An Analysis of Regional Trading Blocs

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "An Analysis of Regional Trading Blocs"

Transcription

1 Chulalongkorn Journal of Economics 8(3), September 1996 : An Analysis of Regional Trading Blocs Teerana Bhongmakapat Faculty of Economics Chulalongkom University C P t I 1. Introduction About a decade before ending the millennium, the world economy has witnessed a few major changes that have led to serious debates among many trade economists. Now that the Cold War has ended, thanks to Mr. Gorbachev, one might reasonably take an optimistic view about the future prospects of the world economy. However, international economic rivalry has intensified, and as the Uruguay round has been launched since the mid-1980s, the role of regional economic integration has emerged as a substitute for (rather than a complement to) global trade negotiations under the GATT. Together with bilateralism adopted by the U.S. congress and the executive branch under the Reagan and Bush administrations, regionalism has been seen by many to rise and undermine GATT-wide free trade principles. Completion of the EC's internal market has progressed very rapidly. The result has been considerable worries among many external countries, particularly the U.S. and Western Pacific Rim countries, that the EC may turn into an economic "fortress" and become a closed market. In North America, the U.S. (the GATT's The author is grateful to the Research Institute of International Trade and Industry, MITI. Japan, for research suppon in 1991.

2 404 Chulalongkorn Journal of Economics 8(3), September 1996 founder and long-time strong supporter) has entered into a free trade agreement with Canada and will do so very soon with Mexico. This is partly a strategic response to the EC integration. In East Asia, now the most dynamic region in the world, some nations have called for an economic grouping (though many of them are opposed to bilateralism and regionalism); in fact, ASEAN countries have just agreed to gradually form a free trade area, largely in response to the strong tendency towards rising regionalism and protectionist pressures in Europe and North America. Recent developments in the world trading system indicate "successful" regional trading blocs and the likelihood that a GATT-sponsored multilateral mechanism will not be supported by the two major players as strongly as it was in the past. There is a wide belief that, if these trends continue into the future, the world economy will be fragmented into three major regional trading blocs : (1) the EC with further enlargements to include EFTA and Eastern Europe, (2) the NAFTA, which will probably include some Latin American countries, and (3) East Asia which will be urgently formed. In 1990, the trade between countries belonging to the EC and the NAFTA already accounted for almost 60 percent of world trade (see Table 1 for detailed comparisons). Provided that East Asian countries form trading bloc (which would possibly include Australia and New Zealand who already have made a free trade agreement) the three major regional trading blocs could have their trade shares amounting to approximately 90 percent of world trade. Nonetheless, whether or not the future world trading system will be overwhelmingly dominated by the trading blocs remains an open question, although it may be partially answered by the "success" or "failure" of the Uruguay Round, the conclusion of which will be postponed until early 1993.

3 T. Bhongmakapat : Regional Trading Blocs 405 Table 1 Regional Trading Blocs (1990) Population GDP GDP per Total Trade (million) (bil. US$) capita Exports Imports Trade Share (US$) (bil.$) (bil.$) (bil.$) (%) NAFTA I* NAFTA It** USA Canada Mexico EC (12) W.Gennany EFTA East Asia (excl. China) Japan South Korea Hong Kong Taiwan China ASEAN (6) Singapore Thailand Malaysia Indonesia Philippines Brunei Australia & New Zealand Australia New Zealand World Note : Source * NAFTA I is comprised of the U.S. and Canada. ** NAFTA I1 is comprised of the U.S., Canada, and Mexico. : IMF, International Financial Statistics Yearbook, 1991, and various other sources.

4 406 Chulalongkorn Journal of Economics 8(3), September 1996 Although the formation of any regional economic zone involves political or noneconomic objectives, it is crucial to examine its economic essence, including its role in the world trading system. In this regard, many prominent trade economists, notably Baldwin (1987a and 1990), Bhagwati (1991), Corden (1987), and Krueger (1990) view multilateral free trade as preferable to bilateral and regional approaches, and are alarmed that bilateralism and regionalism may divide the world into three large trade blocs, posing serious dangers to world trade and security (see also Aho and Aronson (1985), Noland (1989b), and Schott (1989). On the contrary, many influential scholars and policy analysts, such as Dornbusch and Krugman, have started to advocate bilateral and regional initiatives (see also Hufbauer (1984), for an earlier view). Dornbusch (1990) praises a U.S. trade bloc, including the U.S.-Mexico deal and free trade arrangements with other Latin American nations, and strongly argues in favor of bilateralism and regionalism. According to Dornbusch, these can be effective bargaining tools for the U.S., and strategic move to handle Japan. More recently, Krugman (1991a and 1991b), whose name is closely connected with the new stream of trade theory, states the importance of the "natural (regional) trading blocs" concept over conventional economic explanations, and prefers that the U.S. forms a free trade zone with neighboring countries, i.e. Canada and Mexico, rather than ones with foreign lands further away, such as Israel and South Korea. Is a geographically discriminatory trading arrangement a good idea? Will its role activate and replace multilateral free trade? How will it affect the future of the global trade system and the world economy? If regional-biased practices are prevalent, how would small countries that tend to be "left on the shelf' respond to such a global movement? The purpose of this paper is to consider these issues and particularly to closely examine the relevance of the natural trading blocs argued for recently and influentially by Krugman (1 991 b).

5 T. Bhongmakapat : Regional Trading Blocs 407 In this paper, we first consider the theory of preferential trading arrangements, sometimes called customs union theory, in order to emphasize and clarify certain economic issues. Since this theory is a large subject and has also been reviewed elsewhere, discussion here is only an attempt at laying down some of the relevant findings and recent theoretical developments in the field. In section 3, we examine the hypothesis of "natural trading blocs" by looking at the resulting trade creation and possible efficiency losses. In this section, an econometric analysis of U.S. bilateral trade flows is also presented. Section 4 discusses the role of regional trading blocs in shaping the future of the post-cold War world economy. Section 4 also glances at possible reactions taken by small countries in East-Southeast Asia or Western Pacific Rim, as well as strategies that these nations may adopt in responding to the geographically discriminatory practices that have emerged in Europe and North America. 2. Trading Blocs in International Trade Theory Theoretical literature on customs unions, or more precisely on preferential trading arrangements, is crucial to understand the gains and losses that may be associated with the formation of trading blocs. ' Forming a free trade area involves substantial reductions in tariffs and nontariff impediments among member nations, therefore one may be led to believe that such a formation is a move fowards 1 free trade that helps raise welfare rather than reducing it. However, trade theory in general asserts that its impact is indeed ambiguous, since it involves both free trade among members, and protectionist 1 discrimination against outsiders. This is fundamentally the question of second-best policy, with one distortion replaced by another, thereby making the question very difficult to answer with certainty. I -- ' The terms, "free trade area," "customs union," "regional economic integration," "preferential trading arrangements," and "trading blocs," are here used interchangeably, although they may not be defined exactly the same.

6 408 Chulalongkorn Journal of Ecotlomics 8(3), September 1996 Although trade theory contains some deficiencies in explaining the existence and effects of preferential trade in which various distortions exist, forming a trading bloc is not a purely political phenomenon. Of course, a good answer should have both empirical and theoretical foundations. In this section then, it is worthwhile to see some major points which trade theorists have asserted on how a bloc-building policy affects trade and welfare. Standard Customs Union Theory One of the early contributions came from Viner's 1950 book. His seminal contributions were the concepts of "trade creation" and "trade diversion" that help identify conditions under which a customs union is welfare improving. Trade creation is the replacement of high cost domestic production by imports from a partner, whereas trade diversion is the replacement of low cost imports from outsiders by imports from a partner. Therefore, for the donor country who gives a preferential tariff reduction, trade creation is beneficial in moving the country toward free trade, but trade diversion is protective and harmful since it results in resource misallocation. Without empirical estimates of these two conflicting effects, the desirability of a customs union is indeterminate. Since these two "Vinerian effects" are very fundamental to analyses of trading blocs, it is probably useful to precisely illustrate them in a more detailed manner. Suppose that we are in an idealized world where we have perfect competition, full employment of resources, no adjustment costs, and perfect mobility of factors within countries, but not across countries. By assumption, there is one good and there are three countries: A, B, and C. Countries A and B are to form a trading bloc, leaving C (or the rest of the world) as an outsider. In Figure 1, D, is A's demand curve, while S,, S,, and S, are supply curves for A, B, and C, respectively. C's supply curve is assumed to be

7 T. Bhongmakapat : Regional Trading Blocs 409 perfectly elastic, so the world price is a constant, P,. Initially before the trading bloc formation, A imposes a non-descriminatory tariff, t, leading to domestic production and imports of OQ, and Q,Q2, respectively. It is simple to see that A pays Q,FGQ2 for imports from C, while domestic consumers pay QIABQ2 for the same amount of imports, giving tariff revenue equal to FABG for the government. With the bloc, imports from B will not be subject to tariff and thus will increase to Q,Q,. Domestic production will decrease to OQ,, while domestic consumption will increase to OQ,. As a result, net gain due to an increase in consumer surplus and a decrease in producer surplus will equal CAI+JBD. Note that, since there will be no tariff imposed on B's imports, tariff revenue equal to IABJ will transferred back to consumers. However, A will have to pay QlIJQ2 for the original amount of imports that used to cost only Q,FGQ2, leading to a loss in government revenue by FIJG. Trade economists show trade creation as Q3Q,+Q2Q4, or in terms of welfare, the areas CAI+JBD, and trade diversion as Q,Q2 or the welfare represented by area FIJG.

8 410 Chulalongkorn Journal of Economics 8(3), September 1996 The above analysis simply shows that, although removing intra-bloc trade barriers improves economic efficiency through trade creation, barriers that remain on extra-bloc trade will lead to an efficiency loss through trade diversion. The latter concept has led many to believe that a unilateral tariff reduction is superior to a customs union. Indeed, Cooper and Massell (1965a) asserted that this was true within the framework represented in Figure 1. Under the small country assumption that international terms of trade are unchanged due to the customs union formation, Cooper and Massell (1965a) showed that tariff reductions indiscriminate from P, to P,, and the subsequent union formation between A and B would yield gains from trade creation (CAI+JBD) without resulting in trade diversion, for imports continue to come from the rest of the world. This led to the proposition made by Johnson (1965) and Cooper and Massell (1965b) that a customs union is not theoretically efficient; therefore, the formation of customs unions and other preferential trading arrangements is driven by non-economic objectives. Parallel to the traditional line of partial equilibrium analysis pioneered by Viner, an alternative theoretical approach was introduced by Vanek (1965), and further expounded and developed by Kemp (1969) and Kemp and Wan (1978). Vanek, in his great book, explored various possibilities within the powerful framework of general equilibrium. He accepted the statement that a customs union may or may not raise welfare, but specified the conditions under which it will be Pareto-superior to the initial situation. The formation of a customs union may make the country granting preferential tariffs worse off and make its partner better off; however, the loser can be compensated, as can the rest of the world which loses from being left out. In compensating the rest of the world, Vanek introduced

9 T. Bhongmakapat : Regional Trading Blocs 411 an important concept: that of the compensating common tariff The compensating common tariff refers to the common external tariff (CET) imposed jointly by customs union members that keep the rest of the world as well off as before. An interpretation of this concept is that the union sets its external tariff such that its volume of trade with the rest of the world remains unchanged. Although the Vanek-Kemp-Wan approach justifies the existence and motives of customs union, under the compensation scheme the union does not necessarily maximize welfare with respect to its joint external tariff; therefore, the compensating common tariff may not be as attractive as unilateral nonpreferential tariff reduction. By using this approach, Berglas (1979) came up with a conclusion which supported that of the Johnson-Cooper- Massell proposition. That is, if world prices are constant for the recipient member who compensates the granting country who loses, the net gain accrued to it can also be achieved through unilateral tariff reduction (while the granting country remains as well off as before the union). Later Contributions In spite of the proposition in favor of unilateral free trade over customs unions, there exist certain conditions under which the latter is superior to the former. The case for unilateral tariff liberalization stated by Johnson (1965) and Cooper and Massell (1965a) is the first-best outcome where there is essentially no change in the terms of trade, no foreign tariff, no economies of scale, etc. In the previous analysis, A and B are assumed small, whereas C is a large country, which means world prices remain unchanged after the union. If the countries that form a union are significant enough in size to have an influence on international terms of trade, there will normally be an additional source of gains from the

10 412 Chulalongkorn Journal of Economics 8(3), September 1996 formatioc; that is, gain due to changes in the terms of trade. In Figure 1, if we allow for increasing costs so that A imports from both B and C, preferential tariff reduction given by A to B will raise B's producer prices, but reduce prices received by C. Changing terms of trade in favor of the bloc and against the rest of the world thus leads to a welfare gain and thereby indicates a trade-off between trade distortion and its offsetting terms-of-trade gain.2 On theoretical grounds, this result is not necessarily valid in all cases. Forming a customs union is usually reciprocal, i.e. both A and B offer preferential tariffs to each other, and the effects on terms of trade between A and B may not be canceled out. If there are more than two goods, and both goods from A and B are imported by C, the union's terms of trade versus C can finally go into any direction, depending on the resulting intra-union terms of trade between A and B. In normal cases, however, outsiders will face worsening terms of trade from trade diversion, while the bloc will improve terms of trade as a result of it. One of the main and obvious reasons why a unilateral tariff reduction is not very attractive to policy makers is that it'is not accompanied by changes in tariffs (or trade barriers) abroad. In the presence of foreign tariffs, there exists an opportunity of mutually provide tariff preferences, as analyzed in Wonnacott and Wonnacott (1981). Multilateral free trade can be seen as explicit cooperation that dominates the option that each country reduces its own tariffs unilaterally. Under some circumstances, reciprocity arranged with certain countries may appear to a given country to be more feasible than reciprocity arranged with an Since under general equilibrium conditions, A's terms of trade is the sum of B's and C's terms-of-trade effects, the terms of trade between A and C can not be predicted theoretically. Nonetheless, as stated by Mundell (1964) in his pioneering work, B's terms of trade unambiguously improve as a result of discriminatory tariff reductions offered by A.

11 T. Bhongmakapa! : Regional Trading Blocs 413 unlimited number of nations. However, the rampant discrimination involved in forming a bloc which is narrowly-based or not open to outsiders is not truly supported by this argument since it ignores possible benefits from mutual cooperation with many other countries. And of course, there is the theoretical question of the optimal choice of partners. In the presence of scale economies, customs union formation was suggested by Corden (1972) to include two additional effects : cost reduction gain and trade suppression loss. With economies of scale for production in A, its average cost curve is sloped downward; therefore, as a result of average cost pricing and preferred tariffs provided by its partner country, B for example, export expansion into B will lead to a cost saving along the average cost curve, thereby yielding the cost reduction effect. A loss from trade suppression for A may occur when the union formation allows production in A to emerge and replace imports into A from the rest of the world, C. If A's production also replaces imports into B from C, there will be trade diversion for B. i Although there have been several theories addressing the question of why a trading bloc or customs union has incentives to from, terms-of-trade changes that could benefit member countries at the expense of outsiders may lead to the undesirable outcome of trade warfare and retaliation. The terms-of-trade gain from the grouping will encourage others to do the same thing. As the analysis of tariff retaliation equilibrium pioneered by Johnson (1954) implies, if only one bloc is large and the others are too small, the large bloc may finally have a net gain, while the others lose. However, if the blocs are large, retaliation may finally leave them worse off than before starting the bloc-building policies. Krugman (1991b) also explains that, in a theoretical sense, since trading blocs can, due to improving terms of trade, raise market power and

12 414 Chulalongkorn Journal of Economics 8(3), September 1996 thereby tariffs on imports from outside, they may lead to tariflwarfare that quite possibly could leave all of them worse off than they would have been had the trading blocs not been formed. Trading Blocs with Imperfect Competition In the preceding discussion, trading blocs are analyzed by the "conventional" theory of international trade, in which perfect competition is a crucial assumption. Discussion concerning Corden's trade reduction and trade suppression effects is the only exception examined thus far that departs from the traditional perfect competition setup. With a growing belief that imperfectly competitive behavior is of great importance in world trade, much of trade literature has recently been developed by incorporating the theory of imperfect competition into the theory of trade and tariffs. Nevertheless, regarding the topic of trading blocs, very little work has been done. Ethier and Horn (1984) and Krugman (1991a) are probably the only two major theoretical studies that attempt to develop a formal model within the general equilibrium framework of Charnberlinian monopolistic competition. To understand the effects of trade bloc formation under imperfect competition, it is important to look at the "large group" Chamberlinian case and the "small group" oligopolistic competition case separately. In the former case, forming a bloc will have an additional impact on product varieties. Suppose that all three countries, A, B and C, produce manufactured goods that are differentiated and imperfectly substitute, and there are n, m, and m* varieties produced in countries A, B, and C, respectively. Assume that for each country the preference of its representative consumer is that of the Dixit-Stiglitz variant. See Dixit and Stiglitz (1977). This preference is affected by not only

13 T. Bhongmakapat : Regional Trading Blocs 415 I the amounts of varieties consumed, but also the numbers of varieties: n, m, and m*. Theoretically, trade liberalization adopted by A or B can have an ambiguous impact on the total number of varieties, the elasticity of substitution among varieties, and product prices, and thus on elfa are.^ To make things less complicated, let's assume that the substitution elasticity is constant. Now, if A anb B form a trading bloc, leaving C out in the cold, reducing trade barriers by A will force n to fall and m to rise. Extrabloc varieties will be discouraged, so m* will fall. The replacement of n by m illustrates a trade creating effect, and the replacement of m* by m is an example of trade diversion, or more exactly, trade modification. For A, discriminatory tariff reduction may or may not be welfare improving, depending upon the relative gain due to more varieties from B and losses due to less varieties from inside the country and from outside the bloc. If A and B offer reciprocal tariff reductions and both of them are rather symmetric, n and m will increase, and m* will fall in both countries. Moreover, in normal cases, terms of trade will also improve for the bloc and worsen for the rest of the world. As a result, it is quite similar to the concepts introduced by standard theory, forming a trading bloc normally leads to a welfare gain due to trade creating and terms-of-trade effects, and a welfare loss due to trade diversion or trade modification. Countries outside the bloc will unambiguously be worse off. Since in monopolistically competitive industries, firms act as minimonopolist over their varieties, the effects of scale economies or cost reduction effects will be theoretically trivial, unless the substitution elasticity is 3 Changes in varieties play an important role here. As shown in my dissertation (Bhongmakapat, 1988). unilateral tariff reduction will have an ambiguous effect on the total number of varieties; therefore, if the substitution elasticity is not constant, but affected by the total number of varieties, the ambiguous changes in varieties will cause the substitution elasticity, prices, and welfare to go in any direction.

14 416 Chulalongkorn Journal of Economics 8(3), September 1996 allowed to move downward sufficiently as a result of bloc f~rmation.~ A major concern about forming a trading bloc is its impact on world welfare. By assuming symmetric trading blocs, Krugman (1991a) shows that the formation of trading blocs will not only result in trade diversion, but also in an increase in external tariffs due to terms-of-trade changes in favor of the bloc. According to this analysis, without natural trading blocs, world welfare is maximized with free trade and minimized with "three trading blocs." In the case of oligopolistic competition, the effects of trading bloc formation are highly sensitive to what assumptions are made regarding the interaction between firms. This is actually an intrinsic problem of game theory, any correct answer has to rely on empirical work. Due to its partial equilibrium character, this approach has not had much to say about the economy-wide benefits and costs of customs unions, which is an important consideration for economists. Among a few others, Smith and Venables (1988) and Venables (1990) attempted to develop a formal model of intra-industry trade (but not within a general equilibrium setup) to analyze and quantify the effects of a trading bloc under increasing returns to scale and various types of oligopolistic competition. Their economic analysis can be briefly described as follows. Forming a customs union leads to more competition between firms located in different countries, and may influence the form of the competitive game that firms play. More competition should help cut oligopolistic prices, thus benefiting consumers in the union. Another type of gain from competition is the resulting reduction in the number of firms in the industry, causing firms that Theoretically, pricing behavior that is derived from the optimization problem is usually preferred. However, this can be a matter of empirical evidence. If prices set by domestic firms are affected enough by the prices of imported varieties, as in Harris (1984). the effects of scale economies will be significant.

15 T. Bhongmakapar : Regional Trading Blocs 417 I continue to stay in the industry to become larger and further?, rationalize or extend the lengths of production runs to exploit more 1 economies of scale. If markets are fully integrated, as in the single i market model, a lower degree of market segmentation will reduce the domestic firms' market power as their ability to price discriminate ) between markets goes down. The changing form of the game being i played is supposed to be pro-competitive at home. In this type of model, 1 the effects from economies of scale and terms of trade will benefit t the bloc, but as in Corden's analysis, there will be trade diversion, 4 5 trade suppression, and worsening of outsiders' terms of trade. '! 3 3. The Irrelevance of Natural lkading Blocs As trade theory generally suggests, a trading bloc is a distortion i comprised of both free trade and protectionist components. After ; the bloc formation, member countries may or may not experience 1) a net gain. This depends on the relative magnitudes of trade I creation, terms-of-trade, and the effects of scale economies, versus trade diverting and trade modification effects. Outsiders are normally worse off due to trade diversion, trade modification, and terms-oftrade changes. If the protectionist component is significant and encourages trade warfare or retaliation, world welfare will ultimately diminish and every one will be worse off. I r Since theoretical predictions suffer from the second-best nature of the problem being analyzed, any good answer cannot be overly generalized and empirical evidence should be seriously considered. A number of studies have assessed the effects of discriminatory trading arrangements on trade and welfare, mostly in the case of European integration. According to most of these studies, trade creation and terms-of-trade benefits would outweigh trade diversion losses. Under imperfectly competitive markets, the net welfare effects of EC integration and the U.S.-Canada Free Trade Agreement for member countries are positive and larger than under

16 418 Chulalongkorn Journal of Economics 8(3), September 1996 perfect competition, see Smith and Venables (1998) and Venables (1991) for European integration, and Brown and Stem (1989) for the U.S.-Canada pact.5 These empirical results might be embraced by European federalists and NAlTA advocates, but in fact they do not indicate impressively large gains. Furthermore, in general, as illustrated by Richardson (1989), empirical research on trade policy under imperfect competition has shown that trade liberalization leads to gains much larger than those estimated under perfect competition. This implies that under imperfect competition with increasing returns, multilateral free trade may be much more beneficial than customs unions that result in protectionist trade diversion and trade modification effects. What is clearly suggested by empirical evidence currently available is that trade bloc formation could make outsiders significantly worse off. Sampson and Snape (1980) estimated substantial welfare diverted from nonmembers to EC members. Hamilton and Whalley (1985) simulated general equilibrium welfare effects of various free trade areas involving the U.S., and found that most excluded regions generally would experience sizeable.welfare losses. Considering that the welfare gains from a trading bloc, either the EC or NAFTA, are not very large, but lead to adverse effects on outsiders and the world at large, one is reasonably convinced that regionalism is probably a bad idea, particularly from long-term and global perspectives. Nonetheless, Krugman (1991b) views recent popular movements towards free trade areas as being With increasing returns and oligopolistic competition, one often accepts the idea that government interventionist measures, such as tariffs and subsidies, are beneficial to "national interests" to a greater extent than what is actually suggested by standard trade theory, see an influential paper of Krugman (1987). However, as indicated by Venables (1991), removing intra-ec trade barriers would yield relatively larger welfare gains with oligopolistic competition than with perfect competition,

17 T Bhongmakapar : Regional Trading Blocs 419 "natural" since the countries that are engaging in free trade agreements are actually natural trading partner^.^ According to Krugman, if the formation of preferential trading agreements follows the line of natural regionalism, they will have "a much better chance of improving welfare than trade arrangements between "unnatural" trading partners." (Krugman, 1991 a : 122),' In supporting the hypothesis of natural trading blocs, Krugman (1991b) estimated a gravity equation with data from G7 countries.' He regressed the value of trade, in logarithm, on the products of the incomes between countries, in logarithms and dummy variables for countries that belong to trade groupings, i.e. the U.S.-Canada, and Europe (4 European countries), and found that the estimated coefficients of the dummies for U.S.-Canada and Europe were statistically significant and equal to and , respectively. Therefore, as interpreted by Kmgman, the regression result indicated "very strongly" the regional bias of trade (Krugman, 1991b : 20)8. Of course, Krugman's analysis advocating natural regionalism is subject to criticism. One of the few major drawbacks r An earlier idea of natural trading blocs was given by Balassa (1961). who conjectured that neighboring countries would have an additional stimulus to trade, but relying on reasons quite different from Kmgman's. Whereas Balassa's idea was based on similarity of tastes and an awareness of common interests, Krugman's explanation aims at economic geography, particularly the role of transportation costs. ' The gravity model relates the value of trade between two countries positively to their incomes using a functional form similar to the gravity equation in physics. Applying it to econometric analyses of international trade flows has been very successful. It has also been standard for estimating trade effects of regional integration. For example. see Aitken (1973). Pelzman (1977), and Brada and Mendez (1985). Based on the above-mentioned coefficients for the dummy variables, the U.S. and Canada did 13 times as much trade as they would if they were not neighbors, while the European countries did 7 times as much.

18 420 Chulalongkorn Journal of Economics 8(3), September 1996 is his regression formulation and interpretation. Since his regression tactic was to "pool" trade flows between the seven countries and include only two dummy variables for the U.S.-Canada, and Europe into the equation, the coefficients he obtained simply indicate that the U.S. bloc and the "EC" would be creating much more trade than an "average pair" of G7 countries would do, and that the U.S. bloc would stimulate much more trade than would Europe. By my interpretation, it simply means that Kmgman has not done enough to show that forming a bloc among neighboring nations will be much more trade creating than forming a bloc between distant countries. Maybe, in terms of trade creation, the U.S. trade bloc would gain more by including economically efficient trading partners located far away than by including those which have a sound geographical advantage, i.e. Canada and Mexico. Therefore, it is very important to test the hypothesis of natural trading blocs by examining the trade-stimulating effects that could possibly occur with some other trading partners as well. In considering the relevance or irrelevance of natural regionalism here, my regression tactic is to employ a crosssectional gravity model of bilateral trade between the U.S. and her trading pa~tners.~ It is then asked whether for the U.S., (i) trading arrangements within NAFTA are more trade stimulating than with any other regions, and (ii) in selecting a country to form a bloc, Canada and Mexico are superior in terms of trade creation with In this paper, the same approach as used in Krugman (1991b) is employed. Although gravity models are quite standard in the empirical analysis of trade policy and regional economic integration, it is by no means an ideal approach in analyzing the economic impacts of trading bloc formation, particularly when the economy-wide effects are concerned. However, considering the questions at hand, this approach should be sufficient.

19 T. Bhongmakapat : Regional Trading Blocs 421 the U.S.1 The model here specifies the value of trade between the U.S. and 84 trading partners as a positive function of the incomes of the trading partners, distance between economic centers, and dummy variables for trade preference areas. The functional form being estimated is as follows: where Tu, is the value of merchandise trade between the U.S. and country j, GDPj is the nominal GDP of country j, measured in millions of US dollars, YN, is the GNP per capita of country j, measured in US dollars, DIST~, denotes the shortest navigable distance between the commercial centers in the U.S. and country j, measured in nautical miles, and DAZ represents the dummy variable for trade between the U.S. and the region or area z (it can be a country).'' As normally specified in gravity models, the GDPj coefficient should have a positive expected sign. NYj measures demand structure or tastes, and is included according to Linder's hypothesis, as suggested by Bergstrand (1989) and Thursby and Thursby (1987). Its expected sign is positive. DISTu, serves as a lo Although in a number of gravity models, data on bilateral trade flows across more than one pair of countries are used and pooled together, it is not uncommon to employ a bilateral trade flow model for a single country, see Thursby and Thursby (1987) and Summary (1989). From an econometric standpoint, Thursby and Thursby (1987) pointed out that a bilateral trade model for each country had an advantage over a bilateral trade model which pooled data from all countries. However, a bilateral trade model for the US is performed here essentially due to the nature of the questions considered, not merely due to statistical criteria. 'I All data used are those for 1989, except for navigable distances. Trade flows data are obtained from the IMF, Directions of Trade Statistics Yearbook, Data on GDP and per capita income are from the World Bank, WorU Development Report, 1991, except for a few countries, data which are from the IMF, Internarional Financial Sratisrics Yearbook, Distances are from the Japan Shipping Exchange, Disrance Tables for World Shipping, Tokyo, 1983.

20 422 Chulalongkortz Journal of Economics 8(3), September 1996 proxy for natural trade resistance which in turn refers to a composite of transportation cost and transport time, and thus its expected sign is negative. The dummy variable, DAz, is actually used to approximate the trade-stimulating effect of trading arrangements between the U.S. and the region (or country) z. Therefore, for any z, its dummy coefficient helps estimate the trade-stimulating effect, in a very approximate fashion of course. A high estimated coefficient value for any group z implies its strong trade creation with the U.S., either with or without existing special trade preferences. It is common for a cross-section analysis using the ordinary least square method to have the heteroscedasticity problem since, in the presence of heteroscedasticity, the variances of the OLS estimators are biased. Therefore, the model is estimated by using the heteroscedasticity-consistent covariance-matrix estimator of White (1980). Table 2 shows the estimated results based on two gravity equations, one with regional dummy variables and the other with country dummies as independent variables with regard to trade stimulation. The former and latter equations are respectively related to questions (i) and (ii) mentioned above. In the first regression, North America is considered versus other major regions, where DNAFTA is the dummy variable for U.S. bilateral trade with the rest of North America (including both Canda and Mexico), DANIE with Asian NIEs (including Taiwan, Hong Kong, and Korea), DSEA with Southeast Asia (including Singapore, Thailand, Malaysia, Indonesia, and the Philippines), DEC with European Community, and DLATIN with Latin America (excluding Mexico). In the second regression, the trade-stimulating effects of trading with Canada and Mexico are compared with other prospective countries, especially those highly competitive in world markets, such as Asian NIEs. DCND denotes the dummy veriable for U.S.

21 T. Bhongmakapar : Regional Trading Blocs 423 bilateral trade with Canada, DMEX with Mexico, DTWAN with Taiwan, DKREA with Korea, DHK with Hong Kong, DSPORE with Singapore, DJPAN with Japan, and DISREL with Israel. Table 2 Regression Results Right-Hand-Side Estimated Variables Coefficients t-statistic (I) Estimated Gravity Equation with Regional Dummies In GDP In YN In DIST DNAFTA DANIE DSEA DEC DLATIN Adjusted R2 = (2) Estimated Gravity Equation with Country Dummies In GDP In YN In DIST DCND DMEX DTWAN DKREA DHK DSPORE D JPAN DISREL Adjusted R2 =

22 424 Chulalongkorn Journal of Economics 8(3), September 1996 As shown in Table 2, the regression results of gravity equation (1) support the idea that U.S. bilateral trade within NAFTA is highly trade creating, but do not indicate that natural trading arrangements do strengthen trade significantly more than trade with "unnatural," remote regions. Although intra-nafta trade has already been promoted by various trade preferences made by all the members, according to the results, U.S. trade within NAFTA is not more trade creating than is bilateral trade between the U.S. and Asian NIEs, and only slightly more trade creating than is U.S. trade with Southeast Asia.12 Of course, it is not surprising that it does stimulate trade relative to U.S. trade with the Latin American region, while the trade creating effect between the U.S. and the EC is unfounded. Furthermore, the importance of natural trading arrangements is not supported by the estimated results in equation (2). The results more or less help indicate trade creating gains from choosing one trading partner over another. As discussed by various authors, all countries considered here are possible candidates or in possible regions for a free trade agreement with the U.S., see Schott (1989). According to the regression, the trade preference effects of NAFTA are significant. U.S. trade with Canada is trade stimulating relative to those with Mexico and some other nations, particularly Japan and Israel. However, trade arrangements with Canada only result in slightly more trade than those with Hong Kong and Taiwan, and less trade than those with Singapore. More importantly, Mexico is quite different from Canada. The U.S.-Mexico grouping is not as beneficial, in terms of trade stimulus, as a US.-"Tiger" grouping, except for Korea, though it is superior to arrangements with Japan and Israel. This is tantamount to saying that building a " During the past decade, the U.S. trade policy has turned to aggressively reduce imports from East Asia, as pointed out by Bhagwati and Patrick (1990). Otherwise, one may see stronger trade creation with Asian NIEs and Southeast Asia.

23 T. Bhongmakapat : Regional Trading Blocs 425 trade bloc with a country or region based on the concept of a natural or geographic alliance is probably not a good idea. Natural regionalism suffers from its lack of solid economic reasoning, although it has political and cultural advantages to sell to short-sighted politicians, special interests, and the public who may not be aware of the long-term, economy-wide costs of the inward protectionist elements embodied in such discriminatory trading arrangements. If we examine trade beyond its aggregate flows and highlight conventional trade economists' view in more detail, we will clearly see the opportunity costs of creating a trading bloc, and that the best trading bloc is by and large multilateral free trade under which a country can broadly acquire potential efficiency gains from specialization. Tables 3-8 show the "revealed" comparative advantage, RCA, of exporters to the U.S., the EC, and Japan, as well as that of the three major trading nations of the world.13 For the U.S., gains from trade can simply occur by doing more trade with countries which have high RCA values for commodities groups in which the U.S. lacks comparative advantage. As shown in Tables 3 and 6, the U.S. has strong revealed comparative advantages in mining or crude materials (except fuels) and machinery and equipment, and the U.S. can find various trading partners that are, in the revealed sense, more efficient than Canada and Mixico in commodity groups in which the U.S. has strong comparative disadvantage, especially energy and non-mechanical manufacturing. If the machinery and equipment group is producing under increasing returns to scale, it " Revealed" comparative advantage is a crude indicator for comparative advantage based on patterns of trade. and it is usually defined as the ratio of the share of a commodity group in total exports for a country or region to that commodity group's share of world exports. However, in Tables 3-5, the indicator is applied to exports to the three markets to allow for market segmentation in world markets. A value greater than 1 indicates a relative comparative advantage for the commodity group.

24 ,426 Chulalongkorn Journal of Economics 8(3), September 1996 will imply that the U.S. can find trading partners with a strong advantage in exporting the product group to the U.S. By exporting more of the commodity groups in which the U.S. had a strong comparative advantage to various countries that experience exceptionally low comparative advantage, the U.S. will clearly gain. In fact, they will gain much more than if they entered a narrowly conceived restrictive trade bloc with a few countries that do not offer economic gains widely and substantially. Multilateral free trade is simply a route which allows every one, who is an importing country for varieties of products, to benefit from trade with least (comparative) cost suppliers. This is indeed a very major reason why trade diversion and trade modification is costly and can be avoided via multilateral free trade. By the same token, for the EC, and much more apparently for Japan, multilateral free trade can be roughly illustrated to be better than regional free trade in terms of gains from specialization. One may argue that in practice multilateral free trade allows the presence of free riders who avoid giving concessions, but that a regional free trade is relatively effective, and can be a force for liberalization. Of course, gains from either regionalism or multilateralism do not depend only on the specialization pattern, but are also crucially dependent on how much trade barriers are to be removed reciprocally by trading partners who join the negotiating tables. However, as illustrated by Baldwin (1987a), if. there are countries other than those engaging in a bilateral free trade agreement and they indeed would like to trail liberal trade policies, multilateral negotiations will lead more to trade liberalization, while still being able to meet other requirements as much as the bilateral deal can do, and while multilateral negotiations do not eliminate the free-rider problem, they help reduce it.i4 Therefore, l4 For a similar line of arguments, see an explanation made by Lawrence (Lawrence and Schultz, 1990 : 23).

25 T. Bhongrnakapar : Regional Trading Blocs 427 Table 3 "Revealed" Comparative Advantage of Exporters lo the U.S. ( ) Agriculture Non-Mechanical Mach~nery & Partners\SITC and Food Mining Energy Manufacturing Equipment NAITA II* Canada Mexico EC (12) Germany EITA Latin America Middle East Far East Far East excl. Japan Japan South Korea Taiwan Hong Kong China ASEAN (6) Singapore Thailand Malaysia Indonesia Philippines Brunei Others Australia & New Zealand Austrialia New Zealand Rest of the world (0+1) (2+4) (3) (5+6+8) (7) Note : *NAFTA I1 is comprised of the U.S., Canada, and Mexico. Source : Data compiled from OECD, Foreign Trade by Commodity.

26 428 Chulalongkorn Journal of Economics 8(3), September 1996 Table 4 "Revealed" Comparative Advantage of Exporters to the U.S. ( ) Agriculture Non-Mechanical Machinery & Partners\SITC and Food Mining Energy Manufacturing Equipment (0+1) (2+4) (3) (5+6+8) (7) NAFTA I* NAFTA II* Canada U.S.A Mexico EC (12) Germany EFTA Latin America Middle East Far East Far East excl. Japan Japan South Korea Taiwan Hong Kong China ASEAN (6) Singapore Thailand Malaysia Indonesia Philippines Brunei Others Australia & New Zealand Austrialia New Zealand Rest of the world Note : * NAFTA I is comprised of the US and Canada. ** NAFTA I1 is comprised of the US, canada, and Mexico Source : Data compiled from OECD, Foreign Trade by Commodity.

27 T. Bhongmakapat : Regional Trading Blocs 429 Table 5 "Revealed" Compara~ive Advantage of Exporters to Japan ( ) Agriculture Non-Mechanical Machinery & Partners\SITC and Food Mining Energy Manufacturing Equipment NAFTA I* NAFTA 11* Canada USA Mexico EC (12) Germany EFTA Latin America Middle East Far East South Korea Taiwan Hong Kong China ASEAN (6) Singapore Thailand Malaysia Indonesia Philippines Brunei Others Australia & New Zealand Australia New Zealand Rest of the world (0+1) (2+4) (3) (5+6+8) (7) - Note : * NAFTA I is comprised of the US and Canada. ** NAFTA I1 is comprised of the US, canada, and Mexico Source : Data compiled from OECD, Foreign Trade by Commodity.

28 430 Chulalongkorn Journal of Economics 8(3), September 1996 Table 6- "Revealed" Comparative Advantage of the U.S. ( ) Average Agriculture and Food Mining Energy Non-Mechanical Manufactures Machinery & Equipment Source : Data compiled from United Nations, International Trade Statistics Yearbook, Table 7 "Revealed" Comparative Advantage of the EC ( ) Average Agriculture and Food Mining Energy Non-Mechanical Manufactures Machinery &Equipment Source : Data compiled from United Nations, International Trade Statistics Yearbook, Table 8 "Revealed" Comparative Advantage of the Japan ( ) Average -- - Agriculture and Food Mining Energy Non-Mechanical Manufactures Machinery & Equipment Source : Data compiled from United Nations, International Trade Statistics Yearbook, 1991.

29 T. Bhongmakapar : Regional Trading Blocs 431 even in the presence of asymmetric willingness among a large number of countries to liberalize trade, the broad-based multilateralism can potentially benefit each country in the process of liberalization by bringing all interested parties to the table simultaneously. Furthermore, over a period of time, as a number of trading partners experience changes in comparative advantage (which may not only be due to possible discriminatory trading arrangements, but also to the countries' supply-side dynamism), forming a trading bloc (which usually requires long-term commitments with "preferred" trading partners) may not be consistently desirable. This is especially true when the bloc is relatively inefficient, or leading to a relative decline in its international competitiveness. 4. Regional Trading Blocs and Future of the World Economy As we are approaching a new millennium, the world economy is increasingly being transformed for the new coming era. It is an era in which butter will be far more vital than guns, and international competition among major powers, defined mainly by economic criteria, will be intensified. While the Cold War ended with the collapse of the former Soviet Empire, the relative power of the U.S. has dramatically declined. In the 1990s, it is expected that the hegemonic role of the U.S. will decline further, whereas the EC will grow relative to the U.S., or more or less maintain its world GDP share as it did during the 1980s. The rise of Japanese will continue (e.g. Bergsten, 1990 and Lo et. al., 1989). See also Table 9. This will create a state of US.-Europe-Japan "Tripolarity" which will replace the US.-dominated world order of the postwar period. Such a global transformation will result in strong international economic rivalry among the three major world powers. If the international rivalry is viewed by the major players as a zero-sum

The World Trade Organization and the future of multilateralism Note Key principles behind GATT general principle rules based not results based

The World Trade Organization and the future of multilateralism Note Key principles behind GATT general principle rules based not results based The World Trade Organization and the future of multilateralism By Richard Baldwin, Journal of Economic perspectives, Winter 2016 The GATT (General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade) was established in unusual

More information

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr Abstract. The Asian experience of poverty reduction has varied widely. Over recent decades the economies of East and Southeast Asia

More information

Volume Title: Trade Policy Issues and Empirical Analysis. Volume URL:

Volume Title: Trade Policy Issues and Empirical Analysis. Volume URL: This PDF is a selection from an out-of-print volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: Trade Policy Issues and Empirical Analysis Volume Author/Editor: Robert E. Baldwin, ed. Volume

More information

3) The European Union is an example of integration. A) regional B) relative C) global D) bilateral

3) The European Union is an example of integration. A) regional B) relative C) global D) bilateral 1 International Business: Environments and Operations Chapter 7 Economic Integration and Cooperation Multiple Choice: Circle the one best choice according to the textbook. 1) integration is the political

More information

Volume Author/Editor: Takatoshi Ito and Anne O. Krueger, Eds. Volume URL:

Volume Author/Editor: Takatoshi Ito and Anne O. Krueger, Eds. Volume URL: This PDF is a selection from an out-of-print volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: Regionalism versus Multilateral Trade Arrangements, NBER-EASE Volume 6 Volume Author/Editor:

More information

Trans-Pacific Trade and Investment Relations Region Is Key Driver of Global Economic Growth

Trans-Pacific Trade and Investment Relations Region Is Key Driver of Global Economic Growth Trans-Pacific Trade and Investment Relations Region Is Key Driver of Global Economic Growth Background The Asia-Pacific region is a key driver of global economic growth, representing nearly half of the

More information

Chapter 5: Internationalization & Industrialization

Chapter 5: Internationalization & Industrialization Chapter 5: Internationalization & Industrialization Chapter 5: Internationalization & Industrialization... 1 5.1 THEORY OF INVESTMENT... 4 5.2 AN OPEN ECONOMY: IMPORT-EXPORT-LED GROWTH MODEL... 6 5.3 FOREIGN

More information

INTERNATIONAL ECONOMICS, FINANCE AND TRADE Vol. II - Strategic Interaction, Trade Policy, and National Welfare - Bharati Basu

INTERNATIONAL ECONOMICS, FINANCE AND TRADE Vol. II - Strategic Interaction, Trade Policy, and National Welfare - Bharati Basu STRATEGIC INTERACTION, TRADE POLICY, AND NATIONAL WELFARE Bharati Basu Department of Economics, Central Michigan University, Mt. Pleasant, Michigan, USA Keywords: Calibration, export subsidy, export tax,

More information

The Gravity Model on EU Countries An Econometric Approach

The Gravity Model on EU Countries An Econometric Approach European Journal of Sustainable Development (2014), 3, 3, 149-158 ISSN: 2239-5938 Doi: 10.14207/ejsd.2014.v3n3p149 The Gravity Model on EU Countries An Econometric Approach Marku Megi 1 ABSTRACT Foreign

More information

Preferential Trading Arrangements: Gainers and Losers from Regional Trading Blocs

Preferential Trading Arrangements: Gainers and Losers from Regional Trading Blocs SRDC No. 198-8 This is the third series of trade leaflets entitled Southern Agriculture in a World Economy. These leaflets are a product of the Southern Extension International Trade Task Force sponsored

More information

International Business Global Edition

International Business Global Edition International Business Global Edition By Charles W.L. Hill (adapted for LIUC2016 by R.Helg) Copyright 2013 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. Chapter 9 Regional Economic Integration

More information

The Trade Liberalization Effects of Regional Trade Agreements* Volker Nitsch Free University Berlin. Daniel M. Sturm. University of Munich

The Trade Liberalization Effects of Regional Trade Agreements* Volker Nitsch Free University Berlin. Daniel M. Sturm. University of Munich December 2, 2005 The Trade Liberalization Effects of Regional Trade Agreements* Volker Nitsch Free University Berlin Daniel M. Sturm University of Munich and CEPR Abstract Recent research suggests that

More information

Assessing Barriers to Trade in Education Services in Developing ESCAP Countries: An Empirical Exercise WTO/ARTNeT Short-term Research Project

Assessing Barriers to Trade in Education Services in Developing ESCAP Countries: An Empirical Exercise WTO/ARTNeT Short-term Research Project Assessing Barriers to Trade in Education Services in Developing ESCAP Countries: An Empirical Exercise WTO/ARTNeT Short-term Research Project Ajitava Raychaudhuri, Jadavpur University Kolkata, India And

More information

Declining Industries, Mechanisms of Structural Adjustment, and Trade Policy in Pacific Basin Economies. Hugh Patrick. Working Paper No.

Declining Industries, Mechanisms of Structural Adjustment, and Trade Policy in Pacific Basin Economies. Hugh Patrick. Working Paper No. Declining Industries, Mechanisms of Structural Adjustment, and Trade Policy in Pacific Basin Economies Hugh Patrick Working Paper No. 28 Hugh Patrick is the R. D. Calking Professor of International Business

More information

SECTION THREE BENEFITS OF THE JSEPA

SECTION THREE BENEFITS OF THE JSEPA SECTION THREE BENEFITS OF THE JSEPA 1. Section Two described the possible scope of the JSEPA and elaborated on the benefits that could be derived from the proposed initiatives under the JSEPA. This section

More information

MEGA-REGIONAL FTAS AND CHINA

MEGA-REGIONAL FTAS AND CHINA Multi-year Expert Meeting on Enhancing the Enabling Economic Environment at All Levels in Support of Inclusive and Sustainable Development (2nd session) Towards an enabling multilateral trading system

More information

Japan s Policy to Strengthen Economic Partnership. November 2003

Japan s Policy to Strengthen Economic Partnership. November 2003 Japan s Policy to Strengthen Economic Partnership November 2003 1. Basic Structure of Japan s External Economic Policy -Promoting Economic Partnership Agreements with closely related countries and regions

More information

International Business

International Business International Business 10e By Charles W.L. Hill Copyright 2015 McGraw-Hill Education. All rights reserved. No reproduction or distribution without the prior written consent of McGraw-Hill Education. Chapter

More information

The term developing countries does not have a precise definition, but it is a name given to many low and middle income countries.

The term developing countries does not have a precise definition, but it is a name given to many low and middle income countries. Trade Policy in Developing Countries KOM, Chap 11 Introduction Import substituting industrialization Trade liberalization since 1985 Export oriented industrialization Industrial policies in East Asia The

More information

GRAVITY EQUATIONS IN INTERNATIONAL TRADE. based on Chapter 5 of Advanced international trade: theory and evidence by R. C. Feenstra (2004, PUP)

GRAVITY EQUATIONS IN INTERNATIONAL TRADE. based on Chapter 5 of Advanced international trade: theory and evidence by R. C. Feenstra (2004, PUP) GRAVITY EQUATIONS IN INTERNATIONAL TRADE based on Chapter 5 of Advanced international trade: theory and evidence by R. C. Feenstra (2004, PUP) Intro: increasing returns to scale and international trade

More information

Preferential Trade Liberalization: The Traditional Theory and New Developments

Preferential Trade Liberalization: The Traditional Theory and New Developments Preferential Trade Liberalization: The Traditional Theory and New Developments Arvind Panagariya* *Department of Economics, University of Maryland, College Park MD 20742. Email: panagari@econ.umd.edu Table

More information

TMD DISCUSSION PAPER NO. 34

TMD DISCUSSION PAPER NO. 34 TMD DISCUSSION PAPER NO. 34 TRADE LIBERALIZATION AND REGIONAL INTEGRATION: THE SEARCH FOR LARGE NUMBERS Sherman Robinson International Food Policy Research Institute Karen Thierfelder U.S. Naval Academy

More information

Free Trade Vision for East Asia

Free Trade Vision for East Asia CEAC Commentary introduces outstanding news analyses and noteworthy opinions in Japan, but it does not represent the views of CEAC as an institution. April 28, 2005 Free Trade Vision for East Asia By MATSUDA

More information

Economic integration: an agreement between

Economic integration: an agreement between Chapter 8 Economic integration: an agreement between or amongst nations within an economic bloc to reduce and ultimately remove tariff and nontariff barriers to the free flow of products, capital, and

More information

Economics of the Trans- Pacific Partnership (TPP)

Economics of the Trans- Pacific Partnership (TPP) Economics of the Trans- Pacific Partnership (TPP) AED/IS 4540 International Commerce and the World Economy Professor Sheldon sheldon.1@osu.edu What is TPP? Trans-Pacific Trade Partnership (TPP), signed

More information

Lecture 4 Multilateralism and Regionalism. Hyun-Hoon Lee Professor Kangwon National University

Lecture 4 Multilateralism and Regionalism. Hyun-Hoon Lee Professor Kangwon National University Lecture 4 Multilateralism and Regionalism Hyun-Hoon Lee Professor Kangwon National University 1 The World Trade Organization (WTO) General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT) A multilateral agreement

More information

Chapter 10 Trade Policy in Developing Countries

Chapter 10 Trade Policy in Developing Countries Chapter 10 Trade Policy in Developing Countries Prepared by Iordanis Petsas To Accompany International Economics: Theory and Policy, Sixth Edition by Paul R. Krugman and Maurice Obstfeld Chapter Organization

More information

Chapter Organization. Introduction. Introduction. Import-Substituting Industrialization. Import-Substituting Industrialization

Chapter Organization. Introduction. Introduction. Import-Substituting Industrialization. Import-Substituting Industrialization Chapter 10 Trade Policy in Developing Countries Chapter Organization Introduction The East Asian Miracle Summary Prepared by Iordanis Petsas To Accompany International Economics: Theory and Policy, Sixth

More information

Session 12. International Political Economy

Session 12. International Political Economy Session 12 International Political Economy What is IPE? p Basically our lives are about political economy. p To survive we need food, clothes, and many other goods. p We obtain these provisions in the

More information

8 Is East Asia a natural trade bloc? The trade complementarity index, the intensity index, and the bias index

8 Is East Asia a natural trade bloc? The trade complementarity index, the intensity index, and the bias index 8 Is East Asia a natural trade bloc? The trade complementarity index, the intensity index, and the bias index East Asian countries have become interdependent and economically integrated because of the

More information

Journal of Asian Economics

Journal of Asian Economics Journal of Asian Economics 21 (2010) 485 493 Contents lists available at ScienceDirect Journal of Asian Economics Patterns and determinants of intra-industry trade in Asia William C. Sawyer a, Richard

More information

East Asian Regionalism and the Multilateral Trading System ERIA

East Asian Regionalism and the Multilateral Trading System ERIA Chapter II.9 East Asian Regionalism and the Multilateral Trading System ERIA Yose Rizal Damuri Centre for Strategic and International Studies (CSIS) November 2013 This chapter should be cited as Damuri,

More information

COMMENTS ON L. ALAN WINTERS, TRADE LIBERALISATION, ECONOMIC GROWTH AND POVERTY

COMMENTS ON L. ALAN WINTERS, TRADE LIBERALISATION, ECONOMIC GROWTH AND POVERTY The Governance of Globalisation Pontifical Academy of Social Sciences, Acta 9, Vatican City 2004 www.pass.va/content/dam/scienzesociali/pdf/acta9/acta9-llach2.pdf COMMENTS ON L. ALAN WINTERS, TRADE LIBERALISATION,

More information

The Role of Internet Adoption on Trade within ASEAN Countries plus People s Republic of China

The Role of Internet Adoption on Trade within ASEAN Countries plus People s Republic of China The Role of Internet Adoption on Trade within ASEAN Countries plus People s Republic of China Wei Zhai Prapatchon Jariyapan Faculty of Economics, Chiang Mai University Chiang Mai University, 239 Huay Kaew

More information

Proliferation of FTAs in East Asia

Proliferation of FTAs in East Asia Proliferation of FTAs in East Asia Shujiro URATA Waseda University and RIETI April 8, 2005 Contents I. Introduction II. Regionalization in East Asia III. Recent Surge of FTAs in East Asia IV. The Factors

More information

Development, Politics, and Inequality in Latin America and East Asia

Development, Politics, and Inequality in Latin America and East Asia Institutions in Context: Inequality Development, Politics, and Inequality in Latin America and East Asia Inyoung Cho DPhil student Department of Politics and International Relations University of Oxford

More information

Size of Regional Trade Agreements and Regional Trade Bias

Size of Regional Trade Agreements and Regional Trade Bias Size of Regional Trade Agreements and Regional Trade Bias Michele Fratianni * and Chang Hoon Oh** *Indiana University and Università Politecnica delle Marche **Indiana University Abstract We test the relationship

More information

How Far Have We Come Toward East Asian Community?

How Far Have We Come Toward East Asian Community? Theme 3 How Far Have We Come Toward East Asian Community? Ippei Yamazawa President, International University of Japan, Japan 1. Economic and Social Development in East Asia Section III of our Background

More information

Computation and the Theory of Customs Unions

Computation and the Theory of Customs Unions Computation and the Theory of Customs Unions Lisandro Abrego IMF Raymond Riezman University of Iowa John Whalley Universities of Warwick and Western Ontario and NBER March 31, 2004 Abstract This paper

More information

TOWARDS AN ASEAN ECONOMIC COMMUNITY: THE CHALLENGES AHEAD

TOWARDS AN ASEAN ECONOMIC COMMUNITY: THE CHALLENGES AHEAD TOWARDS AN ECONOMIC COMMUNITY: THE CHALLENGES AHEAD Dr. Poppy S. WINANTI Universitas Gadjah Mada, Indonesia Abstract s ambition to accelerate regional trade liberalisation has been strengthened by the

More information

INTERNATIONAL ECONOMICS, FINANCE AND TRADE Vol. II - Globalization and the Evolution of Trade - Pasquale M. Sgro

INTERNATIONAL ECONOMICS, FINANCE AND TRADE Vol. II - Globalization and the Evolution of Trade - Pasquale M. Sgro GLOBALIZATION AND THE EVOLUTION OF TRADE Pasquale M. School of Economics, Deakin University, Melbourne, Australia Keywords: Accountability, capital flow, certification, competition policy, core regions,

More information

ECONOMIC GROWTH* Chapt er. Key Concepts

ECONOMIC GROWTH* Chapt er. Key Concepts Chapt er 6 ECONOMIC GROWTH* Key Concepts The Basics of Economic Growth Economic growth is the expansion of production possibilities. The growth rate is the annual percentage change of a variable. The growth

More information

Economic Development: Miracle, Crisis and Regionalism

Economic Development: Miracle, Crisis and Regionalism Economic Development: Miracle, Crisis and Regionalism Min Shu School of International Liberal Studies Waseda University 18 Dec 2017 IR of Southeast Asia 1 Outline of the Lecture Southeast Asian economies

More information

With great power comes great responsibility 100 years after World War I Pathways to a secure Asia

With great power comes great responsibility 100 years after World War I Pathways to a secure Asia 8 th Berlin Conference on Asian Security (BCAS) With great power comes great responsibility 100 years after World War I Pathways to a secure Asia Berlin, June 22-24, 2014 A conference jointly organized

More information

International Political Economy

International Political Economy Chapter 12 What is IPE? International Political Economy p Basically our lives are about political economy. p To survive we need food, clothes, and many other goods. p We obtain these provisions in the

More information

CENTRE WILLIAM-RAPPARD, RUE DE LAUSANNE 154, 1211 GENÈVE 21, TÉL

CENTRE WILLIAM-RAPPARD, RUE DE LAUSANNE 154, 1211 GENÈVE 21, TÉL CENTRE WILLIAM-RAPPARD, RUE DE LAUSANNE 154, 1211 GENÈVE 21, TÉL. 022 73951 11 GATT/1540 3 April 1992 ADDRESS BY MR. ARTHUR DUNKEL, DIRECTOR-GENERAL OF GATT TO THE CONFERENCE OF THE INTERNATIONAL HERALD

More information

Rules of Origin Process (Chile)

Rules of Origin Process (Chile) Asia-Pacific Economic Cooperation Secretariat 2004/SOM1/SCCP1/060 Agenda Item: 10.4 Rules of Origin Process (Chile) Sub-Committee on Customs Procedures Santiago, Chile 25-27 February 2004 BACKGROUND The

More information

POLI 12D: International Relations Sections 1, 6

POLI 12D: International Relations Sections 1, 6 POLI 12D: International Relations Sections 1, 6 Spring 2017 TA: Clara Suong Chapter 10 Development: Causes of the Wealth and Poverty of Nations The realities of contemporary economic development: Billions

More information

Determining factors of inbound travel to Japan A stronger yen matters more for the NIEs than China

Determining factors of inbound travel to Japan A stronger yen matters more for the NIEs than China Mizuho Economic Outlook & Analysis February 19, 216 Determining factors of inbound travel to Japan A stronger yen matters more for the NIEs than < Summary > To analyze the sustainability of inbound travel

More information

Growth and Poverty Reduction: An Empirical Analysis Nanak Kakwani

Growth and Poverty Reduction: An Empirical Analysis Nanak Kakwani Growth and Poverty Reduction: An Empirical Analysis Nanak Kakwani Abstract. This paper develops an inequality-growth trade off index, which shows how much growth is needed to offset the adverse impact

More information

Mizuho Economic Outlook & Analysis

Mizuho Economic Outlook & Analysis Mizuho Economic Outlook & Analysis The 18th Questionnaire Survey of Japanese Corporate Enterprises Regarding Business in Asia (February 18) - Japanese Firms Reevaluate China as a Destination for Business

More information

Report for Congress Received through the CRS Web

Report for Congress Received through the CRS Web Order Code 97-389 E Report for Congress Received through the CRS Web Generalized System of Preferences Updated June 28, 2002 William H. Cooper Specialist in International Trade and Finance Foreign Affairs,

More information

APEC and Regional Trading Arrangements in the Pacific

APEC and Regional Trading Arrangements in the Pacific First draft 5/17/94. Revised for publication 6/13/94. APEC and Regional Trading Arrangements in the Pacific Jeffrey A. Frankel Senior Fellow Institute for International Economics 11 Dupont Circle, NW Washington,

More information

TRADE IN THE GLOBAL ECONOMY

TRADE IN THE GLOBAL ECONOMY TRADE IN THE GLOBAL ECONOMY Learning Objectives Understand basic terms and concepts as applied to international trade. Understand basic ideas of why countries trade. Understand basic facts for trade Understand

More information

ECONOMIC INTEGRATION IN NORTHEAST ASIA: CHALLENGES AND STRATEGIES FOR SOUTH KOREA

ECONOMIC INTEGRATION IN NORTHEAST ASIA: CHALLENGES AND STRATEGIES FOR SOUTH KOREA New Paradigms for Transpacific Collaboration 15 ECONOMIC INTEGRATION IN NORTHEAST ASIA: CHALLENGES AND STRATEGIES FOR SOUTH KOREA Kar-yiu Wong * CONTENTS I. Introduction II. Mutual Dependence among South

More information

NON-TARIFF BARRIERS ON TRADE IN SERVICES

NON-TARIFF BARRIERS ON TRADE IN SERVICES Suyanto, Non-tariff Barriers On Trade In Services NON-TARIFF BARRIERS ON TRADE IN SERVICES Suyanto Fakultas Ekonomi Universitas Surabaya Abstract The increasing role of services in international trade

More information

REGIONAL INTEGRATION AND TRADE IN AFRICA: AUGMENTED GRAVITY MODEL APPROACH

REGIONAL INTEGRATION AND TRADE IN AFRICA: AUGMENTED GRAVITY MODEL APPROACH REGIONAL INTEGRATION AND TRADE IN AFRICA: AUGMENTED GRAVITY MODEL APPROACH Edris H. Seid The Horn Economic & Social Policy Institute (HESPI) 2013 African Economic Conference Johannesburg, South Africa

More information

Chapter 9. The Political Economy of Trade Policy. Slides prepared by Thomas Bishop

Chapter 9. The Political Economy of Trade Policy. Slides prepared by Thomas Bishop Chapter 9 The Political Economy of Trade Policy Slides prepared by Thomas Bishop Preview International negotiations of trade policy and the World Trade Organization Copyright 2006 Pearson Addison-Wesley.

More information

Chapter 11. Trade Policy in Developing Countries

Chapter 11. Trade Policy in Developing Countries Chapter 11 Trade Policy in Developing Countries Preview Import-substituting industrialization Trade liberalization since 1985 Trade and growth: Takeoff in Asia Copyright 2015 Pearson Education, Inc. All

More information

Trade, Border Effects, and Regional Integration between Russia s Far East and Northeast Asia

Trade, Border Effects, and Regional Integration between Russia s Far East and Northeast Asia Trade, Border Effects, and Regional Integration between Russia s Far East and Northeast Asia Russia s Far East (RFE) is set to benefit from Russia s growing economic cooperation with China in the face

More information

SUBREGIONAL TRADING ARRANGEMENTS AMONG APEC ECONOMIES: MANAGING DIVERSITY IN THE ASIA PACIFIC

SUBREGIONAL TRADING ARRANGEMENTS AMONG APEC ECONOMIES: MANAGING DIVERSITY IN THE ASIA PACIFIC SUBREGIONAL TRADING ARRANGEMENTS AMONG APEC ECONOMIES: MANAGING DIVERSITY IN THE ASIA PACIFIC Since 1999, there has been a sharp rise of interest in new subregional trading arrangements (SRTAs) involving

More information

Two-dimensional Fragmentation in East Asia: Conceptual Framework and Empirics =

Two-dimensional Fragmentation in East Asia: Conceptual Framework and Empirics = Two-dimensional Fragmentation in East Asia: Conceptual Framework and Empirics = Fukunari Kimura and Mitsuyo Ando Faculty of Economics, Keio University Tokyo, Japan (fkimura@econ.keio.ac.jp; m-ando@mbj.nifty.com)

More information

The Significance of Trade Integration among Developing Countries: A Comparison between ASEAN and AMU

The Significance of Trade Integration among Developing Countries: A Comparison between ASEAN and AMU Volume 23, Number 1, June 1998 The Significance of Trade Integration among Developing Countries: A Comparison between ASEAN and AMU Abdelaziz Testas ** 2 This paper analyses the significance of trade integration

More information

Mega-Regionalism in Asia: 5 Economic Implications

Mega-Regionalism in Asia: 5 Economic Implications Mega-Regionalism in Asia: 5 Economic Implications Ganeshan Wignaraja Advisor, Economic Research and Regional Cooperation Department, Asian Development Bank gwignaraja@adb.org London October 16, 2015 Selected

More information

UNIVERSITY OF COLORADO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS. Course Outline

UNIVERSITY OF COLORADO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS. Course Outline UNIVERSITY OF COLORADO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS Economics 8413 International Trade James R. Markusen August 2004 Phone: 492-0748 Office: 216 Office hours: Monday, Wednesday, 1:30-3:00 e-mail: james.markusen@colorado.edu

More information

An Empirical Analysis of Pakistan s Bilateral Trade: A Gravity Model Approach

An Empirical Analysis of Pakistan s Bilateral Trade: A Gravity Model Approach 103 An Empirical Analysis of Pakistan s Bilateral Trade: A Gravity Model Approach Shaista Khan 1 Ihtisham ul Haq 2 Dilawar Khan 3 This study aimed to investigate Pakistan s bilateral trade flows with major

More information

Trade theory and regional integration

Trade theory and regional integration Trade theory and regional integration Dr. Mia Mikic mia.mikic@un.org Myanmar Capacity Building Programme Training Workshop on Regional Cooperation and Integration 9-11 May 2016, Yangon Outline of this

More information

Charting South Korea s Economy, 1H 2017

Charting South Korea s Economy, 1H 2017 Charting South Korea s Economy, 1H 2017 Designed to help executives interpret economic numbers and incorporate them into company s planning. Publication Date: January 3 rd, 2017 Next Issue: To be published

More information

IMPLICATIONS OF U.S. FREE TRADE AGREEMENT WITH SOUTH KOREA

IMPLICATIONS OF U.S. FREE TRADE AGREEMENT WITH SOUTH KOREA JOURNAL OF ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT 27 Volume 33, Number 1, June 2008 IMPLICATIONS OF U.S. FREE TRADE AGREEMENT WITH SOUTH KOREA RENAN ZHUANG AND WON W. KOO * North Dakota State University This paper examines

More information

GENDER EQUALITY IN THE LABOUR MARKET AND FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT

GENDER EQUALITY IN THE LABOUR MARKET AND FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT THE STUDENT ECONOMIC REVIEWVOL. XXIX GENDER EQUALITY IN THE LABOUR MARKET AND FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT CIÁN MC LEOD Senior Sophister With Southeast Asia attracting more foreign direct investment than

More information

WORLD ECONOMIC EXPANSION in the first half of the 1960's has

WORLD ECONOMIC EXPANSION in the first half of the 1960's has Chapter 5 Growth and Balance in the World Economy WORLD ECONOMIC EXPANSION in the first half of the 1960's has been sustained and rapid. The pace has probably been surpassed only during the period of recovery

More information

Regional Economic Cooperation of ASEAN Plus Three: Opportunities and Challenges from Economic Perspectives.

Regional Economic Cooperation of ASEAN Plus Three: Opportunities and Challenges from Economic Perspectives. Regional Economic Cooperation of ASEAN Plus Three: Opportunities and Challenges from Economic Perspectives. Budiono Faculty of Economics and Business, Universitas Padjadjaran. Presented for lecture at

More information

Regional Trade Agreements. Chan KIM Gwenafaye MCCORMICK Rurika SUZUKI Suiran MURATA Chun H CHAN

Regional Trade Agreements. Chan KIM Gwenafaye MCCORMICK Rurika SUZUKI Suiran MURATA Chun H CHAN Regional Trade Agreements Chan KIM Gwenafaye MCCORMICK Rurika SUZUKI Suiran MURATA Chun H CHAN Forms of Regional Trade Cooperation Chan Kim 1M141065-0 General concept of regional economic integration An

More information

Geoeconomic and Geopolitical Considerations

Geoeconomic and Geopolitical Considerations 4 Geoeconomic and Geopolitical Considerations Any discussion of a prospective US-Taiwan FTA is embedded in a broader context, which is that the United States is using FTAs strategically to prod forward

More information

6. Policy Recommendations on How to Strengthen Financial Cooperation in Asia Wang Tongsan

6. Policy Recommendations on How to Strengthen Financial Cooperation in Asia Wang Tongsan 6. Policy Recommendations on How to Strengthen Financial Cooperation in Asia Wang Tongsan Institute of Quantitative & Technical Economics Chinese Academy of Social Sciences -198- Since the Chiang Mai Initiative

More information

Services Trade Liberalization between the European Union and Africa Caribbean and Pacific Countries: A Dynamic Approach

Services Trade Liberalization between the European Union and Africa Caribbean and Pacific Countries: A Dynamic Approach Services Trade Liberalization between the European Union and Africa Caribbean and Pacific Countries: A Dynamic Approach by Manitra A. Rakotoarisoa Selected Paper for the 20th Annual Conference on Global

More information

Debapriya Bhattacharya Executive Director, CPD. Mustafizur Rahman Research Director, CPD. Ananya Raihan Research Fellow, CPD

Debapriya Bhattacharya Executive Director, CPD. Mustafizur Rahman Research Director, CPD. Ananya Raihan Research Fellow, CPD Preferential Market Access to EU and Japan: Implications for Bangladesh [Methodological Notes presented to the CDG-GDN Research Workshop on Quantifying the Rich Countries Policies on Poor Countries, Washington

More information

The Clash of Liberalizations: Preferential Trade Agreements as a Stumbling Block to Multilateral Liberalization. Nuno Limão

The Clash of Liberalizations: Preferential Trade Agreements as a Stumbling Block to Multilateral Liberalization. Nuno Limão The Clash of Liberalizations: Preferential Trade Agreements as a Stumbling Block to Multilateral Liberalization Nuno Limão University of Maryland and CEPR August 2005 Comments prepared for the conference

More information

World trade interdependencies: a New Zealand perspective

World trade interdependencies: a New Zealand perspective World trade interdependencies: a New Zealand perspective David Gillmore and Phil Briggs A key determinant of New Zealand s growth is its trade with the rest of the world. We have developed a world inputoutput

More information

The Development of FTA Rules of Origin Functions

The Development of FTA Rules of Origin Functions The Development of FTA Rules of Origin Functions Xinxuan Cheng School of Management, Hebei University Baoding 071002, Hebei, China E-mail: cheng_xinxuan@126.com Abstract The rules of origin derived from

More information

Ethnic networks and trade: Intensive vs. extensive margins

Ethnic networks and trade: Intensive vs. extensive margins MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Ethnic networks and trade: Intensive vs. extensive margins Cletus C Coughlin and Howard J. Wall 13. January 2011 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/30758/ MPRA

More information

Migration of Labor From Ten Asian Countries to Japan -- An Economic Analysis

Migration of Labor From Ten Asian Countries to Japan -- An Economic Analysis Utah State University DigitalCommons@USU Economic Research Institute Study Papers Economics 1994 Migration of Labor From Ten Asian Countries to Japan -- An Economic Analysis Ikuko Saito Utah State University

More information

Preview. Chapter 9. The Cases for Free Trade. The Cases for Free Trade (cont.) The Political Economy of Trade Policy

Preview. Chapter 9. The Cases for Free Trade. The Cases for Free Trade (cont.) The Political Economy of Trade Policy Chapter 9 The Political Economy of Trade Policy Preview The cases for free trade The cases against free trade Political models of trade policy International negotiations of trade policy and the World Trade

More information

Market-Driven Trading Blocs in East Asia: Empirical Evidence from 1980 to 2000

Market-Driven Trading Blocs in East Asia: Empirical Evidence from 1980 to 2000 Journal of Economic Integration 23(2), June 2008; 272-296 Market-Driven Trading Blocs in East Asia: Empirical Evidence from 1980 to 2000 Deng-Shing Huang Institute of Economics, Academia Sinica Abstract

More information

Industrialization, Innovation and Industrial Policy

Industrialization, Innovation and Industrial Policy Industrialization, Innovation and Industrial Policy Lawrence J. Lau, Ph. D., D. Soc. Sc. (hon.) Kwoh-Ting Li Professor of Economic Development Department of Economics Stanford University Stanford, CA 94305-6072,

More information

2 The Case for Financial Regionalism

2 The Case for Financial Regionalism 2 The Case for Financial Regionalism The fundamental question posed by Asian regional financial cooperation is whether international financial relations should be organized primarily on a multilateral

More information

Global and Regional Economic Cooperation: China s Approach (Zou Mingrong)

Global and Regional Economic Cooperation: China s Approach (Zou Mingrong) Global and Regional Economic Cooperation: China s Approach (Zou Mingrong) Thank you, Jusuf (Co-Chair), for giving me the floor. I shall use the slot to cover briefly my interpretation on regional cooperation

More information

Chapter 4 Specific Factors and Income Distribution

Chapter 4 Specific Factors and Income Distribution Chapter 4 Specific Factors and Income Distribution Chapter Organization Introduction The Specific Factors Model International Trade in the Specific Factors Model Income Distribution and the Gains from

More information

Introduction to World Trade. Economia Internacional I International Trade theory August 15 th, Lecture 1

Introduction to World Trade. Economia Internacional I International Trade theory August 15 th, Lecture 1 Introduction to World Trade Economia Internacional I International Trade theory August 15 th, 2012 Lecture 1 Free Trade Free Trade occurs when a government does not attempt to influence, through quotas

More information

Cancún: Crisis or Catharsis? Bernard Hoekman, World Bank 1. September 20, 2003

Cancún: Crisis or Catharsis? Bernard Hoekman, World Bank 1. September 20, 2003 Cancún: Crisis or Catharsis? Bernard Hoekman, World Bank 1 September 20, 2003 During September 10-14, 2003, WTO members met in Cancún for a mid-term review of the Doha Round of trade negotiations, launched

More information

D/2005/2020/06 THE RISE OF CHINA: PROSPECTS OF REGIONAL TRADE POLICY. Filip ABRAHAM Jan VAN HOVE. International Economics

D/2005/2020/06 THE RISE OF CHINA: PROSPECTS OF REGIONAL TRADE POLICY. Filip ABRAHAM Jan VAN HOVE. International Economics THE RISE OF CHINA: PROSPECTS OF REGIONAL TRADE POLICY by Filip ABRAHAM Jan VAN HOVE International Economics Center for Economic Studies Discussion Paper Series DPS 05.06 http://www.econ.kuleuven.ac.be/ew/admin/default.htm

More information

Mohammad Ghodsi: Summary of Ph.D. Dissertation Trade Policy, Trade Conflicts, Determinants, and Consequences of Protectionism

Mohammad Ghodsi: Summary of Ph.D. Dissertation Trade Policy, Trade Conflicts, Determinants, and Consequences of Protectionism Mohammad Ghodsi: Summary of Ph.D. Dissertation Trade Policy, Trade Conflicts, Determinants, and Consequences of Protectionism Issues related to trade policy, its determinants and consequences have been

More information

International Trade Theory College of International Studies University of Tsukuba Hisahiro Naito

International Trade Theory College of International Studies University of Tsukuba Hisahiro Naito International Trade Theory College of International Studies University of Tsukuba Hisahiro Naito The specific factors model allows trade to affect income distribution as in H-O model. Assumptions of the

More information

Regional free-trade areas: sorting out the tangled spaghetti

Regional free-trade areas: sorting out the tangled spaghetti Regional free-trade areas: sorting out the tangled spaghetti Ross Garnaut and David Vines Abstract As a result of the difficulties in negotiating the liberalization of trade globally, countries seek liberalization

More information

Honors General Exam Part 1: Microeconomics (33 points) Harvard University

Honors General Exam Part 1: Microeconomics (33 points) Harvard University Honors General Exam Part 1: Microeconomics (33 points) Harvard University April 9, 2014 QUESTION 1. (6 points) The inverse demand function for apples is defined by the equation p = 214 5q, where q is the

More information

Chapter Nine. Regional Economic Integration

Chapter Nine. Regional Economic Integration Chapter Nine Regional Economic Integration Introduction 9-3 One notable trend in the global economy in recent years has been the accelerated movement toward regional economic integration - Regional economic

More information

The New Regionalism and Asia: Impact and Options. Jeffrey A. Frankel

The New Regionalism and Asia: Impact and Options. Jeffrey A. Frankel The New Regionalism and Asia: Impact and Options May 24, 1995 & 6/13 Jeffrey A. Frankel Department of Economics, 549 Evans Hall # 3880 University of California Berkeley, CA 94720-3880 USA; and Institute

More information

Charting Indonesia s Economy, 1H 2017

Charting Indonesia s Economy, 1H 2017 Charting Indonesia s Economy, 1H 2017 Designed to help executives interpret economic numbers and incorporate them into company s planning. Publication Date: January 3 rd, 2017 Next Issue: To be published

More information

Export Growth and Industrial Policy: Lessons from the East Asian Miracle Experience

Export Growth and Industrial Policy: Lessons from the East Asian Miracle Experience Latin America/Caribbean and Asia/Pacific Economics and Business Association An initiative of the Inter-American Development Bank and the Asian Development Bank Institute Second LAEBA Annual Meeting Buenos

More information

INTERNATIONAL TRADE & ECONOMICS LAW: THEORIES OF INTERNATIONAL TRADE AND ECONOMICS

INTERNATIONAL TRADE & ECONOMICS LAW: THEORIES OF INTERNATIONAL TRADE AND ECONOMICS Open Access Journal available at jlsr.thelawbrigade.com 1 INTERNATIONAL TRADE & ECONOMICS LAW: THEORIES OF INTERNATIONAL TRADE AND ECONOMICS Written by Abha Patel 3rd Year L.L.B Student, Symbiosis Law

More information