Economic inequality and growth before the industrial revolution: the case of the Low Countries (fourteenth to nineteenth centuries)

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Economic inequality and growth before the industrial revolution: the case of the Low Countries (fourteenth to nineteenth centuries)"

Transcription

1 European Review of Economic History, 20, 1 22 The Author Published by Oxford University Press on behalf of the European Historical Economics Society. All rights reserved. For permissions, please journals.permissions@oup.com doi: /ereh/hev018 Advance Access publication September 25, 2015 Economic inequality and growth before the industrial revolution: the case of the Low Countries (fourteenth to nineteenth centuries) WOUTER RYCKBOSCH Fund for Scientific Research Flanders (FWO), University of Antwerp, Antwerpen, Belgium, wouter.ryckbosch@uantwerpen.be This article studies a collection of data on economic inequality in fifteen towns in the Southern and Northern Low Countries from the late Middle Ages until the end of the nineteenth century. By using a single and consistent source type and adopting a uniform methodology, it is possible to study levels of urban economic inequality across time and place comparatively. The results indicate a clear growth in economic inequality in the two centuries prior to the industrial revolution and the onset of sustained economic growth per capita. The results presented lend support to the classical explanation of inequality as the consequence of a changing functional distribution of income favoring capital over labor over the course of the early modern period. These findings provide an alternative resolution of the conundrum presented by optimist and pessimists interpretations of early modern economic development. 1. Inequality in history The growth of income inequality in many countries of the Western world over the last thirty years has significantly bolstered the centrality of inequality to debates in economics, social sciences, and policy making. Nevertheless, inequality s somewhat unexpected return to public consciousness and research agendas has confronted social scientists and policymakers alike with the finding that most knowledge of its fundamental causes and effects is still limited and often highly contested. As a result, many economists have turned to the past for more insight into the underlying logic of inequality movements through time. In particular, the long-term relationship between inequality and economic development has been central to much historical investigation. This strand of economic history has sought answers to the question whether inequality is good for economic development and has tried to do so by looking at the experience of the past two centuries. The current paper addresses the same issue of the relationship between inequality and economic development, but goes further back in time, and focuses on the long formative period of Western, capitalist economies. It aims to determine the extent to which pre-industrial levels of inequality were affected by economic development, and by the long-term emergence of a capitalist economy, and to consider how inequality might have influenced development itself. Several theories on the relationship between inequality and development exist for the modern era, but given the scarcity of sources that allow for the reconstruction of income and wealth inequality before the twentieth century, their applicability to the pre- and early industrial period is largely unclear. As is well known, the most influential modeling of the relationship between economic growth and inequality was presented first by Simon Kuznets in his 1954 presidential address to the American Economic Association (Kuznets 1955). Based on cross-sectional data on the level

2 2 European Review of Economic History of inequality in countries at different stages of their economic development, Kuznets proposed an association between levels of income per capita and inequality in the shape of an inverted U-curve. The empirical work by Peter Lindert and Jeffrey Williamson has indeed shown that in Britain and the United States income inequality rose during the initial stages of the industrial revolution (Lindert and Williamson 1976, 1982, 1983; Williamson and Lindert 1980; Lindert 2000). They have attributed this upswing to two processes associated with early industrialization: unbalanced technological change (causing growing income differentials between different economic sectors, and driving up the skill premium for human capital), and demographic growth (causing the wage profit ratio to rise as a result of increasing labor abundance) (Kaelble and Thomas 1991). Globalization has been offered as the most likely candidate for explaining the subsequent downswing of inequality in the developed world after the industrial revolution (Williamson 1996). Other recent explanations for the positive association of economic development with inequality during early industrialization, and the negative association from the late nineteenth century onward, have focused on the role of capital. Oded Galor and Omer Moav, for instance, have argued that this pattern was due to the transition from an economy relying on physical capital accumulation, to one where the relative importance of human capital accumulation has become dominant (Galor and Moav 2004). Thomas Piketty and coauthors, on the other hand, have gathered data on the evolution of top 1 percent income in a large number of countries and have identified in these a U-shaped pattern of declining and then rising inequality in the course of the twentieth century (Piketty et al. 2006; Atkinson et al. 2011; Piketty 2013). Contrary to Kuznets, this leads Piketty to argue that the return to capital will be higher than economic growth in the long run, unless the redistribution of wealth ownership (through wealth shocks or redistribution) can negate this tendency. These insights into the dynamics of the relation between inequality and economic development in the modern world offer new challenges and opportunities to economic historians of the pre-industrial period. If changes in the wealth-income ratio have indeed driven the most important developments in the overall level of modern inequality, then how did inequality behave during the pre-modern period in which the foundations of capital-driven economic growth were laid? Or, to phrase the matter differently, was the high level of inequality in early nineteenthcentury Western Europe with which Piketty begins his analysis a persistent feature of the pre-industrial world, or on the contrary, a more recent consequence of the formation of a capitalist economy during the preceding centuries? Did a lack of biased technological growth and globalization prior to the industrial revolution imply a lack of changes in the income distribution during the pre-industrial period? Or did inequality grow in the centuries leading up to industrialization, so as to allow for a sufficient degree of capital concentration to enable industrialization and growth? Theories on the relation between pre-industrial economic development and long-term changes in economic inequality are still rare. Two decades ago Jan Luiten van Zanden launched the idea of a super Kuznets curve based on the observation that in early modern Holland inequality rose during phases of pre-industrial economic growth (Van Zanden 1995). Pre-industrial merchant-capitalist growth, Van Zanden argued, caused the price of capital to rise, while the (real) price of labor declined. The result was the growth of inequality during phases of early modern and modern economic growth alike, until excess labor supplies disappeared around the beginning of the twentieth century. More recent empirical research has begun to qualify this hypothesis. Guido Alfani has shown how inequality in Northern Italy increased even when there was no economic growth (Alfani 2014; Alfani and Ammannati 2014), while Osamu Saito has demonstrated that this was not the case in remarkably egalitarian Japan before industrialization (Saito 2015). Both cases indicate the need to consider explanations

3 Economic inequality and growth before the industrial revolution 3 taking issues of market extension, redistribution, and political economy into account when trying to explain pre-industrial patterns of inequality. This article aims to re-examine the long-term trend in income inequality before and during the industrial revolution and to consider its relationship to economic development. It will do so by adding two new regions (Flanders and Brabant) to the growing body of empirical research into early modern inequality across Europe (Van Zanden 1995; Alfani 2010; Milanovic et al. 2011; Santiago-Caballero 2011; Hanus 2013; Alfani and Ammannati 2014), and comparing those to Van Zanden s seminal work on Holland. In doing so, the applicability of the aforementioned theoretical models on the development of income inequality in the Low Countries between the fourteenth and nineteenth centuries will be tested. Section 2 of the article presents the context, sources, and methodology. In section 3, the longterm trend in income inequality in the Northern and Southern Netherlands will be presented, and a regression analysis will attempt to account for the main determinants of inequality levels. In section 4, I move on to interpretations in light of the main historical theories of inequality, considering the role of capital, relative factor prices, factor endowments, and political economy. 2. Objectives and methodology 2.1 The Low Countries as a case study The current paper aims to add to the available evidence on inequality for the pre-industrial period by examining the distribution of the (rental) value of houses in seven towns in the Southern Low Countries ( Belgium ), and published data on eight other towns in the Northern Low Countries ( the Netherlands ) during the late medieval, early modern, and modern periods. In doing so, it hopes to provide more depth to the sketchy picture of inequality developments in the preindustrial period in particular by contrasting the trends in inequality in two separate regions with divergent economic trajectories throughout most of this era. In fact, as one of the areas in Europe with the highest levels of economic performance and urbanization, yet with large regional contrasts within its boundaries, the Low Countries offer an ideal test case for exploring the relationship between economic development and inequality (Van Bavel 2010; Gelderblom and Jonker 2014). During the high middle ages the core of the area s (urban) economic development was situated in the Southern provinces, particularly in the centers of urban textile (woollens) production such as Ghent, and in the main commercial hub for long-distance trade: Bruges (Murray 2005; Blockmans 2010). Around the end of the fifteenth century, political strife and geographic vagaries relocated the dominant commercial (and to a lesser extent industrial) activities northwards toward Antwerp and its surroundings. During the first half of the sixteenth century, Antwerp would become the principal hub for trade in North-Western Europe, serving as a staple market for English textiles and Portuguese spices, but also stimulating industrial production within its own walls and hinterlands (Van Der Wee 1963). The Dutch Revolt would bring an end to this. After the closure of Antwerp s sea port on the Scheldt, following the Spanish repossession of the city in 1585 during the Eighty-Year War, the focal point of international trade routes would shift northwards again, this time to the Maritime Dutch provinces in the North, and Amsterdam in particular. From then on, the Northern and Southern Low Countries would become divided in terms of religion, politics, and state, but also with regard to commerce and economic fate (map 1).

4 4 European Review of Economic History Map 1. The Low Countries in the early modern period. Note: The white area represents the Low Countries; the horizontal dark gray line in the middle represents the border between the Northern and Southern Netherlands (end of sixteenth century); the borders of the three principal provinces (to which the case studies presented here pertain) are shown in lighter gray; and the black dots show the locations of the cities used as case studies in this article. From the end of the sixteenth century onward, a pronounced contrast in the economic fortunes of the Northern and Southern Low Countries emerged. Whereas in the latter region the weight of rural proto-industry (linen) grew, and urban production figures slowly dwindled, the towns in the North were bolstered by the human and physical capital of wealthy migrants from the south and became increasingly connected to new avenues of international trade and textile industry (De Vries and Van Der Woude 1997). Less than two centuries later, economic fortunes would reverse again for both regions. During the eighteenth century, the economy in the Northern Low Countries would increasingly stagnate at a high level of living standard and remain relatively unchanged until its late industrialization around the end of the nineteenth century (Mokyr 1976). Yet in the Southern Low Countries, a new phase of rapid demographic growth (from the middle of the eighteenth century) went hand-in-hand with commercial expansion, retail growth, and modest forms of labor concentration in the form of nonmechanized

5 Economic inequality and growth before the industrial revolution 5 workshops (manufactures) based on centralized wage labor (Dejongh and Segers 2001). Proper industrialization would start from the beginning of the nineteenth century in Ghent and Aalst, and approximately two or three decades later in Bruges and Kortrijk. As Flanders was among the earliest industrializing areas on the Continent, the contrast with Holland which was among the latest is again particularly clear. 2.2 Sources and methodology For the purpose of reconstructing long-term changes in the distribution of income or wealth in the pre-industrial period, two major source types have been mobilized thus far: fiscal data, and social tables. 1 The latter approach involves the reliance on contemporary estimates of the existing social classes in a given society, with estimates of their corresponding sizes and average incomes, to calculate inequality measures in pre-industrial societies (Milanovic et al. 2011; Modalsli 2011; Saito 2015). This method offers the unique advantage of providing a first glimpse at the issue of inequality for a wide range of historical societies for which wewill probably never have enough detailed information available to allow for a different sort of reconstruction. Yet, since this approach tends to have a blind spot with regard to within-group inequality and often confounds social, cultural, and political groups with economic classes, there are limits to the insights this approach can offer in this case. Fiscal sources generally allow for a more detailed reconstruction of income or wealth distributions, but come with their own set of problems. Since direct income taxes are a relatively rare find for the pre-industrial period (and when available they often cover only a limited fraction of the population), such sources do not often allow for a sufficiently long-term reconstruction of changes over time. Information on wealth holdings, on the other hand, is easier to come by in some European regions, especially in the South (for instance Herlihy and Klapisch-Zuber 1985; Alfani 2010), but has so far proven relatively sketchy for the Low Countries (Zuijderduijn and De Moor 2012). As a result, many scholars have found it difficult to draw out long-term trends in inequality based on such disparate and often unique sources. The present article aims to overcome this problem by turning to a less ideal but more widely available and more easily comparable alternative to direct income tax records: fiscal sources detailing the (rental) value of houses. In what follows, the surviving unique and noncomparable fiscal sources will be deliberately ignored (however promising some of those might be), in order to focus upon a single consistent source type. Based on the assumption that the distribution of the value of the houses inhabited by a community s household indirectly reflects the distribution of its incomes. The crucial advantage of using these sources is that they allow for the collection of data that is (1) diachronically comparable over long stretches of time, while keeping the spatial unit of analysis constant, and (2) easily comparable from one place to the other. Throughout the late medieval and early modern period, as well as during much of the nineteenth century, the estimated value of houses was commonly used as a basis for personal taxation in cities and thus explicitly taken as an external reflection of status and income. Today, economic historians argue that housing consumption is closely tied to permanent income, based on the assumption that the income elasticity of demand for housing is not only close to one, but also fixed through time (the issue was discussed at length by Williamson 1985, and Feinstein 1988; 1 Alternatives have occasionally been used as well, such as probate inventories (Ryckbosch 2010; Overton forthcoming), worth statements by witnesses (Shepard and Spicksley 2010), aggregate consumption patterns (Segers 2001), and body length (Depauw 2012).

6 6 European Review of Economic History Hoffman et al. 2002; Hanus 2013). 2 Depending on the methodology and definition of income used, studies of different places across the world find that the income elasticity of homes usually lays between 0.4 and 0.6 (De Leeuw 1971; Garliner 1973; Hansen et al. 1996; Fernández-Kranz and Hon 2006; Chen and Minzhou 2014). The elasticity tends to be slightly higher in the case of permanent income that is, a measure of average income over a longer period of several years. The fact that the elasticity is significantly different from unity implies that Engel effects generally cause the proportion of the budget spent on housing to decline with income, so that measures of inequality based on the original distribution of housing values will seriously underestimate the inequality level. However, since there is no reason to assume that this elasticity changed over time, this does not diminish the value of the sources for the reconstruction of historical changes from one housing value distribution to the other. To get a glimpse of what actual permanent income inequality might have looked like, the housing value distributions have been converted to permanent income distributions. For this calculation, an elasticityof wasassumed. 3 Theformulaused toconvertthe housingdistributions to permanent income distributions then reads (Y is income, and H is the value of the home) ln H = a(ln Y)+b(other factors)+e, where H = the value of the home, Y = income, a = 0.6; and the error term e approaches zero for large aggregators. Some caveats present themselves when using these sources to study changes in income distribution over time. First, changes in the structure of the housing market itself could have an autonomous impact on the level of inequality reflected in measurements based on the housing values, without accurately reflecting changes in the income distribution. Periods of higher demographic pressure in the lower regions of the house value distribution, for instance, could boost prices at the bottom of the housing market independent of any concomitant changes in (permanent) incomes (Hanus 2010). Since neither the amplitude nor the direction of this effect can be reliably predicted, there is no straightforward way to compensate for this effect. It can nevertheless be assumed that in the long run such temporary distortions were offset by a reshuffling of the market until supply and demand reached a new equilibrium, and again accurately reflected proportionate income levels. A second caveat when tracing long-term patterns in inequality over time by using housing values is the fact that information is available only for (heads of) households, and not for individual family members. Economic historians have recently drawn attention to the effect of different household sizes on the habitual measurements of income or wealth inequality (Hanus 2013). Since most sources providing information on socioeconomic inequality take the household as their basic unit of analysis, the results are only valid in so far as inter-household inequality is the measure in which we are most interested. If, however, historical household sizes differ according to socioeconomic position, this implies that the inequality measures will be biased if one is really interested in inequality at the individual (or adult equivalent) level. And if, furthermore, demographic changes over time affected this bias differentially, the results of comparisons over time and space might be distorted as well. A comparison between census data and the rental 2 For cities in the Low Countries, Hanus (2010) and (2013) tested the relationship between taxed house rents and income in the sixteenth century (and arrived at some important qualifications, considered in the next paragraph), while Ryckbosch (2012) tested the association between housing value and wealth in the eighteenth century. 3 For s-hertogenbosch in the sixteenth century Jord Hanus found an income elasticity of (Hanus 2013), while the nonreal estate wealth elasticity of housing for eighteenth century Aalst was (Ryckbosch 2012). In line with modern estimates, and in search for a measure of permanent income, I have settled upon as an appropriate elasticity here. Calculations with alternative elasticity assumptions are available from the author upon request.

7 Economic inequality and growth before the industrial revolution 7 values of houses for one particular eighteenth-century Netherlandish town with a fortunate archival situation (Nivelles) confirms the existence of this bias, but also reveals that any changes through time were most likely offset by the growing tendency of families to share housing facilities, so that the total number of individuals per taxed house remained more or less constant. For these reasons, the housing taxes available do not appear to be precisely ideal, but are by and large suitable for tracing changes in income inequality through time. A total of forty-four fiscal records of housing valuations from Flanders and Brabant (Southern Low Countries) have been gathered for the purpose of this study (Supplementary material, Appendix A). Taken together, these forty-four communities represented 50 percent of the total urban population of the Southern Low Countries in 1500 (De Vries 1984). Each of these records details nearly all dwellings within the town to which it pertains, including both rental and owneroccupied homes. Within the urban fiscal context of the Low Countries, tax exemptions were generally rare and only applied frequently to the real estate occupied by the regular clergy, and until the seventeenth century some of the dwellings inhabited by the higher aristocracy (Janssens 2012). 4 The composition of the (proto-)cadastral ledgers indicates that officials (usually clerks and land surveyors) noted each house they encountered, including those that were vacant or exempt from taxes. This implies that also the homes of the poor were included in these sources, even if they were not able to actually pay the tax on the rental value of their home. Therefore, the truncation at the bottom is very limited. The only notable exception pertains to boarders and sub-renters. Such small households which could be of varying socioeconomic status but generally included a larger number of single and poor persons were usually not included in the fiscal records. On top of the forty-four new fiscal distributions for the Southern Low Countries, the inequality measures and summary statistics from fifteen additional housing value distributions from the Northern Low Countries (Van den Berg and Van Zanden 1993; Soltow and Van Zanden 1998) have been included in the analysis for the purpose of comparison. The rental values of houses recorded in the (proto-)cadastral surveys, and the income distributions derived from those, have been used to reconstruct approximate household distributions of income. Because of its widespread use, its straightforward interpretability, and its sensitivity to changes around the distribution s modus, the Gini coefficient has been chosen as the main tool for inequality measurement (Champernowne 1974; Allison 1978; Cowell 2000). The Gini coefficient essentially attempts to summarize a Lorenz curve (plotting cumulative shares of population and income) and can thus be written in terms of relative mean difference. For an ordered population, this will be: n i=1 G = (2i n 1)x i. n 2 m The Gini index varies between 0 and 1, where the former denotes complete equality, and the latter complete inequality. For the purpose of adding comparative depth to what follows, it might be useful to note that the average Gini coefficient of OECD countries in 2011 was The use of an alternative statistic from the Entropy family of inequality, such as the Theil coefficient, does not alter the main findings, but the results are included in the Supplementary material, Appendix. 4 Such exemptions for clergy and noblemen pertained only to their primary houses of residence and not to the real estate they leased out.

8 8 European Review of Economic History Figure 1. Income inequality in the Southern Low Countries (Gini). Source: see Supplementary material, Appendix A. Figure 2. Income inequality in the Southern Low Countries (Top 5 percent share). Source: see Supplementary material, Appendix A. 3. Results: a U-curve of inequality (fourteenth to nineteenth centuries) As a first step toward the analysis of the results, figures 1 and 2 present the levels of (estimated) income inequality in the cities of the Southern Low Countries included in this study. Whether

9 Economic inequality and growth before the industrial revolution 9 one looks at the Gini coefficient or at the share in income flowing to the top 5 percent of urban society, the pattern is roughly the same. Between 1400 and 1900 inequality followed what could be described as a skewed U-curve. Since the data points for the fourteenth and fifteenth centuries are few, the downswing in inequality prior to the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries is difficult to attest with much certainty. However, the subsequent upswing in inequality is clear enough: almost everywhere inequality was much higher at the end of the nineteenth century than it had been at any point in time since the late Middle Ages. Moreover, this high degree of nineteenth-century inequality was not the result of the industrial revolution, since it wasalready well under way for at least half a century prior to its take-off. This rise spanned periods of urban commercial growth (c c. 1650; c c. 1850) as well as of decline (c c. 1600; c c. 1750). This suggests not only that inequality was not straightforwardly connected to the industrialization process, but also that its association with economic growth appears to be rather ambiguous (a similar conclusion was reached in Alfani 2010; Alfani and Ammannati 2014). The general pattern is the same whether one considers the Gini coefficient or the income share flowing to the top 5 percent of the distribution: both measures suggest that the gaps between rich and poor grew wider during the early modern period, regardless of the specific method of summarizing the distribution. In order to further explore these results, their interpretation has been divided into three parts. In the first segment, a simple Ordinary Least Squares (OLS) regression is introduced in order to study some of the main determinants affecting income inequality in this dataset. In the second section, I compare the experience of the Northern and Southern Low Countries during the early modern period in order to explore the relationship between growth and inequality. In the final part, I examine alternative factors that could explain changes in inequality in the Low Countries over time. 4. Interpretations 4.1 General determinants: regression analysis In order to gain a first indication of the determinants of pre-industrial urban inequality in the Low Countries, the Gini coefficients for the Southern Low Countries ( Belgium ) presented above can be compared with the Gini coefficients for the Northern Low Countries ( the Netherlands )published by Jan Luiten van Zanden. As mentioned above, both regions set out on very different paths of economic development from the 1580s onward: while the North embarked upon the success story of the Dutch Republic and its first modern economy, long stagnation until the middle of the eighteenth century hit the South. Nevertheless, for the sixteenth until the eighteenth centuries, a period for which we have overlapping data from both regions, the trend of rising inequality appears to be similar. Not only the trend, but also the absolute level of inequality in the Northern Low Countries remains broadly comparable to that in the Southern Low Countries (figure 3). Even in the seventeenth century, during the heyday of Holland s economic miracle, the level of inequality in towns such as Leiden and Alkmaar did not greatly surpass that in Aalst (a Flemish town of comparable size). Only the high degree of inequality in Amsterdam appears as an outlier, which is easily attributable to the much greater size of its urban population. A more elaborate analysis of the determinants of inequality in the early modern Low Countries can be undertaken by means of an OLS regression on the Gini coefficient (table 1). The Gini coefficients from towns in both the Northern and Southern Low Countries are taken as the dependent

10 10 European Review of Economic History Figure 3. Housing inequality in the Northern and Southern Low Countries compared (fourteenth to nineteenth centuries). Sources: Supplementary material, Appendix A; Van den Berg and Van Zanden (1993); and Soltow and Van Zanden (1998). Note: The towns in the Southern Low Countries are shown in gray, those in the Northern Low Countries in black. variable in the model. Since most variables commonly invoked in modern econometric studies of inequality are not readily available for the pre-industrial era, some perhaps rather rough proxies have been included here as independent variables instead. Population size and relative population change could be derived thanks to the data collected by Jan De Vries and Paul Bairoch (De Vries 1984; Bairoch et al. 1988) and was complemented by more detailed local studies (see Supplementary material, Appendix C). Population change, in this case, refers to the relative growth of the city s population size during the previous fifty years. Testing for the influence of economic growth and the development of living standards is considerably more difficult since GDP per capita and real wage estimations are not generally available at the local level for all the towns under scrutiny. Instead of using Angus Maddison s regional GDP per capita estimates (Bolt and Van Zanden 2014), I have opted for an alternative proxy for economic development: the deflated average (rental) value of houses. Since several studies have demonstrated how the development of housing rents in the pre-industrial Low Countries accurately reflects economic performance, this can be considered a relatively reliable proxy for per capita economic performance (Van Ryssel 1967; Soly 1974). Real wages are more difficulttoobtainforeachofthe casestudies, since that wouldrequire price and wage series for all of the towns. However, a comparison of the available wage and grain price series for most of the towns studied here indicates that prices and wages tended to co-vary from place to place (price and wage data in Verlinden and Scholliers 1973). That is to say: where wages were lower (for instance in Aalst and Kortrijk, when compared with Ghent or Antwerp),

11 Table 1. Results from OLS regressions on the Gini coefficient in urban case studies of the Low Countries (fifteenth to nineteenth centuries) a A B C b (std error) β b (std error) β B (std error) β Population size (Ln) 4.00 (0.73) 0.59*** 1.52 (0.91) (0.88) 0.41*** Population change 0.02 (0.14) (0.15) 0.02 Average house value (Ln) 4.06 (1.07) 0.49*** Real wage (Ln) 6.84 (3.64) 0.24* Northern Low Countries (dummy) 1.70 (1.62) (1.42) 0.02 Port city (dummy) 3.22 (1.92) 0.20* 2.24 (2.13) 0.14 Capital function (dummy) 6.31 (2.47) 0.31** 5.96 (2.76) 0.30** Golden age (dummy) 0.67 (2.05) (2.19) 0.15 Industrial (dummy) 3.92 (1.88) 0.26** 4.90 (1.99) 0.32** F 29.89*** 4.02*** 6.70*** R N Sources: see Supplementary material, Appendices A and C. a The same analysis has been undertaken with the delta values for population size and the Gini coefficient for each case study, with essentially the same results as those presented here. Results are from an OLS regression with the Gini coefficient per town as the dependent variable. Standard assumptions appropriate to OLS regression have avoided rejection: there is no clear problematic multicollinearity (average variance inflation factor (VIF) = 1.87; max. VIF = 2.22); the assumption of serially independent errors is not rejected (Durbin Watson = 1.508); and the residuals could be normally distributed, without heteroscedasticity. *p < 0.1,**p < 0.05, ***p < Economic inequality and growth before the industrial revolution 11

12 12 European Review of Economic History grain prices were usually lower to a similar degree (a similar remark in Van Zanden 1999). Therefore, the real wage indices for the Northern and Southern Low Countries constructed by Robert Allen, and based on price and wage data from Amsterdam, and Bruges, Ghent, and Antwerp (respectively) can serve as an acceptable proxy. 5 Unfortunately, this means that the real wage variable only reflects the general level and trend in each region, not the real wage in each individual city separately. Dummyvariables havebeenadded tolook at theeffect ofthelocal characteristicsofacasestudy: whether the town was located in the Northern Low Countries, and whether it was a maritime port city, or a capital city. Two additional dummy variables were entered to single out effects related to timing: (1)a golden age variable, which traces the center of international economic performance within the Low Countries moving from Flanders in the fourteenth century, to Brabant in the sixteenth, and Holland in the seventeenth century, and (2) an industrial dummy which indicates whether a town s industrial production is undergoing, or already underwent, mechanization based on the local economic historiography for each of the cases in point. A more detailed description of all the variables used can be found in the Supplementary material, Appendix. What are the main interpretations to be derived from this analysis? Although population size appears to be a strong predictor of urban inequality levels (model A), the effect can at least partially be explained by a range of related variables (model B). Nevertheless, larger cities tend to have higher levels of inequality. A more diverse economic structure, but also higher levels of immigration needed to sustain larger urban population sizes (in the context of low or negative urban natural demographic growth) seem likely candidates to explain this effect. Since the towns under scrutiny generally tended to grow through time and especially during the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries this in itself partially helps to explain the growing inequality pattern established earlier. Even though population size is a rather strong predictor of inequality in this model, the addition of a number of other independent variables nevertheless significantly improves the explanatory value of the model. Population change, which serves as a proxy for migration, does not turn out to be significant. In contrast, both the average value of houses in a town (which serves as a proxy for income per capita) and the real wage level are significant and produce relatively strong positive and negative effects, respectively. This finding offers support for Van Zanden s theory of a super Kuznets curve in the early modern Low Countries: towns with higher level of economic performance also experienced sharper inequality. At the same time, the fact that lower wages tend to contribute to higher inequality levels perhaps helps to explain why studies are increasingly finding pre-industrial rises in inequality throughout Europe even in the absence of economic growth. Alternatively, the real wage and average house value variables might be interpreted not as independent variables explaining inequality, but rather as alternative forms of (specific) aspects of the outcome inequality itself. Therefore, regression equation C presents an alternative model in which both variables have been left out. This model exclusively considers the strength of the independent variables of a prior causative nature: location in the Southern or Northern Low Countries, maritime and capital economic functions, spells of pre-industrial economic efflorescence, and industrialization. 5 The index can be found on the website of the International Institute of Social History ( php).

13 Economic inequality and growth before the industrial revolution 13 Strikingly, the dummy variable for the Northern Low Countries does not turn up as significant in the regression in either model B or C. This indicates that there were no large differences in urban inequality levels between North and South, even after the Revolt, when controlling for economic growth and real wages. A similar conclusion has to be drawn for the golden age dummy, which looks for the effect of the shifting location of economic gravity from late medieval Flanders, to sixteenth-century Brabant, and seventeenth-century Holland. Taken together, these times and places did not experience significantly higher levels of inequality (when controlling for the other independent variables). Interpreted in another way, this confirms what was also suggested by figure 3: inequality was not significantly lower in the Southern Low Countries after the Dutch Revolt than it had been before, or than it became afterward in the North. The presence of a maritime port function seems to have had a slightly depressing effect upon local inequality levels, although this effect is no longer significant in model C. At the very least this indicates that international trade did not exert a direct positive influence on inequality. In contrast, if a town carried the administrative or political functions of a capital city, that tended to increase the local level of inequality. This suggests that political factors had an important role to play, in both direct and indirect ways. Lastly, the dummy variable for industrialization is significant and points to a positive effect. Thus, over and above the influence of economic growth, the mechanization of industry during the nineteenth century went hand in hand with deepening inequality. 4.2 Discussion of the results The comparison between the Northern and Southern Netherlands and the results from the regression analysis suggest that largely similar dynamics characterized the relationship between economic development and inequality in the Low Countries before and after the Dutch Revolt. This is noteworthy, since the exceptional modern and merchant capitalist economic efflorescence formerly invoked to explain the growth of inequality cannot account for the consistently high levels of inequality in the early modern Southern Low Countries. Therefore, the relative lack of economic growth in the South poses the question: what explanatory variables must be invoked to explain the similarity in the path of inequality to the Northern Low Countries? 6 In the remainder of this article, I will focus on the potential causal factors underlying the U-curve of inequality observed in the Southern Low Countries. Two main explanatory factors will be considered in more detail: (1) the respective roles of labor and capital in preindustrial economic development, and (2) the role of institutions. In looking to explain long-term patterns of inequality, economists and economic historians have recently begun to re-emphasize the causal elements that figured prominently in the classical theories of inequality. This means that much attention is again paid to the functional distribution of income, which is the distribution of income shares flowing to each of the factors of production within an economy, i.e., labor, capital, and land. 7 Those functional income shares are determined by both the relative price of the factors of production and their distribution across the population. Recently, Piketty has argued that the growth of inequality today, and 6 It is worth reminding the reader here that according to Van Zanden (1995) the rise in inequality in Holland was overexplained. 7 It is considered a classical approach to inequality, as the classical economists stressed the division of income between production factors, see for instance Adam Smith s factor price model, David Ricardo s theory of distribution, and Karl Marx s laws of capitalist accumulation.

14 14 European Review of Economic History Figure 4. The ratio of real wage to GDP per capita in the Southern Low Countries. Sources: Bolt and van Zanden (2014). Robert C. Allen, Consumer price indices, and real wages of building craftsmen and labourers, ( People/sites/Allen/SitePages/Biography.aspx) Note: The real wage is the wage of a skilled building laborer (mason). the high levels of inequality before the twentieth century, can be explained by the fact that in the long term, the price of capital tends to be higher than the price of labor. As a result, the return to capital will be higher than the growth of the economy as a whole, which Piketty summarized as r > g (Piketty 2013; Piketty and Zucman 2014). The argument is not entirely dissimilar to the one put forward by Van Zanden for the pre-industrial period, since he argued that the primary cause for the growth of inequality in the early modern Northern Low Countries was the discrepancy between the falling factor price of labor (i.e., declining real wages) and the rising price of capital during the rise of Dutch merchant capitalism (Van Zanden 1995; Soltow and Van Zanden 1998). Yet not only the respective prices of capital and labor matter, so also do their distribution across the population. This is the question of initial factor endowments : who owned capital, and who had only their labor to sell? For the classical economists factor endowments presented themselves as external to the laws of economic growth, as determined by historical processes of political or otherwise extra-economic developments. 8 Although not generally considered a part of mainstream economic history today, several social historians have argued how a process of proletarianization caused growing levels of economic insecurity, poverty, and inequality among large strands of the European population during the early modern period (Friedrichs 1975; Lis and Soly 1979; Wrightson and Levine 1979; Tilly 1984; Van Bavel 2010). Unfortunately, by neglecting the question of how these changes in the functional 8 Most influentially, for instance, Marx saw initial factor endowments as the result of the gradual dispossession of the working class from their means of production through diverse political processes (most famously the English enclosures ).

15 Economic inequality and growth before the industrial revolution 15 distribution of income influenced the personal distribution of income, this historiography has largely failed to connect to the findings of economic historians of the nineteenth and twentieth centuries. Can the arguments about factor prices and factor endowments be invoked for the case of the Southern Low Countries where, contrary to early modern England and the Northern Low Countries, economic growth was very slow, if not nonexistent before the end of the eighteenth century? Figure 4 shows the ratio of the real wage to GDP per capita in the Low Countries from the sixteenth to the end of the nineteenth century. At the beginning of the period under scrutiny, roughly the period , real wages were high relative to the GDP per capita. In fact, almost everywhere in Europe real wages were at a high point following the relative scarcity of labor resulting from the drop in population caused by the ecological and epidemiological crisis of the late Middle Ages (Allen 2001). This brought about a period of Burgundian affluence for the Flemish cities, and in particular for the urban craftsmen who experienced Das Goldene Zeitalter des Handwerks (Van Der Wee 1963; Sosson 1977; Soens and Thoen 2010). The demographic effect of the Black Death on the labor supply in the Southern Low Countries was reinforced by specific institutional arrangements. After craft guilds had gained access to urban political power around the beginning of the fourteenth century, the export-oriented (textile) industries in the Flemish cities became increasingly subject to corporatist organization and regulation (Lis and Soly 2006). The industrial structure of the region was transformed from a low-wage economy based on a high degree of labor division to a skill-intensive export industry in which the quality of labor formed the foundation of added value and economic gains (Van Der Wee 1988). Thus, the scarcity of labor relative to the stock of capital, buttressed by the emergent institutional framework of corporatism, provided for a relatively high price of labor. Moreover, since small-scale production by independent master-artisans dominated production relations, factor endowments of capital were less unequal than they had been before. The result appears to have been a decline in inequality during the fifteenth century confirmed at least by the case of Bruges, where a prolonged decline in inequality set in after the fourteenth century. Although the institutional context remained the same, this situation of relative equality would come under growing pressure as the second half of the sixteenth century proceeded, especially when price inflation and wage rigidity slowly undermined the purchasing power of urban wage laborers. Unsurprisingly, this went hand in hand with an upswing in inequality in most of the towns surveyed here. What caused this gradual fall of real wages relative to GDP per capita? Spreading out from the smaller towns and the countryside from the sixteenth century onward, the production of coarser, standardized textiles destined for domestic and overseas markets gained the upper hand (Van Der Wee 1988). With the decline of the urban luxury trades came the waning social and political power of the corporatist system (Friedrichs 1975; De Munck 2011). The use of putting-out systems became increasingly common, for instance in the growing sector of urban lace production where merchant-entrepreneurs employed growing numbers of women and children at low wages (Soly 1988). This economic reconversion from a high-wage luxury producer and fashion-maker to a low-cost manufacturer of export commodities did not only bring about a declining income share of labor as opposed to capital. Dependency relations also deepened, as putting-out and subcontracting networks controlled by merchant-entrepreneurs and artisan-entrepreneurs expanded. The largest industrial export-industries became less based on the corporatist sector of production, its regulations and its political power. This wider tendency toward capital concentration is exemplified by a similar trend toward concentration in the urban real estate market. For all case studies for which we have indications of home ownership during the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries, it was clearly in

16 16 European Review of Economic History Figure 5. The share of rental houses per town, Southern Netherlands, Sources: see Supplementary material, Appendix A. decline (figure 5). By the end of the seventeenth century, the proportion of rental houses was almost nowhere lower than 50 percent of all dwellings, and in Mechelen, Ghent, or Bruges even higher than 65 percent. These trends toward capital concentration in both industry and real estate help explain why economic decline during the second half of the seventeenth and the beginning of the eighteenth centuries corresponded to deepening levels of economic inequality. Political institutions further reinforced these tendencies. The Habsburg central state implemented a fiscal system that was mostly aimed at pacification and preservation of the status quo: existing fiscal prerogatives were maintained, while the bulk of the burden was carried by regressive consumption taxes (Janssens 2012). Since the tax burden increased significantly during the eighteenth century, its regressive character probably contributed to the further growth of inequality (Van Isterdael 1983). During the final period considered here, roughly from 1750 to 1900, the industries of the Southern Low Countries became rapidly mechanized. In the urban sector, as on the countryside, tendencies toward proletarianization were increasingly clear from at least the middle of the eighteenth century onward (Lottin and Soly 1983; Soly 1988; Lis and Soly 1997). The influx of an evergrowing number of wage-dependent laborers, along with the abolishment of the guild system (in 1795) again eroded the wage GDP per capita ratio. Subcontracting networks enabled considerable capital concentration in the hands of small numbers of artisan-entrepreneurs, while it reduced large numbers of urban artisans to de facto wage laborers (Lis and Soly 2008). Such organizational restructuring lay at the heart of the expanding textile industries, where the manufacture of mixed linen and cotton fabrics, cotton spinning, and printing reached new heights of industrial productivity (Sabbe 1945). By the last quarter of the eighteenth century, most towns counted several manufactures where large volumes of wage labor in textiles, tobacco processing, and sugar refining were concentrated in the hands of a small number of entrepreneurs (Coppejans-Desmedt 1952; Moureaux 1974; Ryckbosch 2012).

Inequality and Economic History

Inequality and Economic History Inequality and Economic History EINITE ERC Starting Grant Guido Alfani DONDENA Centre for Research on Social Dynamics Bocconi University, Milan, Italy The story so far Up until recently, we had very little

More information

Inequality and economic growth

Inequality and economic growth Introduction One of us is a theorist, and one of us is an historian, but both of us are economists interested in modern debates about technical change, convergence, globalization, and inequality. The central

More information

GLOBALISATION AND WAGE INEQUALITIES,

GLOBALISATION AND WAGE INEQUALITIES, GLOBALISATION AND WAGE INEQUALITIES, 1870 1970 IDS WORKING PAPER 73 Edward Anderson SUMMARY This paper studies the impact of globalisation on wage inequality in eight now-developed countries during the

More information

There is a seemingly widespread view that inequality should not be a concern

There is a seemingly widespread view that inequality should not be a concern Chapter 11 Economic Growth and Poverty Reduction: Do Poor Countries Need to Worry about Inequality? Martin Ravallion There is a seemingly widespread view that inequality should not be a concern in countries

More information

A poverty-inequality trade off?

A poverty-inequality trade off? Journal of Economic Inequality (2005) 3: 169 181 Springer 2005 DOI: 10.1007/s10888-005-0091-1 Forum essay A poverty-inequality trade off? MARTIN RAVALLION Development Research Group, World Bank (Accepted:

More information

Edexcel (A) Economics A-level

Edexcel (A) Economics A-level Edexcel (A) Economics A-level Theme 4: A Global Perspective 4.2 Poverty and Inequality 4.2.2 Inequality Notes Distinction between wealth and income inequality Wealth is defined as a stock of assets, such

More information

Rising inequality in China

Rising inequality in China Page 1 of 6 Date:03/01/2006 URL: http://www.thehindubusinessline.com/2006/01/03/stories/2006010300981100.htm Rising inequality in China C. P. Chandrasekhar Jayati Ghosh Spectacular economic growth in China

More information

Volume Publisher: University of Chicago Press. Volume URL: Chapter URL:

Volume Publisher: University of Chicago Press. Volume URL:  Chapter URL: This PDF is a selection from an out-of-print volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: Wages and Labor Markets in the United States, 1820-1860 Volume Author/Editor: Robert A. Margo

More information

Volume 35, Issue 1. An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach

Volume 35, Issue 1. An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach Volume 35, Issue 1 An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach Brian Hibbs Indiana University South Bend Gihoon Hong Indiana University South Bend Abstract This

More information

Mexico: How to Tap Progress. Remarks by. Manuel Sánchez. Member of the Governing Board of the Bank of Mexico. at the. Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas

Mexico: How to Tap Progress. Remarks by. Manuel Sánchez. Member of the Governing Board of the Bank of Mexico. at the. Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas Mexico: How to Tap Progress Remarks by Manuel Sánchez Member of the Governing Board of the Bank of Mexico at the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas Houston, TX November 1, 2012 I feel privileged to be with

More information

vi. rising InequalIty with high growth and falling Poverty

vi. rising InequalIty with high growth and falling Poverty 43 vi. rising InequalIty with high growth and falling Poverty Inequality is on the rise in several countries in East Asia, most notably in China. The good news is that poverty declined rapidly at the same

More information

Urban Real Wages in Constantinople-Istanbul,

Urban Real Wages in Constantinople-Istanbul, Urban Real Wages in Constantinople-Istanbul,1100-2000 (and more generally around the Eastern Mediterranean) paper presented to the Conference Towards a Global History of Prices and Wages Utrecht, 19-21

More information

Globalization and Inequality : a brief review of facts and arguments

Globalization and Inequality : a brief review of facts and arguments Globalization and Inequality : a brief review of facts and arguments François Bourguignon Paris School of Economics LIS Lecture, July 2018 1 The globalization/inequality debate and recent political surprises

More information

Part 1: Focus on Income. Inequality. EMBARGOED until 5/28/14. indicator definitions and Rankings

Part 1: Focus on Income. Inequality. EMBARGOED until 5/28/14. indicator definitions and Rankings Part 1: Focus on Income indicator definitions and Rankings Inequality STATE OF NEW YORK CITY S HOUSING & NEIGHBORHOODS IN 2013 7 Focus on Income Inequality New York City has seen rising levels of income

More information

Thomas Piketty Capital in the 21st Century

Thomas Piketty Capital in the 21st Century Thomas Piketty Capital in the 21st Century Excerpts: Introduction p.20-27! The Major Results of This Study What are the major conclusions to which these novel historical sources have led me? The first

More information

AQA Economics A-level

AQA Economics A-level AQA Economics A-level Microeconomics Topic 7: Distribution of Income and Wealth, Poverty and Inequality 7.1 The distribution of income and wealth Notes Distinction between wealth and income inequality

More information

and with support from BRIEFING NOTE 1

and with support from BRIEFING NOTE 1 and with support from BRIEFING NOTE 1 Inequality and growth: the contrasting stories of Brazil and India Concern with inequality used to be confined to the political left, but today it has spread to a

More information

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr Abstract. The Asian experience of poverty reduction has varied widely. Over recent decades the economies of East and Southeast Asia

More information

Rewriting the Rules of the Market Economy to Achieve Shared Prosperity. Joseph E. Stiglitz New York June 2016

Rewriting the Rules of the Market Economy to Achieve Shared Prosperity. Joseph E. Stiglitz New York June 2016 Rewriting the Rules of the Market Economy to Achieve Shared Prosperity Joseph E. Stiglitz New York June 2016 Enormous growth in inequality Especially in US, and countries that have followed US model Multiple

More information

Spatial Inequality in Cameroon during the Period

Spatial Inequality in Cameroon during the Period AERC COLLABORATIVE RESEARCH ON GROWTH AND POVERTY REDUCTION Spatial Inequality in Cameroon during the 1996-2007 Period POLICY BRIEF English Version April, 2012 Samuel Fambon Isaac Tamba FSEG University

More information

Trends in inequality worldwide (Gini coefficients)

Trends in inequality worldwide (Gini coefficients) Section 2 Impact of trade on income inequality As described above, it has been theoretically and empirically proved that the progress of globalization as represented by trade brings benefits in the form

More information

Rural and Urban Migrants in India:

Rural and Urban Migrants in India: Rural and Urban Migrants in India: 1983 2008 Viktoria Hnatkovska and Amartya Lahiri This paper characterizes the gross and net migration flows between rural and urban areas in India during the period 1983

More information

Towards an explanation of inequality in pre-modern societies: the role of colonies, urbanization and high population density

Towards an explanation of inequality in pre-modern societies: the role of colonies, urbanization and high population density Towards an explanation of inequality in pre-modern societies: the role of colonies, urbanization and high population density Branko Milanovic Groningen, 28 June 2017 Limited knowledge of pre-industrial

More information

POPULATION STUDIES RESEARCH BRIEF ISSUE Number

POPULATION STUDIES RESEARCH BRIEF ISSUE Number POPULATION STUDIES RESEARCH BRIEF ISSUE Number 2008021 School for Social and Policy Research 2008 Population Studies Group School for Social and Policy Research Charles Darwin University Northern Territory

More information

Violent Conflict and Inequality

Violent Conflict and Inequality Violent Conflict and Inequality work in progress Cagatay Bircan University of Michigan Tilman Brück DIW Berlin, Humboldt University Berlin, IZA and Households in Conflict Network Marc Vothknecht DIW Berlin

More information

Labour Market Reform, Rural Migration and Income Inequality in China -- A Dynamic General Equilibrium Analysis

Labour Market Reform, Rural Migration and Income Inequality in China -- A Dynamic General Equilibrium Analysis Labour Market Reform, Rural Migration and Income Inequality in China -- A Dynamic General Equilibrium Analysis Yinhua Mai And Xiujian Peng Centre of Policy Studies Monash University Australia April 2011

More information

Reducing income inequality by economics growth in Georgia

Reducing income inequality by economics growth in Georgia Reducing income inequality by economics growth in Georgia Batumi Shota Rustaveli State University Faculty of Economics and Business PhD student in Economics Nino Kontselidze Abstract Nowadays Georgia has

More information

Benchmarking the Middle. Ages. XV century Tuscany. in European Perspective

Benchmarking the Middle. Ages. XV century Tuscany. in European Perspective Benchmarking the Middle Ages. XV century Tuscany in European Perspective Jan Luiten van Zanden Utrecht University Emanuele Felice Università G. D Annunzio Chieti-Pescara The Groningen Growth and Development

More information

Inequality and the Global Middle Class

Inequality and the Global Middle Class ANALYZING GLOBAL TRENDS for Business and Society Week 3 Inequality and the Global Middle Class Mauro F. Guillén Mini-Lecture 3.1 This week we will analyze recent trends in: Global inequality and poverty.

More information

THE COFFEES OF THE SECRETARY-GENERAL JAMES K. GALBRAITH

THE COFFEES OF THE SECRETARY-GENERAL JAMES K. GALBRAITH THE COFFEES OF THE SECRETARY-GENERAL JAMES K. GALBRAITH 18 June 2010 THE COFFEES OF THE SECRETARY-GENERAL Bringing New Perspectives to the OECD Secretary-General s Speech Writing and Intelligence Outreach

More information

HOW ECONOMIES GROW AND DEVELOP Macroeconomics In Context (Goodwin, et al.)

HOW ECONOMIES GROW AND DEVELOP Macroeconomics In Context (Goodwin, et al.) Chapter 17 HOW ECONOMIES GROW AND DEVELOP Macroeconomics In Context (Goodwin, et al.) Chapter Overview This chapter presents material on economic growth, such as the theory behind it, how it is calculated,

More information

China s (Uneven) Progress Against Poverty. Martin Ravallion and Shaohua Chen Development Research Group, World Bank

China s (Uneven) Progress Against Poverty. Martin Ravallion and Shaohua Chen Development Research Group, World Bank China s (Uneven) Progress Against Poverty Martin Ravallion and Shaohua Chen Development Research Group, World Bank 1 Around 1980 China had one of the highest poverty rates in the world We estimate that

More information

Labor Market Dropouts and Trends in the Wages of Black and White Men

Labor Market Dropouts and Trends in the Wages of Black and White Men Industrial & Labor Relations Review Volume 56 Number 4 Article 5 2003 Labor Market Dropouts and Trends in the Wages of Black and White Men Chinhui Juhn University of Houston Recommended Citation Juhn,

More information

THE IMPACT OF TAXES ON MIGRATION IN NEW HAMPSHIRE

THE IMPACT OF TAXES ON MIGRATION IN NEW HAMPSHIRE THE IMPACT OF TAXES ON MIGRATION IN NEW HAMPSHIRE Jeffrey Thompson Political Economy Research Institute University of Massachusetts, Amherst April 211 As New England states continue to struggle with serious

More information

Economic Reflections on The Dutch Republic and Britain, Aster Chin. Lowell High School San Francisco, CA

Economic Reflections on The Dutch Republic and Britain, Aster Chin. Lowell High School San Francisco, CA Economic Reflections on The Dutch Republic and Britain, 1500-1800 Aster Chin Lowell High School San Francisco, CA NEH Seminar 2007; The Dutch Republic and Britain: The Making of Modern Society and a European

More information

LONG RUN GROWTH, CONVERGENCE AND FACTOR PRICES

LONG RUN GROWTH, CONVERGENCE AND FACTOR PRICES LONG RUN GROWTH, CONVERGENCE AND FACTOR PRICES By Bart Verspagen* Second draft, July 1998 * Eindhoven University of Technology, Faculty of Technology Management, and MERIT, University of Maastricht. Email:

More information

In a core chapter in their book, Unequal Gains: American Growth. Journal of SUMMER Mark Thornton VOL. 21 N O

In a core chapter in their book, Unequal Gains: American Growth. Journal of SUMMER Mark Thornton VOL. 21 N O The Quarterly Journal of VOL. 21 N O. 2 158 162 SUMMER 2018 Austrian Economics The Great Leveling: A Note Mark Thornton ABSTRACT: Peter H. Lindert and Jeffrey G. Williamson, in their book Unequal Gains:

More information

ECONOMIC GROWTH* Chapt er. Key Concepts

ECONOMIC GROWTH* Chapt er. Key Concepts Chapt er 6 ECONOMIC GROWTH* Key Concepts The Basics of Economic Growth Economic growth is the expansion of production possibilities. The growth rate is the annual percentage change of a variable. The growth

More information

FOREIGN FIRMS AND INDONESIAN MANUFACTURING WAGES: AN ANALYSIS WITH PANEL DATA

FOREIGN FIRMS AND INDONESIAN MANUFACTURING WAGES: AN ANALYSIS WITH PANEL DATA FOREIGN FIRMS AND INDONESIAN MANUFACTURING WAGES: AN ANALYSIS WITH PANEL DATA by Robert E. Lipsey & Fredrik Sjöholm Working Paper 166 December 2002 Postal address: P.O. Box 6501, S-113 83 Stockholm, Sweden.

More information

5. Destination Consumption

5. Destination Consumption 5. Destination Consumption Enabling migrants propensity to consume Meiyan Wang and Cai Fang Introduction The 2014 Central Economic Working Conference emphasised that China s economy has a new normal, characterised

More information

LABOUR-MARKET INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS IN OECD-COUNTRIES: WHAT EXPLANATIONS FIT THE DATA?

LABOUR-MARKET INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS IN OECD-COUNTRIES: WHAT EXPLANATIONS FIT THE DATA? LABOUR-MARKET INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS IN OECD-COUNTRIES: WHAT EXPLANATIONS FIT THE DATA? By Andreas Bergh (PhD) Associate Professor in Economics at Lund University and the Research Institute of Industrial

More information

SHOULD THE UNITED STATES WORRY ABOUT LARGE, FAST-GROWING ECONOMIES?

SHOULD THE UNITED STATES WORRY ABOUT LARGE, FAST-GROWING ECONOMIES? Chapter Six SHOULD THE UNITED STATES WORRY ABOUT LARGE, FAST-GROWING ECONOMIES? This report represents an initial investigation into the relationship between economic growth and military expenditures for

More information

CHAPTER 2 LITERATURE REVIEWS

CHAPTER 2 LITERATURE REVIEWS CHAPTER 2 LITERATURE REVIEWS The relationship between efficiency and income equality is an old topic, but Lewis (1954) and Kuznets (1955) was the earlier literature that systemically discussed income inequality

More information

Ghana Lower-middle income Sub-Saharan Africa (developing only) Source: World Development Indicators (WDI) database.

Ghana Lower-middle income Sub-Saharan Africa (developing only) Source: World Development Indicators (WDI) database. Knowledge for Development Ghana in Brief October 215 Poverty and Equity Global Practice Overview Poverty Reduction in Ghana Progress and Challenges A tale of success Ghana has posted a strong growth performance

More information

WID.world Working Paper N 2018/4. Extreme inequality: evidence from Brazil, India, the Middle East and South Africa

WID.world Working Paper N 2018/4. Extreme inequality: evidence from Brazil, India, the Middle East and South Africa WID.world Working Paper N 2018/4 Extreme inequality: evidence from Brazil, India, the Middle East and South Africa Lydia Assouad Lucas Chancel Marc Morgan January 2018 Extreme inequality: evidence from

More information

Secondary Towns and Poverty Reduction: Refocusing the Urbanization Agenda

Secondary Towns and Poverty Reduction: Refocusing the Urbanization Agenda Secondary Towns and Poverty Reduction: Refocusing the Urbanization Agenda Luc Christiaensen (World Bank) and Ravi Kanbur (Cornell University) The Quality of Growth in Sub-Saharan Africa Workshop of JICA-IPD

More information

Dietlind Stolle 2011 Marc Hooghe. Shifting Inequalities. Patterns of Exclusion and Inclusion in Emerging Forms of Political Participation.

Dietlind Stolle 2011 Marc Hooghe. Shifting Inequalities. Patterns of Exclusion and Inclusion in Emerging Forms of Political Participation. Dietlind Stolle 2011 Marc Hooghe Shifting Inequalities. Patterns of Exclusion and Inclusion in Emerging Forms of Political Participation. European Societies, 13(1), 119-142. Taylor and Francis Journals,

More information

Income and wealth inequalities

Income and wealth inequalities Understanding the World Economy Master in Economics and Business Income and wealth inequalities Lecture 4 Nicolas Coeurdacier nicolas.coeurdacier@sciencespo.fr People care about inequalities--- the Ultimatum

More information

The transition of corruption: From poverty to honesty

The transition of corruption: From poverty to honesty February 26 th 2009 Kiel and Aarhus The transition of corruption: From poverty to honesty Erich Gundlach a, *, Martin Paldam b,1 a Kiel Institute for the World Economy, P.O. Box 4309, 24100 Kiel, Germany

More information

Research Report. How Does Trade Liberalization Affect Racial and Gender Identity in Employment? Evidence from PostApartheid South Africa

Research Report. How Does Trade Liberalization Affect Racial and Gender Identity in Employment? Evidence from PostApartheid South Africa International Affairs Program Research Report How Does Trade Liberalization Affect Racial and Gender Identity in Employment? Evidence from PostApartheid South Africa Report Prepared by Bilge Erten Assistant

More information

LECTURE 23: A SUMMARY OF CAPITAL IN THE 21 ST CENTURY

LECTURE 23: A SUMMARY OF CAPITAL IN THE 21 ST CENTURY LECTURE 23: A SUMMARY OF CAPITAL IN THE 21 ST CENTURY Dr. Aidan Regan Email: aidan.regan@ucd.ie Website: www.aidanregan.com Teaching blog: www.capitalistdemocracy.wordpress.com Twitter: @aidan_regan #CapitalUCD

More information

Rural and Urban Migrants in India:

Rural and Urban Migrants in India: Rural and Urban Migrants in India: 1983-2008 Viktoria Hnatkovska and Amartya Lahiri July 2014 Abstract This paper characterizes the gross and net migration flows between rural and urban areas in India

More information

Regional Income Trends and Convergence

Regional Income Trends and Convergence Regional Income Trends and Convergence J. Fred Giertz and Shekhar Mehta Institute of Government and Public Affairs University of Illinois February 13, 1996.... This paper is one of a series associated

More information

REPORT. Highly Skilled Migration to the UK : Policy Changes, Financial Crises and a Possible Balloon Effect?

REPORT. Highly Skilled Migration to the UK : Policy Changes, Financial Crises and a Possible Balloon Effect? Report based on research undertaken for the Financial Times by the Migration Observatory REPORT Highly Skilled Migration to the UK 2007-2013: Policy Changes, Financial Crises and a Possible Balloon Effect?

More information

REEXAMINING THE DISTRIBUTION OF WEALTH IN 1870

REEXAMINING THE DISTRIBUTION OF WEALTH IN 1870 THE UNIVERSITY OF KANSAS WORKING PAPERS SERIES IN THEORETICAL AND APPLIED ECONOMICS REEXAMINING THE DISTRIBUTION OF WEALTH IN 1870 Joshua L. Rosenbloom Department of Economics and Policy Research Institute,

More information

Pro-Poor Growth and the Poorest

Pro-Poor Growth and the Poorest Background Paper for the Chronic Poverty Report 2008-09 Pro-Poor Growth and the Poorest What is Chronic Poverty? The distinguishing feature of chronic poverty is extended duration in absolute poverty.

More information

Southern Africa Labour and Development Research Unit

Southern Africa Labour and Development Research Unit Southern Africa Labour and Development Research Unit Drivers of Inequality in South Africa by Janina Hundenborn, Murray Leibbrandt and Ingrid Woolard SALDRU Working Paper Number 194 NIDS Discussion Paper

More information

Differences Lead to Differences: Diversity and Income Inequality Across Countries

Differences Lead to Differences: Diversity and Income Inequality Across Countries Illinois State University ISU ReD: Research and edata Master's Theses - Economics Economics 6-2008 Differences Lead to Differences: Diversity and Income Inequality Across Countries Michael Hotard Illinois

More information

The widening income dispersion in Hong Kong :

The widening income dispersion in Hong Kong : Lingnan University Digital Commons @ Lingnan University Staff Publications Lingnan Staff Publication 3-14-2008 The widening income dispersion in Hong Kong : 1986-2006 Hon Kwong LUI Lingnan University,

More information

GENDER EQUALITY IN THE LABOUR MARKET AND FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT

GENDER EQUALITY IN THE LABOUR MARKET AND FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT THE STUDENT ECONOMIC REVIEWVOL. XXIX GENDER EQUALITY IN THE LABOUR MARKET AND FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT CIÁN MC LEOD Senior Sophister With Southeast Asia attracting more foreign direct investment than

More information

Response to the Evaluation Panel s Critique of Poverty Mapping

Response to the Evaluation Panel s Critique of Poverty Mapping Response to the Evaluation Panel s Critique of Poverty Mapping Peter Lanjouw and Martin Ravallion 1 World Bank, October 2006 The Evaluation of World Bank Research (hereafter the Report) focuses some of

More information

How s Life in Portugal?

How s Life in Portugal? How s Life in Portugal? November 2017 Relative to other OECD countries, Portugal has a mixed performance across the different well-being dimensions. For example, it is in the bottom third of the OECD in

More information

GLOBALIZATION AND THE GREAT U-TURN: INCOME INEQUALITY TRENDS IN 16 OECD COUNTRIES. Arthur S. Alderson

GLOBALIZATION AND THE GREAT U-TURN: INCOME INEQUALITY TRENDS IN 16 OECD COUNTRIES. Arthur S. Alderson GLOBALIZATION AND THE GREAT U-TURN: INCOME INEQUALITY TRENDS IN 16 OECD COUNTRIES by Arthur S. Alderson Department of Sociology Indiana University Bloomington Email aralders@indiana.edu & François Nielsen

More information

Remittances and Poverty. in Guatemala* Richard H. Adams, Jr. Development Research Group (DECRG) MSN MC World Bank.

Remittances and Poverty. in Guatemala* Richard H. Adams, Jr. Development Research Group (DECRG) MSN MC World Bank. Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Remittances and Poverty in Guatemala* Richard H. Adams, Jr. Development Research Group

More information

Using data provided by the U.S. Census Bureau, this study first recreates the Bureau s most recent population

Using data provided by the U.S. Census Bureau, this study first recreates the Bureau s most recent population Backgrounder Center for Immigration Studies December 2012 Projecting Immigration s Impact on the Size and Age Structure of the 21st Century American Population By Steven A. Camarota Using data provided

More information

Capital in the 21 st century A Middle East Perspective. Thomas Piketty Paris School of Economics Cairo, June

Capital in the 21 st century A Middle East Perspective. Thomas Piketty Paris School of Economics Cairo, June Capital in the 21 st century A Middle East Perspective Thomas Piketty Paris School of Economics Cairo, June 2 2016 This presentation is partly based upon my book Capital in the 21 st century (HUP, 2014)

More information

How s Life in the Netherlands?

How s Life in the Netherlands? How s Life in the Netherlands? November 2017 In general, the Netherlands performs well across the OECD s headline well-being indicators relative to the other OECD countries. Household net wealth was about

More information

Econ Global Inequality and Growth. Introduction. Gabriel Zucman

Econ Global Inequality and Growth. Introduction. Gabriel Zucman Introduction zucman@berkeley.edu 1 Roadmap 1. What is this course about? 2. Inequality and growth in the history of economic thought 3. Course organization: grading, readings, etc. 4. Overview of the five

More information

Changing Times, Changing Enrollments: How Recent Demographic Trends are Affecting Enrollments in Portland Public Schools

Changing Times, Changing Enrollments: How Recent Demographic Trends are Affecting Enrollments in Portland Public Schools Portland State University PDXScholar School District Enrollment Forecast Reports Population Research Center 7-1-2000 Changing Times, Changing Enrollments: How Recent Demographic Trends are Affecting Enrollments

More information

Poverty and Inequality

Poverty and Inequality Poverty and Inequality Sherif Khalifa Sherif Khalifa () Poverty and Inequality 1 / 50 Sherif Khalifa () Poverty and Inequality 2 / 50 Sherif Khalifa () Poverty and Inequality 3 / 50 Definition Income inequality

More information

How s Life in Belgium?

How s Life in Belgium? How s Life in Belgium? November 2017 Relative to other countries, Belgium performs above or close to the OECD average across the different wellbeing dimensions. Household net adjusted disposable income

More information

How s Life in France?

How s Life in France? How s Life in France? November 2017 Relative to other OECD countries, France s average performance across the different well-being dimensions is mixed. While household net adjusted disposable income stands

More information

Human Capital and Income Inequality: New Facts and Some Explanations

Human Capital and Income Inequality: New Facts and Some Explanations Human Capital and Income Inequality: New Facts and Some Explanations Amparo Castelló and Rafael Doménech 2016 Annual Meeting of the European Economic Association Geneva, August 24, 2016 1/1 Introduction

More information

CHAPTER 12: The Problem of Global Inequality

CHAPTER 12: The Problem of Global Inequality 1. Self-interest is an important motive for countries who express concern that poverty may be linked to a rise in a. religious activity. b. environmental deterioration. c. terrorist events. d. capitalist

More information

Fiscal Impacts of Immigration in 2013

Fiscal Impacts of Immigration in 2013 www.berl.co.nz Authors: Dr Ganesh Nana and Hugh Dixon All work is done, and services rendered at the request of, and for the purposes of the client only. Neither BERL nor any of its employees accepts any

More information

Jens Thomsen: The global economy in the years ahead

Jens Thomsen: The global economy in the years ahead Jens Thomsen: The global economy in the years ahead Statement by Mr Jens Thomsen, Governor of the National Bank of Denmark, at the Indo- Danish Business Association, Delhi, 9 October 2007. Introduction

More information

Karl Marx ( )

Karl Marx ( ) Karl Marx (1818-1883) Karl Marx Marx (1818-1883) German economist, philosopher, sociologist and revolutionist. Enormous impact on arrangement of economies in the 20th century The strongest critic of capitalism

More information

DEMOGRAPHIC SHOCKS: THE VIEW FROM HISTORY. DISCUSSION

DEMOGRAPHIC SHOCKS: THE VIEW FROM HISTORY. DISCUSSION DEMOGRAPHIC SHOCKS: THE VIEW FROM HISTORY. DISCUSSION David N. Weil* Massimo Livi-Bacci has taken us on a fascinating tour of demographic history. What lessons for developments in the world today can we

More information

The Impact of Interprovincial Migration on Aggregate Output and Labour Productivity in Canada,

The Impact of Interprovincial Migration on Aggregate Output and Labour Productivity in Canada, The Impact of Interprovincial Migration on Aggregate Output and Labour Productivity in Canada, 1987-26 Andrew Sharpe, Jean-Francois Arsenault, and Daniel Ershov 1 Centre for the Study of Living Standards

More information

Test Bank for Economic Development. 12th Edition by Todaro and Smith

Test Bank for Economic Development. 12th Edition by Todaro and Smith Test Bank for Economic Development 12th Edition by Todaro and Smith Link download full: https://digitalcontentmarket.org/download/test-bankfor-economic-development-12th-edition-by-todaro Chapter 2 Comparative

More information

How s Life in Mexico?

How s Life in Mexico? How s Life in Mexico? November 2017 Relative to other OECD countries, Mexico has a mixed performance across the different well-being dimensions. At 61% in 2016, Mexico s employment rate was below the OECD

More information

L8: Inequality, Poverty and Development: The Evidence

L8: Inequality, Poverty and Development: The Evidence L8: Inequality, Poverty and Development: The Evidence Dilip Mookherjee Ec320 Lecture 8, Boston University Sept 25, 2014 DM (BU) 320 Lect 8 Sept 25, 2014 1 / 1 RECAP: Measuring Inequality and Poverty We

More information

Chapter 4 Specific Factors and Income Distribution

Chapter 4 Specific Factors and Income Distribution Chapter 4 Specific Factors and Income Distribution Chapter Organization Introduction The Specific Factors Model International Trade in the Specific Factors Model Income Distribution and the Gains from

More information

Poverty in Israel: Reasons and Labor Market Policy

Poverty in Israel: Reasons and Labor Market Policy Poverty in Israel: Reasons and Labor Market Policy Zvi Eckstein and Tali Larom * Policy Paper 2016.08 November 2016 The Aaron Institute s policy papers series is a product of research and policy suggestions

More information

Eric M. Uslaner, Inequality, Trust, and Civic Engagement (1)

Eric M. Uslaner, Inequality, Trust, and Civic Engagement (1) Eric M. Uslaner, Inequality, Trust, and Civic Engagement (1) Inequality, Trust, and Civic Engagement Eric M. Uslaner Department of Government and Politics University of Maryland College Park College Park,

More information

Inequality is Bad for the Poor. Martin Ravallion * Development Research Group, World Bank 1818 H Street NW, Washington DC

Inequality is Bad for the Poor. Martin Ravallion * Development Research Group, World Bank 1818 H Street NW, Washington DC Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Inequality is Bad for the Poor Martin Ravallion * Development Research Group, World Bank

More information

Poverty and Inequality

Poverty and Inequality Chapter 4 Poverty and Inequality Problems and Policies: Domestic After completing this chapter, you will be able to 1. Measure poverty across countries using different approaches and explain how poverty

More information

Spain s average level of current well-being: Comparative strengths and weaknesses

Spain s average level of current well-being: Comparative strengths and weaknesses How s Life in Spain? November 2017 Relative to other OECD countries, Spain s average performance across the different well-being dimensions is mixed. Despite a comparatively low average household net adjusted

More information

Inequality in Indonesia: Trends, drivers, policies

Inequality in Indonesia: Trends, drivers, policies Inequality in Indonesia: Trends, drivers, policies Taufik Indrakesuma & Bambang Suharnoko Sjahrir World Bank Presented at ILO Country Level Consultation Hotel Borobudur, Jakarta 24 February 2015 Indonesia

More information

TRENDS IN INCOME INEQUALITY: GLOBAL, INTER-COUNTRY, AND WITHIN COUNTRIES Zia Qureshi 1

TRENDS IN INCOME INEQUALITY: GLOBAL, INTER-COUNTRY, AND WITHIN COUNTRIES Zia Qureshi 1 TRENDS IN INCOME INEQUALITY: GLOBAL, INTER-COUNTRY, AND WITHIN COUNTRIES Zia Qureshi 1 Over the last three decades, inequality between countries has decreased while inequality within countries has increased.

More information

Do Bilateral Investment Treaties Encourage FDI in the GCC Countries?

Do Bilateral Investment Treaties Encourage FDI in the GCC Countries? African Review of Economics and Finance, Vol. 2, No. 1, Dec 2010 The Author(s). Published by Print Services, Rhodes University, P.O.Box 94, Grahamstown, South Africa Do Bilateral Investment Treaties Encourage

More information

Conclusions. Size and directions

Conclusions. Size and directions Conclusions During the early modern period, the North Sea region set the stage for the exchange of culture, practices and goods, but as this study has shown, also of people. Within the North Sea basin

More information

The Industrial Revolution Beginnings. Ways of the World Strayer Chapter 18

The Industrial Revolution Beginnings. Ways of the World Strayer Chapter 18 The Industrial Revolution Beginnings Ways of the World Strayer Chapter 18 Explaining the Industrial Revolution The global context for the Industrial Revolution lies in a very substantial increase in human

More information

The Comparative Advantage of Nations: Shifting Trends and Policy Implications

The Comparative Advantage of Nations: Shifting Trends and Policy Implications The Comparative Advantage of Nations: Shifting Trends and Policy Implications The Nobel Prize-winning economist Paul Samuelson once famously argued that comparative advantage was the clearest example of

More information

Support Materials. GCE Economics H061/H461: Exemplar Materials. AS/A Level Economics

Support Materials. GCE Economics H061/H461: Exemplar Materials. AS/A Level Economics Support Materials GCE Economics H061/H461: Exemplar Materials AS/A Level Economics Contents 1 Unit F581: Markets In Action 3 2 Unit F582: The National and International Economy 6 3 Unit F583: Economics

More information

Global Income Inequality by the Numbers: In History and Now An Overview. Branko Milanovic

Global Income Inequality by the Numbers: In History and Now An Overview. Branko Milanovic Global Income Inequality by the Numbers: In History and Now An Overview. Branko Milanovic Usually inequality looked at within a state (for govt program access e.g.) Also, across countries (the poor, the

More information

Does Inequality Matter for Poverty Reduction? Evidence from Pakistan s Poverty Trends

Does Inequality Matter for Poverty Reduction? Evidence from Pakistan s Poverty Trends The Pakistan Development Review 45 : 3 (Autumn 2006) pp. 439 459 Does Inequality Matter for Poverty Reduction? Evidence from Pakistan s Poverty Trends HAROON JAMAL * The paper explores the linkages between

More information

The Future of Rural Policy: Lessons from Spatial Economics

The Future of Rural Policy: Lessons from Spatial Economics SERC POLICY PAPER 8 The Future of Rural Policy: Lessons from Spatial Economics Henry G. Overman (SERC, Department of Geography & Environment, London School of Economics) Steve Gibbons (SERC, Department

More information

The impact of Chinese import competition on the local structure of employment and wages in France

The impact of Chinese import competition on the local structure of employment and wages in France No. 57 February 218 The impact of Chinese import competition on the local structure of employment and wages in France Clément Malgouyres External Trade and Structural Policies Research Division This Rue

More information

Growth and Poverty Reduction: An Empirical Analysis Nanak Kakwani

Growth and Poverty Reduction: An Empirical Analysis Nanak Kakwani Growth and Poverty Reduction: An Empirical Analysis Nanak Kakwani Abstract. This paper develops an inequality-growth trade off index, which shows how much growth is needed to offset the adverse impact

More information