Is migration a good substitute for education subsidies?

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Is migration a good substitute for education subsidies?"

Transcription

1 Journal of Development Economics 86 (2008) Is migration a good substitute for education subsidies? Frédéric Docquier a,b,c,, Ousmane Faye d,e, Pierre Pestieau d,f,g,h a FNRS, National Fund for Scientific Research, Belgium b IRES, Catholic University of Louvain, Belgium c World Bank, USA d CREPP, University of Liège, Belgium e APHRC, Nairobi, Kenya f CORE, Catholic University of Louvain, Belgium g PSE Paris, France h CEPR, UK Received 25 December 2005; received in revised form 14 December 2007; accepted 21 December 2007 Abstract Assuming a given educational policy, the recent brain drain literature reveals that skilled migration can boost the average level of schooling in developing countries. In this paper, we introduce educational subsidies determined by governments concerned by the number of skilled workers remaining in the country. Our theoretical analysis shows that developing countries can benefit from skilled emigration when educational subsidies entail high fiscal distortions. However when taxes are not too distortionary, it is desirable to impede emigration and subsidize education. We then investigate the empirical relationship between educational subsidies and migration prospects, obtaining a negative relationship for 105 countries. Based on this result, we revisit the country specific effects of skilled migration upon human capital. We show that the endogeneity of public subsidies reduces the number of winners and increases the magnitude of the losses Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved. JEL classification: F22; J24; O15 Keywords: Brain drain; Human capital; Immigration policy; Development 1. Introduction The recent literature on the brain drain asserts that the migration of the highly skilled may entail beneficial feedback effects for source countries. Remittances, return migration and diaspora externalities are potentially Corresponding author. IRES, Catholic University of Louvain, 3 Place Montesquieu, B-1348 Louvain-La-Neuve, Belgium. Tel.: ; fax: address: frederic.docquier@uclouvain.be (F. Docquier). important feedback channels. In addition, several authors such as Vidal (1998), Mountford (1999), Beine et al. (2001) and Stark and Wang (2002) have recently argued that migration prospects increase the expected returns to education and may foster educational investments in developing countries, therefore making it possible for a brain drain to be beneficial to the source country (i.e., the country may end up with a higher level of human capital after emigration is netted out). Obviously, causality is hard to establish in cross-sectional regressions and the brain gain concept deserves /$ - see front matter 2008 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved. doi: /j.jdeveco

2 264 F. Docquier et al. / Journal of Development Economics 86 (2008) See also Kangasniemi et al. (2004), Commander et al. (2004), Lucas (2004) or Batista et al. (2007). 2 These can be related to population size acting as a cultural public good creating social capital, or to externalities associated with the total stock of human capital. Authors such as Kremer (1993), Lagerloef (2003) and Becker et al. (1999) have stressed the role of population growth and population density in the economic/demographic transition. Galor and Weil (2000) argued that a larger stock of human capital generates greater numbers of innovations. further empirical investigations based on richer data. However, Beine et al. (2001, in press) found evidence in support of such an incentive mechanism 1. In this paper, we analyze the policy implications of the brain gain hypothesis, especially the interactions between skilled migration and education policies. These interactions were studied by Stark and Wang (2002) who demonstrated that, by allowing a controlled proportion of skilled individuals to emigrate to a richer country, the government can stimulate the expected returns to schooling so as to obtain the socially desirable level of human capital without subsidies. Although it can be refuted that sending countries (except perhaps totalitarian regimes) have no perfect control over emigration rates, Stark and Wang's analysis suggests that the emigration policy acts as a perfect substitute for public subsidies (i.e. that the higher the skilled emigration rate, the lower is the rate of subsidy required to decentralize the social optimum). The purpose of our paper is to theoretically and empirically revisit the migrationsubsidy policy mix in a more realistic framework where distortions and efficiency costs are factored in. Theoretically, we use a normative approach and derive the optimal emigration and education policies when social costs and distortions are linked to both instruments. The financing of public subsidies usually induces many costs such as tax evasion, distortive effects on labor supply, exit to the informal sector, administrative costs and corruption. Emigration also entails some costs to the government. It can reasonably be argued that emigration causes social welfare losses for the domestic country when the government is concerned by the aggregate stock of residents' human capital or has ethical opposition against skilled emigration 2. In such cases, our model shows that the first best emigration rate is zero. With non-distortive taxes or at low efficiency costs, an appropriate education policy always dominates a controlled emigration policy. When tax distortions are sufficiently large, a controlled and rationed emigration rate can be second best. Skilled migration becomes a substitute to public subsidies, i.e. a negative correlation exists between the second best subsidy and the controlled emigration rate. Interestingly, such a negative relationship is also obtained in a third best framework when the emigration rate is exogenously determined (i.e. when the planner has no control on emigration). Such crowding out effects of skilled migration upon subsidies have been disregarded in the empirical literature, thereby overestimating the magnitude of incentive mechanisms. Empirically, we use a large sample of middle and low-income countries, and confirm the existence of a negative relationship between education subsidies and skilled migration rates. The elasticity of public subsidies to migration equals We then revisit the country specific effects of skilled migration on human capital by considering public subsidies as endogenous. Our counterfactual experiment consists of equating the skilled emigration rate to the unskilled emigration rate (considered as the minimal rate of emigration given colonial ties, distance, etc.) and computing the hypothetical human capital change between 1990 and Unsurprisingly, the endogeneity of public subsidies decreases the relative number of winners, reduces the size of the gains and increases the size of the losses in other countries. It is noteworthy that although a brain gain is observed in the largest developing countries, skilled emigration reduces the number of post-secondary educated in the developing world by about 2.7%. The remainder of this paper is organized as following. Section 2 describes the theoretical model and compares the first best and second best solutions. Section 3 provides the empirical analysis and its implications. The final section concludes. 2. Migration as a second best policy option To analyze the optimal migration-subsidy mix, we consider a small open economy populated by two overlapping generations. As in Stark and Wang (2002), agents are homogenous within generations and there are no credit market imperfections. The number of young individuals living at time t is denoted by N t and the number of adults is denoted by A t. Each adult gives birth to n N1 children. At each period, a composite good (Y t ) is produced using capital (K t ) and labor measured in efficiency units (H t ) according to a neoclassical technology, F(K t,h t ). This good can be consumed, saved or used as an input for the formation of human capital. Young agents inherit a fraction a [0, 1] of adults' human capital, h t. Labor in efficiency units is given by H t ¼ N t ah t þ A t h t ¼ A t ð1 þ naþh t :

3 F. Docquier et al. / Journal of Development Economics 86 (2008) The production function exhibits constant returns to scale and is time invariant. Assuming physical capital is perfectly mobile across countries, the time-invariant world interest rate R determines the wage rate per efficiency unit of labor w. Our economy is assumed to be poor. Due to a technological gap, the wage rate per efficiency unit of labor is lower than it is in the rich world: wbw. We assume no migration costs. Hence, each worker has an incentive to emigrate to rich countries. Individuals are only concerned about their level of consumption in the second period of life, C t +1. They are risk neutral and maximize their expected consumption level. Every young individual has the possibility to invest an amount e t in education, to increase their second period stock of human capital. Individuals face a common training technology: Given decreasing returns to scale in the human capital technology, this function is concave and there is a unique interior steady state level of human capital: a w þ mw4 w h ss ¼ ½ ð ÞŠ Rð1 rþ a 1 a d : ð4þ Hence, our model is compatible with the analysis of Vidal (1998) and Stark and Wang (2002). When individuals are equally capable of responding to emigration incentives, migration prospects have an unambiguously positive impact on human capital. In the absence of distortions, public subsidies and a properly controlled emigration policy can be used to reach any level of human capital. Would this result resist a normative analysis? h tþ1 ¼ e a t hd t ð1þ 2.1. The first best utilitarian solution with α+δb1 (decreasing returns to scale) The latter condition will ensure the convergence of the human capital stock to a steady state. A fraction σ t of education expenditures is subsidized by the government (σ t is a Pigouvian policy instrument). The public budget constraint is balanced by levying lump-sum taxes on the young (τ t y ) and adults (τ t a ). This implies: nσ t e t = nτ t y +τ t a. Individuals' saving if given by S t =wah t e t (1 σ t ) τ t y. Young agents make their education decision by anticipating a probability m t +1 of emigrating to a rich country when reaching adulthood. Their second period consumption equals C t +1=RS t +w h t +1 with probability m t +1, and C t +1 =RS t +wh t +1 τ a t +1 with probability (1 m t +1 ). Young individuals maximize their expected (linear) utility EC ð tþ1 Þ ¼ R½wah t e t ð1 r t Þ s y t Šþm tþ1 w4h tþ1 þð1 m tþ1 Þ wh tþ1 s a tþ1 : Given our assumptions concerning the training technology, there exists a unique and interior solution to the individuals' maximization problem: 1 e t ¼ ahd t ½w þ m tþ1 ðw4 wþš Rð1 r t Þ 1 a ð2þ and the dynamics of human capital is governed by the equation: h tþ1 ¼ a ½ w þ m tþ1ðw4 wþš Rð1 r t Þ a 1 a h d 1 a t : ð3þ Except in totalitarian regimes, it is fairly obvious that sending countries have little control over emigration. Nevertheless, in line with the new literature on the brain drain, it is worth analyzing whether developing countries can benefit from a positive skilled emigration rates: i.e. what would be their optimal choice if they could perfectly control their skilled emigration rate? To address this question, we suppose that the government is concerned by the total welfare of residents. The social welfare function is of the Benthamite utilitarian form: it sums utilities of all remaining adults. This specification implies that the government is concerned by the resident population size. Through this channel, we summarize all the social costs of emigration for the sending country. Given (R,w,A 0, S 0, h 0 ), the planner's problem involves maximizing the social welfare function subject to the production technology of human capital. At time 0, the Lagrangian can be written as o FB ¼ A 0c 0 b þ Xl b t fa tþ1 ½Rwah t Re t þ wh tþ1 Š ð5þ t¼0 g þk t A tþ1 e a t hd t h tþ1 where β is the factor of social time preference such that βnb1. In the first best problem, the planner has a perfect control on all individual decisions. Using the first order conditions with respect to h t +1, e t and m t +1 (see Appendix A.1), we have: Proposition 1. Decentralizing the first best solution requires setting the emigration rate to zero and using both education subsidies and lump-sum taxes.

4 266 F. Docquier et al. / Journal of Development Economics 86 (2008) The intuition is straightforward. There are two sources of intergenerational externalities in the model: individual education decisions impact upon the next generation income (βnrwa) and affect the future productivity of education investments (βnδ). The long-run level of human capital at the first best is given by: h FB ss ¼ aw ½ 1 þ bnrwa Š R½1 bndš a 1 a d : ð6þ From Eq. (4), two instruments (emigration and subsidies) can be used to increase human capital. Resorting to emigration induces a social loss: the number of skilled residents decreases. Consequently, with no tax distortion, educational subsidy is to be preferred over emigration as it keeps all skilled individuals at home. Comparing Eq. (6) to Eq. (4), the first best solution can be obtained as a market outcome if the government chooses a subsidy rate that corrects for both externalities: r FB ss ¼ bnrwa þ bnd 1 þ bnrwa : ð7þ It can be easily shown that the unique tax-mix that balances the budget constraint and verifies the optimality conditions requires τ ss y,fb =σ ss e ss and τ ss a,fb =0. When the capital stock is exogenous and saving does not matter, there is no need for intergenerational transfers. For simplicity, in the remainder of this paper, we will only consider taxes on the young The second best utilitarian solution Let us now assume that levying taxes induces some distortions. Efficiency costs are denoted by c(τ t y ): levying τ t y dollars induces a fiscal revenue of τ t y c(τ t y ). The idea that revenue collection entails a loss in efficiency is traditionally associated with labor/leisure choices, but they can also be linked to administrative costs of running programs, which in turn can be linked to the quality of governance and rent-seeking activities in developing countries. The planner now faces a second best problem in that he has perfect control of policy instruments, which indirectly affect individual decisions. Hence, the government takes into account that individuals will maximize their own utility taking taxes and subsidies as given. The second best problem now consists of maximizing the utilitarian social welfare function subject to the production technology of human capital (with multiplier λ t ), the government budget constraint including efficiency costs (with multiplier ρ t ), and the individual first order condition (Eq. (2) with multiplier μ t ). At time 0, the Lagrangian can be written as: o SB ¼ A 0c 0 b þ Xl b t A tþ1 f Rwah t Rð1 r t Þe t Rs y t þ wh tþ1 s a tþ1 t¼0 þk t e a t hd t h tþ1 þ qt ½s y t cðs y t Þ r t e t Š þa t ah d t ½w þ m tþ1 ðw4 wþš Rð1 r t g ð8þ Þe 1 a t and must be maximized with respect to h t +1, e t, σ t, τ y t and m t +1. In Appendix A.2, we provide the first order conditions expressed at the steady state. In the absence of any perception cost (c (τ y )=0), the optimal emigration rate is zero and the optimal level of human capital is naturally identical to h FB ss. This is the first best solution. When perception costs are positive (c (τ y )N0), the optimal migration rate can be positive. For the sake of simplicity, we consider the case of linear efficiency costs: c (τ y )=γ. 3 The optimal level of human capital becomes: h SB aw/ g; m ss ¼ ð Þ a 1 a d ð9þ R where ϕ(γ, m), as detailed in Appendix A.2, is a decreasing function of γ and m. We have: Proposition 2. In the case of exogenous emigration rates and linear perception costs, the optimal level of human capital and the subsidy rate are decreasing in m. From Eqs. (6) and (9), decentralizing the second best solution requires a subsidy rate equal to r SB ss ¼ / ðg; m w4 w Þ 1 m ð Þ w ; ð10þ / ðg; mþ which is, for reasonable values of the parameters, a decreasing function of and m The interpretation is intuitive. On the one hand, the probability of migration reduces the social return to education (fewer remaining adults induces fewer externalities), and the optimal level of education decreases. On the other hand, migration stimulates the laissez-faire investment in education. Consequently, the gap between private and social returns to education decreases. 3 Although perception costs in public finance are usually convex, the assumption of linear costs was made for simplicity. The introduction of convex costs would yield similar results.

5 F. Docquier et al. / Journal of Development Economics 86 (2008) The above results characterize the third best solution with exogenous emigration rates, i.e. when the domestic government has no control on the migration rate (or when the first order condition with respect to m t +1 is not used). Is migration good or bad for the sending country? Using the first order condition with respect to m t +1,we can determine whether or not a positive migration rate is desirable from the perspective of the sending country. The condition for a positive emigration rate is AoSB Am N0 evaluated at m=0. This requires g 1 g ahd ðw4 wþnwhð1 þ arþ e: ð11þ We have: Proposition 3. There is a cut off level in the distortion parameter c above which the optimal migration rate is positive. Indeed, the right hand side term in Eq. (11) is decreasing in γ: from Eq. (9), a rise in reduces the level of human capital. The left hand side term is increasing in γ (it tends to infinity when γ tends to one and is equal to zero when γ=0). Fig. 1 below describes the impact of distortion costs on emigration and subsidy rates. As in the exogenous migration case, σ SB ss falls to zero when perception costs are sufficiently high (when / ðg; mþb1 þ m ðw4 wþ w ). Then perception costs vanish and there is no room for increasing the emigration rate. Assuming exogenous educational policies and abstracting from any normative consideration, the recent literature on the brain drain reveals that skilled migration can stimulate human capital accumulation in the sending country. Endogenizing education subsidies, our analysis shows that emigration can be desirable if and only if tax distortions are sufficiently high. On the contrary, when tax distortions are low, impeding emigration and using domestic education policies is preferable. Hence, a welfare improving brain drain can only be obtained in particular circumstances (high fiscal distortions and limited emigration rates). When efficiency costs are low, the beneficial brain drain hypothesis hardly resists a normative analysis. 3. Empirical analysis A central prediction of our theoretical model is that, whether an inefficient government can control emigration or not, there should exist a negative relationship between skilled emigration rates and public education subsidies. In this section, we use a recent data set on emigration to address two empirical issues. Firstly, do human capital accumulation and public subsidies effectively respond to skilled migration rates? Secondly, does the endogeneity of public subsidies modify the gains and losses of skilled migration compared to previous studies? We address these questions in a sample of 108 countries. We eliminate high-income countries (we select nations for which migration is likely to induce a clear incentive effect), countries for which data on public expenditures in education are not available and countries that experienced civil war and political turmoil during the nineties Data on skilled migration Our empirical analysis is based on a recent data set on international migration by educational attainment detailed in Docquier and Marfouk (2006) (henceforth DM). DM use the receiving country r's census or population register to extract information on immigrants' country of birth, age, and skill level. Such statistics were collected for all OECD countries (Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development). Let M r t,s denote the stock of working-age individuals born in a given country, of skill level s=l, h (h stands for individuals with post-secondary certificates, l stands for those with less than post-secondary schooling) and living in country r at time t. The stock of emigrants from a given country for a given education level, M t,s = r M r t,s, is then obtained by summing over receiving countries. Emigration rates by education levels are then obtained by comparing the number of emigrants to the population at origin with similar characteristics, N t,s. Skilled and unskilled emigration rates are denoted by Fig. 1. Perception costs, optimal subsidy and emigration rates. 4 Among countries for which data is available, we exclude Afghanistan, Armenia, Bosnia and Herzegovina, Dem. Rep. of Congo, Croatia, Eritrea, Georgia, Guinea-Bissau, Iraq, Liberia, Macedonia, the Federated States of Micronesia, Rwanda, Serbia and Montenegro, Sierra Leone and Somalia.

6 268 F. Docquier et al. / Journal of Development Economics 86 (2008) M t;h m t ¼ N t;h þm t;h and P m t ¼ M t;l N t;l þm t;l respectively. The data set also allows us to compute the proportion of post- secondary educated among natives H t ¼ P Nt;hþMt;h and ð s Nt;sþMt;sÞ among residents h t ¼ P Nt;h. s The DM estimates are Nt;s built according to a broad definition of skilled migrants in that they include all foreign-born workers with post-secondary schooling wherever they acquired education. 5 Beine et al. (2007) use immigrants' age of entry as a proxy for where education has been acquired. They provide alternative measures of the brain drain by defining skilled immigrants as those who arrived in the receiving country after age 12, 18 or 22. These corrected skilled emigration rates, which can be seen as intermediate bounds to the brain drain estimates, are by construction lower than those computed without age of entry restrictions by DM. Let us denote by m J,t the skilled emigration rate based on migrants who left their country after age J (J =12, 18, 22), i.e. on restrictive measures of M t,h.we denote by H J,t the corresponding proportion of educated among natives. These alternative measures are only available for migrants with post-secondary level education. We use them to evaluate the robustness of our empirical model in Appendix A Empirical model and econometric issues The theoretical model predicts (i) a negative relationship between skilled emigration and subsidy rates and (ii) a positive effect of migration prospects and subsidies on human capital formation. In the theoretical model, individuals live a single adult period. Hence, the stock of human capital is equal to the lagged investment of the young. In the real world, the flow of investment in human capital can be approximated by the change in the stock. Hence, our empirical analysis distinguishes two dependent variables, the growth rate of human capital between 1990 and 2000 and the logarithm of the education subsidy rate in Human capital is measured as the proportion of post-secondary educated natives (including emigrants). The education subsidy rate is measured as the amount of public expenditure in tertiary education per student as percentage of GDP per capita (provided by the United Nations Educational, Scientific and Cultural Organization-UNESCO). 6 We consider 5 For example, Mexican-born individuals who arrived in the US at age 5 or 10 and later graduated from US high-education institutions are counted as highly-skilled Mexican immigrants. 6 There is a high correlation between public expenditure in secondary and tertiary education (67%). This is not the case between the primary and tertiary levels. these two variables as endogenous and estimate two empirical equations. Regarding human capital accumulation, we use a β-convergence equation and regress the log-ratio of human capital, ln(h 00 = H 90 ), on: - the log of the skilled emigration rate in 1990, ln(m 90 ), so as to capture the incentive effect of migration prospects. Note that in our estimates, we first use as a benchmark the skilled emigration rate of all foreignborn individuals regardless of whether they acquire their education in their origin or host country; 7 - the log of tertiary educated in 1990, ln(h 90 ), so as to capture convergence or divergence forces; - the log of public subsidy per student as percentage of GDP per capita in 1990, ln(σ 90 ); so as to control for the local education policy; - the age structure of the population within a country. It can be argued that the growth rate of human capital is stronger in countries where the population turnover (replacement of old cohorts by young ones) is important. Since migrants usually belong to young cohorts, it is important to control for the population structure in our regressions. We account for that possibility by using the demographic share of individuals aged 15 to 24, S15/24, and the share of those 49 to 55, S49/55 (Source: United Nations Population Division); - the urbanization rate, UR 90 ; which accounts for access to schooling facilities within a country (Source: World Development Indicators); - the level of remittances in 1990, R 90 ; which potentially alleviates liquidity constraints impeding human capital investments (Source: World Development Indicators); - a set of regional dummies REGD i (Sub-Saharan Africa, Latin America, Middle East and North Africa, East Asia and Pacific, Eastern Europe and Central Asia) capturing regional unobserved characteristics. South Asia is used as reference. This specification is similar to that used in Beine et al. (in press) but is more general it in several respects. We add new control variables (including regional fixed effects) and use new UNESCO estimates of public expenditures in tertiary education. We expect the inclusion of the latter variable to improve our assessment of the incentive mechanism. 7 In Appendix A.3, we estimate our model using alternative measures of the skilled emigration rate (m J,t ) and human capital stock (H J,t ) which control for the age of entry of migrants.

7 F. Docquier et al. / Journal of Development Economics 86 (2008) Regarding education subsidies, we estimate the log of public expenditure per student as percent of GDP per capita in 1990, ln(σ 90 ); as a function of: ln - the log of the high skilled emigration rate, ln(m 90 ); so as to capture the policy trade-off predicted by our theoretical model; - the investment rate in 1990, I 90 ; since investments in public education are mainly profitable where there are machines to complement skills; - the rule of law dimension of governance measuring the extent to which agents have confidence in and abide the rules of society, RLAW. It ranges from 2.5 (bad governance) to 2.5 (good governance). We average the annual scores provided in Kaufmann et al. (2003); - dummies for middle-income (MINC) countries based on the World Bank classification; - the level of remittances in 1990, R 90 ;soastocapture the political demand for public transfers (as remittances are potential determinants of liquidity constraints); - the same set of regional dummies, REGD i, as above. Our specifications are: H 00 ¼ a 0 þ a 1: lnðm 90 Þþa 2: lnðh 90 Þ H 90 þ a 3 lnr ð 90 Þþa 4 S15=24 þ a 5 S49=55 þ a 6 UR 90 þ a 7 R 90 þ X 12 a i¼8 iregd i þ H lnðr 90 Þ ¼ b 0 þ b 1 lnðm 90 Þþb 2 I 90 þb 3 RLAW þ b 4 MINC þb 5 R 90 þ P 10 i¼6 b iregd i þ r ð12þ ð13þ where ϵ H and ϵ σ are error terms. The potential correlation between unobserved characteristics and the emigration rate can affect both the growth rate of human capital and level of public subsidies per student. Therefore, the OLS method can generate inconsistent estimates. To address such a problem, we use the instrumental variable (IV) method and estimate the two equations with the two-stage least square procedure (2SLS). We consider ln(m 90 ) as the instrumented variable. The recent empirical growth literature (Barro and Sala-i-Martin, 1995; Hall and Jones, 1999) paid attention to the determinants of instruments when estimating a migration equation. However, it is difficult to select excluded instruments for migration due to an obvious presumption of correlation with human capital. Here, the first-stage migration equation uses geographical proximity with developed countries (minimal distance to OECD countries), and two indicators of disadvantageous location (dummies for landlocked countries and small islands). In previous versions of the paper, we ran many regressions with different sets of instruments and obtained similar results. In our estimation strategy, several diagnostic tests are conducted to assess the reliability of the IV estimates. We first check whether our instruments are relevant and valid using the first-stage F-statistic of joint significance of the instruments (the rule of thumb in Staiger and Stock (1997) is that F-statistic should exceed 10), Anderson's canonical correlations likelihood ratio test statistic, and the Cragg Donald statistic for weak instruments. The instruments' strength is analyzed against the null hypothesis of weak instruments, as suggested in Stock and Yogo (2002). The validity of our instruments is assessed using the Hansen J-statistic for overidentification. Finally, provided that our instruments satisfy the relevance and validity conditions, IV estimates can be consistent but inefficient. Therefore, if regressors are exogenous, consistent and more efficient estimates produced by OLS are preferred. Thus, we test for exogeneity of ln(m 90 ) using a C-test. We also correct for the presence of heteroskedasticity in the data and checked for multicollinearity Results for the human capital equation Table 1 reports the OLS and IV estimation results for human capital accumulation using the overall skilled emigration rate regardless of the age of entry of individuals. For each method, the first column corresponds to the full specification of the equation of human capital accumulation; the second column gives a parsimonious specification in which insignificant or weakly significant variables such as I 90 and R 90 are excluded. Note that dropping these variables increases the size of our sample. For IV regressions, we report first and secondstage diagnostic tests. The results in Table 1 show a positive and significant association between skilled migration rates and human capital accumulation. This effect is robust across different specifications and estimation methods. However, the magnitude differs across methods. The size of the IV estimate is twice as large as the one obtained with OLS. Our estimates also indicate that an increase in public subsidies has a positive and stable impact on human capital formation. Another finding worth emphasizing is

8 270 F. Docquier et al. / Journal of Development Economics 86 (2008) Table 1 Log ratio of human capital (H 00 =H 90 ) OLS 1 OLS 2 IV 1 IV 2 ln(m 90 ) (0.021) (0.006) (0.036) (0.037) ln(h 90 ) (0.039) (0.038) (0.040) (0.040) ln(σ 90 ) (0.058) (0.049) (0.060) (0.053) S15/ (0.860) (0.792) (0.821) (0.807) S49/ (3.215) (2.972) (3.112) (3.086) UR (0.137) (0.117) (0.148) (0.147) R (0.000) (0.000) I (0.000) (0.000) REGD Yes Yes Yes Yes F-statistic No. of observations Hansen test (i) p-value First-stage F-statistic (ii) Anderson test (iii) p-value Cragg Donald test (iv) C-test (v) p-value Between brackets, standard errors. Reported heteroskedastic-robust. IV excluded instruments: distance to OECD, dummies for landlocked and small island. (i) Hansen J-statistics over-identification test. (ii) F-statistics for first-stage regression instrument relevance. (iii) Anderson LR statistics instrument relevance. (iv) Cragg Donald statistics instrument relevance. (v) C-test exogeneity of ln(m 90 ). * pb0.1. ** pb0.05. *** pb0.01. the negative and significant impact of the initial human capital stock. This suggests the existence of a conditional convergence process between 1990 and The share of the young cohort S15/24 has negative sign. This can be explained by the fact that human capital formation is lower in poor countries with high fertility and population growth rates. The share of the older cohort S49/55 has negative sign, indicating that a lower turnover of the population reduces the growth rate of human capital. Urbanization has a positive and significant impact on human capital formation. Regional dummies are not reported in the table. In all specifications, the sub-saharan dummy is significant and negative. The dummies for East Asia and Pacific and Eastern Europe and Central Asia are significant and positive. There is no significant effect for Latin America and Middle East and North Africa. In every IV regression, the instruments satisfy the relevance and validity conditions. Indeed, the Hansen statistic has high p-values, suggesting that the null hypothesis is not rejected and the instrument excludability requirement is satisfied. The first-stage statistics support instrument relevance and strength: the F-statistics are above 10; the low p-values of the Anderson canonical correlation likelihood ratio test, indicate rejection of the irrelevance hypothesis. The Cragg Donald weak identification test rejects the weakness of the instruments. However, the C-tests strongly suggest rejection of endogeneity. This indicates that the variable ln(m 90 ) can be treated as exogenous. It follows that the OLS method is the most appropriate estimation technique. Table 2 Public education subsidy, ln(σ 90 ) OLS 1 IV 1 OLS 2 IV 2 ln(m 90 ) (0.041) (0.075) (0.032) (0.057) I (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) RLAW (0.117) (0.138) (0.109) (0.124) MINC (0.136) (0.148) (0.130) (0.125) R (0.000) (0.000) REGD Yes Yes Yes Yes F-statistic No. of observations Hansen test (i) p-value First-stage F-statistic (ii) Anderson test (iii) p-value Cragg Donald test (iv) C-test (v) p-value Between brackets, standard errors. Reported heteroskedastic-robust. IV excluded instruments: distance to OECD, landlocked dummy. (i) Hansen J-statistics over-identification test. (ii) F-statistics for first-stage regression instrument relevance. (iii) Anderson LR statistics instrument relevance. (iv) Cragg Donald statistics instrument relevance. (v) C-test exogeneity of ln(m 90 ). * pb0.1. ** pb0.05. *** pb0.01.

9 F. Docquier et al. / Journal of Development Economics 86 (2008) Fig. 2. Net effect of skilled migration on the proportion of skilled. Thus, based on the F-statistic, the OLS 2 model appears to be the superior specification. The growth rate of human capital between 1990 and 2000 exhibits an elasticity between 3.2 and 4.2% with respect to skilled migration (Beine et al. (in press) found 4.8%) and an elasticity of 12% with respect to public subsidies. Appendix A.3 discusses the robustness of these results Results for the subsidy equation Table 2 gives the OLS and IV estimates for education expenditures per student. In all regressions, we obtain a negative and significant impact of ln(m 90 ) on the subsidy rate. We note that the coefficients of ln(m 90 ) are biased downward in OLS estimations models compared to their magnitudes in IV models. The quality of governance (RLAW) is an important factor, significantly and positively affecting public education subsidies. Subsidies are significantly higher in middle-income countries; remittances and investments have no effect on education expenditures per student. All regional dummies proved to be significant and positive (compared to the reference region, South Asia). The p-values associated with the Chi-square statistics of the C-test suggests the variable ln(m 90 ) is not exogenous. The implication is that OLS estimates are not consistent and that the IV estimation technique is therefore more appropriate. Thus, the estimated coefficients of model IV2 (the best specification in the table given the F-statistic) indicate a strong and highly significant relationship between these two variables: the average elasticity of public education subsidies to skilled migration rates amounts to Such a result is consistent with the main prediction of our theoretical model. For IV regressions, F-tests on excluded instruments indicate that these are jointly significant in predicting the endogenous regressor, ln(m 90 ). The Anderson relevance tests suggest that these instruments as a set are relevant and strong predictors of ln(m 90 ). The Cragg Donald statistics exceed the critical value of 9.08 (at least in model IV2), which imply a bias relative to OLS of less than 10% (Stock and Yogo, 2002). The over-identification tests (Hansen J-statistic) do not reject the null hypothesis that the instruments are independent of the second-stage disturbance terms at the 5% level of significance Brain drain and human capital accumulation Let us now use our empirical findings to simulate the effect of skilled migration on human capital accumulation. We use a counterfactual experiment, which consists of setting the 1990 skilled emigration rate to the level of the unskilled rate, P m The unskilled migration rate may be considered as a minimal emigration rate given country characteristics such as size, geographic proximity, colonial and linguistic 8 For a couple of countries where the unskilled emigration is very close to zero, we impose a lower bound equal to one tenth of the skilled emigration rate. Since we use a log specification, this avoids unrealistic effects.

10 272 F. Docquier et al. / Journal of Development Economics 86 (2008) Fig. 3. Net effect of skilled emigration on the number of skilled residents. links with OECD members and political factors at origin. Hence, our experiment consists of minimizing the size of the brain drain. We first use Eq. (13) to simulate the impact on education subsidies, rˆ90, and then use Eq. (12) to predict the 2000 level of human capital among natives, Ĥ 00. Note that a similar method is used in Beine et al. (in press) to compute the effect of skilled migration on human capital accumulation between 1990 and However, taking education subsidies as exogenous (BDR method) potentially overestimates the size of the incentive effect on human capital formation. We compare the observed and hypothetical proportions/numbers of skilled residents. Fig. 2 gives the simulated impact of skilled emigration on the proportion of skilled among residents (intensive measure of human capital) and Fig. 3 gives the impact on the number of skilled residents (extensive measure). A positive amount means that the country benefit from skilled migration, i.e. has more human capital than in the counterfactual scenario where the brain drain is reduced. The grey lines reports simulations with exogenous subsidies (BDR method). Setting skilled migration rates to unskilled migration rates induces a rise in the subsidy rate in almost all countries. 9 On average the rate is multiplied by about Notwithstanding the rise in education subsidies, reducing skilled migration rates would have a negative impact on the proportion of educated in 20 countries and 9 The only exception is Bulgaria where the unskilled emigration rate exceeds the skilled emigration rate. a negative impact on the number of educated in 18 countries (out of 108 countries). Such brain gain or beneficial brain drain cases are obtained in large countries combining relatively low levels of human capital and low skilled emigration rates, confirming the BDR results. The group of winners includes large countries (e.g., China, India, Brazil, Bangladesh) which represent a large fraction of the population residing in developing countries. Our results are more pessimistic than those of Beine et al. (in press) who treat education subsidies as exogenous (see grey line on Figs. 2 and 3). The BDR method gives 51 winners, larger gains or smaller losses. In addition, BDR predict that the brain drain generates a positive net gain for developing countries as a whole (+ 2.2% of post-secondary graduates). Endogenizing education subsidies increases the number of losers and the size of the losses. On the whole, the brain drain induces a net negative effect on the total number of postsecondary educated in the developing world ( 2.7%). 4. Conclusion One of the argument levelled at the brain drain is the loss of investment of public spending in the education of emigrants. How do developing countries adjust their education policies to skilled migration? What is the resulting effect of their policy on human capital accumulation? Our paper addresses these questions both theoretically and empirically. Assuming exogenous education policies, the new literature on the brain drain asserts that high-skill

11 F. Docquier et al. / Journal of Development Economics 86 (2008) migration entails beneficial feedback effects for the source countries. Authors such as Vidal (1998), Mountford (1999) and Stark and Wang (2002) argue that migration prospects may foster education investments in developing countries, thus making it possible for a brain drain to be beneficial to the source country. Survey data and macroeconometric studies confirm that possibility. Endogenizing education subsidies, our theoretical analysis reveals that a positive emigration can be desirable if, and only if, tax distortions are sufficiently high, i.e. if the local government is unable to decentralize the first best solution with non-distortive tax-transfers. Conversely, when tax distortions are low, impeding skilled emigration would be socially better. The optimal emigration rate is zero. Hence, resorting to the brain drain must be considered as a second best policy option that reflects the inability of the government to costlessly use domestic instruments. Some recent studies such as Beine et al. (2001, in press) provide empirical support for the beneficial brain drain hypothesis, abstracting from various indirect effects on skill premia, fiscal policies, etc. In particular, they disregard possible crowding out fiscal effects on public subsidies. Investigating the empirical relationship between education subsidies and migration prospects, we obtain a significant and negative relationship in a cross-section of 108 countries. Skilled migration and public subsidies are empirical substitutes. We then revisit the country specific effects of skilled migration on human capital by considering public subsidies as endogenous. Our counterfactual experiment consists in setting the skilled emigration rate to the unskilled rate. We then compute the hypothetical human capital change between 1990 and The endogeneity of public subsidies strongly reduces the relative number of losers, increases the size of the losses and reduces the size of the gains in other countries. Obviously, focusing on human capital formation, our analysis abstracts from all other indirect channels though which migration affects the sending country (through return migration, remittances, network effects, etc.) or the domestic return to education (wage rate, skill premium, etc.). Although the perspective of a beneficial brain drain appears more limited than in previous studies, we still obtained winning countries. However, the net effect on the total number of educated workers residing in the developing world becomes negative. Acknowledgements We thank Raouf Boucekkine, Simon Commander, David De la Croix, Saul Estrin, Gordon Hanson, Omar Licandro, Fabio Mariani, Caglar Ozden, Christopher Parsons, Sergio Perelman, Hillel Rapoport and Maurice Schiff for their comments. Helpful remarks and suggestions from referees were appreciated. A previous version of this paper was presented at the workshop in Development Economics (Louvain-La-Neuve, Sept 2005) and the CNEM seminar (London Business School, Nov 2005). Ousmane Faye gratefully acknowledges financial support from the Government of Luxemburg ( Bourse Formation- Recherche, BFR ). The usual disclaimers apply. Appendix A A.1. Proof of Proposition 1 Using A t +1 =na t (1 m t +1 ), the planner maximizes FB in Eq. (5) with respect to h t +1, e t and m t +1. This gives the following first order conditions: Ao FB ¼ b t A tþ1 w þ b tþ1 A tþ2 Rwa b t A tþ1 k t þ b tþ1 A tþ2 k tþ1 e a tþ1 Ah dhd 1 tþ1 ¼ 0 tþ1 Ao FB ¼ b t A tþ1 R þ b t A tþ1 k t ae a 1 t h d t ¼ 0 Ae t Ao FB ¼ b t A t nc tþ1 b0: Am tþ1 ¼ w½1þbnrwaš Focusing on the steady state, the social return to human capital, k FB ss 1 bnd, exceeds the private return on human capital, w. From the first order condition with respect to m t +1, emigration deteriorates social welfare. The optimal emigration rate is therefore zero.

12 274 F. Docquier et al. / Journal of Development Economics 86 (2008) A.2. Proof of Proposition 2 At the steady state, the first order conditions of Eq. (8) are: (i) 0=w[1+βn(1 m)rwa] λ[1 βn(1 m)δ]+βn(1 m)μα[w+m(w w)]δh δ 1 (ii) 0= R(1 σ t )+λαe α 1 h δ ρnσ μr(1 σ)(1 α)e α (iii) 0=R ρn+μre (iv) 0= R+ρn[1 c (τ y )] (v) 0 C +μ(1 m)αh δ (w w). Clearly, when c (τ y )=0, conditions (iii) (iv) imply ρn=r and μ=0. From condition (v), the optimal migration rate is zero. From condition (i), the social return on human capital λ is identical to the first best value, λ FB ss. Consequently, the first best solution emerges. When perception costs are positive, c (τ y )N0, we have ρnnr, μn0 so that the optimal migration rate can be positive. Assuming linear efficiency costs (c (τ y )=γ) and combining conditions (i), (iii) and (iv), the social return on human capital is given by: n h io w 1 þ bnð1 mþrwa þ bnð1 mþ gda k SB 1 g 1 þ m ðw4 wþ w ss ¼ 1 bnð1 mþd From condition (ii), the optimal level of education amounts to: " ss ¼ ahd ð1 gþk SB ss þ ag ð w þ mw4 ð w ÞÞ # 1 R e SB 1 a Combining these results and using Eq. (1) yields: h SB ss ¼ aw/ ð g; m Þ R a 1 a d ð1 gþ½1þbnð1 mþrwašþgbnð1 mþad½1þmw4 w w Šþag½1þm with /ðg; mþu w4 w w Š½1 bnð1 mþdš 1 bnð1 mþd, which is, for reasonable values of the parameters, a decreasing function of γ and m (at least for γ ranging from 0 to 0.5 and for any m). Note that, we have w/ ð0; 0Þ ¼ w½1þbnrwaš 1 bnd ¼ k FB ss. Decentralizing the second best solution requires a subsidy rate equal to: r SB ss ¼ / ðg; m w4 w Þ 1 m ð w / ðg; mþ such that the subsidy rate is a decreasing function of both γ and m: 1 þ m ð w4 w Þ /V m ð w4 w Þ / Ar Am ¼ w w / 2 b0 1 þ m ð w4 w Þ /V g Ar Ag ¼ w / 2 b0: Þ It should be noted that σ SB ss can be negative for high emigration rates (when / ðg; mþb1 þ m w4 w w ). The budget constraint requires s y ss ¼ rsb ss esb ss = ð1 gþ.

13 F. Docquier et al. / Journal of Development Economics 86 (2008) A.3. Human capital regressions Robustness check The incentive effect of skilled emigration on human capital accumulation remains positive and significant whatever the measures of brain drain used. Table A reports replications of the specifications OLS2 and IV2 of Table 1 distinguishing different ages of entry. We only report estimates for the three main explanatory variables although results for other controls and diagnostic tests are almost identical to those in Table 1. Clearly, Table A supports the robustness of the incentive mechanism and the positive effect of public education subsidies. In previous version of the paper, we investigated the robustness of this mechanism using functional forms other than the log-linear specification we have adopted here. The incentive mechanism depicted in Table 1 is robust to the alternative specifications: results with m 90 or ln(1+m 90 ); rather than ln(m 90 ), can be obtained upon request. It could also be argued that further efficiency gains would be obtained by estimating both equations simultaneously as a system. We tested our model using a three-stage least squares (3SLS) system and obtained similar results. 10 Table A Log ratio of human capital (H J,00 =H J,90 ), controlling for age of entry J=12 J=18 J=22 OLS IV OLS IV OLS IV ln(m J,90 ) (0.015) (0.036) (0.016) (0.036) (0.016) (0.036) ln(h J,90 ) (0.038) (0.040) (0.038) (0.040) (0.038) (0.040) ln(σ 90 ) (0.049) (0.053) (0.048) (0.051) (0.048) (0.051) Other controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes F-statistic No. of observations Between brackets, standard errors. Reported heteroskedastic-robust. pb0.1. pb0.05. pb0.01. References Barro, R., Sala-i-Martin, X., Economic Growth. McGraw Hill. Batista, C., Lacuesta, A., Vicente, P.C., Brain Drain or Brain Gain? Micro Evidence from an African Success Story, Discussion Paper No. 3055, IZA-Bonn. Becker, G.S., Glaeser, E.L., Murphy, K.M., Population and economic growth. American Economic Review 89 (2), Beine, M., Docquier, F., Rapoport, H., Brain drain and economic growth: theory and evidence. Journal of Development Economics 64 (1), Beine, M., Docquier, F., Rapoport, H., Measuring international skilled migration: new estimates controlling for age of entry. World Bank Economic Review 21, Beine, M., Docquier, F., Rapoport, H., in press. Brain drain and human capital formation in developing countries: winners and losers. Economic Journal. Commander, S., Chanda, R., Kangasniemi, M., Winters, L.A., Must Skilled Migration be a Brain Drain? Evidence from the Indian Software Industry, Discussion Paper No. 1422, IZA-Bonn. Docquier, F., Marfouk, A., International migration by educational attainment ( ). In: Ozden, C., Schiff, M. (Eds.), 10 These results can be obtained upon request to the authors. International Migration, Remittances and Development, Chapter 5. MIT Press, New York. Galor, O., Weil, D., From the Malthusian stagnation to modern growth. American Economic Review 89, Hall, R.E., Jones, Ch. I., Why do some countries produce so much more output per worker than others? The Quarterly Journal of Economics 114 (1), Kangasniemi, M., Winters, L.A., Commander, S., Is the Medical Brain Drain Beneficial? Evidence from Overseas Doctors in the UK, Mimeo, London Business School. Kaufmann, D., Kraay, A., Mastruzzi, M., Governance Matters III: Governance Indicators for , World Bank Policy Research Working Paper Kremer, M., Population growth and technological change: 1,000,000 B.C. to Quarterly Journal of Economics August. Lagerloef, N.P., From Malthus to modern growth: can epidemics explain the three regimes. International Economic Review 44 (2), Lucas, R.E.B., International Migration Regimes and Economic Development, Report for the Expert Group on Development Issues (EGDI), Swedish Ministry of Foreign Affairs. Mountford, A., Can a brain drain be good for growth in the source economy? Journal of Development Economics 53 (2),

Is migration a good substitute for education subsidies?

Is migration a good substitute for education subsidies? Is migration a good substitute for education subsidies? Frédéric Docquier, Ousmane Faye & Pierre Pestieau October 2007 Docquier, Faye, Pestieau (Institute) Migration, substitute for subsidies? October

More information

Supplemental Appendix

Supplemental Appendix Supplemental Appendix Michel Beine a, Frédéric Docquier b and Hillel Rapoport c a University of Luxemburg and Université Libre de Bruxelles b FNRS and IRES, Université Catholique de Louvain c Department

More information

Brain drain and Human Capital Formation in Developing Countries. Are there Really Winners?

Brain drain and Human Capital Formation in Developing Countries. Are there Really Winners? Brain drain and Human Capital Formation in Developing Countries. Are there Really Winners? José Luis Groizard Universitat de les Illes Balears Ctra de Valldemossa km. 7,5 07122 Palma de Mallorca Spain

More information

Measuring International Skilled Migration: New Estimates Controlling for Age of Entry

Measuring International Skilled Migration: New Estimates Controlling for Age of Entry Measuring International Skilled Migration: New Estimates Controlling for Age of Entry Michel Beine a,frédéricdocquier b and Hillel Rapoport c a University of Luxemburg and Université Libre de Bruxelles

More information

THE BRAIN DRAIN + Frédéric Docquier a and Hillel Rapoport b. FNRS and IRES, Université Catholique de Louvain

THE BRAIN DRAIN + Frédéric Docquier a and Hillel Rapoport b. FNRS and IRES, Université Catholique de Louvain THE BRAIN DRAIN + Frédéric Docquier a and Hillel Rapoport b a FNRS and IRES, Université Catholique de Louvain b Department of Economics, Bar-Ilan University, EQUIPPE, Universités de Lille, and Center for

More information

Immigration and Internal Mobility in Canada Appendices A and B. Appendix A: Two-step Instrumentation strategy: Procedure and detailed results

Immigration and Internal Mobility in Canada Appendices A and B. Appendix A: Two-step Instrumentation strategy: Procedure and detailed results Immigration and Internal Mobility in Canada Appendices A and B by Michel Beine and Serge Coulombe This version: February 2016 Appendix A: Two-step Instrumentation strategy: Procedure and detailed results

More information

Remittances and the Brain Drain: Evidence from Microdata for Sub-Saharan Africa

Remittances and the Brain Drain: Evidence from Microdata for Sub-Saharan Africa Remittances and the Brain Drain: Evidence from Microdata for Sub-Saharan Africa Julia Bredtmann 1, Fernanda Martinez Flores 1,2, and Sebastian Otten 1,2,3 1 RWI, Rheinisch-Westfälisches Institut für Wirtschaftsforschung

More information

International Remittances and Brain Drain in Ghana

International Remittances and Brain Drain in Ghana Journal of Economics and Political Economy www.kspjournals.org Volume 3 June 2016 Issue 2 International Remittances and Brain Drain in Ghana By Isaac DADSON aa & Ryuta RAY KATO ab Abstract. This paper

More information

Migration and Labor Market Outcomes in Sending and Southern Receiving Countries

Migration and Labor Market Outcomes in Sending and Southern Receiving Countries Migration and Labor Market Outcomes in Sending and Southern Receiving Countries Giovanni Peri (UC Davis) Frederic Docquier (Universite Catholique de Louvain) Christian Dustmann (University College London)

More information

Tilburg University. Can a brain drain be good for growth? Mountford, A.W. Publication date: Link to publication

Tilburg University. Can a brain drain be good for growth? Mountford, A.W. Publication date: Link to publication Tilburg University Can a brain drain be good for growth? Mountford, A.W. Publication date: 1995 Link to publication Citation for published version (APA): Mountford, A. W. (1995). Can a brain drain be good

More information

Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation

Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation S. Roy*, Department of Economics, High Point University, High Point, NC - 27262, USA. Email: sroy@highpoint.edu Abstract We implement OLS,

More information

Skilled Migration and Business Networks

Skilled Migration and Business Networks Open Econ Rev DOI 10.1007/s11079-008-9102-8 RESEARCH ARTICLE Skilled Migration and Business Networks Frédéric Docquier Elisabetta Lodigiani Springer Science + Business Media, LLC 2008 Abstract The role

More information

Human capital transmission and the earnings of second-generation immigrants in Sweden

Human capital transmission and the earnings of second-generation immigrants in Sweden Hammarstedt and Palme IZA Journal of Migration 2012, 1:4 RESEARCH Open Access Human capital transmission and the earnings of second-generation in Sweden Mats Hammarstedt 1* and Mårten Palme 2 * Correspondence:

More information

Quantitative Analysis of Migration and Development in South Asia

Quantitative Analysis of Migration and Development in South Asia 87 Quantitative Analysis of Migration and Development in South Asia Teppei NAGAI and Sho SAKUMA Tokyo University of Foreign Studies 1. Introduction Asia is a region of high emigrant. In 2010, 5 of the

More information

Emigration and source countries; Brain drain and brain gain; Remittances.

Emigration and source countries; Brain drain and brain gain; Remittances. Emigration and source countries; Brain drain and brain gain; Remittances. Mariola Pytliková CERGE-EI and VŠB-Technical University Ostrava, CReAM, IZA, CCP and CELSI Info about lectures: https://home.cerge-ei.cz/pytlikova/laborspring16/

More information

Migration and Education Decisions in a Dynamic General Equilibrium Framework

Migration and Education Decisions in a Dynamic General Equilibrium Framework Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Pol i c y Re s e a rc h Wo r k i n g Pa p e r 4775 Migration and Education Decisions

More information

Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US

Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US Ben Ost a and Eva Dziadula b a Department of Economics, University of Illinois at Chicago, 601 South Morgan UH718 M/C144 Chicago,

More information

The Wage Effects of Immigration and Emigration

The Wage Effects of Immigration and Emigration The Wage Effects of Immigration and Emigration Frederic Docquier (UCL) Caglar Ozden (World Bank) Giovanni Peri (UC Davis) December 20 th, 2010 FRDB Workshop Objective Establish a minimal common framework

More information

The transition of corruption: From poverty to honesty

The transition of corruption: From poverty to honesty February 26 th 2009 Kiel and Aarhus The transition of corruption: From poverty to honesty Erich Gundlach a, *, Martin Paldam b,1 a Kiel Institute for the World Economy, P.O. Box 4309, 24100 Kiel, Germany

More information

English Deficiency and the Native-Immigrant Wage Gap

English Deficiency and the Native-Immigrant Wage Gap DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 7019 English Deficiency and the Native-Immigrant Wage Gap Alfonso Miranda Yu Zhu November 2012 Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit Institute for the Study of Labor

More information

Brain Drain and Emigration: How Do They Affect Source Countries?

Brain Drain and Emigration: How Do They Affect Source Countries? The University of Akron IdeaExchange@UAkron Honors Research Projects The Dr. Gary B. and Pamela S. Williams Honors College Spring 2019 Brain Drain and Emigration: How Do They Affect Source Countries? Nicholas

More information

Riccardo Faini (Università di Roma Tor Vergata, IZA and CEPR)

Riccardo Faini (Università di Roma Tor Vergata, IZA and CEPR) Immigration in a globalizing world Riccardo Faini (Università di Roma Tor Vergata, IZA and CEPR) The conventional wisdom about immigration The net welfare effect of unskilled immigration is at best small

More information

On the robustness of brain gain estimates M. Beine, F. Docquier and H. Rapoport. Discussion Paper

On the robustness of brain gain estimates M. Beine, F. Docquier and H. Rapoport. Discussion Paper On the robustness of brain gain estimates M. Beine, F. Docquier and H. Rapoport Discussion Paper 2009-18 On the robustness of brain gain estimates Michel Beine a, Frédéric Docquier b and Hillel Rapoport

More information

Endogenous antitrust: cross-country evidence on the impact of competition-enhancing policies on productivity

Endogenous antitrust: cross-country evidence on the impact of competition-enhancing policies on productivity Preliminary version Do not cite without authors permission Comments welcome Endogenous antitrust: cross-country evidence on the impact of competition-enhancing policies on productivity Joan-Ramon Borrell

More information

Brain Drain in Developing Countries

Brain Drain in Developing Countries The World Bank Economic Review Advance Access published June 13, 2007 Brain Drain in Developing Countries Frédéric Docquier, Olivier Lohest, and Abdeslam Marfouk An original data set on international migration

More information

Corruption and quality of public institutions: evidence from Generalized Method of Moment

Corruption and quality of public institutions: evidence from Generalized Method of Moment Document de travail de la série Etudes et Documents E 2008.13 Corruption and quality of public institutions: evidence from Generalized Method of Moment Gbewopo Attila 1 University Clermont I, CERDI-CNRS

More information

Direction of trade and wage inequality

Direction of trade and wage inequality This article was downloaded by: [California State University Fullerton], [Sherif Khalifa] On: 15 May 2014, At: 17:25 Publisher: Routledge Informa Ltd Registered in England and Wales Registered Number:

More information

Trading Goods or Human Capital

Trading Goods or Human Capital Trading Goods or Human Capital The Winners and Losers from Economic Integration Micha l Burzyński, Université catholique de Louvain, IRES Poznań University of Economics, KEM michal.burzynski@uclouvain.be

More information

Corruption, Political Instability and Firm-Level Export Decisions. Kul Kapri 1 Rowan University. August 2018

Corruption, Political Instability and Firm-Level Export Decisions. Kul Kapri 1 Rowan University. August 2018 Corruption, Political Instability and Firm-Level Export Decisions Kul Kapri 1 Rowan University August 2018 Abstract In this paper I use South Asian firm-level data to examine whether the impact of corruption

More information

262 Index. D demand shocks, 146n demographic variables, 103tn

262 Index. D demand shocks, 146n demographic variables, 103tn Index A Africa, 152, 167, 173 age Filipino characteristics, 85 household heads, 59 Mexican migrants, 39, 40 Philippines migrant households, 94t 95t nonmigrant households, 96t 97t premigration income effects,

More information

Table A.2 reports the complete set of estimates of equation (1). We distinguish between personal

Table A.2 reports the complete set of estimates of equation (1). We distinguish between personal Akay, Bargain and Zimmermann Online Appendix 40 A. Online Appendix A.1. Descriptive Statistics Figure A.1 about here Table A.1 about here A.2. Detailed SWB Estimates Table A.2 reports the complete set

More information

Wage Effects of High-Skilled Migration: International Evidence

Wage Effects of High-Skilled Migration: International Evidence Wage Effects of High-Skilled Migration: International Evidence Volker Grossmann and David Stadelmann The international migration of high-skilled workers may trigger productivity effects at the macro level

More information

Supplementary information for the article:

Supplementary information for the article: Supplementary information for the article: Happy moves? Assessing the link between life satisfaction and emigration intentions Artjoms Ivlevs Contents 1. Summary statistics of variables p. 2 2. Country

More information

Brain drain and home country institutions

Brain drain and home country institutions Brain drain and home country institutions Frédéric Docquier a, Elisabetta Lodigiani b,hillel Rapoport c and Maurice Schiff d a IRES, Université Catholique de Louvain, IZA, and CReAM b CREA, Université

More information

Is Corruption Anti Labor?

Is Corruption Anti Labor? Is Corruption Anti Labor? Suryadipta Roy Lawrence University Department of Economics PO Box- 599, Appleton, WI- 54911. Abstract This paper investigates the effect of corruption on trade openness in low-income

More information

Immigrant-native wage gaps in time series: Complementarities or composition effects?

Immigrant-native wage gaps in time series: Complementarities or composition effects? Immigrant-native wage gaps in time series: Complementarities or composition effects? Joakim Ruist Department of Economics University of Gothenburg Box 640 405 30 Gothenburg, Sweden joakim.ruist@economics.gu.se

More information

Do Migrants Improve Governance at Home? Evidence from a Voting Experiment

Do Migrants Improve Governance at Home? Evidence from a Voting Experiment Do Migrants Improve Governance at Home? Evidence from a Voting Experiment Catia Batista Trinity College Dublin and IZA Pedro C. Vicente Trinity College Dublin, CSAE-Oxford and BREAD Second International

More information

EXPORT, MIGRATION, AND COSTS OF MARKET ENTRY EVIDENCE FROM CENTRAL EUROPEAN FIRMS

EXPORT, MIGRATION, AND COSTS OF MARKET ENTRY EVIDENCE FROM CENTRAL EUROPEAN FIRMS Export, Migration, and Costs of Market Entry: Evidence from Central European Firms 1 The Regional Economics Applications Laboratory (REAL) is a unit in the University of Illinois focusing on the development

More information

English Deficiency and the Native-Immigrant Wage Gap in the UK

English Deficiency and the Native-Immigrant Wage Gap in the UK English Deficiency and the Native-Immigrant Wage Gap in the UK Alfonso Miranda a Yu Zhu b,* a Department of Quantitative Social Science, Institute of Education, University of London, UK. Email: A.Miranda@ioe.ac.uk.

More information

Can migration reduce educational attainment? Evidence from Mexico * and Stanford Center for International Development

Can migration reduce educational attainment? Evidence from Mexico * and Stanford Center for International Development Can migration reduce educational attainment? Evidence from Mexico * David McKenzie a and Hillel Rapoport b a Development Research Group, World Bank WPS3952 b Department of Economics, Bar-Ilan University,

More information

Can migration reduce educational attainment? Evidence from Mexico *

Can migration reduce educational attainment? Evidence from Mexico * Can migration reduce educational attainment? Evidence from Mexico * David McKenzie, World Bank, IZA and BREAD Hillel Rapoport, Department of Economics, Bar-Ilan University, EQUIPPE, University of Lille

More information

The Analytics of the Wage Effect of Immigration. George J. Borjas Harvard University September 2009

The Analytics of the Wage Effect of Immigration. George J. Borjas Harvard University September 2009 The Analytics of the Wage Effect of Immigration George J. Borjas Harvard University September 2009 1. The question Do immigrants alter the employment opportunities of native workers? After World War I,

More information

Schooling and Cohort Size: Evidence from Vietnam, Thailand, Iran and Cambodia. Evangelos M. Falaris University of Delaware. and

Schooling and Cohort Size: Evidence from Vietnam, Thailand, Iran and Cambodia. Evangelos M. Falaris University of Delaware. and Schooling and Cohort Size: Evidence from Vietnam, Thailand, Iran and Cambodia by Evangelos M. Falaris University of Delaware and Thuan Q. Thai Max Planck Institute for Demographic Research March 2012 2

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE EFFECT OF IMMIGRATION ON PRODUCTIVITY: EVIDENCE FROM US STATES. Giovanni Peri

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE EFFECT OF IMMIGRATION ON PRODUCTIVITY: EVIDENCE FROM US STATES. Giovanni Peri NBER WKG PER SEES THE EFFE OF IMGRATION ON PRODUIVITY: EVEE FROM US STATES Giovanni Peri Working Paper 15507 http://www.nber.org/papers/w15507 NATION BUREAU OF ENOC RESECH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge,

More information

Volume 35, Issue 1. An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach

Volume 35, Issue 1. An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach Volume 35, Issue 1 An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach Brian Hibbs Indiana University South Bend Gihoon Hong Indiana University South Bend Abstract This

More information

65. Broad access to productive jobs is essential for achieving the objective of inclusive PROMOTING EMPLOYMENT AND MANAGING MIGRATION

65. Broad access to productive jobs is essential for achieving the objective of inclusive PROMOTING EMPLOYMENT AND MANAGING MIGRATION 5. PROMOTING EMPLOYMENT AND MANAGING MIGRATION 65. Broad access to productive jobs is essential for achieving the objective of inclusive growth and help Turkey converge faster to average EU and OECD income

More information

Test Bank for Economic Development. 12th Edition by Todaro and Smith

Test Bank for Economic Development. 12th Edition by Todaro and Smith Test Bank for Economic Development 12th Edition by Todaro and Smith Link download full: https://digitalcontentmarket.org/download/test-bankfor-economic-development-12th-edition-by-todaro Chapter 2 Comparative

More information

PROJECTING THE LABOUR SUPPLY TO 2024

PROJECTING THE LABOUR SUPPLY TO 2024 PROJECTING THE LABOUR SUPPLY TO 2024 Charles Simkins Helen Suzman Professor of Political Economy School of Economic and Business Sciences University of the Witwatersrand May 2008 centre for poverty employment

More information

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr Abstract. The Asian experience of poverty reduction has varied widely. Over recent decades the economies of East and Southeast Asia

More information

The (Self-)Selection of International Migrants Reconsidered: Theory and New Evidence

The (Self-)Selection of International Migrants Reconsidered: Theory and New Evidence DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 2052 The (Self-)Selection of International Migrants Reconsidered: Theory and New Evidence Herbert Brücker Cécily Defoort March 2006 Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der

More information

Migration and Tourism Flows to New Zealand

Migration and Tourism Flows to New Zealand Migration and Tourism Flows to New Zealand Murat Genç University of Otago, Dunedin, New Zealand Email address for correspondence: murat.genc@otago.ac.nz 30 April 2010 PRELIMINARY WORK IN PROGRESS NOT FOR

More information

CENTRO STUDI LUCA D AGLIANO DEVELOPMENT STUDIES WORKING PAPERS N January 2017

CENTRO STUDI LUCA D AGLIANO DEVELOPMENT STUDIES WORKING PAPERS N January 2017 WWW.DAGLIANO.UNIMI.IT CENTRO STUDI LUCA D AGLIANO DEVELOPMENT STUDIES WORKING PAPERS N. 421 January 2017 Income disparities, population and migration flows over the 21st century Frédéric Docquier* Joël

More information

A Panel Data Analysis of the Brain Gain

A Panel Data Analysis of the Brain Gain A Panel Data Analysis of the Brain Gain Michel Beine a, Cecily Defoort b and Frédéric Docquier c a University of Luxemburg b EQUIPPE, University of Lille c FNRS and IRES, Catholic University of Louvain,

More information

Migration and Remittances: Causes and Linkages 1. Yoko Niimi and Çağlar Özden DECRG World Bank. Abstract

Migration and Remittances: Causes and Linkages 1. Yoko Niimi and Çağlar Özden DECRG World Bank. Abstract Public Disclosure Authorized Migration and Remittances: Causes and Linkages 1 WPS4087 Public Disclosure Authorized Yoko Niimi and Çağlar Özden DECRG World Bank Abstract Public Disclosure Authorized Public

More information

Remittances and Poverty. in Guatemala* Richard H. Adams, Jr. Development Research Group (DECRG) MSN MC World Bank.

Remittances and Poverty. in Guatemala* Richard H. Adams, Jr. Development Research Group (DECRG) MSN MC World Bank. Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Remittances and Poverty in Guatemala* Richard H. Adams, Jr. Development Research Group

More information

Residential segregation and socioeconomic outcomes When did ghettos go bad?

Residential segregation and socioeconomic outcomes When did ghettos go bad? Economics Letters 69 (2000) 239 243 www.elsevier.com/ locate/ econbase Residential segregation and socioeconomic outcomes When did ghettos go bad? * William J. Collins, Robert A. Margo Vanderbilt University

More information

Unemployment and the Immigration Surplus

Unemployment and the Immigration Surplus Unemployment and the Immigration Surplus Udo Kreickemeier University of Nottingham Michael S. Michael University of Cyprus December 2007 Abstract Within a small open economy fair wage model with unemployment

More information

Educated Migrants: Is There Brain Waste?

Educated Migrants: Is There Brain Waste? 7 Educated Migrants: Is There Brain Waste? Çaḡlar Özden Introduction The welfare of migrants is one of the key issues that need to be considered when migration policies are evaluated. The literature to

More information

Inflation and relative price variability in Mexico: the role of remittances

Inflation and relative price variability in Mexico: the role of remittances Applied Economics Letters, 2008, 15, 181 185 Inflation and relative price variability in Mexico: the role of remittances J. Ulyses Balderas and Hiranya K. Nath* Department of Economics and International

More information

Skilled migration and the transfer of institutional norms 1

Skilled migration and the transfer of institutional norms 1 Skilled migration and the transfer of institutional norms 1 by Michel Beine (University of Luxembourg and CES Ifo) and Khalid Sekkat (University of Brussels and ERF) This version: September 2011 Abstract

More information

Volume 36, Issue 1. Impact of remittances on poverty: an analysis of data from a set of developing countries

Volume 36, Issue 1. Impact of remittances on poverty: an analysis of data from a set of developing countries Volume 6, Issue 1 Impact of remittances on poverty: an analysis of data from a set of developing countries Basanta K Pradhan Institute of Economic Growth, Delhi Malvika Mahesh Institute of Economic Growth,

More information

Investigating the Effects of Migration on Economic Growth in Aging OECD Countries from

Investigating the Effects of Migration on Economic Growth in Aging OECD Countries from Bowdoin College Bowdoin Digital Commons Honors Projects Student Scholarship and Creative Work 5-2017 Investigating the Effects of Migration on Economic Growth in Aging OECD Countries from 1975-2015 Michael

More information

Immigration Policy In The OECD: Why So Different?

Immigration Policy In The OECD: Why So Different? Immigration Policy In The OECD: Why So Different? Zachary Mahone and Filippo Rebessi August 25, 2013 Abstract Using cross country data from the OECD, we document that variation in immigration variables

More information

Migratory pressures in the long run: international migration projections to 2050

Migratory pressures in the long run: international migration projections to 2050 ECONOMIC BULLETIN 4/2017 ANALYTICAL ARTICLES Migratory pressures in the long run: international migration projections to 2050 Rodolfo Campos 5 December 2017 This article presents bilateral international

More information

Skilled migration and sending economies. Testing brain drain and brain gain theories

Skilled migration and sending economies. Testing brain drain and brain gain theories Skilled migration and sending economies. Testing brain drain and brain gain theories José L. Groizard Universitat de les Illes Balears Department of Applied Economics E-mail: joseluis.groizard@uib.es URL:

More information

Demographic Changes and Economic Growth: Empirical Evidence from Asia

Demographic Changes and Economic Growth: Empirical Evidence from Asia Illinois Wesleyan University Digital Commons @ IWU Honors Projects Economics Department 2013 Demographic Changes and Economic Growth: Empirical Evidence from Asia Sijia Song Illinois Wesleyan University,

More information

Demographic Evolutions, Migration and Remittances

Demographic Evolutions, Migration and Remittances Demographic Evolutions, Migration and Remittances Presentation by L Alan Winters, Director, Develeopment Research Group, The World Bank 1. G20 countries are at different stages of a major demographic transition.

More information

Lured in and crowded out? Estimating the impact of immigration on natives education using early XXth century US immigration

Lured in and crowded out? Estimating the impact of immigration on natives education using early XXth century US immigration Lured in and crowded out? Estimating the impact of immigration on natives education using early XXth century US immigration June 2013 Abstract Immigration can impact educational decisions of natives through

More information

EU enlargement and the race to the bottom of welfare states

EU enlargement and the race to the bottom of welfare states Skupnik IZA Journal of Migration 2014, 3:15 ORIGINAL ARTICLE Open Access EU enlargement and the race to the bottom of welfare states Christoph Skupnik Correspondence: christoph.skupnik@fu-berlin.de School

More information

The interaction effect of economic freedom and democracy on corruption: A panel cross-country analysis

The interaction effect of economic freedom and democracy on corruption: A panel cross-country analysis The interaction effect of economic freedom and democracy on corruption: A panel cross-country analysis Author Saha, Shrabani, Gounder, Rukmani, Su, Jen-Je Published 2009 Journal Title Economics Letters

More information

TITLE: AUTHORS: MARTIN GUZI (SUBMITTER), ZHONG ZHAO, KLAUS F. ZIMMERMANN KEYWORDS: SOCIAL NETWORKS, WAGE, MIGRANTS, CHINA

TITLE: AUTHORS: MARTIN GUZI (SUBMITTER), ZHONG ZHAO, KLAUS F. ZIMMERMANN KEYWORDS: SOCIAL NETWORKS, WAGE, MIGRANTS, CHINA TITLE: SOCIAL NETWORKS AND THE LABOUR MARKET OUTCOMES OF RURAL TO URBAN MIGRANTS IN CHINA AUTHORS: CORRADO GIULIETTI, MARTIN GUZI (SUBMITTER), ZHONG ZHAO, KLAUS F. ZIMMERMANN KEYWORDS: SOCIAL NETWORKS,

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE SKILL COMPOSITION OF MIGRATION AND THE GENEROSITY OF THE WELFARE STATE. Alon Cohen Assaf Razin Efraim Sadka

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE SKILL COMPOSITION OF MIGRATION AND THE GENEROSITY OF THE WELFARE STATE. Alon Cohen Assaf Razin Efraim Sadka NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE SKILL COMPOSITION OF MIGRATION AND THE GENEROSITY OF THE WELFARE STATE Alon Cohen Assaf Razin Efraim Sadka Working Paper 14738 http://www.nber.org/papers/w14738 NATIONAL BUREAU

More information

DETERMINANTS OF IMMIGRANTS EARNINGS IN THE ITALIAN LABOUR MARKET: THE ROLE OF HUMAN CAPITAL AND COUNTRY OF ORIGIN

DETERMINANTS OF IMMIGRANTS EARNINGS IN THE ITALIAN LABOUR MARKET: THE ROLE OF HUMAN CAPITAL AND COUNTRY OF ORIGIN DETERMINANTS OF IMMIGRANTS EARNINGS IN THE ITALIAN LABOUR MARKET: THE ROLE OF HUMAN CAPITAL AND COUNTRY OF ORIGIN Aim of the Paper The aim of the present work is to study the determinants of immigrants

More information

The Impact of Migration and Remittances on Household Welfare: Evidence from Vietnam

The Impact of Migration and Remittances on Household Welfare: Evidence from Vietnam Int. Migration & Integration https://doi.org/10.1007/s12134-018-0571-3 The Impact of Migration and Remittances on Household Welfare: Evidence from Vietnam Nguyen Viet Cuong 1,2 & Vu Hoang Linh 3 # Springer

More information

Complementarities between native and immigrant workers in Italy by sector.

Complementarities between native and immigrant workers in Italy by sector. Complementarities between native and immigrant workers in Italy by sector. Ivan Etzo*; Carla Massidda*; Romano Piras** (Draft version: June 2018) Abstract This paper investigates the existence of complementarities

More information

Family Ties, Labor Mobility and Interregional Wage Differentials*

Family Ties, Labor Mobility and Interregional Wage Differentials* Family Ties, Labor Mobility and Interregional Wage Differentials* TODD L. CHERRY, Ph.D.** Department of Economics and Finance University of Wyoming Laramie WY 82071-3985 PETE T. TSOURNOS, Ph.D. Pacific

More information

Brain Drain, Brain Gain, and Economic Growth in China

Brain Drain, Brain Gain, and Economic Growth in China MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Brain Drain, Brain Gain, and Economic Growth in China Wei Ha and Junjian Yi and Junsen Zhang United Nations Development Programme, Economics Department of the Chinese

More information

Migration Policy and Welfare State in Europe

Migration Policy and Welfare State in Europe Migration Policy and Welfare State in Europe Assaf Razin 1 and Jackline Wahba 2 Immigration and the Welfare State Debate Public debate on immigration has increasingly focused on the welfare state amid

More information

Weather Variability, Agriculture and Rural Migration: Evidence from India

Weather Variability, Agriculture and Rural Migration: Evidence from India Weather Variability, Agriculture and Rural Migration: Evidence from India Brinda Viswanathan & K.S. Kavi Kumar Madras School of Economics, Chennai Conference on Climate Change and Development Policy 27

More information

Gains from "Diversity": Theory and Evidence from Immigration in U.S. Cities

Gains from Diversity: Theory and Evidence from Immigration in U.S. Cities Gains from "Diversity": Theory and Evidence from Immigration in U.S. Cities GianmarcoI.P.Ottaviano,(Universita dibolognaandcepr) Giovanni Peri, (UC Davis, UCLA and NBER) March, 2005 Preliminary Abstract

More information

The Effect of Ethnic Residential Segregation on Wages of Migrant Workers in Australia

The Effect of Ethnic Residential Segregation on Wages of Migrant Workers in Australia The Effect of Ethnic Residential Segregation on Wages of Migrant Workers in Australia Mathias G. Sinning Australian National University and IZA Bonn Matthias Vorell RWI Essen March 2009 PRELIMINARY DO

More information

The Determinants and the Selection. of Mexico-US Migrations

The Determinants and the Selection. of Mexico-US Migrations The Determinants and the Selection of Mexico-US Migrations J. William Ambrosini (UC, Davis) Giovanni Peri, (UC, Davis and NBER) This draft March 2011 Abstract Using data from the Mexican Family Life Survey

More information

Do Remittances Promote Household Savings? Evidence from Ethiopia

Do Remittances Promote Household Savings? Evidence from Ethiopia Do Remittances Promote Household Savings? Evidence from Ethiopia Ademe Zeyede 1 African Development Bank Group, Ethiopia Country Office, P.O.Box: 25543 code 1000 Abstract In many circumstances there are

More information

Innovation and Intellectual Property Rights in a. Product-cycle Model of Skills Accumulation

Innovation and Intellectual Property Rights in a. Product-cycle Model of Skills Accumulation Innovation and Intellectual Property Rights in a Product-cycle Model of Skills Accumulation Hung- Ju Chen* ABSTRACT This paper examines the effects of stronger intellectual property rights (IPR) protection

More information

Household Inequality and Remittances in Rural Thailand: A Lifecycle Perspective

Household Inequality and Remittances in Rural Thailand: A Lifecycle Perspective Household Inequality and Remittances in Rural Thailand: A Lifecycle Perspective Richard Disney*, Andy McKay + & C. Rashaad Shabab + *Institute of Fiscal Studies, University of Sussex and University College,

More information

International Migration and Gender Discrimination among Children Left Behind. Francisca M. Antman* University of Colorado at Boulder

International Migration and Gender Discrimination among Children Left Behind. Francisca M. Antman* University of Colorado at Boulder International Migration and Gender Discrimination among Children Left Behind Francisca M. Antman* University of Colorado at Boulder ABSTRACT: This paper considers how international migration of the head

More information

Female Migration, Human Capital and Fertility

Female Migration, Human Capital and Fertility Female Migration, Human Capital and Fertility Vincenzo Caponi, CREST (Ensai), Ryerson University,IfW,IZA January 20, 2015 VERY PRELIMINARY AND VERY INCOMPLETE Abstract The objective of this paper is to

More information

GEORG-AUGUST-UNIVERSITÄT GÖTTINGEN

GEORG-AUGUST-UNIVERSITÄT GÖTTINGEN GEORG-AUGUST-UNIVERSITÄT GÖTTINGEN FACULTY OF ECONOMIC SCIENCES CHAIR OF MACROECONOMICS AND DEVELOPMENT Bachelor Seminar Economics of the very long run: Economics of Islam Summer semester 2017 Does Secular

More information

International labor migration and social security: Analysis of the transition path

International labor migration and social security: Analysis of the transition path J Popul Econ (2004) 17:535 551 DOI 10.1007/s00148-004-0202-5 International labor migration and social security: Analysis of the transition path Doris Geide-Stevenson 1, Mun S. Ho 2 1 Weber State University,

More information

Differences in remittances from US and Spanish migrants in Colombia. Abstract

Differences in remittances from US and Spanish migrants in Colombia. Abstract Differences in remittances from US and Spanish migrants in Colombia François-Charles Wolff LEN, University of Nantes Liliana Ortiz Bello LEN, University of Nantes Abstract Using data collected among exchange

More information

Chapter 9. Labour Mobility. Introduction

Chapter 9. Labour Mobility. Introduction Chapter 9 Labour Mobility McGraw-Hill/Irwin Labor Economics, 4 th edition Copyright 2008 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. 9-2 Introduction Existing allocation of workers and firms is

More information

Economic Freedom and Economic Performance: The Case MENA Countries

Economic Freedom and Economic Performance: The Case MENA Countries The Journal of Middle East and North Africa Sciences 016; () Economic Freedom and Economic Performance: The Case Countries Noha Emara Economics Department, utgers University, United States Noha.emara@rutgers.edu

More information

Can migration prospects reduce educational attainments? *

Can migration prospects reduce educational attainments? * Can migration prospects reduce educational attainments? * David McKenzie a and Hillel Rapoport b a Department of Economics, Stanford University, and World Bank Development Research Group b Department of

More information

HIGH SKILLED EMIGRATION AND HUMAN CAPITAL: A THEORETICAL AND EMPIRICAL ESSAY FOR THE CASE OF MIDDLE-INCOME COUNTRIES

HIGH SKILLED EMIGRATION AND HUMAN CAPITAL: A THEORETICAL AND EMPIRICAL ESSAY FOR THE CASE OF MIDDLE-INCOME COUNTRIES HIGH SKILLED EMIGRATION AND HUMAN CAPITAL: A THEORETICAL AND EMPIRICAL ESSAY FOR THE CASE OF MIDDLE-INCOME COUNTRIES Mohamed KOUNI, Assistant professor in Economics at the Higher Institute of Business

More information

I ll marry you if you get me a job Marital assimilation and immigrant employment rates

I ll marry you if you get me a job Marital assimilation and immigrant employment rates The current issue and full text archive of this journal is available at www.emeraldinsight.com/0143-7720.htm IJM 116 PART 3: INTERETHNIC MARRIAGES AND ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE I ll marry you if you get me

More information

An Analysis of Rural to Urban Labour Migration in India with Special Reference to Scheduled Castes and Schedules Tribes

An Analysis of Rural to Urban Labour Migration in India with Special Reference to Scheduled Castes and Schedules Tribes International Journal of Interdisciplinary and Multidisciplinary Studies (IJIMS), 2015, Vol 2, No.10,53-58. 53 Available online at http://www.ijims.com ISSN: 2348 0343 An Analysis of Rural to Urban Labour

More information

The Trade Liberalization Effects of Regional Trade Agreements* Volker Nitsch Free University Berlin. Daniel M. Sturm. University of Munich

The Trade Liberalization Effects of Regional Trade Agreements* Volker Nitsch Free University Berlin. Daniel M. Sturm. University of Munich December 2, 2005 The Trade Liberalization Effects of Regional Trade Agreements* Volker Nitsch Free University Berlin Daniel M. Sturm University of Munich and CEPR Abstract Recent research suggests that

More information

Immigration, Information, and Trade Margins

Immigration, Information, and Trade Margins Immigration, Information, and Trade Margins Shan Jiang November 7, 2007 Abstract Recent theories suggest that better information in destination countries could reduce firm s fixed export costs, lower uncertainty

More information

Split Decisions: Household Finance when a Policy Discontinuity allocates Overseas Work

Split Decisions: Household Finance when a Policy Discontinuity allocates Overseas Work Split Decisions: Household Finance when a Policy Discontinuity allocates Overseas Work Michael Clemens and Erwin Tiongson Review of Economics and Statistics (Forthcoming) Marian Atallah Presented by: Mohamed

More information

Migration, Intermediate Inputs and Real Wages

Migration, Intermediate Inputs and Real Wages Migration, Intermediate Inputs and Real Wages by Tuvana Pastine Bilkent University Economics Department 06533 Ankara, Turkey and Ivan Pastine Bilkent University Economics Department 06533 Ankara, Turkey

More information