A Tale of Two Realisms: Expanding the Institutions Debate1

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "A Tale of Two Realisms: Expanding the Institutions Debate1"

Transcription

1 A Tale of Two Realisms: Expanding the Institutions Debate Author(s): Randall L. Schweller and David Priess Reviewed work(s): Source: Mershon International Studies Review, Vol. 41, No. 1 (May, 1997), pp Published by: Blackwell Publishing on behalf of The International Studies Association Stable URL: Accessed: 22/02/ :56 Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at. JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org. Blackwell Publishing and The International Studies Association are collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Mershon International Studies Review.

2 Mershon International Studies Review (1997) 41, 1-32 REFLECTION, EVALUATION, INTEGRATION A Tale of Two Realisms: Expanding the Institutions Debate1 RANDALL L. SCHWELLER Department of Political Science, Ohio State University DAVID PRIESS Department of Political Science, Duke University Recent developments in the study of international institutions have created a need and opportunity for restating the traditional realist view of the role of institutions in international relations. Advancing what he claimed was realism's perspective on this issue, John Mearsheimer (1994/95) forcefully staked out an extreme position that institutions are essentially epiphenomenal. Mearsheimer's arguments, however, derived from Waltzian neorealism, are inconsistent with traditional realism's concern for the origins and influence of international institutions. Moreover, they do not reflect the views of the newest wave of modified structural realists who adopt many of the insights of neoliberal institutionalism. In an attempt to show that pre-waltzian realists had much to say about institutions, this essay reviews the neorealist/neoliberal debate over institutions, clarifies the basic differences between traditional realism and neorealism, and resurfaces traditional realist arguments concerning the effects of state power and interests on international institutions and global order. Combining insights from both traditional realism and neorealism, a model is constructed that considers how the characteristics of states, their interactions, and the structure of the international system facilitate understanding the ways in which power will be exercised, the type of global order that will be produced, and the level of global institutionalization that can be expected. lan earlier version of this essay was presented at the 1996 annual meeting of the American Political Science Association, San Francisco, August 29-September 1. We thank Damon Coletta, John Duffield, Joe Grieco, John Ikenberry,Jack Snyder, and two anonymous reviewers for their comments and suggestions.? 1997 The Mershon Center at The Ohio State University. Published by Blackwell Publishers, 350 Main Street, Malden, MA 02148, USA, and 108 Cowley Road, Oxford OX4 1JF, UK.

3 2 A Tale of Two Realisms: Expanding the Institutions Debate No topic in international relations theory has generated more debate over the last decade than the role of international institutions-whether institutions matter, why states invest in them, and how they influence decisionmakers' choices in world politics. Institutions, defined by Robert Keohane (1989:3) as "persistent and connected sets of rules (formal and informal) that prescribe behavioral roles, constrain activity, and shape expectations" and byjohn Mearsheimer (1994/95:8) as "a set of rules that stipulate the ways in which states should cooperate and compete with one another," are important to scholars and policymakers alike. Our understanding of them has implications far beyond those of many topics in international relations, as indicated both by the ongoing discussions over the role of the North Atlantic Treaty Organization (NATO) and the United Nations after the Cold War (see Heisborg 1992; Glaser 1993; Hellmann and Wolf 1993; Keohane, Nye, and Hoffmann 1993; Carpenter 1994; Duffield 1994/95, 1996; Chernoff 1995; Risse- Kappen 1995, 1996; McCalla 1996; Walt 1996b; Kupchan forthcoming) and by the efforts to build new institutions to support a liberal multilateral order (Keohane, Nye, and Hoffmann 1993). Mearsheimer's (1994/95) recent contentious tour de force, "The False Promise of International Institutions," has sparked a new round in the international institutions debate. Grounded in the neorealist perspective of Kenneth Waltz (1979, 1986), Mearsheimer (1994/95:7) claims that institutions "matter only on the margins" and "have minimal influence on state behavior." His extreme position effectively puts realists of all stripes on the defensive in discussions about institutions. Using Mearsheimer as a foil, neoliberal institutionalists such as Keohane and Lisa Martin (1995) have been able to (mis)characterize realism as a theory that entirely neglects institutions, while implying that the neoliberal institutionalist school of thought has pride of place in scholarly and policy discourse on institutions. Indeed, neoliberals have thrown down the gauntlet: "We challenge realists to construct an account of institutional variation and effects" (Keohane and Martin 1995:48). Likewise, Joseph Grieco (1993:312) observes that the recent debate drives realists to "think more carefully about how their own preferred approach views the role and significance of international institutions." Traditional realists, however, did recognize that institutions are a vital part of the landscape of world politics. Their writings and those of a new wave of modified structural realists reflect an understanding of the roles institutions can and do play in international relations. This review uses the recent debate on international institutions as a starting point for an analysis of the differences between traditional realism and neorealism and an elucidation of a realist view of institutions that draws insights from each. Its purpose is to argue that although the neorealist movement has added much to our understanding of international affairs through its careful examination of the impact of polarity on state behavior, it has also jettisoned the concern for unit attributes and interactions that was crucial to traditional realist theory, leading to the hyperrealism on institutions that Mearsheimer espouses. By combining neorealism's structural focus with traditional realism's attention to unit attributes and interactions, it is possible to construct a systems theory that offers realist explanations for the creation and influence of international institutions. This review proceeds as follows. First, it traces the recent neorealist/neoliberal debate, demonstrating the need for a realist view of institutions. Second, it analyzes the similarities and differences between traditional realism and neorealism, highlighting how the jettisoning of traditional realist concepts has led to the neorealist view that institutions are unimportant. Third, it examines realist thought on the subject of international institutions and the relation of these institutions to international structures and state interests. Fourth, bringing together insights from both

4 RANDALL L. SCHWELLER AND DAVID PRIESS 3 traditional realism and neorealism, it presents a realist model of the origins and influence of international institutions. Finally, it concludes with a discussion of international institutions in the post-cold War world that is based on the model and some considerations of an agenda for future research that focuses on how to test the model. The Neoliberal/Neorealist Institutions Debate2 Robert Keohane's 1984 book, After Hegemony, marks a turning point in scholarship on international institutions. In this book Keohane (1984:9) adopted several realist assumptions, including the central role of power in politics and the dominance of the nation-state in the contemporary international system.3 In so doing, he was able to explain why even self-interested, rational egoists often prefer multilateral cooperation to competitive unilateral policies. Thus began a new wave of international relations scholarship that has come to be known as "neoliberal institutionalism." The central tenet of neoliberal institutionalism is that "state actions depend to a considerable degree on prevailing institutional arrangements" (Keohane 1989:2). Focusing on the demand for institutions, neoliberals argue that they are valuable because they allow states to overcome "market failures" in international relations. Specifically, institutions enable fruitful interaction by: (1) reducing the "relative costs of transactions" (Keohane 1984:89; see also Ostrom 1991); (2) lengthening the "shadow of the future" (Axelrod 1984; Axelrod and Keohane 1985); and (3) increasing the amount of information available to states about each other, which, neoliberals claim, reduces the likelihood that states will cheat (or profit by cheating) on established agreements or norms (Keohane 1984:92-96, 1989:ch.5). Many of the same ideas are expressed in the international regimes literature, which parallels the neoliberal institutionalist tradition. Many of the regime arguments have also found their way into the institutions debate (Krasner 1983; Haggard and Simmons 1987; Hansenclever, Mayer, and Rittberger 1996). One difficulty in resolving the neorealist/neoliberal dispute is that the two schools assess the effectiveness of institutions in contradictory ways. Neorealists argue that institutions matter to the extent that they cause states to behave in ways they otherwise would not behave-for example, foregoing short-term, self-interest in favor of long-term community goals (Jervis 1983). In contrast, neoliberals claim that institutions matter because they enable states to do things they otherwise could not do, that is, achieve mutual gains from cooperation. Neorealists conceptualize institutions as constraints on state behavior; neoliberals see them as enabling states to reach mutually beneficial, cooperative outcomes. This constraint/empowerment distinction is blurred in traditional realism. Defining politics as the exercise of power and influence in the process of governing, traditional realism encompasses both of these aspects of institutional effectiveness (see the following section). As tools of empowerment, institutions enable Great Powers to rule others and to manage regional and world affairs more effectively and efficiently than would be possible in their absence. As constraints, institutions such as balance-of-power poli- 2For a more detailed discussion of the neoliberal/neorealist debate, see Baldwin (1993). 3Keohane's acceptance of realist assumptions contrasted with traditional perspectives drawn from liberalism. However, the continued relevance of realist concepts to international events in the late 1970s and early 1980s and the failure of such nonstate actors as multinational corporations, the United Nations, and regional international institutions to render the nation-state obsolete, as liberalism had expected, had already caused many liberal theorists to abandon their primary research programs: functionalism (Mitrany 1948, 1966; Haas 1964), regional integration (Haas 1958; Schmitter 1969; Lindberg and Scheingold 1971), and interdependence theory (Keohane and Nye 1977). For more on the realist/liberal debate that predated the modern period, see Waltz (1959) and Thompson (1994).

5 4 A Tale of Two Realisms: Expanding the Institutions Debate tics and Concert diplomacy guide and direct Great Power behavior in accordance with the established rules of the game; Great Powers either conform to the institutional rules and norms or risk suffering the consequences for noncompliance. Other issues hindering resolution of the debate lie within neoliberal institutionalism itself. For one thing, the perspective's assumptions are not delineated clearly from its hypotheses. For example, in International Institutions and State Power, Keohane (1989:2-3) posits that the neoliberal institutionalist perspective is "relevant to an international system only if two key conditions pertain. First, the actors must have some mutual interests... [Second,] variations in the degree of institutionalization exert substantial effects on state behavior." Keohane (1989:5-6) also argues that international institutions "are important for states' actions in part because they affect the incentives facing states,... [and] have constitutive as well as regulative aspects: they help define how interests are defined and how actions are interpreted." Although Keohane's writings remain the clearest exposition of the perspective, it is still difficult to determine (1) if institutions matter, and the perspective will tell us how and why, or (2) if institutions sometimes matter, and the perspective will tell us when. A second issue arises from neoliberal institutionalism's inconsistency regarding the influence of international institutions. Although significant causal weight is attributed to "variations in the institutionalization of world politics," the claim is also made that institutional effectiveness is "not necessarily correlated with institutionalization" (Keohane 1989:2, 6). To reconcile these statements, neoliberal institutionalists must maintain-again using Keohane's (1989:2, 7) words-that institutions that are "of relatively modest significance in world politics" can and do "exert significant effects on the behavior of governments," an apparent contradiction. Despite these questions about the core of neoliberal institutionalist thought, the perspective has gained much attention from international relations scholars. In several issue-areas-including environmental treaty compliance, shipping, air transport, telecommunications and postal service regimes, NATO conventional force levels, and economic sanctions-neoliberal institutionalism appears to provide a persuasive explanation of international relations (see, for example, Duffield 1992, 1994, 1995; Martin 1992a; Mitchell 1994a, 1994b; Zacher 1996). International institutions, these writers claim, can move states toward cooperation, keep them there, and exert profound effects on state choices (see also, Young 1989, 1992; Risse-Kappen 1995, 1996; Wallander and Keohane 1995). Perhaps the optimistic spirit of the neoliberal institutionalist school is justified. Mearsheimer's "False Promise" Claim The neoliberal challenge to the realist understanding of world politics has continued to gain momentum despite a strong realist counterattack in the late 1980s that focused on how an emphasis on relative gains could inhibit international cooperation (Waltz 1979:105; Grieco 1988a, 1988b, 1990, 1993). Attempting to stem this tide and reclaim the high ground for neorealism, Mearsheimer (1994/95:7) maintained that the neoliberal institutionalists have overstated their case and that, in fact, institutions "have no independent effect on state behavior." Mearsheimer waged a two-prong attack against neoliberals. First, he reiterated Grieco's argument that neoliberal institutionalists underestimate the barriers to cooperation in the anarchic international system, in particular the inhibiting effect of relative-gains concerns. In brief, the claim is made that without a higher power, states must worry about any state gaining a relative advantage through cooperation, because "today's friend may be tomorrow's enemy in war" (Grieco 1990:29; for extensions of the debate, see Krasner 1991; Mastanduno 1991; Powell 1991;

6 RANDALL L. SCHWELLER AND DAVID PRIESS 5 Snidal 1991a, 1991b; Milner 1992; Busch and Reinhardt 1993; Grieco, Powell, and Snidal 1993; Keohane 1993; Liberman 1996; Matthews 1996). Therefore, states are less willing to cooperate than neoliberal institutionalists believe. Not only concerns about cheating but worries over the distribution of gains must be overcome for cooperation to blossom. Second, Mearsheimer (1994/95:24, fn. 78) questioned the empirical evidence that neoliberal theorists have forwarded to support their perspective: "What is needed is evidence of cooperation that would not have occurred in the absence of institutions because of fear of cheating, or its actual presence. But scholars have provided little evidence of cooperation of that sort," a point acknowledged by several neoliberal institutionalist writers (Young 1989:206; Martin 1992b:144). Mearsheimer went on to critique some of the leading works of institutionalist theory, including Keohane's (1984) After Hegemony and Martin's (1992a) Coercive Cooperation. Mearsheimer (1994/95:24) concluded, on the basis of his analysis of neoliberal institutionalist logic and evidence, that "institutions have minimal influence on state behavior, and thus hold little promise for promoting stability in the post-cold War world." He did not deny that institutions exist or that states use them to their advantage. Rather, Mearsheimer (1994/95:47) argued: "What is most impressive about institutions, in fact, is how little independent effect they seem to have had on state behavior." The Neoliberal Institutionalist Response Mearsheimer's article elicited direct responses from champions of collective security (Kupchan and Kupchan 1995), constructivism (Wendt 1995), and those sympathetic to neoliberal institutionalism (Keohane and Martin 1995; see also Ruggie 1995). Keohane and Martin (1995:40) asked: "How are we to account for the willingness of major states to invest resources in expanding international institutions, if such institutions are lacking in significance?" Dismissing Mearsheimer's answer that policymakers investing in institutions are ideologically blinded, they placed the burden of proof on neorealists to show that policymakers have suffered from such delusions. At the same time, they acknowledged that neoliberal institutionalist scholarship in the past has underemphasized the distributional concerns arising from cooperation. Keohane and Martin (1995:45-46), however, claimed that "distributional conflict may render institutions more important... Far from leading to the conclusion that institutions are not significant in world politics, the relative-gains debate has led us to understand yet another pathway through which they substantially influence the course of international relations" (emphasis in original). In addition, they contested Mearsheimer's argument that institutionalist theory suffers from a lack of empirical support by citing several key studies on its behalf. But Keohane and Martin (1995:50) did admit that "we do not adequately understand in what domains [institutions] matter most, under what conditions, and how their effects are exerted." Similarly, much of their response was devoted to laying out strategies for future neoliberal institutionalist research rather than showcasing results of previous studies. Keohane and Martin (1995:51) concluded that the neoliberal institutionalist "research program" is "promising," especially when compared to "the extant alternatives." We disagree with Keohane and Martin's conclusion. A competitive "realist" alternative has been overlooked in this ongoing debate. Mearsheimer has made an impressive case against international institutions, but he has taken a narrow neorealist view that ignores arguments advanced by earlier, pre-waltzian realists. Although traditional realists did not develop a full-blown theory of institutions, they had many insights on the subject. The challenge is to reassert these insights and

7 6 A Tale of Two Realisms: Expanding the Institutions Debate merge them with elements of neorealism to form a coherent whole. First, however, we must clearly distinguish traditional realism from neorealism. Traditional Realism and Neorealism: Similarities and Differences Although there are numerous divisions within the realist tradition, all realists subscribe to four assumptions that are held to be the key tenets of the paradigm (see Carr 1946; Morgenthau 1985; Gilpin 1986, 1996; Grieco 1990; Mearsheimer 1994/95; Elman 1996; Frankel 1996; Spegele 1996). Assumption One: humans do not face one another primarily as individuals but as members of groups that command their loyalty (see especially Gilpin 1986: , 1996:7). This assumption most centrally distinguishes realism from liberalism. As Andrew Moravcsik (1993:7-8) has written, liberalism assumes that the fundamental actors in politics are "autonomous individuals and private groups differentiated by their variable interests and resource endowments." In the contemporary world, the primary "conflict group" is the nation-state, leading many realists simply to assert that "states are the major actors in world affairs" (Grieco 1990:3; see also Waltz 1979:95; Frankel 1996:xiv-xv; Gilpin 1996:18-26; Spegele 1996:85). Assumption Two: international affairs take place in a state of anarchy. There is no "higher power" to enforce agreements made between, or to keep the peace among, nation-states. Thus, states ultimately must rely upon themselves to ensure their survival. Assumption Three: the nature of international interaction is essentially conflictual. In the words of Nicholas Spykman (1942:12), "A world without struggle would be a world in which life had ceased to exist." For some realists, conflict is inevitable because of the imperfectibility of human nature and the constant scarcity of material resources, markets, and social goods (Niebuhr 1932, 1944; Morgenthau 1946, 1948). Other realists locate the source of international conflict in the anarchic structure of the international system, which causes constant uncertainty about others' intentions and creates the security dilemma (Waltz 1979; Gilpin 1986:304; see also Jervis 1986; Schweller 1996). Still other realists derive the ubiquity of conflict directly from anarchy and so do not label it an assumption (Grieco 1990:4). As Helen Milner (1991, 1992; see also Wendt 1992; Mercer 1995; Schweller 1996) has pointed out, however, the conflictual nature of politics may not be as clearly derivative of anarchy as some authors have suggested; thus, it is included here as an assumption of the realist paradigm. Assumption Four: power is the fundamental feature of international politics. The absence of a formal international authority and world government means that when all else fails, military force is the final and legitimate arbiter of disputes among states. Because "war lurks in the background of international politics" (Carr 1946:109), "for each state its power in relation to other states is ultimately the key to its survival" (Waltz 1959:210). In the final analysis, power is the basis for securing any state aim, whether it seeks world mastery or simply to be left alone. There is, as Reinhold Niebuhr (1932:42) has put it, "no possibility of drawing a sharp line between the will-to-live and the will-to-power." This logic also lies behind the influence-maximizing assumption adopted by Fareed Zakaria (1995). Disagreements within the realist tradition arise from basic philosophical differences, from placing emphasis on different assumptions or, more often, from vary-

8 RANDALL L. SCHWELLER AND DAVID PRIESS 7 ing interpretations of the preceding assumptions. The major division within realism is between traditional realism and neorealism: the former described in the writings of E. H. Carr (1946), Hans Morgenthau (1946, 1948), Arnold Wolfers (1962), and Robert Gilpin (1981, 1986, 1996); the latter in works by Waltz (1979, 1986, 1993), Christopher Layne (1993, 1994), and Mearsheimer (1990, 1994/95).4 Six major differences divide traditional realists and neorealists. First, there is a philosophical disagreement over the discipline(s) in which realist theory is grounded. Traditional realism is rooted in sociology and history (with some attention to psychology, theology, and economics); neorealism borrows most heavily from microeconomics (Kapstein 1995:771; Jepperson, Wendt, and Katzenstein 1996; Katzenstein 1996; Priess 1996b). Second, traditional realists view power as an end in itself; states can seek to maximize power as well as security (Gilpin 1996:6). Neorealists believe that security is the highest end (Waltz 1979:126). Third, the basic causal variables are not the same for traditional realists and neorealists. Traditional realists posit that power and the interests of states drive behavior; neorealists examine only anarchy and the distribution of capabilities. The fourth and fifth differences center on the meaning of "capability." Traditional realism is a theory of foreign policy, focusing on the relative distribution (balances and imbalances) of capabilities between specific states or coalitions of states, not on the systemwide distribution of capabilities or the polarity of the system. As Morgenthau (1948:137) has written, "The historically most important manifestation of the balance of power... is to be found... in the relations between one nation or alliance and another alliance." Traditional realists understand capability to be neither a unit nor a structural attribute but rather a relationship between states, for example, the potential outcome of military conflict (Snyder 1996). Seen as a product of unit interactions, capability is a process variable that describes the effects of relative dyadic or coalitional power disparities on interstate behavior and strategic interactions. In contrast, neorealism is a theory of international politics,5 focusing on the systemwide distribution of capabilities, that is, the polarity of the system as measured by the number of Great Powers, not the relative inequalities of power among them. Neorealists conceptualize capability as a unit-level property, indicated by a state's inventory of military forces and those resources that can be transformed into military forces; this concept is then merely raised to the system level (see Waltz 1979:126; Mearsheimer 1994/95:10). Such a process yields the main explanatory variable of neorealism: system polarity-a structural property that is largely ignored by traditional realists (Snyder 1996). Sixth, the two camps disagree over the meaning of "system." A system refers to "an arrangement of certain components so interrelated as to form a whole" (Klir 1972:1) or "sets of elements standing in interaction" (von Bertalanffy 1968:38). For traditional realists, the international system is composed of units, interactions, and structure. "Interaction is crucial to the concept of system, for without it, the term system has no meaning," as Barry Buzan and his colleagues (Buzan, Jones, and Little 1993:29) have observed. The inclusion of interaction in the definition of a system allows process variables (for instance, institutions, norms, rules) as well as structural ones to define the nature of world politics and to have an effect on its operation and dynamics (Snyder 1996). In neorealism, such process variables are 4For a different division of realism into two schools labeled "tragedy" and "evil," see Spirtas (1996); see also the analysis of realism in Tellis (1996). 5Elman (1996) has argued that neorealism can produce theories of foreign policy; for a response to his claim, see Waltz (1996).

9 8 A Tale of Two Realisms: Expanding the Institutions Debate not considered system attributes. Although Waltz (1979:79) defines a system as "composed of structure and of interacting units," his distinction between reductionist theories (based on unit attributes and interactions) and systemic theories (based on structural causes) and "his usage of terms such as 'systems theory' and 'systems level' makes the term system effectively a synonym for structure" (Buzan, Jones, and Little 1993:28). In Waltz's (1979:79) words, "definitions of structure must leave aside, or abstract from, the characteristics of units, their behavior, and their interactions." Realists on Institutions In this section, we will build the case for a realist perspective on institutions by reviewing the relationships posited by traditional realists between structure and institutions as well as between interests and institutions. Structure and Institutions: Modified Structural Realism Gilpin (1981:28) describes three basic structures in world politics: The first structure is imperialistic or hegemonic: A single powerful state controls or dominates the lesser states in the system... The second structure is bipolar structure in which two powerful states control and regulate interactions within and between their respective spheres of influence... The third type of structure is a balance of power in which three or more states control one another's actions through diplomatic maneuver, shifting alliances, and open conflict. At its core, neorealist theory seeks to explain the effects that different international structures have on state behavior and international politics. Indeed, as Waltz (1986:329) averred, attention to international structures does "tell us a small number of big and important things." As will be discussed below, these structures affect the development and nature of institutional arrangements: unipolar distributions of power tend toward imposed orders; bipolar structures generate spontaneous, informal orders between the two poles and more formal institutional arrangements within the attendant blocs; and multipolar systems engender both imposed and spontaneous orders. Realists do not deny the veracity of the neoliberal claim that international regimes may be created through negotiated processes (for example, the Concert of Europe under multipolarity). In explaining these kinds of orders, however, realists of all stripes characterize them, not in terms of cooperation to promote the general welfare of states as liberals past and present tend to do, but rather as a form of collusion among powerful oligopolistic actors to serve their perceived interests at the expense of the "others," that is, those states deemed to be outside the elite Great Power club or international "high society." In the eyes of the included Great Powers, concert systems appear as negotiated orders. From the perspective of the excluded powers, these types of institutions are viewed as an imposed order by a few dominant and essentially satisfied actors (Jervis 1983, 1986; see also Kissinger 1994). Building on this notion of institutions as a form of collusion, Edward Mansfield (1995:600; also 1994a) has argued that international institutions are susceptible in varying degrees to capture by specific states and/or special interests within states: "States and interest groups have an incentive to capture international institutions because they can generate power for those that control them. Actors that gain power within an institution have the ability to set its agenda and influence the distribution of benefits and costs among members." States also use institutions to

10 RANDALL L. SCHWELLER AND DAVID PRIESS 9 advance their interests through the strategy of "binding," in which a state seeks to exert some control over another state's policies by incorporating it in a web of institutional arrangements. Historian Paul Schroeder (1976) has pointed out that alliances often are designed to restrain or control partners' actions as well as to balance adversaries. Likewise, Grieco (1995:34; 1996: ) has posited his "voice opportunities" thesis, according to which "weaker but still influential partners will seek to ensure that the rules... will provide sufficient opportunities for them to voice their concerns and interests and thereby prevent or at least ameliorate their domination by stronger partners." Binding, as a realist strategy, offers rising powers a "place at the table" in an attempt to meet their prestige demands, and it gives them "opportunities for an effective voice" while fostering a renewed sense of legitimacy in the established international order. Binding is consistent with, but more encompassing than, Henry Kissinger's (1979:129) "linkage" strat- egy.6 Following Carr and Gilpin, traditional realists view institutions as intervening variables between the theory's basic causal variables and related behavior and outcomes (Krasner 1983:7-8). In other words, outcomes do not always conform to what one would expect from purely power motivations in an anarchic, zero-sum situation because institutions can modify the outcomes and behaviors of actors. How much variation, if any, is attributable to institutions depends on how far removed the action or outcome to be explained is from the creation of the existing order and its associated institutions. According to these theorists, institutions reflect the power relationships that existed at their creation; they are representations of the past that endure beyond the situations and interests that created them. Recently, a new school, which can be called "modified structural realism" following Stephen Krasner (1983:7-8), has emerged in response to the increased complexity and massive economic and social changes wrought by the end of the Cold War. These new complexities and changes have so overwhelmed neorealism's ultraparsimonious, structural formulation that it now appears more as a theoretical straightjacket than a progressive research paradigm. This current wave of realist theory, exemplified by the writings of Jack Snyder (1991), Stephen Van Evera (1991), Steve Fetter (1992), Ted Hopf (1992), Daniel Deudney (1993), Grieco (1993, 1996), and Scott Sagan (1994), borrows heavily from Samuel Huntington's (1968:5) Political Order in Changing Societies, particularly its basic premise that the "primary problem of politics is the lag in the development of political institutions behind social and economic change." Modified structural realists agree with the neoliberal view that a demand exists (now more than ever) for international regimes and institutions, even in the realm of international security. Indeed, Jack Snyder (1991:137, 139) has concluded that the solution to the problem of "security in the changing European order" is "a middle road between the Hobbesian instinct for insulation and the neo-liberal instinct for institutionalized activism." Mindful of the pernicious effects of international anarchy and of the emerging multipolarity in East Asia and Europe that can make cooperation in the form of institution-building difficult to achieve, modified structural realists posit that international institutions serve four vital functions. First, they help create stability and order by filling "the gap between rising political participation and weak governing institutions" and thereby prevent the spread of praetorian regimes (J. Snyder 1991: ). Second, participation, particularly in Western economic institutions, can be offered as a "carrot" in exchange for a strong effort on the part of the 6For a view of binding (or "co-binding") from a liberal perspective, see Deudney (1995, 1996), Deudney and Ikenberry (1996), and Ikenberry (1996).

11 10 A Tale of Two Realisms: Expanding the Institutions Debate target state to dampen hypernationalism, militarism, and conflict among nationalities (Van Evera 1991: ; Hopf 1992: ). Third, international institutions can be used to manage nuclear proliferation and to provide nuclearizing states with technical assistance to secure their deterrents (Van Evera 1991:240; Fetter 1992:397; Hopf 1992: ; Deudney 1993:32-34; Sagan 1994). Fourth, membership in international institutions gives weaker states more opportunities to voice their concerns and, as a consequence, a greater chance to influence the policies of stronger neighbors (Grieco 1993: , 1996: ). Because traditional and modified structural realists acknowledge that outcomes do not always correspond to the actual power distribution among the actors in the system but are instead modified by institutional arrangements, they believe that institutions do indeed matter. Their view contradicts Mearsheimer's (1994/95:49) assertion that institutions "have mattered rather little" in international politics. Moreover, they argue that it is important to examine the disjunction between the actual power distribution and the existing institutional order-the system's prestige and hierarchy. As this disjunction grows with time, it eventually leads to systemic disequilibrium and war, which, in turn, restores some semblance of stability by creating institutions and outcomes that once again reflect the actual power relationships among the major actors (Carr 1946; Gilpin 1981). At a more fundamental level, traditional and modified structural realists believe that institutions matter because even the most rudimentary interactions among states require agreement on, and some shared understanding of, the basic rules of the game. For this reason, order of almost any kind is preferable to chaos; it is the indispensable cement of all social systems (Niebuhr 1932). As Gilpin (1981:35-36) has observed: In addition to the distribution of power and the hierarchy of prestige, the third component of the governance of the international system is a set of rights and rules that govern or at least influence the interactions among states... Every system of human interaction requires a minimum set of rules and the mutual recognition of rights. The need for rules and rights arises from the basic human condition of scarcity of material resources and the need for order and predictability in human affairs. In order to minimize conflict over the distribution of scarce goods and to facilitate fruitful cooperation among individuals, every social system creates rules and laws for governing behavior. This is as true for international systems as for domestic systems.... Although the rights and rules governing interstate behavior are to varying degrees based on consensus and mutual interest, the primary foundation of rights and rules is in the power and interests of the dominant groups or states in a social system... In every social system the dominant actors assert their rights and impose rules on lesser members in order to advance their particular interests. Interests and Institutions7 Less explicit than the distribution of capabilities, but no less important for the traditional realist's view of institutions, is the role of state interests. Power tells us how much influence a state will have over others; interests tell us when and for what purposes that influence will be used. Power and interests are integrally related; that is, the interests of states are also largely a function of their position in the international system. For instance, an economic hegemon has an overriding interest in an open international trading structure precisely because-given its larger size and more advanced economic development vis-a-vis other states-it stands to gain the most from free trade (Gilpin 1987:ch. 3). Similarly, rapid change in the distribution of relative 7The logic of this section follows Schweller (1996).

12 RANDALL L. SCHWELLER AND DAVID PRIESS 11 capabilities tends to promote revisionist aims among the rising powers. Stable bipolar configurations are likely to lead to the adoption of a status quo orientation by the two poles, resulting in a superpower "condominium" of sorts. Even though state interests have been a traditional concern of realists, these unit-level variations were excised from the theory by neorealists for the sake of greater parsimony. Neorealism assumes that all states seek to maximize their security and not necessarily their power. As Waltz (1979:126) has observed, "In anarchy, security is the highest end. Only if survival is assured can states safely seek other goals such as tranquillity, profit, and power." The notion, however, on which this assertion is based-that prior realist theory erringly posited power-maximizing be- havior-is incorrect. Not unlike Wilsonian liberalism, which divided the world into good and bad (democratic and nondemocratic states, respectively), traditional realism distinguishes two types of states: Morgenthau (1948:156) called them imperialistic and status quo states; Frederick Schuman (1948: ) employed the terms satiated and unsatiated powers; Kissinger (1957) saw revolutionary and status quo powers; Carr (1946) distinguished satisfied from dissatisfied states; Johannes Mattern (1942) divided the world into "haves" and "have-nots"; Wolfers (1962: ) referred to status quo and revisionist states; and Raymond Aron (1966:ch.3) posited an eternal struggle between the forces of revision and conservation. Traditional realists viewed this international struggle not in Manichean terms, as a morality play between the forces of light and dark or between good and evil as Wilsonian liberals did, but rather as a natural power struggle between the established, satisfied powers and the rising, dissatisfied ones-often the victors and vanquished in the last major-power war. From the perspective of traditional realists, the concept of power politics should be applied equally to both "haves" and "have nots," status quo and revisionist states. In Carr's (1946:105) words: "It is profoundly misleading to represent the struggle between satisfied and dissatisfied Powers as a struggle between morality on one side and power on the other. It is a clash in which, whatever the moral issue, power politics are equally predominant on both sides" (see also, Bull 1969; Smith 1986:ch.4; Kaufman 1996). Similarly, Aron (1966:584) has maintained: Idealistic diplomacy slips too often into fanaticism; it divides states into good and evil, into peace-loving and bellicose. It envisions a permanent peace by the punishment of the latter and the triumph of the former. The idealist, believing he has broken with power politics, exaggerates its crimes... States, engaged in incessant competition... are not divided, once and for all, into good and evil. It is rare that all the wrongs are committed by one side, that one camp is faultless. At issue in the enduring conflict between satisfied and dissatisfied states is the legitimacy of the institutional arrangements or governance structures that define the established international order. In this regard, it is important to recall that "legitimacy," as realists use the term, does not imply justice. As Kissinger (1957:1) writes, legitimacy... means no more than an international agreement about the nature of workable arrangements and about the permissible aims and methods of foreign policy. It implies the acceptance of the framework of the international order by all major powers, at least to the extent that no state is so dissatisfied that, like Germany after the Treaty of Versailles, it expresses its dissatisfaction in a revolutionary foreign policy. A legitimate order does not make conflicts impossible, but it limits their scope. In a legitimate order, even the most dissatisfied states desire only changes within the system, not a change of the system. Adjustments to the status quo are acceptable as long as they are made within the framework of existing institutional arrangements, not at their expense.

13 12 A Tale of Two Realisms: Expanding the Institutions Debate For realists, following Carr (1946), international institutions reflect the interests of the dominant, established powers and the distribution of capabilities that existed at the time of their creation after the last hegemonic war. Accordingly, international institutions and law are associated with policies of the status quo-the legitimate right of the dominant powers to set the "rules of the game" and to seek to perpetuate their relative power and interests against those of the vanquished and late-developing states. The distribution of power that exists at a particular moment in history finds its legal expression in the peace treaties as well as the international organizations and norms supporting them that have been formulated by the victors of the preceding hegemonic or major-power war (Morgenthau 1985:53-54). Regarding international law, Morgenthau (1985: ) has remarked: Any legal order tends to be primarily a static social force. It defines a certain distribution of power and offers standards and processes to ascertain and maintain it in concrete situations. Domestic law, through a highly developed system of legislation, judicial decisions, and law enforcement, allows for adaptions and sometimes even considerable changes within the general distribution of power. International law, in the absence of such a system making for lawful change, is... not only primarily but essentially, by dint of its very nature, a static force. In addition to international organizations and law, the balance of power itself was seen by classical realists as an elaborate system of rules and rights designed to protect and legitimize the existing order. In stark contrast with the neorealist conception of the balance of power as a self-regulating, unintended consequence of the system's structure, traditional realists view the balance of power as an institution-a deliberate and voluntary cooperative agreement among the dominant powers-resting on common values, common interests, and consensual understandings of the rules of behavior required for its proper functioning (Gulick 1955; Bull 1977:32). As Morgenthau (1985:239) has noted: Before the balance of power could impose its restraints upon the power aspirations of nations through the mechanical interplay of opposing forces, the competing nations had first to restrain themselves by accepting the system of the balance of power as the common framework of their endeavors... It is this consensus-both child and father, as it were, of common moral standards and a common civilization as well as of common interests-that kept in check the limitless desire for power, potentially inherent, as we know, in all imperialisms, and prevented it from becoming a political actuality. Where such a consensus no longer exists or has become weak and is no longer sure of itself, as in the period starting with the partitions of Poland and ending with the Napoleonic Wars, the balance of power is incapable of fulfilling its function for international stability and national independence. Although international institutions are inherently tools of conservation and management, they may also facilitate limited change by providing a general framework of rules and rights within which adjustments can be made that leave the status quo essentially intact. The British conceptualized the League of Nations in this way-as a concert-like forum for the inclusive purposes of consultation, conciliation, and compromise between the satisfied and dissatisfied powers (Kissinger 1994:ch. 9). Similarly, but in a less formal institutional setting, the rules of compensations and indemnities are modes of operation of the balance of power for the purpose of making territorial changes and payments for services or losses without disturbing the relative distribution of power in the system (Wight 1978:ch. 17; Schroeder 1994:6-7). Because international institutions, according to traditional realists, tend to promote the interests of the powerful at the expense of the weak, they ultimately

14 RANDALL L. SCHWELLER AND DAVID PRIESS 13 derive their authority less from shared views of justice and morality than from the superior power of the ruling, status quo state or states. Traditional realists are not, however, suggesting that international order depends at all times on the exercise of brute force or coercive power by the hegemon. Although imposed at its creation, the existing order and its associated institutional arrangements can, nonetheless, assume-or come to assume-a significant measure of legitimacy among the subordinate states. Acceptance by the ruled can arise as a result of either (1) the state as a whole deriving tangible benefits from the hegemon's rule, or (2) elites within the secondary state benefiting materially from the hegemonic order or becoming socialized into the hegemon's value system (Ikenberry and Kupchan 1990). Despite the hegemon's efforts (benign or otherwise), powerful revisionist states eventually emerge; and, as Gilpin (1981:ch. 3) has argued, uneven power growth among states drives hegemonic wars by altering the costs and benefits of territorial, political, and economic expansion to rising, dissatisfied powers. At a minimum, the rising power will issue demands for, inter alia, a "place at the table"- a commitment from the established powers to reshape what it perceives as adverse global norms. The revisionist power, by seeking this new level of prestige, is acting out its desire to voice its concerns in international institutions commensurate with its growth in relative power. Far from being unimportant or epiphenomenal, then, as neorealists like Mearsheimer have claimed, international institutions are the "brass ring," so to speak; the right to create and control them is precisely what the most powerful states have fought for in history's most destructive wars. The reader should note that not all rising powers are dissatisfied with the status quo order. "Whether a state is revisionist or status quo is not an endogenous function of the distribution of capabilities" (Schweller 1993:86); a state's type is not determined simply by its power position within the system. Indeed, that a rising power would ever be dissatisfied with the existing order is rather puzzling, given that, by definition, it is doing better than the established powers under their rules and institutional arrangements. One might say that the rising power is beating the established powers at their own game. This apparent discrepancy between actual performance and satisfaction can be reconciled, however, by simply positing that the dissatisfied power believes it is outperforming its competitors despite the shackles that the established powers have placed on it; the assumption is made that it would rise even faster under its own rules. Traditional realists view system stability as a function of the relative strengths of revisionist and status quo forces. When the forces defending the status quo are stronger than the dissatisfied state(s), the system is stable. This situation is most likely in the immediate aftermath of a major-power war that ends in decisive victory for one party. In contrast, when the revisionist state or coalition is stronger than the forces defending the status quo, the system eventually undergoes transformation. Institutions serve to widen the web of the established order as created by the most powerful, status quo state or coalition. A Model of International Politics Based on Traditional Realism Recently, Buzan and Glenn Snyder have proposed that considerations of state-tostate interactions be added to Waltz's systems theory as a third level of analysis, residing between neorealism's unit and structural levels. Buzan's (Buzan, Jones, and Little 1993:ch. 4) "interactions level" captures a systemwide set of variables that are neither structural nor unit level in character and that affect the "interaction capacity"-the absolute quality of technological and societal capabilities-of the system as a whole. Concurring with, but slightly amending, Buzan's idea, Snyder (1996:172) has added a "relationship" level that consists of static situational ele-

15 14 A Tale of Two Realisms: Expanding the Institutions Debate ments (such as alignments and alliances, common and conflicting interests, and capabilities and interdependence) and establishes the context of interaction rather than the action itself. This section builds on this pathbreaking work and advances a model that combines the theoretical insights of neorealism with those of traditional realism. The model includes traditional realism's concern for state attributes and state-to-state interactions as separate causal levels of analysis that reciprocally affect each other. These subsystemic levels of analysis are, in turn, conditioned by the structure of the system, which constrains and enables state behavior and interstate relationships but, as Waltz has suggested, does not determine outcomes. By incorporating state-level attributes and interactions, the model generates more precise explanations and can offer more determinate predictions than are possible from a purely structural form of realism. Independent Variables At the unit-or nation-state-level, the model focuses on traditional realism's distinction between status quo and revisionist states. Variation in unit interest/motivation is a function of the state's valuation of the established order and whether it seeks greater power or more security. Other state attributes may be substituted for, or added to, interest/motivation (for example, whether the state is liberal/nonliberal, democratic/nondemocratic, or has a homogeneous/heterogeneous culture), depending on what is being explained. At the interactions level of the model are the patterns of interstate relations and behavior (see Buzan, Jones, and Little 1993; Snyder 1996) that can be characterized as either cooperative or conflictual. A variety of strategic interactions that have been the focus of traditional realism but excluded from neorealist models of international politics can be considered-for instance, high versus low security dilemmas, protectionism/free trade, degree of polarization, containment/engagement strategies, alliance behavior (balancing, bandwagoning, chain-ganging, buckpassing), arms racing/arms control, interdependent/dependent economic relations, and coercive diplomacy/crisis bargaining and management. The length of this partial list supports Gilpin's (1981:46) assertion that "changes at the level of interstate interactions constitute the bulk of international relations." Interstate interactions are not only conditioned by the characteristics of the states but also help shape and reinforce state-level attributes. For example, a liberal hegemon fosters interdependence and free trade with its trading partners that, in turn, promote the evolution of more liberal states within the system and reinforce the liberal policies already adopted. In effect, the model posits a reciprocal causal relationship between the unit and interactions levels. The structural level of analysis includes neorealism's concept of polarity as well as two other dimensions: disparities in capabilities among the poles (see Schweller 1993, forthcoming; Mansfield 1994b) and whether the system's relative capability growth rates are static or dynamic. The two additional variables address the concerns that power transition theory (Organski 1958; Gilpin 1981), power cycle theory (Doran 1971, 1991; Copeland 1996), and lateral pressure theory (Choucri and North 1975) have raised about the importance of power inequalities and the relative power trajectories (growth or decline) among the Great Powers for how the system is structured. Dependent Variable Like neorealism, this model also seeks to explain international politics, defining politics as the process of acquiring, shaping, distributing, and exercising power

16 RANDALL L. SCHWELLER AND DAVID PRIESS 15 and influence-or more simply, who governs and by what processes. Borrowing from R. H. Tawney (quoted in Lasswell and Kaplan 1950:75), power is "the capacity of an individual, or group of individuals, to modify the conduct of other individuals or groups in the manner which he desires." It is a relational concept that rests on various bases and is limited by a specific scope and domain (see Baldwin 1985:ch. 2). Governing involves at least three interrelated processes: (1) the way power is exercised, (2) the type of order that is produced, and (3) the degree of institutionalization that prevails. With respect to the first process, power appears to be exercised in three generic ways: as naked power, as influence, and as management. These three ways of governing are distinguished, inter alia, their core values. Specifically, naked power relies on brute force or coercion, that is, the threat of severe sanctions for noncompliance; influence rests on legitimacy, authority, and socialization; management is centered around administrative capacity, skill, and directorship (Lasswell and Kaplan 1950:ch. 5). The second process focuses on the type of order produced. Oran Young (1986:110) identifies three generic mechanisms through which social order can arise: negotiation; imposition; and spontaneous, uncoordinated action. Negotiated orders are the deliberately intended product of voluntary bargaining among roughly equal, rational egoists (self-interested utility maximizers). Imposed orders are also deliberately designed, but they are intended to advance the interests of one or a few dominant actors and, as such, typically do not require the explicit consent of subordinate actors. Spontaneous orders arise without conscious coordination or deliberate purpose and do not involve explicit consent on the part of the subjects; they are the unintended, although often useful, consequences of the coaction of actors seeking their own selfish interests. (For a more extensive discussion, see Young 1982). The third process, and the one most important to our present concerns, revolves around the degree of institutionalization (low, moderate, or high) that characterizes the system. Institutions can be formal or informal; they are the sets of rights and rules governing interstate behavior and world politics. A highly institutionalized system is one in which formal organizations have the capacity, skill, and authority to play a major role in managing the system; the rules and rights governing the system are formal, explicit, and based on shared understandings among the major actors. Although all combinations of these three processes are possible, certain permutations seem more logical and more probable than others. The exercise of naked power is likely to create an imposed order characterized by low institutionalization, as in malevolent hegemony and imperialism. Influence as a means of governing often combines aspects of negotiated and spontaneously generated orders and tends to require a moderate to high level of institutionalization, as in benevolent hegemony, bipolar condominium, Great Power spheres of influence, and balanceof-power politics. Management is the product of negotiated orders and, as a result, usually entails a high level of formal or informal institutionalization, as illustrated by collective security and the Concert system. Institutions under Unipolarity What happens to international institutions when the international system is dominated by one power? Using the variety of levels and variables just outlined and material from the literature on unipolarity, what would the model lead us to expect? When the international system is ruled by a hegemon, governance is probably accomplished through naked power and the imposition of rules or by means

17 16 A Tale of Two Realisms: Expanding the Institutions Debate of a negotiated order. Which order arises and how it is maintained will depend primarily on whether the hegemon assumes the role of a liberal leader or a nonliberal despot. Whether the hegemon imposes or negotiates the institutional arrangements governing the international system, it will attempt to establish its dominance in several issue-areas and to set up a world order based on global rules and rights conducive to its interests. Such institutions, although associated with the hegemon's order and backed by its power, may, even so, exhibit a dramatic independent effect on state behavior. As the hegemon declines-which naturally oc- curs given the law of uneven growth and environmental, international, and domestic changes (Gilpin 1981:ch. 2)-it comes to rely increasingly on these institutions to maintain its position and delay its fall from dominant status. Institutions under unipolarity, therefore, are most effective at the beginning of a hegemon's reign but continue to exert influence on international politics during hegemonic decline until a revisionist challenger gains the strength and motivation to overthrow the established order (Gilpin 1981; Keohane 1984). When the hegemon is not liberal, it creates regimes "by possessing the effective capacity or power to impose institutional arrangements on the group regardless of the preferences of the other members" (Young 1986:110). As imposed orders, such hegemonic institutional arrangements are often underdeveloped, given that they do not involve cooperation but rather submission and adaptation to the stronger power's will. Imposed hegemonic orders based on coercion and brute force are generally perceived as illegitimate by the subordinate states. Consequently, they tend to be costly and inefficient. Hegemons are more successful in implanting institutions of their choice and profiting by them when other states benefit from and accept their leadership as well as fear their wrath (Gilpin 1981:144). Such an order is described by the benevolent version of hegemonic stability theory (Kindleberger 1973, 1981; also Gilpin 1975, 1981). According to this theory, a liberal hegemon assumes the startup costs of providing the collective goods (security and various international institutions) required for an open trading system. The hegemon provides leadership because it has an overriding interest in the creation of such a system and because it is the only state with enough power to do so. To create an open structure, the hegemonic state mixes both carrots and sticks. As Krasner (1976: ) has suggested: In terms of positive incentives, it can offer access to its large domestic market and to its relatively cheap exports. In terms of negative ones, it can withhold foreign grants and engage in competition, potentially ruinous for the weaker state, in third-country markets. The size and robustness of the hegemonic state also enable it to provide the confidence necessary for a stable international monetary system, and its currency can offer the liquidity needed for an increasingly open system. In contrast, the malevolent version of hegemonic stability theory posits a more devious method of making hegemonic rule pay for lesser states: by fostering asymmetric interdependence. Such a relationship can be formed through what Albert Hirschman (1980 [1945]:30-32) has called "the influence effect" of trade: country A, seeking to increase its influence over country B, alters its terms of trade in B's favor (for example, by paying above world prices for B's exports), changing the structure of B's economy such that it becomes highly, and artificially, complementary to A's economy. In effect, the more dependent state (B) benefits more from the relationship than the less dependent state (A). Country A accepts losses in national income in exchange for gains in national power. Consider Nazi Germany's economic relations with its East Central European neighbors; they typified the

18 RANDALL L. SCHWELLER AND DAVID PRIESS 17 deliberate creation of asymmetrical interdependence for the purpose of increasing one's political influence (Hirschman 1980 [1945]). Likewise, Japan's so-called new East Asian Co-Prosperity Sphere contains aspects of an imposed hegemonic order within a regional context with the intent of gaining influence (Samuels 1994; see also Lincoln 1990; Ravenhill 1993:ch. 5). Still another way that a hegemonic order can gain legitimacy or acceptance among the ruled is through a process of socialization in which the hegemon, by manipulating material incentives, successfully transmits its values to secondary states. This "third face of power," or "power of socialization" view, is consistent with the Weberian concept of "legitimate domination": "Experience shows that in no instance does domination voluntarily limit itself to the appeal to material or affectual or ideal motives as a basis for its continuance. In addition every such system attempts to establish and to cultivate the belief in its legitimacy" (Weber as quoted in Ikenberry and Kupchan 1990:289; see also Smith 1986:ch. 2). Building on Weber's insight and the traditional realist view that material power is the source of international authority, John Ikenberry and Charles Kupchan (1990:284) find that "when socialization does occur, it comes about primarily in the wake of the coercive exercise of power. That is, socialization is distinct from, but does not occur independently of, power manifest as the manipulation of material incentives." Ikenberry and Kupchan (1990:315) conclude, however, that hegemonic coercion and material inducements are necessary but not sufficient catalysts for socialization to occur:... the process of socialization can lead to outcomes that are not explicable simply in terms of the exercise of coercive power. Socialization affects the nature, the costs, and the longevity of the interactions that shape hegemonic systems. In particular, socialization leads to the legitimation of hegemonic power in a way that allows international order to be manipulated without the constant threat of coercion. Whichever method is chosen, the hegemon can take full advantage of its exalted position only by solving the paradox presented by its own strength: a hegemon must exert its superior power to influence the behavior of others in a way that achieves its desired ends without, in the process, forcing into existence a counterbalancing coalition. If threat inheres in the hegemon's power regardless of its declared intentions, as some neorealists have suggested (see Layne 1993), then the hegemon's fate is sealed: challengers seeking greater security and autonomy will emerge to balance against it. History tells us, however, that threat is not a necessary derivative of power and that the emergence of powerful states has not always been accompanied by the rise of a challenger or countercoalition. Consider the cases of nineteenth-century Britain, which controlled three-quarters of the world and yet remained in "splendid isolation," as well as the emergence of the United States as a Great Power before World War I without the formation of a balancing alliance (Walt 1985, 1987, 1988). The hegemons that have most successfully navigated their rise to power and established an order consistent with their objectives have been those that most clearly recognized the limits of power as a basis of rule. Of course, power is an important force behind institutional effectiveness. Niebuhr (1946:93) expressed this idea when he observed that one must not fail to recognize "the necessity of coercion for the sake of securing social co-operation." When relied upon and used unwisely, however, naked power will prove ineffective as a means of achieving international organization. Thus, Metternich has been called the "supreme realist" (Kissinger 1957:10). Unlike Napoleon, who believed he could impose universal principles on unwilling subjects simply by the assertion of superior power, Metternich based his diplomacy on the sanctity of treaty relations among states. He

19 18 A Tale of Two Realisms: Expanding the Institutions Debate worked to restore the disintegrated structure of the eighteenth-century international system, the stability of which rested on limited goals and the claim of legitimacy. In other words, the diplomacy of the realist statesman is dictated by prudence and expediency-knowing what is possible and acting in accordance with the particular situation (Kissinger 1957:ch. 2; see also Kissinger 1994). "We must be gardeners," George Kennan (1954:92) declared, in support of political expediency and against the establishment of rigid legal norms, "and not mechanics in our approach to world affairs." A realist foreign policy emphasizes persuasion and consensus on legitimate principles rather than on coercion and universalism. Of the realist statesman, Kissinger (1957:326) has written: His instrument is diplomacy, the art of relating states to each other by agreement rather than by the exercise of force, by the representation of a ground of action which reconciles particular aspirations with a general consensus. Because diplomacy de- pends on persuasion and not imposition, it presupposes a determinate framework, either through an agreement on a legitimizing principle or, theoretically, through an identical interpretation of power-relationships, although the latter is in practice the most difficult to attain. Contrary to the popular conception, the "ideal" realist state is not the power-maximizing, malevolent hegemon that attempts to impose its values on others through naked power and eternal crusades. Rather, the ideal is the prudent, benevolent hegemon that understands the limits of coercive power and so promotes legitimacy and emulation of its values while tolerating pluralism and diversity. Institutions under Bipolarity When the international system contains two superpowers, the model described here would lead us to expect several different institutional patterns, depending on state interests. Specifically, cooperative, although largely informal, institutional practices are likely to develop spontaneously as unintended by-products of the distribution of power. Let us explicate these propositions in more detail. Borrowing from Mancur Olson (1965), Waltz (1979:208) has observed that in a bipolar system... the interest of preeminent powers in the consumption of collective goods is strong enough to cause them to undertake the provision of those goods without being properly paid. They have incentives to act in the interest of the general peace and wider security of nations even though they will be working for the benefit of others as much as for themselves and even though others pay disproportionately small amounts of the costs... Leading states play leading roles in managing world affairs, and they do this even more so as their number shrinks to two. Thus, a bipolar structure generates tacit and spontaneous cooperation between the rival poles for the purpose of managing crises and avoiding inadvertent wars (Lipson 1995:17-21; Miller 1995). For example, during the Cold War, Moscow and Washington implicitly recognized each other's spheres of influence, tacitly regulated their use of force during crises, and cooperated to control and end wars in sensitive areas. As a result, despite forty years of keen ideological antagonism, global competition, a costly arms race, and frequent crises, the U.S.-Soviet bipolar rivalry produced not a single bona fide shooting incident between the two superpowers (Keal 1983; Miller 1995:36; see also Gaddis 1987:ch. 8). These largely informal institutional arrangements are more likely and more effective to the degree that the two poles share affinity for the status quo; if one of the poles is revisionist, such institutions, although likely to still exist, will be much weaker.

20 RANDALL L. SCHWELLER AND DAVID PRIESS 19 Under bipolarity, the identity of the poles as either revisionist or status quo powers is partially an endogenous function of the relative distribution of capabilities between them. Bipolar systems, more than multipolar ones, highlight "the coexistence of hegemonic rivalry with the balancing of military potentials" (Wohlforth 1993: ). To understand how this behavior affects the poles' level of satisfaction with the status quo order, we must incorporate the possibility of both capability inequalities (see Schweller 1993, forthcoming) and dynamic changes in the differentials of power (see Copeland 1996) among the poles. When one pole in a bipolar system is significantly stronger than the other or believes that dynamic change in the relative balance of power between them is possible, it (or both poles) will seek to achieve hegemonic status. Unlimited revisionist aims of this type exacerbate bipolar conflict and competition, as one pole tries to impose a global order on the other pole, which, in turn and for reasons of self-preservation, resists at all costs. Such an unbalanced, dynamic bipolar system characterized the "pre-mutual assured destruction," post-world War II period and led to intense bipolar competition and periodic crises. Conversely, when (1) the two poles are roughly equal in military power, (2) this condition of parity is relatively stable, or (3) both poles perceive the situation as such, the drive for hegemony subsides. Under conditions of static and balanced bipolarity, both poles are likely to become satisfied, status quo powers (unable and unwilling to change the established order), and bipolar accommodation and condominium will replace superpower rivalry. Thus, somewhat counterintuitive to the neorealist perspective, the growth in Soviet power during the 1960s and 1970s led not to increased superpower competition and greater cohesion among the Western allies but rather to superpower d6tente and greater intra-alliance conflict (for example, Brandt's Ostpolitik, and the Sino-Soviet split). This reaction occurred because the Soviets achieved nuclear parity with the United States during this period, which not only satisfied Soviet prestige and security demands but, more important, enhanced system stability and balance-both of which were reinforced by second-strike nuclear weapons. At the state-to-state interactions level, when a stable bipolar balance exists, the intensity of the security dilemma decreases; both poles are "concerned less with scoring relative gains and more with making absolute ones" (Waltz 1979:195). Arms racing gives way to arms control, and crisis management replaces coercive diplomacy. The two poles cooperate to manage the system through the creation of a moderate level of institutionalization and negotiated or tacit "rules of the game" (see, for example, Benjamin Frankel's (1993) analysis of Soviet-U.S. management of nuclear proliferation). At the same time, however, the nonpolar states often view bipolar condominium as an imposed order that carries with it the threat of losing their political autonomy. In contrast with polar relations, intrabloc relations under bipolarity are governed by formal and explicit institutional arrangements, whether negotiated (as in NATO) or imposed (as in the Warsaw Pact). The most commonly discussed form of institutional cooperation in the realist literature is the military alliance.8 Realists see alliances primarily as responses to threats: the greater the threat, the greater the likelihood of alliance formation and, implicitly, the more cohesive the alliance 8The discussion of alliances is included in this section on bipolarity, rather than in the previous section, because alliances are less prominent in unipolar systems, even though they exist. It should be noted that alliances (at least offensive ones) are qualitatively different from most other international institutions in that they are formed, not to reap the benefits of peaceful cooperation, but rather to reap the benefits of cooperation in making and jointly executing war (see Levy 1981:611; Schweller 1994).

21 20 A Tale of Two Realisms: Expanding the Institutions Debate (Walt 1987; see also Walt 1985, 1988; Snyder 1990, 1991; Barnett and Levy 1991; David 1991, 1992; Garnham 1991; Kaufman 1992; Labs 1992; Levy and Barnett 1992; Resende-Santos 1992; Brand 1994a, 1994b; Reiter 1994, 1996; Schroeder 1994; Schweller 1994; Priess 1996a). As George Liska (1962:12) has commented, "alliances are against, and only derivatively for, someone or something." Consider the extraordinary level of cooperation within the Western bloc in the post-world War II period that resulted from the combination of bipolarity, the perceived threat from the Soviet Union, and U.S. hegemony among the advanced capitalist countries. The common perception of a long-term Soviet threat and the virtual disappearance of the possibility of war among the Western allies promoted an absolute gains orientation within the alliance (Grieco 1990:40-47). In such situations even Waltz (1971:467) has claimed that integration is possible: Politics-negotiation, log-rolling, compromise-becomes the means of achieving preferred arrangements. To manage conflict, a closer integration is sought. The organization by which integration is to be promoted then becomes the object of struggle. How shall it be constructed, and what shall its purposes be? Once these become the most important questions, international relations begin to look like domestic politics. At the height of the Cold War, U.S. policymakers, seeking to provide for the common defense and to balance Soviet-bloc power, paid little attention to relative shifts in power capabilities vis-a-vis America's less powerful allies (Pollins 1989a, 1989b; Gowa and Mansfield 1993; Gowa 1994). "The exceptional postwar power capabilities of the United States," Krasner (1986:805) has noted, "elevated them [sic] above such considerations, except with regard to the Soviet Union." As realism predicts, the United States viewed absolute gains by its alliance partners as relative gains for the alliance as a whole with respect to the rival Soviet-bloc coalition. "When a state believes that another not only is not likely to be an adversary, but has sufficient interests in common with it to be an ally, then it will actually welcome an increase in the other's power" (Jervis 1978:175; see also Grieco 1990). Based on the principles of multilateralism and diffuse reciprocity, U.S. foreign economic policy encouraged European unification and tolerated explicit Japanese discrimination against U.S. exports and direct foreign investment. To balance Soviet-bloc power, the United States indulged the free-riding strategies of its European and Japanese friends. These extraordinary measures were dictated by a unique security threat induced by the bipolar world structure. In the absence of bipolarity and the Soviet threat, structural realists (including Waltz, Layne, and Mearsheimer) expect relations between the United States and its erstwhile allies to return to a more normal state of affairs, that is, economic, political, and military competition; a concern for relative shifts in power capabilities; and a struggle for supremacy. As Waltz (1993:76) has observed, "Without the shared perception of a severe Soviet threat, NATO would never have been born"; with the disappearance of that threat, "NATO's days are not numbered, but its years are" (also see Mearsheimer 1990:52, 1994/95:14). In theory, a properly functioning balance-of-power system requires rapid and abrupt switches from amity to enmity among nations. In practice, decisive victories have often converted wartime allies into peacetime adversaries. Why should the end of the Cold War be any different from past history?9 9For a creative, but not entirely convincing, argument (incorporating functionalist, cybernetic, neoliberal institutionalist, and realist elements) that NATO will survive and continue to be important in the post-cold War era, see Chernoff (1995).

22 RANDALL L. SCHWELLER AND DAVID PRIESS 21 Perhaps forty-plus years of transatlantic cooperation have forever changed rela- tions among the advanced industrialized democracies. Positing a variant of this view, adherents of the "Clash of Civilizations/West Against the Rest" school predict that a united "West" will persist because of natural affinity, consciousness of their own civilization, and, consistent with realism, a shared common threat from other non-western civilizations (Huntington 1993, 1996a, 1996b; Mahbubani 1993; Connelly and Kennedy 1994). Similarly, but arising from a liberal foundation, Deudney and Ikenberry (1993/94; Ikenberry 1996) have argued that the West is a unique "industrial liberal" order, likely to persist regardless of recent structural changes. In the eyes of neorealists, however, the idea of the "West" is a mere myth brought into existence by an extremely dangerous, overtly hostile threat from the East; a myth that has outlived its usefulness (see Harries 1993). In contrast to neorealism, traditional realism suggests an answer for the persistence of an institution beyond the time when its raison d'etre vanishes, such as NATO's endurance into the 1990s. States enter into cooperative arrangements, such as alliances, for reasons of expediency. When the reasons that led to a coalition no longer exist, the alliance begins to disintegrate (Morgenthau 1959; Kennan 1984:238; Hellmann and Wolf 1993:10-13).10 Traditional realists, however, do not assert, as neorealists do, that all alliances will disintegrate sooner rather than later. Given traditional realism's assumptions that politics are inherently group-based and that group identities on the world stage are not forever fixed (Gilpin 1981:18; see also Niebuhr 1932, 1944; Carr 1946; Morgenthau 1946, 1985), this theory predicts that some institutions will endure longer than the structural factors or threats that brought them into existence because of a shared sense of "in-group" identity induced by prolonged, intense, and focused threats (Priess 1996b). The idea of the "West" forged by decades of Cold War competition may, therefore, enable NATO to endure longer than a similar institution without such a sense of shared identity. Even though structural changes and shifts in state interests make the disintegration of alliances and attendant institutions inevitable in the long run (a belief distinguishing this realist account from much of the "West Against the Rest" literature), some institutions will endure longer than neorealism predicts because of the development of shared identities, especially if "in-groups" are maintained by the perception of new "others"(mercer 1995; Barnett 1996). Institutions under Multipolarity What if the system has many poles? What kind of international institutions result in a multipolar system, and do the characteristics of the units or their interactions influence the nature of these institutional arrangements? Under multipolarity, the model described here predicts that international institutions could take a variety of forms-most, but not all, of which will be ad hoc and shallow with little or no influence on state behavior. The variance in the degree of institutionalization in the international system will depend on the character of the units, the particular type of multipolar structure in which they are embedded, and several interactionlevel variables-in particular, the degree of inequality and of differential growth rates among the poles as well as the offense-defense balance in military technology (see Christensen and Snyder 1990). When there is an even distribution of power among the multiple poles (each holds an approximately equal percentage share of systemic capabilities) and their growth rates are not widely uneven, the system is unlikely to experience polariza- 10 For a good literature review and spirited liberal critique of this proposition, see Kegley and Raymond (1994).

23 22 A Tale of Two Realisms: Expanding the Institutions Debate tion into rival camps for the purpose of managing dangerous imbalances of power. As long as no alliance handicaps exist, such a balanced and stable multipolar system is fertile ground for the development of systemwide international regimes that define the norms and codes governing interstate relations and offer membership to all the Great Powers (Schroeder 1994). Conversely, when there are large imbalances of power among the poles or vastly uneven growth rates, the system will be characterized by a high level of polarization and concern over relative gains and losses, both of which exacerbate the security dilemma and rule out any attempt to construct systemwide institutional orders. Institutions are most likely to develop and to be effective in a multipolar setting when all the Great Powers are satisfied with the established order. Under this condition, a negotiated order based on management and influence with a moderate to high level of institutionalization would be likely. By definition, status quo states do not require expansion for their security (if they did, they would not be satisfied with the status quo) and, for them, the benefits of peace far outweigh the costs of not engaging in expansion. If each is confident that all the others feel the same way, insti- tutionalized cooperation taking the form of a "Great Power Concert" may develop (Jervis 1983). In such a situation, every pole is willing to forego short-term gains for the long-term benefits of domestic and systemic peace and stability. Other unit-level factors, such as ideological convergence and cultural similarity, also promote the establishment of security regimes among the Great Powers for the purpose of cooperation in conflict resolution (Miller 1995:ch. 2). The post-napoleonic concert, for example, was made possible by the extreme war-weariness of the combatants, which ruled out any thought of nonpeaceful revision, and the common conservative ideology of almost all the great Continental powers after 1815 (Kissinger 1957:31, 1994:98). At the interaction level, a shared perception among all poles that defense has the advantage over offense-that "it is easier to protect and to hold than it is to move forward, destroy, and take" (Jervis 1978:187)-and that defensive weapons and policies are distinct from offensive ones will decrease the security dilemma among major powers and thereby increase the likelihood that security institutions will develop (Glaser 1994/95). Yet, although it is relatively easy to create security regimes under such circumstances, there will be little need for them. Thus, states may opt to forgo cooperative arrangements in favor of individualistic policies. For this reason, the most favorable conditions for the formation of security regimes are cases in which offense has the advantage, and offensive military postures differ from defensive ones, or cases in which offensive measures are indistinguishable from defensive ones, but it is easier to defend than attack. "In either of these worlds the costs or risks of individualistic security policies are great enough to provide status quo powers with incentives to seek security through cooperative means, but the dangers of being taken by surprise by an aggressor are not so great as to discourage the states from placing reliance on joint measures" (Jervis 1983:178). When some of the Great Powers are perceived, rightly or wrongly, to be revisionist and thus dissatisfied with the established international order, security regimes and institutions will either break down or be less effective, as in the Concert system after 1848 and the League of Nations during the interwar period (Jervis 1986). This logic also applies to regional balances of power. In a multipolar region with powerful revisionist states, institutions will be both sparse and ineffective. Consider the modern Middle East, where there have been a number of revisionist states over the last forty years, and where international institutions (apart from the increasingly powerful institution of statism) have been largely impotent (Ajami 1981; Barnett 1993, 1995, 1996).

24 RANDALL L. SCHWELLER AND DAVID PRIESS 23 One form of institution in particular, the military alliance, tends to vary widely in effectiveness under multipolarity. Unlike bipolarity, multipolarity allows for myriad alliance patterns among the poles as a result of the greater uncertainty inherent in such a distribution of power and the number of exit choices that states have. Specifically, multipolar alliances are plagued by states' abilities to manipulate partners vis-a-vis other poles-for instance, by chain-ganging and buck-passing. Thomas Christensen and Jack Snyder (1990) have observed that attention to system structure alone does not allow one to make determinate predictions about which of these strategies will be chosen in any given situation; for these types of predictions, interaction-level variables such as the nature of the offense-defense balance must be included. Multipolar alliances also vary widely in their explicitness. Alliance members must make a trade-off between implicit bonds-which increase states' anxieties concerning abandonment but may lead their partners to honor the alliance (to maintain their reputations)-and explicit bonds-which grant them confidence that the commitments explicated in the agreement will be honored but may entrap them in their allies' adventures (Snyder 1984: ). Ironically, then, alliances and institutions in general are likely to be least effective when the international system has multiple poles-precisely the distribution of power under which uncertainty and risk make cooperation most necessary. In summary, multipolar periods historically have been characterized by both minimal and extensive Great Power institutionalization. Because this variation cannot be explained by the neorealist constant of structural polarity, unit- and interaction-level factors must determine the degree of institutionalization that does or does not develop in such systems. Moreover, given the greater number of actors, and thus complexity, in a multipolar system, any significant cooperation that occurs between the Great Powers will require formal and explicit institutionalized arrangements (Lipson 1991). The Great Powers in a multipolar system cannot engage in effective conflict management and resolution strategies by the tacit rules of spontaneous cooperation; deliberate, conscious negotiation among the poles will be needed for such cooperation to result (Miller 1995: ). Trends and Further Research Neorealism's parsimony has led to excesses such as Mearsheimer's stance on institutions that have left realism without a well-developed model of institutional origins and effectiveness. Most realists, however, understand that institutions can, and sometimes do, matter. The model presented in this article is merely a sketch derived from earlier realists' insights on institutions; far more work remains to be done. This final section briefly describes how this more traditional realist model of international institutions fits into an emerging wave of realist scholarship and suggests some fruitful avenues for future research on international institutions. Back to Realism 's Roots This essay is part of a current intellectual movement away from the starker, more rigorous, neorealist model of international politics toward the richer analytic framework of traditional realism. Recent scholarship, in addition to the research already cited in our discussion of modified structural realism, further highlights this trend. One of the authors (Schweller 1996:92; see also Schweller forthcoming) has observed elsewhere that "differences in state goals-whether states seek the minimum power required for security or additional power for goals other than security-have to be accorded equal consideration with anarchy and the distribution of capabilities." Likewise, Stephen Walt's (1985, 1987, 1988, 1992, 1996a)

25 24 A Tale of Two Realisms: Expanding the Institutions Debate balance-of-threat theory incorporates the traditional realist concern for state interests and intentions. Even Grieco's (1990:45) well-known argument on relative gains, a neorealist cause c6elbre, relies on the "k-factor" that represents a state's "sensitivity to gaps in payoffs," a function of the amity or enmity between states. Although neorealism has been of immense value, the complexity of contemporary world politics requires a systems theory that can incorporate the characteristics of states, their interactions, and a more comprehensive view of system structure than is captured by the concept of polarity. This need for a more elaborate theory does not mean, as many liberals and constructivists have suggested, that realist theory is dead and should be buried (see, for example, Kegley 1993; Lebow 1994). To the contrary, realism contains all the elements necessary to construct a theory of world politics applicable to the twenty-first century; it is a theory, as William Wohlforth (1994/95:92) has noted, that is "rich and varied, and cannot be limited just to structural realism." An Agenda for Realists Our discussion and the model we have described suggest that there should be three important goals in any further development of a realist theory of institutions: (1) to elaborate the causal links among the three levels of analysis and the various dimensions of the dependent variable; (2) to deduce falsifiable hypotheses that posit precisely how the variables are causally related; and (3) to operationalize, test, and refine these propositions by means of case-study and process-tracing methods or standard quantitative/statistical techniques. The most important lines of inquiry for future research center on the following questions: How do the characteristics of states affect their interactions and vice versa? How do state-level interactions, such as alliance behavior or the degree of economic/military interdependence among states, affect the degree of institutionalization and the type of governance in the system as a whole or in a particular subsystem? Does the structure of the system affect the characteristics of its component units and, if so, in what ways? Do changes in the structure of the international system affect the type of order (imposed, negotiated, or spontaneously generated) that results? Or, conversely, does the type of order and the ways in which power is exercised (either through naked force, influence, or management) cause predictable changes in system structure and the nature of state interactions? Along these lines, Layne (1993) has argued that, because overwhelming power is inherently threatening, unipolarity impels eligible states to balance against the hegemon, regardless of whether it adopts a benevolent or coercive strategy or has a recent history of friendship and alliance with the candidates for future polar status. In other words, Layne, a self-described neorealist, is proposing that system structure (unipolarity) affects both unit-level interactions (states become more competitive and go from amity to enmity) and the attributes of the units (satisfied states become dissatisfied with the status quo and seek to revise it). The model we have described offers a competing prediction: If the hegemon adopts a benevolent strategy and creates a negotiated order based on legitimate influence and management, lesser states will bandwagon with, rather than balance against, it. Thus, the United States may be able to prolong and strengthen its present hegemonic rule (Pax Americana) through whatjosefjoffe (1995:113) has called a "Bismarckian strategy of hubs and spokes," whereby it maintains "better relations with all possible contenders than they do among each other." To determine which scenario is most likely to unfold (Layne's or this essay's) as well as the answers to many other equally important puzzles, we must address the questions raised above.

26 RANDALL L. SCHWELLER AND DAVID PRIESS 25 In addition to insights concerning why international institutions are formed and maintained, we also need to explore why and by what processes institutions decay. Even though we have unresolved questions, we know far more about how institutions arise than we do about their decay and disintegration. Neoliberal institutionalism has not been of much assistance in this regard, because authors in this tradition go to the opposite extreme of neorealists and accord great staying power to institutions (Keohane and Nye 1977; Keohane 1984; Young 1992). Just what are the external and internal sources of international regime failure? Is institutional change most often a product of external shock or internal decay? Is institutional failure at the international level a product of the widespread breakdown of domestic and political social structures? Moreover, why do some institutions endure severe shocks and persist whereas others disintegrate when faced with similar perturbations? Scholars have long recognized that states' investments in international institutions are influenced by domestic political and social structures as well as by the demands of the international system, but the precise nature of these ties and their comparative impact have not received much attention. To be sure, tackling this research agenda is a daunting task but one we believe is necessary if realists are to meet the intellectual challenges of the post-cold War world. We urge scholars to develop a new body of literature devoted to uncovering and investigating the causal links, interaction effects, and feedback loops among variables at three levels of analysis-not just two-and between these variables and the type of order in international politics that they produce. This article was intended to show the relevance of such an endeavor for understanding the nature of international institutions. References AJAMI, FOUAD. (1981) The Arab Predicament: Arab Political Thought and Practice Since New York: Cambridge University Press. ARON, RAYMOND. (1966) Peace and War: A Theory of International Relations. Translated by Richard Howard and Annette Baker Fox. Garden City, NJ: Doubleday. AXELROD, ROBERT. (1984) The Evolution of Cooperation. New York: Basic Books. AXELROD, ROBERT, and ROBERT 0. KEOHANE. (1985) Achieving Cooperation Under Anarchy: Strategies and Institutions. World Politics 38: BALDWIN, DAVID A. (1985) Economic Statecraft. Princeton: Princeton University Press. BALDWIN, DAVID A. (1993) Neoliberalism, Neorealism, and World Politics. In Neorealism and Neoliberalism: The Contemporary Debate, edited by David A. Baldwin. New York: Columbia University Press. BARNETT, MICHAEL N. (1993) Institutions, Roles, and Disorder: The Case of the Arab States System. International Studies Quarterly 37: BARNETT, MICHAEL N. (1995) Sovereignty, Nationalism, and Regional Order in the Arab States System. International Organization 49: BARNETT, MICHAEL N. (1996) Identity and Alliances in the Middle East. In The Culture of National Security: Norms and Identity in World Politics, edited by PeterJ. Katzenstein. NewYork: Columbia University Press. BARNETT, MICHAEL N., andjack S. LEVY. (1991) Domestic Sources of Alliances and Alignments: The Case of Egypt, International Organization 45: BRAND, LAURIE A. (1994a) Economics and Shifting Alliances: Jordan's Relations with Syria and Iraq, International Journal of Middle East Studies 26: BRAND, LAURIE A. (1994b) Jordan's Inter-Arab Relations: The Political Economy of Alliance Making. New York: Columbia University Press. BULL, HEDLEY. (1969) The Twenty Years' Crisis Thirty Years On. InternationalJournal 24: BULL, HEDLEY. (1977). TheAnarchical Society: A Study of Orderin World Politics. NewYork: Columbia University Press. BUSCH, MARC L., and ERIC R. REINHARDT. (1993) Nice Strategies in a World of Relative Gains. Journal of Conflict Resolution 37:

27 26 A Tale of Two Realisms: Expanding the Institutions Debate BUZAN, BARRY, CHARLESJONES, and RICHARD LITTLE. (1993) The Logic of Anarchy: Neorealism to Structural Realism. New York: Columbia University Press. CARPENTER, TED GALEN, ED. (1994) The Future of NATO. Special issue, Journal of Strategic Studies 17 (December). CARR, EDWARD HALLETT. (1946) The Twenty Years' Crisis, : An Introduction to the Study of International Relations. New York: Harper and Row. CHERNOFF, FRED. (1995) After Bipolarity: The Vanishing Threat, Theories of Cooperation, and the Future of the Atlantic Alliance. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press. CHOUCRI, NAZLI, and ROBERT C. NORTH. (1975) Nations in Conflict: National Growth and International Violence. San Francisco: W. H. Freeman. CHRISTENSEN, THOMAS J., andjack SNYDER. (1990) Chain Gangs and Passed Bucks: Alliance Patterns in Multipolarity. International Organization 44: CONNELLY, MATTHEW, and PAUL KENNEDY. (1994) Must It Be the Rest Against the West? Atlantic Monthly 274 (December) : COPELAND, DALE C. (1996) Neorealism and the Myth of Bipolar Stability: Toward a New Dynamic Realist Theory of Major War. Security Studies 5 (Spring) : DAVID, STEVEN R. (1991) Explaining Third World Alignment. World Politics 43: DAVID, STEVEN R. (1992) Choosing Sides: Alignment and Realignment in the Third World. Baltimore, MD:Johns Hopkins University Press. DEUDNEY, DANIEL. (1993) Dividing Realism: Structural Realism Versus Security Materialism on Nuclear Security and Proliferation. Security Studies 2 (Spring/Summer):7-36. DEUDNEY, DANIEL. (1995) The Philadelphian System: Sovereignty, Arms Control, and Balance of Power in the American States-Union, International Organization 49: DEUDNEY, DANIEL. (1996) Binding Sovereigns: Authority, Structure, and Geopolitics in Philadelphian Systems. In State Sovereignty as Social Construct, edited by Thomas Biersteiker and Cynthia Weber. New York: Cambridge University Press. DEUDNEY, DANIEL, and G. JOHN IKENBERRY. (1993/94) The Logic of the West. World Policy Journal (Winter): DEUDNEY, DANIEL, and G. JOHN IKENBERRY. (1996) "Structural Liberalism: The Nature and Sources of Postwar Western Political Order." Paper presented at the annual meeting of the American Political Science Association, San Francisco, August 29-September 1. DORAN, CHARLES F. (1971) The Politics of Assimilation: Hegemony and Its Aftermath. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press. DORAN, CHARLES F. (1991) Systems in Crisis: New Imperatives of High Politics at Century's End. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. DUFFIELD,JOHN S. (1992) International Regimes and Alliance Behavior: Explaining NATO Conventional Force Levels. International Organization 46: DUFFIELD,JOHN S. (1994) Explaining the Long Peace in Europe: The Contributions of Regional Security Regimes. Review of International Studies 20: DUFFIELD,JOHN S. (1994/95) NATO's Functions After the Cold War. Political Science Quarterly 109: DUFFIELD,JOHN S. (1995) PowerRules: TheEvolution of NATO's Conventional Force Posture. Stanford: Stanford University Press. DUFFIELD, JOHN S. (1996) The North Atlantic Treaty Organization: Alliance Theory. In Explaining International Relations Since 1945, edited by Ngaire Woods. New York: Oxford University Press. ELMAN, COLIN. (1996) Horses for Courses: Why Not Neorealist Theories of Foreign Policy? Security Studies 6 (Autumn):7-51. FETTER, STEVE. (1992) Ballistic Missiles and Weapons of Mass Destruction: What Is the Threat? What Should Be Done? In America's Strategy in a Changing World, edited by Sean M. Lynn-Jones and Steven E. Miller. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. FRANKEL, BENJAMIN. (1993) The Brooding Shadow: Systemic Incentives and Nuclear Weapons Prolifera- tion. Security Studies 2 (Spring/Summer): FRANKEL, BENJAMIN. (1996) Restating the Realist Case: An Introduction. Security Studies 5 (Spring):ix-xx. GADDIS, JOHN LEWIS. (1987) The Long Peace: Inquiries into the History of the Cold War. New York: Oxford University Press. GARNHAM, DAVID. (1991) Explaining Middle Eastern Alignments During the Gulf War. Jerusalem Journal of International Relations 13 (3) : GILPIN, ROBERT. (1975) U.S. Power and the Multinational Corporation: The Political Economy of Foreign Direct Investment. New York: Basic Books.

28 RANDALL L. SCHWELLER AND DAVID PRIESS 27 GILPIN, ROBERT. (1981) War and Change in World Politics. New York: Cambridge University Press. GILPIN, ROBERT. (1986) The Richness of the Tradition of Political Realism. In Neorealism and Its Critics, edited by Robert O. Keohane. New York: Columbia University Press. GILPIN, ROBERT. (1987) The Political Economy of International Relations. Princeton: Princeton University Press. GILPIN, ROBERT. (1996) No One Loves a Political Realist. Security Studies 5 (Spring):3-26. GLASER, CHARLES L. (1993) Why NATO Is Still Best: Future SecurityArrangements for Europe. International Security 18 (1):5-50. GLASER, CHARLES L. (1994/95) Realists as Optimists: Cooperation as Self-Help. International Security 19 (3): GOWA,JOANNE. (1994) Allies, Adversaries, and International Trade. Princeton: Princeton University Press. GOWA, JOANNE, and EDWAR D. MANSFIELD. (1993) Power Politics and International Trade. American Political Science Review 87: GRIECO, JOSEPH M. (1988a) Anarchy and the Limits of Cooperation: A Realistic Critique of the Newest Liberal Institutionalism. International Organization 42: GRIECO,JOSEPH M. (1988b) Realist Theory and the Problem of International Cooperation: Analysis with an Amended Prisoner's Dilemma Model. Journal of Politics 50: GRIECO,JOSEPH M. (1990) Cooperation AmongNations: Europe, America, and Non-Tariff Barriers to Trade. Ithaca: Cornell University Press. GRIECO, JOSEPH M. (1993) Understanding the Problem of International Cooperation: The Limits of Neoliberal Institutionalism and the Future of Realist Theory. In Neorealism and Neoliberalism: The Contemporary Debate, edited by David A. Baldwin. New York: Columbia University Press. GRIECO, JOSEPH M. (1995) The Maastricht Treaty, Economic and Monetary Union and the Neorealist Research Programme. Review of International Studies 21: GRIECO,JOSEPH M. (1996) State Interests and Institutional Rule Trajectories: A Neorealist Interpretation of the Maastricht Treaty and European Economic and Monetary Union. Security Studies 5 (Spring) : GRIECO, JOSEPH M., ROBERT POWELL, and DUNCAN SNIDAL. (1993) The Relative-Gains Problem for International Cooperation. American Political Science Review 87: GULICK, EDWARD VOSE. (1955) Europe's Classical Balance of Power: A Case History of the Theory and Practice of One of the Great Concepts of European Statecraft. Ithaca: Cornell University Press. HAAS, ERNST B. (1958) The Uniting of Europe: Political, Social, and Economic Forces, Stanford: Stanford University Press. HAAS, ERNST B. (1964) Beyond the Nation-State: Functionalism and International Organization. Stanford: Stanford University Press. HAGGARD, STEPHAN, and BETH A. SIMMONS. (1987) Theories of International Regimes. International Organization 41: HANSENCLEVER, ANDREAS, PETER MAYER, and VOLKER RITTBERGER. (1996) Interests, Power, Knowledge: The Study of International Regimes. Mershon International Studies Review 40: HARRIES, OWEN. (1993) The Collapse of "the West." Foreign Affairs 72 (September/October): HEISBORG, FRANCOIS. (1992) The Future of the Atlantic Alliance: Whither NATO, Whether NATO. Washington Quarterly 15 (Spring): HELLMANN, GUNTHER, and REINHARD WOLF. (1993) Neorealism, Neoliberal Institutionalism, and the Future of NATO. Security Studies 3 (Autumn) :3-43. HIRSCHMAN, ALBERT 0. (1980 [1945]) National Power and the Structure of Foreign Trade. Berkeley: University of California Press. HOPF, TED. (1992) Managing Soviet Disintegration: A Demand for Behavioral Regimes. In America s Strategy in a Changing World, edited by Sean M. Lynn-Jones and Steven E. Miller. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. HUNTINGTON, SAMUEL P. (1968) Political Order in Changing Societies. New Haven: Yale University Press. HUNTINGTON, SAMUEL P. (1993) The Clash of Civilizations? Foreign Affairs 72 (Summer): HUNTINGTON, SAMUEL P. (1996a) The Clash of Civilizations and the Remaking of World Order. NewYork: Simon and Schuster. HUNTINGTON, SAMUEL P. (1996b) The West: Unique, Not Universal. Foreign Affairs 75 (November/December) : IKENBERRY, G.JOHN. (1996) The Myth of the Post-Cold War Chaos. Foreign Affairs 75 (May/June): IKENBERRY, G.JOHN, and CHARLES A. KUPCHAN. (1990) Socialization and Hegemonic Power. International Organization 44:

29 28 A Tale of Two Realisms: Expanding the Institutions Debate JEPPERSON, RONALD L., ALEXANDER WENDT, and PETER J. KATZENSTEIN. (1996) Norms, Identity, and Culture in National Security. In The Culture of National Security: Norms and Identity in World Politics, edited by PeterJ. Katzenstein. New York: Columbia University Press. JERVIS, ROBERT. (1978) Cooperation Under the Security Dilemma. World Politics 30: JERVIS, ROBERT. (1983) Security Regimes. In International Regimes, edited by Stephen D. Krasner. Ithaca: Cornell University Press. JERVIS, ROBERT. (1986) From Balance to Concert: A Study of International Security Cooperation. In Cooperation UnderAnarchy, edited by Kenneth A. Oye. Princeton: Princeton University Press. JOFFE, JOSEF. (1995) "Bismarck" or "Britain"? Toward an American Grand Strategy After Bipolarity. International Security 19 (4): KAPSTEIN, ETHAN B. (1995) Is Realism Dead? The Domestic Sources of International Politics. International Organization 49: KATZENSTEIN, PETERJ. (1996) Introduction: Alternative Perspectives on National Security. In The Culture of National Security: Norms and Identity in World Politics, edited by Peter J. Katzenstein. New York: Columbia University Press. KAUFMAN, ROBERT G. (1992) "To Balance or To Bandwagon?" Alignment Decisions in 1930s Europe. Security Studies 1 (Spring): KAUFMAN, ROBERT G. (1996) E. H. Carr, Winston Churchill, Reinhold Niebuhr, and Us: The Case for Principled, Prudential, Democratic Realism. Security Studies 5 (Winter): KEAL, PAUL. (1983) Unspoken Rules and SuperpowerDominance. London: Macmillan. KEGLEY, CHARLES W.,JR. (1993) The Neoidealist Moment in International Studies? Realist Myths and the New International Realities. International Studies Quarterly 37: KEGLEY, CHARLES W.,JR., and GREGORY A. RAYMOND. (1994) Networks of Intrigue? Realpolitik, Alliances, and International Security. In ReconstructingRealpolitik, edited by Frank W. Wayman and Paul F. Diehl. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan. KENNAN, GEORGE F. (1954) Realities of American Foreign Policy. Princeton: Princeton University Press. KENNAN, GEORGE F. (1984) The Fateful Alliance: France, Russia, and the Coming of the First World War. New York: Pantheon. KEOHANE, ROBERT 0. (1984) AfterHegemony: Cooperation anddiscord in the World Political Economy. Princeton: Princeton University Press. KEOHANE, ROBERT 0. (1989) International Institutions and State Power: Essays in International Theory. Boulder: Westview Press. KEOHANE, ROBERT 0. (1993) Institutional Theory and the Realist Challenge After the Cold War. In Neorealism and Neoliberalism: The Contemporary Debate, edited by David A. Baldwin. New York: Columbia University Press. KEOHANE, ROBERT O., and LISA MARTIN. (1995) The Promise of Institutionalist Theory. International Security 20 (1): KEOHANE, ROBERT O., and JOSEPH S. NYE. (1977) Power and Interdependence: World Politics in Transition. Boston: Little, Brown. KEOHANE, ROBERT O.,JOSEPH S. NYE, and STANLEY HOFFMANN, EDS. (1993) After the Cold War: International Institutions and State Strategies in Europe, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. KINDLEBERGER, CHARLES P. (1973) The World in Depression. Berkeley: University of California Press. KINDLEBERGER, CHARLES P. (1981) Dominance and Leadership in the International Economy: Exploitation, Public Goods, and Free Rides. International Studies Quarterly 25: KISSINGER, HENRY A. (1957) A World Restored: Castlereagh, Metternich, and the Problem of Peace, Boston: Houghton Mifflin. KISSINGER, HENRY A. (1979) White House Years. Boston: Little, Brown. KISSINGER, HENRY A. (1994) Diplomacy. New York: Simon and Schuster. KLIR, GEORGEJ. (1972) The Polyphonic General Systems Theory. In Trends in General Systems Theory, edited by George J. Klir. New York: Wiley Interscience. KRASNER, STEPHEN D. (1976) State Power and the Structure of World Trade. World Politics 28: KRASNER, STEPHEN D. (1983) Structural Causes and Regime Consequences: Regimes as Intervening Variables. In International Regimes, edited by Stephen S. Krasner. Ithaca: Cornell University Press. KRASNER, STEPHEN D. (1986) Trade Conflicts and the Common Defense: The United States and Japan. Political Science Quarterly 101: KRASNER, STEPHEN D. (1991) Global Communications and National Power: Life on the Pareto Frontier. World Politics 43:

30 RANDALL L. SCHWELLER AND DAVID PRIESS 29 KUPCHAN, CHARLES A. (forthcoming) The Future of Transatlantic Relations. New York: Council on Foreign Relations Press. KUPCHAN, CHARLES A., and CLIFFORD A. KUPCHAN. (1995) The Promise of Collective Security. International Security 20 (1): LABS, ERIC. (1992) Do Weak States Bandwagon? Security Studies 1 (Spring): LASSWELL, HAROLD D., and ABRAHAM KAPLAN. (1950) Power and Society: A Framework for Political Inquiry. New Haven: Yale University Press. LAYNE, CHRISTOPHER. (1993) The Unipolar Illusion: Why Great Powers Will Rise. International Security 17 (4):5-51. LAYNE, CHRISTOPHER. (1994) Kant or Cant: The Myth of the Democratic Peace. International Security 19 (2):5-49. LEBOW. RICHARD NED. (1994) The Long Peace, the End of the Cold War, and the Failure of Realism. International Organization 48: LEVY,JACK S. (1981) Alliance Formation and War Behavior: An Analysis of the Great Powers, Journal of Conflict Resolution 25: LEVY, JACK S., and MICHAEL N. BARNETT. (1992) Alliance Formation, Domestic Political Economy, and Third World Security. JerusalemJournal ofinternational Relations 14 (4): LIBERMAN, PETER. (1996) Trading with the Enemy: Security and Relative Economic Gains. International Security 21 (1): LINCOLN, EDWARDJ. (1990) Japan's Unequal Trade. Washington: Brookings Institution. LINDBERG, LEON N., and STUART A. SCHEINGOLD, EDS. (1971) Regional Integration: Theory and Research. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. LIPSON, CHARLES. (1991) Why Are Some International Agreements Informal? International Organization 45: LIPSON, CHARLES. (1995) Are Security Regimes Possible? Historical Cases and Modern Issues. In Regional Security Regimes: Israel and Its Neighbors, edited by Efraim Inbar. Albany: State University of New York Press. LISKA, GEORGE. (1962) Nations in Alliance: The Limits of Interdependence. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press. MAHBUBANI, KISHORE. (1993) The Dangers of Decadence: What the Rest Can Teach the West. Foreign Affairs 72 (September/October) : MANSFIELD, EDWAR D. (1994a) Alliances, Preferential Trading Arrangements and Sanctions. Journal of International Affairs 48: MANSFIELD, EDWARD. (1994b) Power Trade, and War. Princeton: Princeton University Press. MANSFIELD, EDWARD. (1995) International Institutions and Economic Sanctions. World Politics 47: MARTIN, LISA L. (1992a) Coercive Cooperation: Explaining Multilateral Economic Sanctions. Princeton: Princeton University Press. MARTIN, LISA L. (1992b) Institutions and Cooperation: Sanctions During the Falkland Islands Conflict. International Security 16 (4): MASTANDUNO, MICHAEL. (1991) Do Relative Gains Matter? America's Response to Japanese Industrial Policy. International Security 16 (1): MATTERN, JOHANNES. (1942) Geopolitics: Doctrine of National Self-Sufficiency and Empire. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press. MATTHEWS,JAMES C., III. (1996) Current Gains and Future Outcomes: When Cumulative Relative Gains Matter. International Security 21 (1): MCCALLA, ROBERT B. (1996) NATO's Persistence After the Cold War. International Organization 50: MEARSHEIMER, JOHN J. (1990) Back to the Future: Instability in Europe after the Cold War. International Security 15 (1):5-56. MEARSHEIMER,JOHNJ. (1994/95) The False Promise of International Institutions. International Security 19 (3):5-49. MERCER, JONATHON. (1995) Anarchy and Identity. International Organization 49: MILLER, BENJAMIN. (1995) When Opponents Cooperate: Great Power Conflict and Collaboration in World Politics. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press. MILNER, HELEN. (1991) The Assumption of Anarchy in International Relations Theory. Review of International Studies 17: MILNER, HELEN. (1992) International Theories of Cooperation Among Nations: Strengths and Weaknesses. World Politics 44:

31 30 A Tale of Two Realisms: Expanding the Institutions Debate MITCHELL, RONALD B. (1994a) Intentional Oil Pollution at Sea: Environmental Policy and Treaty Compliance. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. MITCHELL, RONALD B. (1994b) Regime Design Matters: Intentional Oil Pollution and Treaty Compliance. International Organization 48: MITRANY, DAVID. (1948) The Functional Approach to World Organization. InternationalAffairs 24: MITRANY, DAVID. (1966) A Working Peace System. Chicago: Quadrangle Books. MORAVCSIK, ANDREW. (1993) "Liberalism and International Relations Theory." Unpublished paper. Harvard University (April). MORGENTHAU, HANSJ. (1946) Scientific Man vs. Power Politics. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. MORGENTHAU, HANSJ. (1948) Politics Among Nations: The Strugglefor Power and Peace. New York: Knopf. MORGENTHAU, HANS J. (1959) Alliances in Theory and Practice. In Alliance Policy in the Cold War, edited by Arnold Wolfers. Baltimore, MD:Johns Hopkins University Press. MORGENTHAU, HANSJ. (1985) Politics Among Nations: The Strugglefor Power and Peace. Sixth edition, revised by Kenneth W. Thompson. New York: Knopf. NIEBUHR, REINHOLD. (1932) Moral Man and Immoral Society: A Study in Ethics and Politics. New York: Charles Scribner's Sons. NIEBUHR, REINHOLD. (1944) The Children of Light and the Children of Darkness: A Vindication of Democracy and a Critique of Its Traditional Defense. New York: Charles Scribner's Sons. NIEBUHR, REINHOLD. (1946) Christianity and Power Politics. New York: Charles Scribner's Sons. OLSON, MANCUR. (1965) The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. ORGANSKI, A. F. K. (1958) World Politics. New York: Knopf. OSTROM, ELINOR. (1991) Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action. New York: Cambridge University Press. POLLINS, BRIAN M. (1989a) Conflict, Cooperation, and Commerce: The Effects of International Political Interactions on Bilateral Trade Flows. American Journal of Political Science 33: POLLINS, BRIAN M. (1989b) Does Trade Still Follow the Flag? American Political Science Review 83: POWELL, ROBERT. (1991) Absolute and Relative Gains in International Relations Theory. American Political Science Review 85: PRIESS, DAVID. (1996a) Balance of Threat Theory and the Genesis of the Gulf Cooperation Council: An Interpretative Case Study. Security Studies 5 (Summer): PRIESS, DAVID. (1996b) "Why Is Breaking Up Hard To Do? A Social Psychological Realist Perspective on Alliance Durability." Unpublished paper. Duke University (September). RAVENHILL,JOHN. (1993) The "Japan Problem" in Pacific Trade. In Pacific Economic Relations in the 1990s: Conflict or Cooperation?, edited by Richard Higgott, Richard Leaver, and John Ravenhill. Boulder: Westview Press. REITER, DAN. (1994) Learning, Realism, and Alliances: The Weight of the Shadow of the Past. World Politics 46: REITER, DAN. (1996) Crucible of Beliefs: Learning, Alliances, and World Wars. Ithaca: Cornell University Press. RESENDE-SANTOS, JOAO. (1992) System and Agent: Comments on Labs and Kaufman. Security Studies 1 (Summer) : RISSE-KAPPEN, THOMAS. (1995) Cooperation Among Democracies: The European Influence on U.S. Foreign Policy. Princeton: Princeton University Press. RISSE-KAPPEN, THOMAS. (1996) Collective Identity in a Democratic Community: The Case of NATO. In The Culture of National Security: Norms and Identity in World Politics, edited by PeterJ. Katzenstein. New York: Columbia University Press. RUGGIE,JOHN GERARD. (1995) The False Premise of Realism. International Security 20 (1): SAGAN, SCOTT. (1994) The Perils of Proliferation: Organizational Theory, Deterrence Theory, and the Spread of Nuclear Weapons. International Security 18 (4) : SAMUELS, RICHARD. (1994) "Rich Nation, Strong Army " National Security and the Technological Transformation ofjapan. Ithaca: Cornell University Press. SCHMITTER, PHILLIPE. (1969) Three Neo-Functional Hypotheses About International Integration. International Organization 23: SCHROEDER, PAUL W. (1976) Alliances, : Weapons of Power and Tools of Management. In Historical Dimensions of National Security Problems, edited by Klaus Knorr. Lawrence: University Press of Kansas. SCHROEDER, PAULW. (1994) The Transformation of European Politics, NewYork: Oxford University Press.

32 RANDALL L. SCHWELLER AND DAVID PRIESS 31 SCHUMAN, FREDERICK L. (1948) International Politics: The Destiny of the Western State System. Fourth edition. New York: McGraw Hill. SCHWELLER, RANDALL L. (1993) Tripolarity and the Second World War. International Studies Quarterly 37: SCHWELLER, RANDALL. (1994) Bandwagoning for Profit: Bringing the Revisionist State Back In. International Security 19 (1): SCHWELLER, RANDALL. (1996) Neorealism's Status-Quo Bias: What Security Dilemma? Security Studies 5 (Spring) : SCHWELLER, RANDALL L. (forthcoming) Deadly Imbalances: Tripolarity and Hitler's Strategy of World Conquest. New York: Columbia University Press. SMITH, MICHAEL JOSEPH. (1986) Realist Thought from Weber to Kissinger. Baton Rouge: Louisiana State University Press. SNIDAL, DUNCAN. (1991a) International Cooperation Among Relative Gains Maximizers. International Studies Quarterly 35: SNIDAL, DUNCAN. (1991b) Relative Gains and the Pattern of International Cooperation. American Political Science Review 85: SNYDER, GLENN H. (1984) The Security Dilemma in Alliance Politics. World Politics 36: SNYDER, GLENN H. (1990) Alliance Theory: A Neorealist First Cut. Journal ofinternationalaffairs 44: SNYDER, GLENN H. (1991) Alliances, Balance, and Stability. International Organization 45: SNYDER, GLENN H. (1996) Process Variables in Neorealist Theory. Security Studies 5 (Spring): SNYDER, JACK. (1991) Averting Anarchy in the New Europe. In The Cold War and After: Prospects for Peace, edited by Sean M. Lynn-Jones and Steven E. Miller. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. SPEGELE, ROGER D. (1996) Political Realism in International Theory. New York: Cambridge University Press. SPIRTAS, MICHAEL. (1996) A House Divided: Tragedy and Evil in Realist Theory. Security Studies 5 (Spring) : SPYKMAN, NICHOLASJOHN. (1942) America's Strategy in World Politics: The United States and thebalanceofpower. New York: Harcourt, Brace and Company. TELLIS, ASHLEYJ. (1996) Reconstructing Political Realism: The Long March to Scientific Theory. Security Studies 5 (Spring): THOMPSON, KENNETH W. (1994) Fathers of International Thought: The Legacy of International Theory. Baton Rouge: Louisiana University Press. VAN EVERA, STEPHEN. (1991) Primed for Peace: Europe after the Cold War. In The Cold War and After: Prospects for Peace, edited by Sean M. Lynn-Jones and Steven E. Miller. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. VON BERTALANFFY, LUDWIG. (1968) General System Theory: Foundations, Development, Applications. New York: George Braziller. WALLANDER, CELESTE A., AND ROBERT O. KEOHANE. (1995) "Toward an Institutional Theory of Alliances." Paper presented at the annual meeting of the International Studies Association, Chicago, February WALT, STEPHEN M. (1985) Alliance Formation and the Balance of World Power. International Security 9 (4):3-43. WALT, STEPHEN M. (1987) The Origins of Alliances. Ithaca: Cornell University Press. WALT, STEPHEN M. (1988) Testing Theories of Alliance Formation. International Organization 42: WALT, STEPHEN M. (1992) Revolution and War. World Politics 44: WALT, STEPHEN M. (1996a) Revolution and War. Ithaca: Cornell University Press. WALT, STEPHEN M. (1996b) "Why Do Alliances Fail? How Do Some Survive?" Paper presented at the annual meeting of the International Institute for Strategic Studies. Dresden, Germany, September 1-4. WALTZ, KENNETH N. (1959) Man, the State and War: A Theoretical Analysis. New York: Columbia University Press. WALTZ, KENNETH N. (1971) Conflict in World Politics. In Conflict in World Politics, edited by Steven L. Spiegel and Kenneth N. Waltz. Cambridge, MA: Winthrop. WALTZ, KENNETH N. (1979) Theory of International Politics. Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley. WALTZ, KENNETH, N. (1986) Reflections on Theory of International Politics: A Response to My Critics. In Neorealism and Its Critics, edited by Robert O. Keohane. New York: Columbia University Press. WALTZ, KENNETH N. (1993) The Emerging Structure of International Politics. International Security 18 (2): WALTZ, KENNETH N. (1996) International Politics Is Not Foreign Policy. Security Studies 6 (Autumn) : WENDT, ALEXANDER. (1992) Anarchy Is What States Make Of It: The Social Construction of Power Politics. International Organization 46:

33 32 A Tale of Two Realisms: Expanding the Institutions Debate WENDT, ALEXANDER. (1995) Constructing International Politics. International Security 20 (1): WIGHT, MARTIN. (1978) Power Politics, edited by Hedley Bull and Carsten Holbrand. London: Leicester University Press. WOHLFORTH, WILLIAM C. (1993) The Elusive Balance: Power and Perceptions During the Cold War. Ithaca: Cornell University Press. WOHLFORTH, WILLIAM C. (1994/95) Realism and the End of the Cold War. International Security 19 (3): WOLFERS, ARNOLD. (1962) Discord and Collaboration: Essays on International Politics. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press. YOUNG, ORAN. (1982) Regime Dynamics: The Rise and Fall of International Regimes. International Organization 36: YOUNG, ORAN. (1986) International Regimes: Toward a New Theory of Institutions. World Politics 39: YOUNG, ORAN. (1989) International Cooperation: Building Regimes for Natural Resources and the Environment. Ithaca: Cornell University Press. YOUNG, ORAN. (1992) The Effectiveness of International Institutions: Hard Cases and Critical Variables. In Governance Without Government: Order and Change in World Politics, edited byjames N. Rosenau and Ernst-Otto Czempiel. New York: Columbia University Press. ZACHER, MARK W. (1996) Governing Global Networks: International Regimes for Transportation and Communications. New York: Cambridge University Press. ZAKARIA, FAREED. (1995) Realism and Domestic Politics: A Review Essay. In The Perils of Anarchy: Contemporary Realism and International Security, edited by Michael E. Brown, Sean M. Lynn-Jones, and Steven E. Miller. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

The third debate: Neorealism versus Neoliberalism and their views on cooperation

The third debate: Neorealism versus Neoliberalism and their views on cooperation The third debate: Neorealism versus Neoliberalism and their views on cooperation The issue of international cooperation, especially through institutions, remains heavily debated within the International

More information

Exam Questions By Year IR 214. How important was soft power in ending the Cold War?

Exam Questions By Year IR 214. How important was soft power in ending the Cold War? Exam Questions By Year IR 214 2005 How important was soft power in ending the Cold War? What does the concept of an international society add to neo-realist or neo-liberal approaches to international relations?

More information

GOVT 2060 International Relations: Theories and Approaches Fall 2017

GOVT 2060 International Relations: Theories and Approaches Fall 2017 THE UNIVERSITY OF THE WEST INDIES ST. AUGUSTINE FACULTY OF SOCIAL SCIENCES DEPARTMENT OF POLITICAL SCIENCE GOVT 2060 International Relations: Theories and Approaches Fall 2017 Topic 4 Neorealism The end

More information

The Liberal Paradigm. Session 6

The Liberal Paradigm. Session 6 The Liberal Paradigm Session 6 Pedigree of the Liberal Paradigm Rousseau (18c) Kant (18c) LIBERALISM (1920s) (Utopianism/Idealism) Neoliberalism (1970s) Neoliberal Institutionalism (1980s-90s) 2 Major

More information

International Relations Theory Political Science 440 Northwestern University Winter 2010 Thursday 2-5pm, Ripton Room, Scott Hall

International Relations Theory Political Science 440 Northwestern University Winter 2010 Thursday 2-5pm, Ripton Room, Scott Hall International Relations Theory Political Science 440 Northwestern University Winter 2010 Thursday 2-5pm, Ripton Room, Scott Hall Jonathan Caverley j-caverley@northwestern.edu 404 Scott Office Hours: Tuesday

More information

INTRODUCTION TO INTERNATIONAL POLITICS Govt 204 Summer Sue Peterson Morton 13 Office Hours: M 2-3, W

INTRODUCTION TO INTERNATIONAL POLITICS Govt 204 Summer Sue Peterson Morton 13 Office Hours: M 2-3, W INTRODUCTION TO INTERNATIONAL POLITICS Govt 204 Summer 2004 Sue Peterson Morton 13 Office Hours: M 2-3, W 3-4 221-3036 Course Description and Goals This course provides an introduction to the study of

More information

John Paul Tabakian, Ed.D. Political Science 2 Modern World Governments Fall 2017 / Spring 2017 Power Point 3

John Paul Tabakian, Ed.D. Political Science 2 Modern World Governments Fall 2017 / Spring 2017 Power Point 3 John Paul Tabakian, Ed.D. Political Science 2 Modern World Governments Fall 2017 / Spring 2017 Power Point 3 Course Lecture Topics (1) This Week s Lecture Covers: The West Versus The Rest Examining Globalization

More information

RPOS 370: International Relations Theory

RPOS 370: International Relations Theory RPOS 370: International Relations Theory Professor: Bryan R. Early Class #: 9947 Class Times: TU-TH 8:45 AM -10:05 AM Room: SS 256 Email: bearly@albany.edu Office Hours: Uptown, Humanities Building B16

More information

Chapter 7: CONTENPORARY MAINSTREAM APPROACHES: NEO-REALISM AND NEO-LIBERALISM. By Baylis 5 th edition

Chapter 7: CONTENPORARY MAINSTREAM APPROACHES: NEO-REALISM AND NEO-LIBERALISM. By Baylis 5 th edition Chapter 7: CONTENPORARY MAINSTREAM APPROACHES: NEO-REALISM AND NEO-LIBERALISM By Baylis 5 th edition INTRODUCTION p. 116 Neo-realism and neo-liberalism are the progeny of realism and liberalism respectively

More information

Liberalism and Neoliberalism

Liberalism and Neoliberalism Chapter 5 Pedigree of the Liberal Paradigm Rousseau (18c) Kant (18c) Liberalism and Neoliberalism LIBERALISM (1920s) (Utopianism/Idealism) Neoliberalism (1970s) Neoliberal Institutionalism (1980s-90s)

More information

RPOS 370: International Relations Theory

RPOS 370: International Relations Theory RPOS 370: International Relations Theory Professor: Bryan R. Early Class Times: MWF 11:30 AM -12:25 PM Room: ES 147 Email: bearly@albany.edu Office Hours: Uptown, Humanities Building B16 Mondays, 9:15-11:15AM

More information

GOVERNMENT 426 CONFLICT & COOPERATION IN WORLD POLITICS Spring 1996 Tuesday 2:15-4:05 p.m. Healy 106

GOVERNMENT 426 CONFLICT & COOPERATION IN WORLD POLITICS Spring 1996 Tuesday 2:15-4:05 p.m. Healy 106 GOVERNMENT 426 CONFLICT & COOPERATION IN WORLD POLITICS Spring 1996 Tuesday 2:15-4:05 p.m. Healy 106 Professor Joseph Lepgold Professor George Shambaugh ICC 665 ICC 674A phone: 687-5635 phone: 687-2979

More information

International Institutions

International Institutions International Institutions Erik Gartzke 154A, Lecture 6 November 06, 2012 What is an IO? What is an international organization? Def: group designed to achieve collective action, usually across international

More information

REALISM INTRODUCTION NEED OF THEORY OF INTERNATIONAL RELATIONS

REALISM INTRODUCTION NEED OF THEORY OF INTERNATIONAL RELATIONS REALISM INTRODUCTION NEED OF THEORY OF INTERNATIONAL RELATIONS We need theories of International Relations to:- a. Understand subject-matter of IR. b. Know important, less important and not important matter

More information

POSITIVIST AND POST-POSITIVIST THEORIES

POSITIVIST AND POST-POSITIVIST THEORIES A theory of international relations is a set of ideas that explains how the international system works. Unlike an ideology, a theory of international relations is (at least in principle) backed up with

More information

Systems Thinking and Culture in International Relations: A Foreign Policy Approach

Systems Thinking and Culture in International Relations: A Foreign Policy Approach Systems Thinking and Culture in International Relations: A Foreign Policy Approach By Roozbeh Safdari Ghandehari Thesis submitted to the Faculty of Graduate and Postdoctoral Studies In partial fulfillment

More information

Test Bank. to accompany. Joseph S. Nye David A. Welch. Prepared by Marcel Dietsch University of Oxford. Longman

Test Bank. to accompany. Joseph S. Nye David A. Welch. Prepared by Marcel Dietsch University of Oxford. Longman Test Bank to accompany Understanding Global Conflict and Cooperation Joseph S. Nye David A. Welch Prepared by Marcel Dietsch University of Oxford Longman New York Boston San Francisco London Toronto Sydney

More information

ANARCHY AND POWER What Causes War? Ch. 10. The International System notes by Denis Bašić

ANARCHY AND POWER What Causes War? Ch. 10. The International System notes by Denis Bašić ANARCHY AND POWER What Causes War? Ch. 10. The International System notes by Denis Bašić INTERNATIONAL SYSTEM AND ANARCHY Some scholars believe that the international system is characterized by anarchy;

More information

Introduction to International Relations Political Science S1601Q Columbia University Summer 2013

Introduction to International Relations Political Science S1601Q Columbia University Summer 2013 Introduction to International Relations Political Science S1601Q Columbia University Summer 2013 Instructor: Sara Bjerg Moller Email: sbm2145@columbia.edu Office Hours: Prior to each class or by appointment.

More information

CONTENDING THEORIES IN INTERNATIONAL POLITICS

CONTENDING THEORIES IN INTERNATIONAL POLITICS The City University of New York The Graduate School Dept of Political Science PSC 86001 Spring 2003 Prof. W. Ofuatey-Kodjoe CONTENDING THEORIES IN INTERNATIONAL POLITICS This seminar will examine the role

More information

GOVT 2060 International Relations: Theories and Approaches

GOVT 2060 International Relations: Theories and Approaches THE UNIVERSITY OF THE WEST INDIES ST. AUGUSTINE FACULTY OF SOCIAL SCIENCES DEPARTMENT OF POLITICAL SCIENCES GOVT 2060 International Relations: Theories and Approaches Fall 2017 1/29 ab1234.yolasite.com

More information

Unit Three: Thinking Liberally - Diversity and Hegemony in IPE. Dr. Russell Williams

Unit Three: Thinking Liberally - Diversity and Hegemony in IPE. Dr. Russell Williams Unit Three: Thinking Liberally - Diversity and Hegemony in IPE Dr. Russell Williams Required Reading: Cohn, Ch. 4. Class Discussion Reading: Outline: Eric Helleiner, Economic Liberalism and Its Critics:

More information

Final Syllabus, January 27, (Subject to slight revisions.)

Final Syllabus, January 27, (Subject to slight revisions.) Final Syllabus, January 27, 2008. (Subject to slight revisions.) Politics 558. International Cooperation. Spring 2008. Professors Robert O. Keohane and Helen V. Milner Tuesdays, 1:30-4:20. Prerequisite:

More information

Institutions and Collective Goods

Institutions and Collective Goods Quiz #5 1. According to the textbook, North America accounts for what percent of all transnational terrorist attacks in the past 38 years: a.) 1%, b.) 4%, c.) 9%, d.) 27%, e.) 42%. 2. Which is NOT a right

More information

POSC 172 Fall 2016 Syllabus: Introduction to International Relations

POSC 172 Fall 2016 Syllabus: Introduction to International Relations Dr. Paul E. Schroeder Main Idea: Diplomacy, War & the Fates of Nations Enduring Understandings: Traditional issues of state-to-state relations and the causes of war, along with issues of sustainability

More information

2. Realism is important to study because it continues to guide much thought regarding international relations.

2. Realism is important to study because it continues to guide much thought regarding international relations. Chapter 2: Theories of World Politics TRUE/FALSE 1. A theory is an example, model, or essential pattern that structures thought about an area of inquiry. F DIF: High REF: 30 2. Realism is important to

More information

Essentials of International Relations Eighth Edition Chapter 3: International Relations Theories LECTURE SLIDES

Essentials of International Relations Eighth Edition Chapter 3: International Relations Theories LECTURE SLIDES Essentials of International Relations Eighth Edition Chapter 3: International Relations Theories LECTURE SLIDES Copyright 2018 W. W. Norton & Company Learning Objectives Explain the value of studying international

More information

Draft Syllabus. International Relations (Govt ) June 04-July 06, Meeting Location: ICC 104 A. Farid Tookhy

Draft Syllabus. International Relations (Govt ) June 04-July 06, Meeting Location: ICC 104 A. Farid Tookhy Draft Syllabus International Relations (Govt 060-10) June 04-July 06, 2018 Meeting Times: 8:30-10:30 AM; MTWR Meeting Location: ICC 104 Instructor: A. Farid Tookhy (at449@georgetown.edu) Office Hours:

More information

International Relations Field Seminar

International Relations Field Seminar International Relations Field Seminar GOVT 540-001, Spring 2016 George Mason University, SPGIA Monday 7:20-10:00 PM in Founders 308 Instructor: Joseph Kochanek (email: jkochane@gmu.edu) Office Hours: Monday,

More information

Theory Talks THEORY TALK #9 ROBERT KEOHANE ON INSTITUTIONS AND THE NEED FOR INNOVATION IN THE FIELD. Theory Talks. Presents

Theory Talks THEORY TALK #9 ROBERT KEOHANE ON INSTITUTIONS AND THE NEED FOR INNOVATION IN THE FIELD. Theory Talks. Presents Theory Talks Presents THEORY TALK #9 ROBERT KEOHANE ON INSTITUTIONS AND THE NEED FOR INNOVATION IN THE FIELD Theory Talks is an interactive forum for discussion on actual International Relations-related

More information

Realism. John Lee Department of Political Science Florida State University

Realism. John Lee Department of Political Science Florida State University Realism John Lee Department of Political Science Florida State University Lenses of Analysis First level is the individual. Second level if the state. Third level is the system. Many consider these distinctions

More information

1 Introduction. Cambridge University Press International Institutions and National Policies Xinyuan Dai Excerpt More information

1 Introduction. Cambridge University Press International Institutions and National Policies Xinyuan Dai Excerpt More information 1 Introduction Why do countries comply with international agreements? How do international institutions influence states compliance? These are central questions in international relations (IR) and arise

More information

Nationalism in International Context. 4. IR Theory I - Constructivism National Identity and Real State Interests 23 October 2012

Nationalism in International Context. 4. IR Theory I - Constructivism National Identity and Real State Interests 23 October 2012 Nationalism in International Context 4. IR Theory I - Constructivism National Identity and Real State Interests 23 October 2012 The International Perspective We have mainly considered ethnicity and nationalism

More information

FOREIGN POLICY ANALYSIS

FOREIGN POLICY ANALYSIS I IBIIIUUI t A/553920 SAGE LIBRARY OF INTERNATIONAL RELATIONS FOREIGN POLICY ANALYSIS VOLUME I Edited by Walter Carlsnaes and Stefano Guzzini (S)SAGE Los Angeles London New Delhi Singapore Washington DC

More information

Defense Cooperation: The South American Experience *

Defense Cooperation: The South American Experience * Defense Cooperation: The South American Experience * by Janina Onuki Universidade de São Paulo, São Paulo, São Paulo, Brazil (Rezende, Lucas Pereira. Sobe e Desce: Explicando a Cooperação em Defesa na

More information

1) Is the "Clash of Civilizations" too broad of a conceptualization to be of use? Why or why not?

1) Is the Clash of Civilizations too broad of a conceptualization to be of use? Why or why not? 1) Is the "Clash of Civilizations" too broad of a conceptualization to be of use? Why or why not? Huntington makes good points about the clash of civilizations and ideologies being a cause of conflict

More information

International Relations

International Relations International Relations GOVT 540-001, Summer 2017 George Mason University Schar School of Policy and Government Tuesdays and Thursdays at 4:30 in Enterprise 277 Instructor: Joseph Kochanek (email: jkochane@gmu.edu)

More information

POLITICAL SCIENCE 240/IRGN 254: International Relations Theory. The following books are available for purchase at the UCSD bookstore:

POLITICAL SCIENCE 240/IRGN 254: International Relations Theory. The following books are available for purchase at the UCSD bookstore: POLITICAL SCIENCE 240/IRGN 254: International Relations Theory Professors Miles Kahler and David A. Lake Winter Quarter 2002 Tuesdays, 1:30 PM 4:20 PM Course readings: The following books are available

More information

Peter Katzenstein, ed. The Culture of National Security: Norms and Identity in World Politics

Peter Katzenstein, ed. The Culture of National Security: Norms and Identity in World Politics Peter Katzenstein, ed. The Culture of National Security: Norms and Identity in World Politics Peter Katzenstein, Introduction: Alternative Perspectives on National Security Most studies of international

More information

GOVT 102 Introduction to International Politics Spring 2010 MW 11:00am-12:15pm Kirby 204

GOVT 102 Introduction to International Politics Spring 2010 MW 11:00am-12:15pm Kirby 204 GOVT 102 Introduction to International Politics Spring 2010 MW 11:00am-12:15pm Kirby 204 Professor Seo-Hyun Park Office: Kirby 102 Phone: (610) 330-5412 Email: parksh@lafayette.edu Office hours: MW 1:00-3:00pm

More information

CHAPTER 3 THEORISING POLITICO-SECURITY REGIONALISM

CHAPTER 3 THEORISING POLITICO-SECURITY REGIONALISM 49 CHAPTER 3 THEORISING POLITICO-SECURITY REGIONALISM 3.1 Introduction The previous chapter attempted to conceptualise politico-security regionalism not only with defining security and regionalism respectively,

More information

DIPL 6000: Section AA International Relations Theory

DIPL 6000: Section AA International Relations Theory 1 DIPL 6000: Section AA International Relations Theory Professor Martin S. Edwards E-Mail: edwardmb@shu.edu Office: 106 McQuaid Office Phone: (973) 275-2507 Office Hours: By Appointment This is a graduate

More information

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at The Progressive Power of Realism Author(s): Stephen M. Walt Source: The American Political Science Review, Vol. 91, No. 4 (Dec., 1997), pp. 931-935 Published by: American Political Science Association

More information

Why are Regimes and Regime Theory Accepted by Realists and Liberals?

Why are Regimes and Regime Theory Accepted by Realists and Liberals? 1 Why are Regimes and Regime Theory Accepted by Realists and Liberals? Stoyan Stoyanov Regimes gained popularity during the 20th century as states began increasingly to get involved in international agreements

More information

CHAPTER 3: Theories of International Relations: Realism and Liberalism

CHAPTER 3: Theories of International Relations: Realism and Liberalism 1. According to the author, the state of theory in international politics is characterized by a. misunderstanding and fear. b. widespread agreement and cooperation. c. disagreement and debate. d. misperception

More information

International Relations. Dr Markus Pauli , Semester 1

International Relations. Dr Markus Pauli , Semester 1 International Relations Dr Markus Pauli 2018-19, Semester 1 Course Information Location: TBC Time: Thursdays 9:00 12:00 Instructor Information Instructor: Markus Pauli (markus.pauli@yale-nus.edu.sg) Office:

More information

Toward a Dynamic Model of State Choice: Gains Pursuit Debate and the World System

Toward a Dynamic Model of State Choice: Gains Pursuit Debate and the World System University of Tennessee, Knoxville Trace: Tennessee Research and Creative Exchange Doctoral Dissertations Graduate School 8-2002 Toward a Dynamic Model of State Choice: Gains Pursuit Debate and the World

More information

Graduate Seminar on International Relations Political Science (PSCI) 5013/7013 Spring 2007

Graduate Seminar on International Relations Political Science (PSCI) 5013/7013 Spring 2007 Graduate Seminar on International Relations Political Science (PSCI) 5013/7013 Spring 2007 Instructor: Moonhawk Kim Office: Ketchum 122A E-mail: moonhawk.kim@colorado.edu Phone: (303) 492 8601 Office Hours:

More information

Spring 2013 Theories of International Relations SA Professor Jakub Grygiel 1/10/2013

Spring 2013 Theories of International Relations SA Professor Jakub Grygiel 1/10/2013 Theories of International Relations SA.100.761.01 Professor Jakub Grygiel 1/10/2013 *Disclaimer: Please note that the syllabus may change before or during the class. The most upto-date syllabus can be

More information

Theory of International Relations

Theory of International Relations Theory of International Relations Fall Semester, 2012 Course Type: 3 Unit Core Course Department: Institute of China and Asia-Pacific Studies Professor: Yujen Kuo, Ph.D. Political Science, University of

More information

International Security: An Analytical Survey

International Security: An Analytical Survey EXCERPTED FROM International Security: An Analytical Survey Michael Sheehan Copyright 2005 ISBNs: 1-58826-273-1 hc 1-58826-298-7 pb 1800 30th Street, Ste. 314 Boulder, CO 80301 USA telephone 303.444.6684

More information

Power in World Politics

Power in World Politics University of Göttingen Faculty of Social Sciences Department of Political Science B.Pol.4 Power in World Politics Winter semester 2014/15 Prof. Dr. Tobias Lenz Email tobias.lenz@sowi.uni-goettingen.de

More information

Essential Readings in World Politics

Essential Readings in World Politics SUB Hamburg A/566626 Essential Readings in World Politics FOURTH EDITION EDITED BY Karen A. Mingst and Jack L. Snyder W. W. NORTON & COMPANY NEW YORK LONDON Contents 1 Preface ix Approaches 1 One World,

More information

Social Constructivism and International Relations

Social Constructivism and International Relations Social Constructivism and International Relations Philosophy and the Social Sciences Jack Jenkins jtjenkins919@gmail.com Explain and critique constructivist approaches to the study of international relations.

More information

Academic foundations of global economic governance an assessment

Academic foundations of global economic governance an assessment Academic foundations of global economic governance an assessment Sterian Maria Gabriela Department of Trade, European Integration and International Affairs Romanian-American University Bucharest, Romania

More information

Syllabus International Cooperation

Syllabus International Cooperation Syllabus International Cooperation Instructor: Oliver Westerwinter Fall Semester 2016 Time & room Thursday, 10:15-12h in 01-208 Office Oliver Westerwinter Room: 33-506, Rosenbergstr. 51, 5th floor Email:

More information

Political Science 217/317 International Organization

Political Science 217/317 International Organization Phillip Y. Lipscy Spring, 2008 email: plipscy@stanford.edu Office Hours: Wed 10am-12pm or by appointment Encina Hall, Central 434 Course Description Political Science 217/317 International Organization

More information

1 Democratization and international relations

1 Democratization and international relations 1 Democratization and international relations Few events have captured the attention of policymakers and the public like the collapse of the Soviet Union and the emergence of independent states in Central

More information

American Hegemony and Postwar Regional Integration:

American Hegemony and Postwar Regional Integration: American Hegemony and Postwar Regional Integration: The Evolution of Interest and Strategy (Dissertation) Supervisor: Professor SHINOHARA Hatsue Song Wei Student ID: 4004s308-3 Graduate School of Asia

More information

Last time we discussed a stylized version of the realist view of global society.

Last time we discussed a stylized version of the realist view of global society. Political Philosophy, Spring 2003, 1 The Terrain of a Global Normative Order 1. Realism and Normative Order Last time we discussed a stylized version of the realist view of global society. According to

More information

COOPERATIVE CAPACITY: US FOREIGN POLICY AND BUILDING STABILITY IN NORTHEAST ASIA

COOPERATIVE CAPACITY: US FOREIGN POLICY AND BUILDING STABILITY IN NORTHEAST ASIA COOPERATIVE CAPACITY: US FOREIGN POLICY AND BUILDING STABILITY IN NORTHEAST ASIA A Thesis submitted to the Faculty of the Graduate School of Arts and Sciences of Georgetown University in partial fulfillment

More information

Follow links Class Use and other Permissions. For more information, send to:

Follow links Class Use and other Permissions. For more information, send  to: COPYRIGHT NOTICE: Edited by Helen V. Milner & Andrew Moravcsik: Power, Interdependence, and Nonstate Actors in World Politics is published by Princeton University Press and copyrighted, 2009, by Princeton

More information

Public Policy 429 FOUNDATIONS OF INTERNATIONAL POLITICAL ECONOMY

Public Policy 429 FOUNDATIONS OF INTERNATIONAL POLITICAL ECONOMY Public Policy 429 FOUNDATIONS OF INTERNATIONAL POLITICAL ECONOMY Harris School of Public Policy Studies The University of Chicago Winter 2006 Tuesdays 3:30-6:20pm (Room 140A) Professor Lloyd Gruber Office:

More information

Structural Realism in a more complex world

Structural Realism in a more complex world Review of International Studies (2003), 29, 403 414 Copyright British International Studies Association DOI: 10.1017/S0260210503004030 Structural Realism in a more complex world CHARLES L. GLASER The editors

More information

Is Anybody Still a Realist?

Is Anybody Still a Realist? Is Anybody Still a Realist? Legro, Jeffrey W., and Andrew Moravcsik. "Is Anybody Still a Realist?" International Security 24.2 (1999): 5. Realism, the oldest and most prominent theoretical paradigm in

More information

POSC 249 Theories of International Relations Mo/Wed/Fri 4a

POSC 249 Theories of International Relations Mo/Wed/Fri 4a POSC 249 Theories of International Relations Mo/Wed/Fri 4a Contact Information ppetzsch@carleton.edu office phone: x7837 Venue: Willis 203 Office Hours (please use moodle to book a slot): Leighton 213

More information

Waltz s book belongs to an important style of theorizing, in which far-reaching. conclusions about a domain in this case, the domain of international

Waltz s book belongs to an important style of theorizing, in which far-reaching. conclusions about a domain in this case, the domain of international Notes on Waltz Waltz s book belongs to an important style of theorizing, in which far-reaching conclusions about a domain in this case, the domain of international politics are derived from a very spare

More information

Liberalism and Neo-Liberalism

Liberalism and Neo-Liberalism Liberalism and Neo-Liberalism Different operational assumptions from Realisms Units of analysis include the state, interest groups, or international institutions Neo-liberal institutionalists accept the

More information

440 IR Theory Winter 2014

440 IR Theory Winter 2014 440 IR Theory Winter 2014 Ian Hurd ianhurd@northwestern.edu rm 306, Scott Hall Seminar meetings: Friday 9 to 12, Ripton Room Office hours Wednesday 10 to 12. All discussion of international politics rests

More information

International Law and International Relations: Together, Apart, Together?

International Law and International Relations: Together, Apart, Together? Chicago Journal of International Law Volume 1 Number 1 Article 10 3-1-2000 International Law and International Relations: Together, Apart, Together? Stephen D. Krasner Recommended Citation Krasner, Stephen

More information

GOVT 102 Introduction to International Politics Spring 2011 Section 01: Tues/Thurs 9:30-10:45am Section 02: Tues/Thurs 11:00am-12:15pm Kirby 107

GOVT 102 Introduction to International Politics Spring 2011 Section 01: Tues/Thurs 9:30-10:45am Section 02: Tues/Thurs 11:00am-12:15pm Kirby 107 GOVT 102 Introduction to International Politics Spring 2011 Section 01: Tues/Thurs 9:30-10:45am Section 02: Tues/Thurs 11:00am-12:15pm Kirby 107 Professor Seo-Hyun Park Office: Kirby 102 Phone: (610) 330-5412

More information

SNU/GSIS : Understanding International Cooperation Fall 2017 Tuesday 9:30am-12:20pm Building 140-1, Room 101

SNU/GSIS : Understanding International Cooperation Fall 2017 Tuesday 9:30am-12:20pm Building 140-1, Room 101 SNU/GSIS 875.520: Understanding International Cooperation Fall 2017 Tuesday 9:30am-12:20pm Building 140-1, Room 101 Instructor: Jiyeoun Song Office: Building 140-1, Room 614 Phone: 02-880-4174 Email: jiyeoun.song@snu.ac.kr

More information

NEOREALISM, NEOLIBERAL INSTITUTIONALISM

NEOREALISM, NEOLIBERAL INSTITUTIONALISM Published in: Security Studies, Vol. 3, No. 1 (1993), pp 3-43. NEOREALISM, NEOLIBERAL INSTITUTIONALISM AND THE FUTURE OF NATO Gunther Hellmann and Reinhard Wolf* The cold war is over, the Warsaw Pact has

More information

ED IT ED B Y DAV I DE OR SI, J. R. AVGU ST IN & MA X N U R N U S. Realism in Practice. An Appraisal

ED IT ED B Y DAV I DE OR SI, J. R. AVGU ST IN & MA X N U R N U S. Realism in Practice. An Appraisal ED IT ED B Y DAV I DE OR SI, J. R. AVGU ST IN & MA X N U R N U S Realism in Practice An Appraisal This e-book is provided without charge via free download by E-International Relations (www.e-ir.info).

More information

POLITICS AMONG NATIONS The Struggle for Power and Peace

POLITICS AMONG NATIONS The Struggle for Power and Peace SEVENTH EDITION POLITICS AMONG NATIONS The Struggle for Power and Peace Hans J. Morgenthau Late Albert A. Michelson Distinguished Service Professor ofpolitical Science and Modern History at the University

More information

Guidelines for Comprehensive Exams in International Relations Department of Political Science Pennsylvania State University.

Guidelines for Comprehensive Exams in International Relations Department of Political Science Pennsylvania State University. Guidelines for Comprehensive Exams in International Relations Department of Political Science Pennsylvania State University Spring 2011 The International Relations comprehensive exam consists of two parts.

More information

Essentials of International Relations

Essentials of International Relations Chapter 3 INTERNATIONAL RELATIONS THEORIES Essentials of International Relations SEVENTH EDITION L E CTURE S L IDES Copyright 2016, W.W. Norton & Co., Inc Learning Objectives Explain the value of studying

More information

Chapter 1: Theoretical Approaches to Global Politics

Chapter 1: Theoretical Approaches to Global Politics Chapter 1: Theoretical Approaches to Global Politics I. Introduction A. What is theory and why do we need it? B. Many theories, many meanings C. Levels of analysis D. The Great Debates: an introduction

More information

Theories of European integration. Dr. Rickard Mikaelsson

Theories of European integration. Dr. Rickard Mikaelsson Theories of European integration Dr. Rickard Mikaelsson 1 Theories provide a analytical framework that can serve useful for understanding political events, such as the creation, growth, and function of

More information

DOCTORAL DISSERTATION

DOCTORAL DISSERTATION BABEŞ-BOLYAI UNIVERSITY CLUJ-NAPOCA FACULTY OF HISTORY AND PHILOSOPHY INTERNATIONAL RELATIONS AND EUROPEAN STUDIES DEPARTMENT DOCTORAL DISSERTATION The Power Statute in the International System post-cold

More information

CONSTRUCTIVISM AS THE FRAMEWORK FOR INTERNATIONAL ORDERS

CONSTRUCTIVISM AS THE FRAMEWORK FOR INTERNATIONAL ORDERS AIR COMMAND AND STAFF COLLEGE AIR UNIVERSITY CONSTRUCTIVISM AS THE FRAMEWORK FOR INTERNATIONAL ORDERS by Charles Stretch, Major, USAF A Research Paper Submitted to the Faculty In Partial Fulfillment of

More information

ALLIANCES IN INTERNATIONAL POLITICS: A COMPARATIVE STUDY OF KENNETH WALTZ S AND STEPHEN WALT S THEORIES OF ALLIANCES

ALLIANCES IN INTERNATIONAL POLITICS: A COMPARATIVE STUDY OF KENNETH WALTZ S AND STEPHEN WALT S THEORIES OF ALLIANCES KAAV INTERNATIONAL JOURNAL OF ARTS, HUMANITIES & SOCIAL SCIENCES A REFEREED BLIND PEER REVIEW QUARTERLY JOURNAL KIJAHS/JUL-SEP2017/VOL-4/ISS-3/A9 PAGE NO-44-51 ISSN: 2348-4349 IMPACT FACTOR (2017) 7.9183

More information

Critical Theory and Constructivism

Critical Theory and Constructivism Chapter 7 Pedigree of the Critical Theory Paradigm Critical Theory and Ø Distinguishing characteristics: p The critical theory is a kind of reflectivism, comparative with rationalism, or problem-solving

More information

SHOULD THE UNITED STATES WORRY ABOUT LARGE, FAST-GROWING ECONOMIES?

SHOULD THE UNITED STATES WORRY ABOUT LARGE, FAST-GROWING ECONOMIES? Chapter Six SHOULD THE UNITED STATES WORRY ABOUT LARGE, FAST-GROWING ECONOMIES? This report represents an initial investigation into the relationship between economic growth and military expenditures for

More information

changes in the global environment, whether a shifting distribution of power (Zakaria

changes in the global environment, whether a shifting distribution of power (Zakaria Legitimacy dilemmas in global governance Review by Edward A. Fogarty, Department of Political Science, Colgate University World Rule: Accountability, Legitimacy, and the Design of Global Governance. By

More information

INTL. RELATIONS IN THE AGE OF GLOBALIZATION

INTL. RELATIONS IN THE AGE OF GLOBALIZATION Syllabus INTL. RELATIONS IN THE AGE OF GLOBALIZATION - 58360 Last update 07-08-2013 HU Credits: 2 Degree/Cycle: 1st degree (Bachelor) Responsible Department: International Relations Academic year: 0 Semester:

More information

Quiz #1. Take out a piece of paper and answer the following questions (Write your name and student number on the top left-hand corner):

Quiz #1. Take out a piece of paper and answer the following questions (Write your name and student number on the top left-hand corner): Quiz #1 Take out a piece of paper and answer the following questions (Write your name and student number on the top left-hand corner): When a state is trying preserve the status quo through the threat

More information

CHAPTER 1 PROLOGUE: VALUES AND PERSPECTIVES

CHAPTER 1 PROLOGUE: VALUES AND PERSPECTIVES CHAPTER 1 PROLOGUE: VALUES AND PERSPECTIVES Final draft July 2009 This Book revolves around three broad kinds of questions: $ What kind of society is this? $ How does it really work? Why is it the way

More information

Theory and Realism POL3: INTRO TO IR

Theory and Realism POL3: INTRO TO IR Theory and Realism POL3: INTRO TO IR I. Theories 2 Theory: statement of relationship between causes and events i.e. story of why a relationship exists Two components of theories 1) Dependent variable,

More information

DIGITAL PUBLIC DIPLOMACY & NATION BRANDING: SESSION 4 THE GREAT DEBATES IN INTERNATIONAL RELATIONS

DIGITAL PUBLIC DIPLOMACY & NATION BRANDING: SESSION 4 THE GREAT DEBATES IN INTERNATIONAL RELATIONS DIGITAL PUBLIC DIPLOMACY & NATION BRANDING: SESSION 4 THE GREAT DEBATES IN INTERNATIONAL RELATIONS Universidad Del Desarrollo Prof. Matt Erlandsen August 22 nd, 2017 PREVIOUSLY Definition of International

More information

Chapter 1. Realism, Alliances, Balance of Power: A Theoretical Perspective

Chapter 1. Realism, Alliances, Balance of Power: A Theoretical Perspective Chapter 1 Realism, Alliances, Balance of Power: A Theoretical Perspective The discipline of International Relations has been dominated by several major theoretical traditions that have emerged mostly in

More information

RPOS/RPAD 583: Global Governance

RPOS/RPAD 583: Global Governance Professor: Bryan R. Early Class Times: Tuesdays, 5:45 8:35 PM Room: Husted 013 Email: bearly@albany.edu Office Hours: Tuesdays 1:30-2:30 PM Milne 300A Course Description RPOS/RPAD 583: Global Governance

More information

03/12/07-03:59:20 <gv214-2_07a1_ _05f09517fb19a81f a08cabe827a2d>

03/12/07-03:59:20 <gv214-2_07a1_ _05f09517fb19a81f a08cabe827a2d> Evaluating the democratic peace thesis using the case of the Iraq war Evaluating the democratic peace thesis (DPT) using the example of the Iraq War is a hopeless task. A theory can only strife to explain

More information

POL 230 Theories of International Relations Spring 2010

POL 230 Theories of International Relations Spring 2010 Lahore University of Management Sciences POL 230 Theories of International Relations Spring 2010 Instructor: Uzma Hussain Office: Room 239-I (Old SS Wing) Office Hours: TBA E-mail: uzmah@lums.edu.pk (N.B:

More information

Chapter 8: Power in Global Politics and the Causes of War

Chapter 8: Power in Global Politics and the Causes of War Chapter 8: Power in Global Politics and the Causes of War I. Introduction II. The quest for power and influence A. Power has always been central to studies of conflict B. Hard power C. Soft power D. Structural

More information

INTERNATIONAL THEORY

INTERNATIONAL THEORY INTERNATIONAL THEORY Political Science 550 Winter 2012 Instructor Alexander Wendt Teaching Assistant Sebastien Mainville Office: 2180 Derby Hall Office: 2031 Derby Hall Office Hrs: TR 4:30+ and by appt

More information

International Law for International Relations. Basak Cali Chapter 2. Perspectives on international law in international relations

International Law for International Relations. Basak Cali Chapter 2. Perspectives on international law in international relations International Law for International Relations Basak Cali Chapter 2 Perspectives on international law in international relations How does international relations (IR) scholarship perceive international

More information

Liberalism. Neoliberalism/Liberal Institutionalism

Liberalism. Neoliberalism/Liberal Institutionalism IEOs Week 2 October 24 Theoretical Foundations I Liberalism - Grotius (17 th ), Kant (18 th ), Wilson (20 th ) - Humans are basically good, rational, and capable of improving their lot. Injustice, aggression,

More information

The Goals and Tactics of the Lesser Allies Introduction

The Goals and Tactics of the Lesser Allies Introduction The Goals and Tactics of the Lesser Allies Introduction Naomi Konda Research Fellow, The Sasakawa Peace Foundation On July 9, 2016, NATO decided to strengthen its deterrence and defence posture at the

More information

SEMINAR IN WORLD POLITICS PLSC 650 Spring 2015

SEMINAR IN WORLD POLITICS PLSC 650 Spring 2015 SEMINAR IN WORLD POLITICS PLSC 650 Spring 2015 Instructor: Benjamin O. Fordham E-mail: bfordham@binghamton.edu Office: LNG-58 Office Hours: Tuesdays and Thursdays, 1:00-2:30, and by appointment This course

More information