coalition. Because the number of competitive parties within a constituency is typically only two, we simplify coalitional analysis by coding parties that are part of the ruling coalition as majority, with all others serving as opponents. 5 III. Data and Empirical Specification Our dataset contains information about the voting decisions of 1.58 billion voters in 21,532 electoral competitions in 28 Indian states over the period The unit of observation is, unless otherwise noted, the administrative district-election interaction. Voting outcomes are aggregated up from the constituency-level to the district level. 6 We augment this dataset with information about rainfall, crop yields, population characteristics, and disaster relief spending. Electoral data, from the Election Commission of India, provide for every election candidate the name, sex, party affiliation, and number of votes won. There are 594 administrative districts. A district is an administrative unit within a state roughly equivalent to a U.S. county; the number of constituencies in a district ranges from 1 to over 50, with a median of 5. We begin our analysis in 1977, after which Congress victory was no longer assured. 4 Of the 21,532 elections in our data, we are able to identify the incumbent party in 17,744 elections. We cannot identify the incumbents following state political reorganizations, which resulted in the creation of entirely new legislative assemblies for the new states. 5 Information on coalitions is not officially disseminated by any source we know of. Newspaper articles from the Times of India describing the outcome of each election were used to group parties into coalitions. 6 The original unit of observation for our analysis was the electoral constituency, rather than the administrative district. However, because there are no time-varying regressors at the sub-district level, we choose the more conservative approach of aggregating results to the district * election year.

10 Rainfall data, gathered by Willmott and Matsuura (2001), provide monthly aggregate rainfall interpolated at the 0.5 degree level, or approximately 30 miles, which we match to districts. 7 We account for spatial correlation of error terms by clustering results at the state-election level; the results are robust to clustering at the state level (available upon request). Data on agricultural output, from Sanghi, Kumar, and McKinsey (1998), provide the quantity, yield, and price for 25 of the most common agricultural crops in India. The dataset runs from 1950 to 1994; for the subsequent years, we use an updated version created by Rohini Pande. 8 Table 1 describes the summary statistics from our datasets. An average state election in our dataset had 156 seats. The most successful party won, on average, 56 percent of the seats in a state election. Only a plurality is necessary to win a constituency, and the winning candidate on average received approximately 48 percent of the vote. Finally, the incumbent ruling coalition won, on average, only 35 percent of votes in a constituency. Panel B describes the weather data. We use as our main measure of rainfall the total amount of rain falling in a district from June 1 to September 30, which roughly approximates the Kharif growing season. This monsoon period is the most important for agriculture. The average of mean rainfall across districts is approximately 995mm, with a standard deviation of 667mm. Within a district, there is less variation: the median district receives an average rainfall of 890mm, with a standard deviation of 231mm. Panel C gives mean disaster expenditure per person in constant 1998 rupees, using a deflator from the Reserve Bank of India; this amounted to 10 rupees per person (with a standard deviation of 12 rupees), equivalent to approximately $0.32 today. We adopt a general approach to map the quality of the monsoon to the value of agricultural output, using simple transformations of total rainfall occurring during the 7 To match districts to rainfall, we calculate the centroid of each district using a 2001 GIS map. We then define a district's rainfall pattern as the grid point that is closest to the centroid. While this induces some measurement error, we are confident that the match is close. 8 Indian districts are periodically re-organized, typically by dividing one district into two districts. Thus, the number of districts increases over time. We map our electoral data and rainfall data to the most recent district boundaries (594 districts). The agricultural dataset was collected in a manner that maintains consistent data over the period , and therefore contains 272 districts per year.

11 monsoon period. 9 The first of our two measures of weather, weather dt, is normalized Raindt Raind rainfall,, where Rain dt is the number of millimeters of rainfall during the s d kharif season, and s d is the standard deviation of annual kharif rainfall within the district. The relationship between normalized rainfall and outcomes need not be linear: a quadratic specification allows for the possibility that excess rainfall may cause crop damage. 10 Our second measure is the absolute deviation of normalized rainfall from the Raindt Raind district optimum: 1. This second measure is meant to represent the s d degree to which rain varies from the optimal amount, measured in standard deviations from the district mean. The next section demonstrates that the optimal level of rainfall is about one standard deviation above the mean. We are interested in the effect of weather events on three general classes of outcomes: crop yield, government response, and voting. The primary contribution of this paper is the elucidation of the relationship between weather, government response, and electoral response to both weather and government action. Of course, necessary first steps are to verify that weather indeed affects crop yields, and that governments respond to natural disasters. We measure the relationship between rainfall and crop yield with the following regression, run on a panel of 272 districts over 32 years: (1) Yield dt = α + γ d + τ t + β*weather dt + e dt where Yield dt is a measure of the log value of a district s crop output, and include fixed effects for district,γ d, and year, τ t. We weight the regressions by the number of votes in the district; the results are robust to non-weighted specifications (available upon request). As described previously, we use two different measures of weather dt to ensure that our 9 While different crops have different rainfall requirements, farmers grow crops that are appropriate for their climatic region; we thus believe the most logical analysis maps total monsoon rainfall to crop output. 10 Non-parametric estimation, not reported, suggests that a quadratic specification provides a good approximation of the true relationship between rainfall and voting, expenditures, and crop yield.

12 results are robust. Agronomic models indicate yield increases in rain up to an optimal point, at which point yields fall, as excess rainfall damages the crops. Thus, using the second measure, the absolute normalized deviation of rain from the optimal rainfall, we expect a negative and monotonic relationship. Our measurement of the relationship between rainfall and relief is similar. We regress the log of state expenditure on disaster relief, at the state level, on total state expenditure (excluding relief expenditure), state and year fixed effects, and lagged weather. (2) Relief st = α + γ s + τ t +η *TotalSpending st + β*weather st-1 + e st In the above equation, we take the mean of the weather variable across the state in a given year. We lag weather because the Indian fiscal year ends on March 31. Thus, relief spending for the 2000 fiscal year, represents spending in the twelve months from April 1999 to March We therefore relate relief spending from April 1999 to March 2000 to weather from May 1999 to October 1999, the most recent monsoon season. We expect our coefficients on weather to be the opposite from those in equation (1): more extreme weather should generate higher relief spending. 11 Finally, we estimate the relationship between weather and voting with the following equation: (3) VoteShare dct = α + γ d + τ t + β*weather dt-1 + e dt VoteShare dct is the vote share in a constituency c for the candidate from the incumbent ruling party. We use the previous year s weather, as the main kharif season is from June to September, while the elections typically occur in February and March. Thus the rain in 11 Many states in India have a second growing season, called Rabi, in the winter. However, there is little rainfall during this time, and crops grown during Rabi typically depend either on irrigation or moisture retained in the soil from the Kharif rains.

13 the calendar year before the election is the most salient. 12 This equation will allow us to test, in the Indian context, the general hypothesis of Achen and Bartels (2004) and Healy (2008), that incumbents are punished for acts of God in the time leading up to their election. To control for unobserved geographic heterogeneity, we estimate specifications including state fixed effects or district fixed effects. Our results are robust across specifications and all of our results hold when either state or district fixed effects (or neither) are included. In the following discussion, we focus on the results obtained by using district (and year) fixed effects; this specification controls for the most unobserved variation. IV. Results This section reports our main results. We find that abnormally low or high rain in a district leads to lower agricultural output and more disaster relief. On average, severe weather costs the incumbent coalition a large share of the vote, but spending on disaster relief can eliminate some of this cost. Rainfall matters We first examine the relationship between severe weather and crop yields, as measured by the log value of agricultural output (in rupees). 13 Table 2 tests various iterations of equation (1), using the natural log of crop yield as the dependent variable. As expected, all specifications indicate a strong relationship between rainfall and agricultural output. The magnitudes are large, and the t-statistics with our preferred specifications containing district fixed effects are greater than 4. Standard errors are clustered at the state-year level. Columns (1)-(2) present the linear relationship between normalized rainfall and output: the coefficient is positive and very statistically significant (t-statistics 12 A second option is to include rainfall from previous years directly in the estimating equation; we have done so, and found that the previous year s rain is far more important than earlier years rainfall, whose impact is often statistically indistinguishable from zero. 13 Adjusting for inflation is not necessary, as all the regressions include year fixed-effects.

14 are given in parentheses). On average, a one standard deviation increase in rainfall results in a 3 to 4 percent increase in the value of output. In columns (3)-(4), we include a quadratic term in normalized rainfall. The linear term is positive, while the quadratic is negative, indicating that revenue increases to an optimal point (the optimum is reached around standard deviations above the mean, depending on the specification, with the result being 1.27 standard deviations for the specification that includes district fixed effects). From this we assume an optimal amount of rainfall of one standard deviation above the mean in our second weather measure outlined in Section III. 14 Columns (5)-(6) measure how the value of output falls as rainfall departs from this optimum. Controlling for district effects and the time trend, the specification in column (6) indicates that rain that is one standard deviation away from this optimum leads to a 5.4 percent drop in agricultural output, on average. Since farmers typically pay a substantial cost to grow crops (seeds, fertilizer, etc.), a 5.4 percent variation in the value of output likely implies a significantly higher amount of variation in a farmer s net income. It is important to note that adverse effects of this shock to agricultural output are not limited to land-owners. While the effects on price are mitigated to some extent by government price controls, particularly for staples, the demand for agricultural labor is strongly correlated with rainfall: Jayachandran (2006) demonstrates that wage workers suffer significant reductions in wages during adverse weather shocks. Governments are responsive We also test for what Besley and Burgess (2002) refer to as government activism: governmental responses to shocks to the population. In the previous section, we predicted that relief expenditures would be higher when crop yields are lower; in other words, when weather is more extreme. Table 3 tests various specifications for equation (2), using the different definitions of weather outlined above. 14 The optimal amount of rainfall does not vary significantly by state: all states fall within 0.5 to 1.5 standard deviations above the mean.

15 As Table 3 shows, state disaster relief spending does show the opposite relationship with rain from crop yields. The first two columns indicate that more rain, on average, is associated with less disaster relief. When a squared term for normalized district rainfall is included, we see that extreme amounts of rain lead to higher amounts of disaster spending particularly droughts. A minimum amount of disaster spending occurs at about one and a half standard deviations of rain above the mean in a district, as estimated in columns (3) and (4), consistent with our estimates of rain and agricultural yield, although the squared term in rain is not significant, suggesting that disaster expenditure particularly increases during droughts. The point estimates in columns (5) through (6) indicate that as rainfall moves one standard deviation further from the optimum, disaster spending goes up by percentage points. All of these relationships are statistically significant at standard levels. Besley and Burgess (2002) present some evidence on what factors affect the general level of government response to droughts. They find that economic factors play little to no role. Urbanization, log state income, budget transfers from the central government, and share of population that is rural do not predict calamity relief expenditures. 15 Budget transfers from the central government for the purpose of calamity relief were often provided as matching funds, directly proportional to the amount spent by the state. 16 Voters are unimpressed, on average Poor weather reduces crop yields, which makes voters worse off, but also generates government response, which provides tangible evidence of politicians desire and ability to help the public. What is the net effect of poor weather on support for the ruling party? In this section, we measure the effect of rainfall shocks on the vote share for the ruling party. 15 Their paper does demonstrate an important role of the media in determining the level of government responsiveness. Our results are unaffected by including measures of media distribution (results available upon request). 16 For a discussion of India s historical calamity relief management, see a speech given on June 25, 2004 by C. S. Rao ( last accessed May 24, 2008). We do not include spending by non-governmental organizations in our analysis. Winchester (2000) argues that while NGOs may be efficient providers of disaster relief, only the government has the resources and scale to have meaningful impact on large-scale natural disasters.

16 We start by graphing the basic relationship between rainfall and voting behavior in India. Figure 1 gives the average vote share of the ruling party by rainfall category: the bar graph gives the mean for each indicated bin; the line gives results from a nonparametric regression. The ruling party does very poorly during extreme droughts, but its performance increases steadily with rainfall, reaching an optimum at a point between 0 and 1 standard deviations above the mean. As rainfall exceeds this optimum, support for the ruling party declines. This relationship mirrors the relationship between rain and crop yields in the previous section. In Panel B, we present a falsification test, plotting the relationship between current rain and the vote share for the ruling party s vote share in the previous election. For example, in Panel A the 1987 West Bengal electoral outcomes is correctly matched to 1986 weather; in Panel B, we instead match 1982 elections to 1986 weather. As expected, there is no effect of rain for this control group, confirming that there is nothing mechanical behind these relationships. Panel C compares how the ruling coalition s vote share depends on the rain when it is also the incumbent in the constituency, compared to when it is not. In both cases, the same pattern obtains, but the ruling party s vote share is much more sensitive to rainfall when it also controls the constituency. One way to measure this is to calculate how much the party suffers, on average, when rainfall drops from 0-1 standard deviations above the district average to a level more than 2 standard deviations below the district average. Such a drop would penalize the ruling party by 9.8 percentage points if the constituency s parliamentarian was part of the ruling coalition; it would cost the ruling coalition only 2.9 percentage points if it did not control the constituency. When we control for year and district effects, we show that much of this gap disappears. Still, it appears to be the case that the ruling party is hurt more when it also controls the constituency. This evidence suggests that some blame for weather-induced income losses goes to the incumbent parliamentarian in the constituency and not just simply to the ruling coalition. Table 4 presents regression results estimating the relationship between voting decisions and rainfall. The shape of the relationship between rain and the ruling party s vote share closely resembles the shape of the relationship between rain and crop yields. The coefficient on rain is positive and significant across all specifications; the coefficient

17 on the quadratic term is negative and significant. Likewise, increases in the deviation of rain from the optimal amount causes incumbents to lose vote share. The results in columns (5) and (6) of Table 4 indicate that rainfall one standard deviation from the optimum causes a drop of more than 3 percentage points in the vote that the ruling party receives. The specification in column (6), which includes district fixed effects, gives an estimate that a one standard deviation worsening of the weather will cost the incumbent party 3.25 percentage points of the vote. Given that one-fourth of the contests in our sample are decided by a margin of 5.26 percentage points or less, rainfall is an important determinant of electoral outcomes. We also test formally the pattern in Panel C of Figure 1, by separately estimating the effect of rainfall on whether this effect is different for incumbents affiliated with the ruling majority versus those who are not. The graphical pattern holds: in our preferred specification, using standard deviations from optimum rain with year and district fixed effects, we find that the ruling coalition suffers a loss of 4.2 percentage points (t = -3.18) when it controls the constituency, compared to a penalty of only 1.8 (t = -1.49) for politicians not affiliated with the incumbent party. 17 Heterogeneous impact The effect of rain need not be constant across time or space. An advantage of our setting is the very large number of elections, combined with detailed data at the district level, which allows us to test for heterogeneous effects. Leigh (2004) shows that voters in more educated countries are less likely to reward their leaders for swings in the global economy beyond their leaders control. He interprets this as evidence that better informed voters are more rational. In Table 5, we investigate the possibility that different kinds of voter characteristics may predict a higher tendency to respond to the weather. We consider two characteristics: the share of farm households in a district and the literacy rate in a district. Each of these variables comes from the Indian Census, so we only observe data from the years 1971, 1981, and If the vote share that the incumbent party receives in a constituency is used as the dependent variable instead of the share of the share for the ruling coalition, generally similar results are obtained. Rainfall has a significant effect on the vote share received by the incumbent party when it is part of the ruling coalition, but it has no significant effect on the vote share it receives when it is not part of the coalition.

18 We use a district s 1981 literacy rate to proxy for its literacy rate for each election from For each variable, we include the variable by itself as well as its interaction with the number of standard deviations of rain from the district optimal amount. For the interaction terms, we use the deviation of rainfall from its mean amount in the dataset. Centering the interaction in does not affect the coefficient on the interaction term; it does allow estimation of the coefficient on the linear term at the mean value of rain. In columns (1) - (2), we present results for share involved in agriculture, columns (3) - (4) adds literacy rate, and (5) - (6) include each of these variables in the same specifications. Somewhat surprisingly, we find no significant effects, although the estimated coefficients have the expected signs. The point estimates suggest that farming districts may punish the incumbent more for weather shocks, and literate districts less. Do voters reward the government for responding to a crisis? Even though voters, on average, appear to punish governments for extreme weather beyond their control, we might expect voters to condition their responses on how well politicians respond to extreme weather. A responsive electorate would punish politicians who deal poorly with a weather-caused crisis, but also reward politicians who demonstrate their competence by effectively dealing with a crisis. To determine how voters responses to extreme weather are affected by government response to that event, we look at natural disaster relief expenditures made by the government during the year of an election, and interact it with the weather variable. 18 (4) VoteShare dct = α + γ d + τ t + β*weather dt-1 + λ*relief st + δ*weather dt-1 *relief st + e dt If voters do respond to the presence of disaster spending in the face of bad weather, then we would expect that δ would be positive in the above regressions. 19 We note that there 18 We do not lag relief expenditures because they correspond to the fiscal year leading up to the calendar year thus covering the rainy season under analysis. 19 Khemani (2004) finds that overall state expenditure does not vary in election years, although the composition of taxes does. We do not find an election year effect on disaster relief spending (p =.77).

19 is tremendous heterogeneity in government response, and the variance in relief spending increases in the severity of the weather. Table 6 reports the results of estimating equation (4). 20 We find that voters do indeed reward politicians for disaster spending in response to extreme weather, with δ positive, and consistently significant across all specifications. To understand the magnitude of the coefficient estimate, consider the implied effect that rainfall becoming one standard deviation further from optimal has on disaster expenditure. With state effects, Table 3 indicates that rain becoming one standard deviation further from optimal leads to an increase in log disaster spending of Combining this result with the estimate from Table 6, we estimate that a party which responds to bad rainfall with an average increase in disaster spending will gain about 0.52 percentage points of vote share (0.178*2.91) compared to a coalition that does not increase its disaster response when the weather shock occurs. Since a one standard deviation worsening in weather costs the incumbent party 3.25 percentage points of the vote share on average, failing to respond in the face of a crisis should lead to an average cost of 3.77 percent. Thus an average disaster response offsets about one seventh of the electoral cost of the bad weather. We likewise estimate that a government with a twice-average response would offset about one quarter of the cost of the shock. In other words, the weather still hurts the ruling coalition even when they respond vigorously, but less so. Voters do not filter out entirely the effect of weather, and punish the ruling coalition even for circumstances beyond its control. However, at least some voters do reward responsive governments. Robustness Finding that voters are more likely to reelect an incumbent who has responded well to an emergency does not necessarily imply that the voters are directly rewarding the government for its responsiveness during the crisis. A second possibility is that that our measure of government responsiveness (rainfall shock interacted with relief spending) 20 We note that λ, the coefficient of voting on relief, is negative although small and insignificant most likely reflecting the electoral effect of non-rainfall catastrophe. This relationship persists with nearly identical coefficients if we include controls for a higher-order polynomial in rainfall.

20 simply picks up the general competence level of the state government. After all, a government that responds well to one crisis may just be a better government, and therefore do better at the ballot box for a whole host of reasons; crisis management might play only a small part. While this alternative interpretation is consistent with the broader theme of the paper, two pieces of evidence suggest that our narrower, crisis-management interpretation is correct First, in Appendix 1 we add a number of controls at the state level to our preferred specification in Table 6 that should be correlated with general government competence. None of these variables state GDP growth, change in cash balances, and budget deficits is a perfect measure of government behavior; yet, they are likely correlated with voters perception of the quality of government. As can be seen in the table, the addition of these controls has little impact on the coefficient of rainfall shock interacted with relief spending: it is still statistically and economically quite significant. Second, we take advantage of non election-year data in an attempt to control for unobservable characteristics of the state government. Our test derives from the welldocumented recency-bias, identified in the psychology literature (Calkins 1896), that individuals put greater weight on more recent events. While general government competence is likely correlated with crisis response, it is unlikely to be correlated with crises only in certain years. On the other hand, voters may be better at recollecting government responses to crises that occurred more recently. Thus, controlling for government responsiveness to crises in non-recent years will control for some of the unobserved general government competence that is correlated with crisis response. In Table A2, we first present strong evidence for the recency bias, by considering separately rainfall the year prior to the election and rainfall in the year before that. Columns (1) and (2) provide strong evidence of this bias: rainfall from more than one year prior to the election does not affect the electorate s decision. Similarly, we find that, in the earlier year, there is no relationship between vote share for the incumbent coalition and our measure of responsiveness, the interaction between relief expenditure and rainfall (columns (3) and (4)). If our measures were picking up general competence of the government, we might expect the same relationship throughout the electoral cycle, or for the coefficient on responsiveness in the year prior to

21 the election to diminish. Yet we find the coefficient on recent crisis response maintains its magnitude and significance, while on earlier years is economically and statistically insignificant. Taken together, the results from these two tables suggest that endogeneity concerns are not that important in this context. V. Are Major Crises Different? Sen s contention that democracies do better at responding to major disasters than to quiet emergencies may stem not from the ability of the opposition to shame the incumbent, as he argues, but rather from the inherent biases of voters. We can investigate whether voters are more sensitive to government responsiveness to major crises than they are to minor crises. As it turns out, the data suggest that extreme rainfall events, relative to less severe events, do present an opportunity for the ruling coalition to gain. Most coalitions do not gain from extreme crises, but the data suggests that particularly good responses may at least not hurt the ruling coalition in this case. We define bad weather as rainfall in the 80 th to 90 th percentiles away from the optimal amount, and extreme weather as rainfall in the 90 th to 100 th percentiles away from the optimal amount. Table 7 measures how governments respond to bad weather and extreme weather. Compared to the omitted category of good weather, bad weather results in a 16-percent increase in relief spending, much smaller than the 57-percent increase during bouts of extreme weather (We report the numbers from column (2), which includes state and year fixedeffects). The coefficients thus suggest that government relief aid increases four times as much during the most severe weather events. The results in columns (3) - (4) attempt to separate these differences into those that occur in election years and those that occur in other years. We observe no significant effects in this decomposition. The highly non-linear response of government spending to weather would not be surprising if extreme weather was substantially worse for crop yields than bad weather. However, when we regress log crop yield on dummies for bad and extreme weather in columns (1) through (2) of Table 8, we find the impact on agricultural yield is less severe. In the specification with district and year fixed effects, bad weather results in an 8- percent decline in agricultural output, while extreme weather causes a 12-percent drop in

22 output. The declines in yields associated with both bad and extreme weather may well be large enough to create food crises: the Great Bengal Famine of 1943 was associated with a 5-percent reduction in food output (Sen 1981, p. 58), while the Ethiopia famine of involved an 11 percent decline (Drèze 1990). This suggests that a competent government responding optimally to drought is likely to respond not only in cases of severe bad weather, but also in instances of bad weather. However, we observe large responses only in cases of severe weather. In columns (3) through (4) we explore nonlinear effects of severe weather on voting. Bad weather costs the ruling coalition 4.0 percent of the vote and extreme weather 6.2 percent of the vote, on average, compared to good weather. Ignoring heterogeneity in response, then, we find that voters punish the ruling coalition more for extreme weather than for bad weather even as the government is more responsive to extreme weather events. In the bottom panel of Table 8 we examine the relationship between extreme weather, disaster expenditure, and voting behavior. The results are striking. Voters are twice as sensitive to relief spending during extreme weather as they are to relief spending during bad weather. As column (2) indicates, an increase in log relief spending of 1 (for example, by increasing per capita expenditure from Rs. 5 per person to Rs per person) in response to bad weather will lead to an increase of more than 3 percent in the ruling coalition s vote share, while the same increase in response to extreme weather generates a nearly 7-percent increase in vote share. These effects are estimated precisely; the difference between the two effects is statistically significant (p =.032). Although the estimates are statistically precise, we note the limitations of this approach. Since we do not have district-level data on relief, we cannot rule out the possibility that the districts worst hit by the climactic shock are also receiving the most relief. Moreover, since we cannot observe other kinds of relief -like visits from politicians, the higher elasticity to measured relief aid under extreme weather may simply be capturing other crisis responses that are, themselves, nonlinear in the severity of the shock. Given the above caveat, these estimates indicate that a government that reacts with an average response to an extreme weather event will do about 3.8 percent (0.566*6.72) better than a government that fails to increase its response when the drought

Do Voters Demand Responsive Governments? Evidence from Indian Disaster Relief

Do Voters Demand Responsive Governments? Evidence from Indian Disaster Relief Digital Commons@ Loyola Marymount University and Loyola Law School Economics Faculty Works Economics 3-1-2012 Do Voters Demand Responsive Governments? Evidence from Indian Disaster Relief Shawn Cole Harvard

More information

Women s Education and Women s Political Participation

Women s Education and Women s Political Participation 2014/ED/EFA/MRT/PI/23 Background paper prepared for the Education for All Global Monitoring Report 2013/4 Teaching and learning: Achieving quality for all Women s Education and Women s Political Participation

More information

Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US

Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US Ben Ost a and Eva Dziadula b a Department of Economics, University of Illinois at Chicago, 601 South Morgan UH718 M/C144 Chicago,

More information

Political Economics II Spring Lectures 4-5 Part II Partisan Politics and Political Agency. Torsten Persson, IIES

Political Economics II Spring Lectures 4-5 Part II Partisan Politics and Political Agency. Torsten Persson, IIES Lectures 4-5_190213.pdf Political Economics II Spring 2019 Lectures 4-5 Part II Partisan Politics and Political Agency Torsten Persson, IIES 1 Introduction: Partisan Politics Aims continue exploring policy

More information

Can Politicians Police Themselves? Natural Experimental Evidence from Brazil s Audit Courts Supplementary Appendix

Can Politicians Police Themselves? Natural Experimental Evidence from Brazil s Audit Courts Supplementary Appendix Can Politicians Police Themselves? Natural Experimental Evidence from Brazil s Audit Courts Supplementary Appendix F. Daniel Hidalgo MIT Júlio Canello IESP Renato Lima-de-Oliveira MIT December 16, 215

More information

Research Report. How Does Trade Liberalization Affect Racial and Gender Identity in Employment? Evidence from PostApartheid South Africa

Research Report. How Does Trade Liberalization Affect Racial and Gender Identity in Employment? Evidence from PostApartheid South Africa International Affairs Program Research Report How Does Trade Liberalization Affect Racial and Gender Identity in Employment? Evidence from PostApartheid South Africa Report Prepared by Bilge Erten Assistant

More information

Online Appendix: Robustness Tests and Migration. Means

Online Appendix: Robustness Tests and Migration. Means VOL. VOL NO. ISSUE EMPLOYMENT, WAGES AND VOTER TURNOUT Online Appendix: Robustness Tests and Migration Means Online Appendix Table 1 presents the summary statistics of turnout for the five types of elections

More information

Model of Voting. February 15, Abstract. This paper uses United States congressional district level data to identify how incumbency,

Model of Voting. February 15, Abstract. This paper uses United States congressional district level data to identify how incumbency, U.S. Congressional Vote Empirics: A Discrete Choice Model of Voting Kyle Kretschman The University of Texas Austin kyle.kretschman@mail.utexas.edu Nick Mastronardi United States Air Force Academy nickmastronardi@gmail.com

More information

Publicizing malfeasance:

Publicizing malfeasance: Publicizing malfeasance: When media facilitates electoral accountability in Mexico Horacio Larreguy, John Marshall and James Snyder Harvard University May 1, 2015 Introduction Elections are key for political

More information

Non-Voted Ballots and Discrimination in Florida

Non-Voted Ballots and Discrimination in Florida Non-Voted Ballots and Discrimination in Florida John R. Lott, Jr. School of Law Yale University 127 Wall Street New Haven, CT 06511 (203) 432-2366 john.lott@yale.edu revised July 15, 2001 * This paper

More information

Women and Power: Unpopular, Unwilling, or Held Back? Comment

Women and Power: Unpopular, Unwilling, or Held Back? Comment Women and Power: Unpopular, Unwilling, or Held Back? Comment Manuel Bagues, Pamela Campa May 22, 2017 Abstract Casas-Arce and Saiz (2015) study how gender quotas in candidate lists affect voting behavior

More information

Subhasish Dey, University of York Kunal Sen,University of Manchester & UNU-WIDER NDCDE, 2018, UNU-WIDER, Helsinki 12 th June 2018

Subhasish Dey, University of York Kunal Sen,University of Manchester & UNU-WIDER NDCDE, 2018, UNU-WIDER, Helsinki 12 th June 2018 Do Political Parties Practise Partisan Alignment in Social Welfare Spending? Evidence from Village Council Elections in India Subhasish Dey, University of York Kunal Sen,University of Manchester & UNU-WIDER

More information

Prologue Djankov et al. (2002) Reinikka & Svensson (2004) Besley & Burgess (2002) Epilogue. Media and Policy

Prologue Djankov et al. (2002) Reinikka & Svensson (2004) Besley & Burgess (2002) Epilogue. Media and Policy Media and Policy EC307 ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT Dr. Kumar Aniket University of Cambridge & LSE Summer School Lecture 2 created on June 30, 2009 READINGS Tables and figures in this lecture are taken from: Djankov,

More information

Being a Good Samaritan or just a politician? Empirical evidence of disaster assistance. Jeroen Klomp

Being a Good Samaritan or just a politician? Empirical evidence of disaster assistance. Jeroen Klomp Being a Good Samaritan or just a politician? Empirical evidence of disaster assistance Jeroen Klomp Netherlands Defence Academy & Wageningen University and Research The Netherlands Introduction Since 1970

More information

Does opportunism pay off?

Does opportunism pay off? Does opportunism pay off? Linda G. Veiga, Francisco José Veiga Universidade do Minho and NIPE, Portugal Received 22 June 2006; received in revised form 1 December 2006; accepted 20 December 2006 Available

More information

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr Abstract. The Asian experience of poverty reduction has varied widely. Over recent decades the economies of East and Southeast Asia

More information

political budget cycles

political budget cycles P000346 Theoretical and empirical research on is surveyed and discussed. Significant are seen to be primarily a phenomenon of the first elections after the transition to a democratic electoral system.

More information

Immigrant Legalization

Immigrant Legalization Technical Appendices Immigrant Legalization Assessing the Labor Market Effects Laura Hill Magnus Lofstrom Joseph Hayes Contents Appendix A. Data from the 2003 New Immigrant Survey Appendix B. Measuring

More information

Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation

Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation S. Roy*, Department of Economics, High Point University, High Point, NC - 27262, USA. Email: sroy@highpoint.edu Abstract We implement OLS,

More information

Uncertainty and international return migration: some evidence from linked register data

Uncertainty and international return migration: some evidence from linked register data Applied Economics Letters, 2012, 19, 1893 1897 Uncertainty and international return migration: some evidence from linked register data Jan Saarela a, * and Dan-Olof Rooth b a A bo Akademi University, PO

More information

Supplementary Tables for Online Publication: Impact of Judicial Elections in the Sentencing of Black Crime

Supplementary Tables for Online Publication: Impact of Judicial Elections in the Sentencing of Black Crime Supplementary Tables for Online Publication: Impact of Judicial Elections in the Sentencing of Black Crime Kyung H. Park Wellesley College March 23, 2016 A Kansas Background A.1 Partisan versus Retention

More information

Table A.2 reports the complete set of estimates of equation (1). We distinguish between personal

Table A.2 reports the complete set of estimates of equation (1). We distinguish between personal Akay, Bargain and Zimmermann Online Appendix 40 A. Online Appendix A.1. Descriptive Statistics Figure A.1 about here Table A.1 about here A.2. Detailed SWB Estimates Table A.2 reports the complete set

More information

Legislatures and Growth

Legislatures and Growth Legislatures and Growth Andrew Jonelis andrew.jonelis@uky.edu 219.718.5703 550 S Limestone, Lexington KY 40506 Gatton College of Business and Economics, University of Kentucky Abstract This paper documents

More information

Political Reservation and Substantive Representation: Evidence from Indian Panchayats

Political Reservation and Substantive Representation: Evidence from Indian Panchayats Political Reservation and Substantive Representation: Evidence from Indian Panchayats Esther Duflo (based on joint work with Lori Beaman, Raghabendra Chattopadhyay, Rohini Pande and Petia Topalova October

More information

By Any Means Necessary: Multiple Avenues of Political Cycles

By Any Means Necessary: Multiple Avenues of Political Cycles By Any Means Necessary: Multiple Avenues of Political Cycles Andrew 2014 EITM Summer Institute University of Houston June 22, 2014 Motivation Are Political Budget Cycles (PBCs) the only tool an incumbent

More information

Prologue Djankov et al. (2002) Reinikka & Svensson (2004) Besley & Burgess (2002) Epilogue. Media and Policy. Dr. Kumar Aniket

Prologue Djankov et al. (2002) Reinikka & Svensson (2004) Besley & Burgess (2002) Epilogue. Media and Policy. Dr. Kumar Aniket Media and Policy EC307 ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT Dr. Kumar Aniket University of Cambridge & LSE Summer School Lecture 2 created on June 6, 2010 READINGS Tables and figures in this lecture are taken from: Djankov,

More information

CAN FAIR VOTING SYSTEMS REALLY MAKE A DIFFERENCE?

CAN FAIR VOTING SYSTEMS REALLY MAKE A DIFFERENCE? CAN FAIR VOTING SYSTEMS REALLY MAKE A DIFFERENCE? Facts and figures from Arend Lijphart s landmark study: Patterns of Democracy: Government Forms and Performance in Thirty-Six Countries Prepared by: Fair

More information

Incumbency as a Source of Spillover Effects in Mixed Electoral Systems: Evidence from a Regression-Discontinuity Design.

Incumbency as a Source of Spillover Effects in Mixed Electoral Systems: Evidence from a Regression-Discontinuity Design. Incumbency as a Source of Spillover Effects in Mixed Electoral Systems: Evidence from a Regression-Discontinuity Design Forthcoming, Electoral Studies Web Supplement Jens Hainmueller Holger Lutz Kern September

More information

Workshop / Atelier. Disaster Risk Financing and Insurance (DRFI) Financement et Assurance des Risques de Désastres Naturels

Workshop / Atelier. Disaster Risk Financing and Insurance (DRFI) Financement et Assurance des Risques de Désastres Naturels Workshop / Atelier Disaster Risk Financing and Insurance (DRFI) Financement et Assurance des Risques de Désastres Naturels Thursday-Friday, June 4-5, 2015 Jeudi-Vendredi 4-5 Juin 2015 Voters Response to

More information

Guns and Butter in U.S. Presidential Elections

Guns and Butter in U.S. Presidential Elections Guns and Butter in U.S. Presidential Elections by Stephen E. Haynes and Joe A. Stone September 20, 2004 Working Paper No. 91 Department of Economics, University of Oregon Abstract: Previous models of the

More information

Does Political Competition Reduce Ethnic Discrimination?

Does Political Competition Reduce Ethnic Discrimination? Does Political Competition Reduce Ethnic Discrimination? Evidence from the Samurdhi Food Stamp Program in Sri Lanka Iffath Sharif Senior Economist South Asia Social Protection February 14, 2011 Presentation

More information

Practice Questions for Exam #2

Practice Questions for Exam #2 Fall 2007 Page 1 Practice Questions for Exam #2 1. Suppose that we have collected a stratified random sample of 1,000 Hispanic adults and 1,000 non-hispanic adults. These respondents are asked whether

More information

Supplementary Materials for Strategic Abstention in Proportional Representation Systems (Evidence from Multiple Countries)

Supplementary Materials for Strategic Abstention in Proportional Representation Systems (Evidence from Multiple Countries) Supplementary Materials for Strategic Abstention in Proportional Representation Systems (Evidence from Multiple Countries) Guillem Riambau July 15, 2018 1 1 Construction of variables and descriptive statistics.

More information

A Global Economy-Climate Model with High Regional Resolution

A Global Economy-Climate Model with High Regional Resolution A Global Economy-Climate Model with High Regional Resolution Per Krusell Institute for International Economic Studies, CEPR, NBER Anthony A. Smith, Jr. Yale University, NBER February 6, 2015 The project

More information

Supplemental Online Appendix to The Incumbency Curse: Weak Parties, Term Limits, and Unfulfilled Accountability

Supplemental Online Appendix to The Incumbency Curse: Weak Parties, Term Limits, and Unfulfilled Accountability Supplemental Online Appendix to The Incumbency Curse: Weak Parties, Term Limits, and Unfulfilled Accountability Marko Klašnja Rocío Titiunik Post-Doctoral Fellow Princeton University Assistant Professor

More information

Electoral Rules and Public Goods Outcomes in Brazilian Municipalities

Electoral Rules and Public Goods Outcomes in Brazilian Municipalities Electoral Rules and Public Goods Outcomes in Brazilian Municipalities This paper investigates the ways in which plurality and majority systems impact the provision of public goods using a regression discontinuity

More information

Openness and Poverty Reduction in the Long and Short Run. Mark R. Rosenzweig. Harvard University. October 2003

Openness and Poverty Reduction in the Long and Short Run. Mark R. Rosenzweig. Harvard University. October 2003 Openness and Poverty Reduction in the Long and Short Run Mark R. Rosenzweig Harvard University October 2003 Prepared for the Conference on The Future of Globalization Yale University. October 10-11, 2003

More information

Determinants and Effects of Negative Advertising in Politics

Determinants and Effects of Negative Advertising in Politics Department of Economics- FEA/USP Determinants and Effects of Negative Advertising in Politics DANILO P. SOUZA MARCOS Y. NAKAGUMA WORKING PAPER SERIES Nº 2017-25 DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS, FEA-USP WORKING

More information

Partisan Advantage and Competitiveness in Illinois Redistricting

Partisan Advantage and Competitiveness in Illinois Redistricting Partisan Advantage and Competitiveness in Illinois Redistricting An Updated and Expanded Look By: Cynthia Canary & Kent Redfield June 2015 Using data from the 2014 legislative elections and digging deeper

More information

Rural and Urban Migrants in India:

Rural and Urban Migrants in India: Rural and Urban Migrants in India: 1983-2008 Viktoria Hnatkovska and Amartya Lahiri July 2014 Abstract This paper characterizes the gross and net migration flows between rural and urban areas in India

More information

A positive correlation between turnout and plurality does not refute the rational voter model

A positive correlation between turnout and plurality does not refute the rational voter model Quality & Quantity 26: 85-93, 1992. 85 O 1992 Kluwer Academic Publishers. Printed in the Netherlands. Note A positive correlation between turnout and plurality does not refute the rational voter model

More information

Do Parties Matter for Fiscal Policy Choices? A Regression-Discontinuity Approach

Do Parties Matter for Fiscal Policy Choices? A Regression-Discontinuity Approach Do Parties Matter for Fiscal Policy Choices? A Regression-Discontinuity Approach Per Pettersson-Lidbom First version: May 1, 2001 This version: July 3, 2003 Abstract This paper presents a method for measuring

More information

Corruption, Political Instability and Firm-Level Export Decisions. Kul Kapri 1 Rowan University. August 2018

Corruption, Political Instability and Firm-Level Export Decisions. Kul Kapri 1 Rowan University. August 2018 Corruption, Political Instability and Firm-Level Export Decisions Kul Kapri 1 Rowan University August 2018 Abstract In this paper I use South Asian firm-level data to examine whether the impact of corruption

More information

B R E A D Working Paper

B R E A D Working Paper Can Mandated Political Representation Increase Policy Influence for Disadvantaged Minorities? Theory and Evidence from India Rohini Pande BREAD Working Paper No. 024 April 2003 Copyright 2003 Rohini Pande

More information

Democratic Tipping Points

Democratic Tipping Points Democratic Tipping Points Antonio Ciccone March 2018 Barcelona GSE Working Paper Series Working Paper nº 1026 Democratic Tipping Points Antonio Ciccone March 2018 Abstract I examine whether transitory

More information

Pavel Yakovlev Duquesne University. Abstract

Pavel Yakovlev Duquesne University. Abstract Ideology, Shirking, and the Incumbency Advantage in the U.S. House of Representatives Pavel Yakovlev Duquesne University Abstract This paper examines how the incumbency advantage is related to ideological

More information

The Case of the Disappearing Bias: A 2014 Update to the Gerrymandering or Geography Debate

The Case of the Disappearing Bias: A 2014 Update to the Gerrymandering or Geography Debate The Case of the Disappearing Bias: A 2014 Update to the Gerrymandering or Geography Debate Nicholas Goedert Lafayette College goedertn@lafayette.edu May, 2015 ABSTRACT: This note observes that the pro-republican

More information

Remittances and Poverty. in Guatemala* Richard H. Adams, Jr. Development Research Group (DECRG) MSN MC World Bank.

Remittances and Poverty. in Guatemala* Richard H. Adams, Jr. Development Research Group (DECRG) MSN MC World Bank. Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Remittances and Poverty in Guatemala* Richard H. Adams, Jr. Development Research Group

More information

Path-Breakers: How Does Women s Political Participation Respond to Electoral Success? *

Path-Breakers: How Does Women s Political Participation Respond to Electoral Success? * Path-Breakers: How Does Women s Political Participation Respond to Electoral Success? * Sonia Bhalotra University of Bristol Irma Clots-Figueras Universidad Carlos III de Madrid Lakshmi Iyer Harvard Business

More information

Rural and Urban Migrants in India:

Rural and Urban Migrants in India: Rural and Urban Migrants in India: 1983 2008 Viktoria Hnatkovska and Amartya Lahiri This paper characterizes the gross and net migration flows between rural and urban areas in India during the period 1983

More information

Rainfall and Migration in Mexico Amy Teller and Leah K. VanWey Population Studies and Training Center Brown University Extended Abstract 9/27/2013

Rainfall and Migration in Mexico Amy Teller and Leah K. VanWey Population Studies and Training Center Brown University Extended Abstract 9/27/2013 Rainfall and Migration in Mexico Amy Teller and Leah K. VanWey Population Studies and Training Center Brown University Extended Abstract 9/27/2013 Demographers have become increasingly interested over

More information

AVOTE FOR PEROT WAS A VOTE FOR THE STATUS QUO

AVOTE FOR PEROT WAS A VOTE FOR THE STATUS QUO AVOTE FOR PEROT WAS A VOTE FOR THE STATUS QUO William A. Niskanen In 1992 Ross Perot received more votes than any prior third party candidate for president, and the vote for Perot in 1996 was only slightly

More information

Pork Barrel as a Signaling Tool: The Case of US Environmental Policy

Pork Barrel as a Signaling Tool: The Case of US Environmental Policy Pork Barrel as a Signaling Tool: The Case of US Environmental Policy Grantham Research Institute and LSE Cities, London School of Economics IAERE February 2016 Research question Is signaling a driving

More information

From Banerjee and Iyer (2005)

From Banerjee and Iyer (2005) From Banerjee and Iyer (2005) History, Institutions, and Economic Performance: The Legacy of Colonial Land Tenure Systems in India American Economic Review, Vol. 95, No. 4 (Sep., 2005), pp. 1190-1213 Similar

More information

English Deficiency and the Native-Immigrant Wage Gap

English Deficiency and the Native-Immigrant Wage Gap DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 7019 English Deficiency and the Native-Immigrant Wage Gap Alfonso Miranda Yu Zhu November 2012 Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit Institute for the Study of Labor

More information

Congressional Gridlock: The Effects of the Master Lever

Congressional Gridlock: The Effects of the Master Lever Congressional Gridlock: The Effects of the Master Lever Olga Gorelkina Max Planck Institute, Bonn Ioanna Grypari Max Planck Institute, Bonn Preliminary & Incomplete February 11, 2015 Abstract This paper

More information

Volume 35, Issue 1. An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach

Volume 35, Issue 1. An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach Volume 35, Issue 1 An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach Brian Hibbs Indiana University South Bend Gihoon Hong Indiana University South Bend Abstract This

More information

SocialSecurityEligibilityandtheLaborSuplyofOlderImigrants. George J. Borjas Harvard University

SocialSecurityEligibilityandtheLaborSuplyofOlderImigrants. George J. Borjas Harvard University SocialSecurityEligibilityandtheLaborSuplyofOlderImigrants George J. Borjas Harvard University February 2010 1 SocialSecurityEligibilityandtheLaborSuplyofOlderImigrants George J. Borjas ABSTRACT The employment

More information

On the Causes and Consequences of Ballot Order Effects

On the Causes and Consequences of Ballot Order Effects Polit Behav (2013) 35:175 197 DOI 10.1007/s11109-011-9189-2 ORIGINAL PAPER On the Causes and Consequences of Ballot Order Effects Marc Meredith Yuval Salant Published online: 6 January 2012 Ó Springer

More information

Incumbency Advantages in the Canadian Parliament

Incumbency Advantages in the Canadian Parliament Incumbency Advantages in the Canadian Parliament Chad Kendall Department of Economics University of British Columbia Marie Rekkas* Department of Economics Simon Fraser University mrekkas@sfu.ca 778-782-6793

More information

Disasters and Incumbent Electoral Fortunes: No Implications for Democratic Competence

Disasters and Incumbent Electoral Fortunes: No Implications for Democratic Competence Disasters and Incumbent Electoral Fortunes: No Implications for Democratic Competence Scott Ashworth Ethan Bueno de Mesquita February 1, 2013 Abstract A recent empirical literature shows that incumbent

More information

Gender and Elections: An examination of the 2006 Canadian Federal Election

Gender and Elections: An examination of the 2006 Canadian Federal Election Gender and Elections: An examination of the 2006 Canadian Federal Election Marie Rekkas Department of Economics Simon Fraser University 8888 University Drive Burnaby, BC V5A 1S6 mrekkas@sfu.ca 778-782-6793

More information

Rainfall, Financial Development, and Remittances: Evidence from Sub-Saharan Africa

Rainfall, Financial Development, and Remittances: Evidence from Sub-Saharan Africa Rainfall, Financial Development, and Remittances: Evidence from Sub-Saharan Africa by Rabah Arezki and Markus Brückner September 2011 Abstract: We use annual variations in rainfall to examine the effects

More information

Are Female Leaders Good for Education? Evidence from India.

Are Female Leaders Good for Education? Evidence from India. Are Female Leaders Good for Education? Evidence from India. Irma Clots-Figueras Department of Economics, London School of Economics JOB MARKET PAPER October 2005 Abstract This paper studies the impact

More information

Benefit levels and US immigrants welfare receipts

Benefit levels and US immigrants welfare receipts 1 Benefit levels and US immigrants welfare receipts 1970 1990 by Joakim Ruist Department of Economics University of Gothenburg Box 640 40530 Gothenburg, Sweden joakim.ruist@economics.gu.se telephone: +46

More information

Voter Rationality and Exogenous Shocks: Misattribution of Responsibility for Economic Shocks

Voter Rationality and Exogenous Shocks: Misattribution of Responsibility for Economic Shocks Voter Rationality and Exogenous Shocks: Misattribution of Responsibility for Economic Shocks ABSTRACT Elections serve as a democratic mechanism to hold leaders accountable for their actions. Voters are

More information

1. The Relationship Between Party Control, Latino CVAP and the Passage of Bills Benefitting Immigrants

1. The Relationship Between Party Control, Latino CVAP and the Passage of Bills Benefitting Immigrants The Ideological and Electoral Determinants of Laws Targeting Undocumented Migrants in the U.S. States Online Appendix In this additional methodological appendix I present some alternative model specifications

More information

The Interdependence of Sequential Senate Elections: Evidence from

The Interdependence of Sequential Senate Elections: Evidence from The Interdependence of Sequential Senate Elections: Evidence from 1946-2002 Daniel M. Butler Stanford University Department of Political Science September 27, 2004 Abstract Among U.S. federal elections,

More information

A Vote Equation and the 2004 Election

A Vote Equation and the 2004 Election A Vote Equation and the 2004 Election Ray C. Fair November 22, 2004 1 Introduction My presidential vote equation is a great teaching example for introductory econometrics. 1 The theory is straightforward,

More information

Does Political Business Cycle exist in India? By

Does Political Business Cycle exist in India? By Does Political Business Cycle exist in India? By Ashok K Nag* Extended Abstract There exists a vast literature inquiring and modelling the nexus between politics and macroeconomic policy making. Mostly

More information

Schooling and Cohort Size: Evidence from Vietnam, Thailand, Iran and Cambodia. Evangelos M. Falaris University of Delaware. and

Schooling and Cohort Size: Evidence from Vietnam, Thailand, Iran and Cambodia. Evangelos M. Falaris University of Delaware. and Schooling and Cohort Size: Evidence from Vietnam, Thailand, Iran and Cambodia by Evangelos M. Falaris University of Delaware and Thuan Q. Thai Max Planck Institute for Demographic Research March 2012 2

More information

Amy Tenhouse. Incumbency Surge: Examining the 1996 Margin of Victory for U.S. House Incumbents

Amy Tenhouse. Incumbency Surge: Examining the 1996 Margin of Victory for U.S. House Incumbents Amy Tenhouse Incumbency Surge: Examining the 1996 Margin of Victory for U.S. House Incumbents In 1996, the American public reelected 357 members to the United States House of Representatives; of those

More information

BJP s Demographic Dividend in the 2014 General Elections: An Empirical Analysis ±

BJP s Demographic Dividend in the 2014 General Elections: An Empirical Analysis ± BJP s Demographic Dividend in the 2014 General Elections: An Empirical Analysis ± Deepankar Basu and Kartik Misra! [Published in Economic and Political Weekly, Vol. 50, No. 3] 1. Introduction In the 2014

More information

Pathbreakers? Women's Electoral Success and Future Political Participation

Pathbreakers? Women's Electoral Success and Future Political Participation Pathbreakers? Women's Electoral Success and Future Political Participation Sonia Bhalotra, University of Essex Irma Clots-Figueras, Universidad Carlos III de Madrid Lakshmi Iyer, University of Notre Dame

More information

Election Outcomes and Individual Well-being: Evidence from British Panel Data

Election Outcomes and Individual Well-being: Evidence from British Panel Data Election Outcomes and Individual Well-being: Evidence from British Panel Data Daniel Gray, Harry Pickard and Luke Munford ISSN 1749-8368 SERPS no. 2018018 December 2018 Election Outcomes and Individual

More information

USING MULTI-MEMBER-DISTRICT ELECTIONS TO ESTIMATE THE SOURCES OF THE INCUMBENCY ADVANTAGE 1

USING MULTI-MEMBER-DISTRICT ELECTIONS TO ESTIMATE THE SOURCES OF THE INCUMBENCY ADVANTAGE 1 USING MULTI-MEMBER-DISTRICT ELECTIONS TO ESTIMATE THE SOURCES OF THE INCUMBENCY ADVANTAGE 1 Shigeo Hirano Department of Political Science Columbia University James M. Snyder, Jr. Departments of Political

More information

Online Appendix for Redistricting and the Causal Impact of Race on Voter Turnout

Online Appendix for Redistricting and the Causal Impact of Race on Voter Turnout Online Appendix for Redistricting and the Causal Impact of Race on Voter Turnout Bernard L. Fraga Contents Appendix A Details of Estimation Strategy 1 A.1 Hypotheses.....................................

More information

Political Budget Cycles in New versus Established Democracies

Political Budget Cycles in New versus Established Democracies Political Budget Cycles in New versus Established Democracies Adi Brender a and Allan Drazen *,b a Research Department, Bank of Israel, Jerusalem 91007, ISRAEL b Department of Economics, University of

More information

A REPLICATION OF THE POLITICAL DETERMINANTS OF FEDERAL EXPENDITURE AT THE STATE LEVEL (PUBLIC CHOICE, 2005) Stratford Douglas* and W.

A REPLICATION OF THE POLITICAL DETERMINANTS OF FEDERAL EXPENDITURE AT THE STATE LEVEL (PUBLIC CHOICE, 2005) Stratford Douglas* and W. A REPLICATION OF THE POLITICAL DETERMINANTS OF FEDERAL EXPENDITURE AT THE STATE LEVEL (PUBLIC CHOICE, 2005) by Stratford Douglas* and W. Robert Reed Revised, 26 December 2013 * Stratford Douglas, Department

More information

Trust, Growth and Political Stability. (Preliminary Draft)

Trust, Growth and Political Stability. (Preliminary Draft) Trust, Growth and Political Stability (Preliminary Draft) Nathan Nunn, Nancy Qian and Jaya Wen December 8, 2016 Abstract This paper makes a new observation: that economic recessions are less likely to

More information

Chapter Four: Chamber Competitiveness, Political Polarization, and Political Parties

Chapter Four: Chamber Competitiveness, Political Polarization, and Political Parties Chapter Four: Chamber Competitiveness, Political Polarization, and Political Parties Building off of the previous chapter in this dissertation, this chapter investigates the involvement of political parties

More information

HOW VULNERABLE IS THE MOLDOVAN ECONOMY

HOW VULNERABLE IS THE MOLDOVAN ECONOMY ECONOMIC ANALYSIS AND FORECAST PAPER NR. 1/2012 DATE: 27/02/2012 HOW VULNERABLE IS THE MOLDOVAN ECONOMY TO EXTERNAL ECONOMIC SHOCKS? FORECASTS FOR 2012 ADRIAN LUPUȘOR, ADRIAN BABIN, ANA POPA Summary: The

More information

Figure 2: Proportion of countries with an active civil war or civil conflict,

Figure 2: Proportion of countries with an active civil war or civil conflict, Figure 2: Proportion of countries with an active civil war or civil conflict, 1960-2006 Sources: Data based on UCDP/PRIO armed conflict database (N. P. Gleditsch et al., 2002; Harbom & Wallensteen, 2007).

More information

Weather Variability, Agriculture and Rural Migration: Evidence from India

Weather Variability, Agriculture and Rural Migration: Evidence from India Weather Variability, Agriculture and Rural Migration: Evidence from India Brinda Viswanathan & K.S. Kavi Kumar Madras School of Economics, Chennai Conference on Climate Change and Development Policy 27

More information

Educated Preferences: Explaining Attitudes Toward Immigration In Europe. Jens Hainmueller and Michael J. Hiscox. Last revised: December 2005

Educated Preferences: Explaining Attitudes Toward Immigration In Europe. Jens Hainmueller and Michael J. Hiscox. Last revised: December 2005 Educated Preferences: Explaining Attitudes Toward Immigration In Jens Hainmueller and Michael J. Hiscox Last revised: December 2005 Supplement III: Detailed Results for Different Cutoff points of the Dependent

More information

Voting for Parties or for Candidates: Do Electoral Institutions Make a Difference?

Voting for Parties or for Candidates: Do Electoral Institutions Make a Difference? Voting for Parties or for Candidates: Do Electoral Institutions Make a Difference? Elena Llaudet Department of Government Harvard University April 11, 2015 Abstract Little is known about how electoral

More information

Workers Remittances. and International Risk-Sharing

Workers Remittances. and International Risk-Sharing Workers Remittances and International Risk-Sharing Metodij Hadzi-Vaskov March 6, 2007 Abstract One of the most important potential benefits from the process of international financial integration is the

More information

Unequal Recovery, Labor Market Polarization, Race, and 2016 U.S. Presidential Election. Maoyong Fan and Anita Alves Pena 1

Unequal Recovery, Labor Market Polarization, Race, and 2016 U.S. Presidential Election. Maoyong Fan and Anita Alves Pena 1 Unequal Recovery, Labor Market Polarization, Race, and 2016 U.S. Presidential Election Maoyong Fan and Anita Alves Pena 1 Abstract: Growing income inequality and labor market polarization and increasing

More information

Politics Before Pupils? Electoral Cycles and School Resources in India

Politics Before Pupils? Electoral Cycles and School Resources in India Politics Before Pupils? Electoral Cycles and School Resources in India Sonja Fagernäs University of Sussex Panu Pelkonen University of Sussex CEE, London School of Economics and Political Science IZA 6

More information

The Trade Liberalization Effects of Regional Trade Agreements* Volker Nitsch Free University Berlin. Daniel M. Sturm. University of Munich

The Trade Liberalization Effects of Regional Trade Agreements* Volker Nitsch Free University Berlin. Daniel M. Sturm. University of Munich December 2, 2005 The Trade Liberalization Effects of Regional Trade Agreements* Volker Nitsch Free University Berlin Daniel M. Sturm University of Munich and CEPR Abstract Recent research suggests that

More information

There is a seemingly widespread view that inequality should not be a concern

There is a seemingly widespread view that inequality should not be a concern Chapter 11 Economic Growth and Poverty Reduction: Do Poor Countries Need to Worry about Inequality? Martin Ravallion There is a seemingly widespread view that inequality should not be a concern in countries

More information

Cleavages in Public Preferences about Globalization

Cleavages in Public Preferences about Globalization 3 Cleavages in Public Preferences about Globalization Given the evidence presented in chapter 2 on preferences about globalization policies, an important question to explore is whether any opinion cleavages

More information

Ohio State University

Ohio State University Fake News Did Have a Significant Impact on the Vote in the 2016 Election: Original Full-Length Version with Methodological Appendix By Richard Gunther, Paul A. Beck, and Erik C. Nisbet Ohio State University

More information

Labor Market Dropouts and Trends in the Wages of Black and White Men

Labor Market Dropouts and Trends in the Wages of Black and White Men Industrial & Labor Relations Review Volume 56 Number 4 Article 5 2003 Labor Market Dropouts and Trends in the Wages of Black and White Men Chinhui Juhn University of Houston Recommended Citation Juhn,

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES HOMEOWNERSHIP IN THE IMMIGRANT POPULATION. George J. Borjas. Working Paper

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES HOMEOWNERSHIP IN THE IMMIGRANT POPULATION. George J. Borjas. Working Paper NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES HOMEOWNERSHIP IN THE IMMIGRANT POPULATION George J. Borjas Working Paper 8945 http://www.nber.org/papers/w8945 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge,

More information

The Impact of Interprovincial Migration on Aggregate Output and Labour Productivity in Canada,

The Impact of Interprovincial Migration on Aggregate Output and Labour Productivity in Canada, The Impact of Interprovincial Migration on Aggregate Output and Labour Productivity in Canada, 1987-26 Andrew Sharpe, Jean-Francois Arsenault, and Daniel Ershov 1 Centre for the Study of Living Standards

More information

Retrospective Voting

Retrospective Voting Retrospective Voting Who Are Retrospective Voters and Does it Matter if the Incumbent President is Running Kaitlin Franks Senior Thesis In Economics Adviser: Richard Ball 4/30/2009 Abstract Prior literature

More information

Political Parties and Economic

Political Parties and Economic Political Parties and Economic Outcomes. A Review Louis-Philippe Beland 1 Abstract This paper presents a review of the impact of the political parties of US governors on key economic outcomes. It presents

More information

Runoff Elections and the Number of Presidential Candidates A Regression Discontinuity Design Using Brazilian Municipalities

Runoff Elections and the Number of Presidential Candidates A Regression Discontinuity Design Using Brazilian Municipalities Runoff Elections and the Number of Presidential Candidates A Regression Discontinuity Design Using Brazilian Municipalities Timothy J. Power University of Oxford Rodrigo Rodrigues-Silveira University of

More information

Residual Wage Inequality: A Re-examination* Thomas Lemieux University of British Columbia. June Abstract

Residual Wage Inequality: A Re-examination* Thomas Lemieux University of British Columbia. June Abstract Residual Wage Inequality: A Re-examination* Thomas Lemieux University of British Columbia June 2003 Abstract The standard view in the literature on wage inequality is that within-group, or residual, wage

More information