EXPORT, MIGRATION, AND COSTS OF MARKET ENTRY EVIDENCE FROM CENTRAL EUROPEAN FIRMS

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "EXPORT, MIGRATION, AND COSTS OF MARKET ENTRY EVIDENCE FROM CENTRAL EUROPEAN FIRMS"

Transcription

1 Export, Migration, and Costs of Market Entry: Evidence from Central European Firms 1 The Regional Economics Applications Laboratory (REAL) is a unit in the University of Illinois focusing on the development and use of analytical models for urban and region economic development. The purpose of the Discussion Papers is to circulate intermediate and final results of this research among readers within and outside REAL. The opinions and conclusions expressed in the papers are those of the authors and do not necessarily represent those of the University of Illinois. All requests and comments should be directed to Geoffrey J. D. Hewings, Director, Regional Economics Applications Laboratory, 607 South Mathews, Urbana, IL, , phone (217) , FAX (217) Web page: EXPORT, MIGRATION, AND COSTS OF MARKET ENTRY EVIDENCE FROM CENTRAL EUROPEAN FIRMS Dieter Pennerstorfer REAL 11-T-09 November, 2011 This working paper has also been published in the WIFO Working Paper Series, No. 405 (2011).

2 Export, Migration, and Costs of Market Entry: Evidence from Central European Firms 1 Dieter Pennerstorfer 2 Abstract: In this article I analyze the export behavior of firms located in different Central European countries (Austria, Hungary, Czech Republic and Slovakia) with respect to migration. Ever since the seminal article by Gould (1994) on immigrant links to their home country and due to empirical research following his contribution, it is a well established result that immigrants from a particular country spur exports to and imports from that destination. Chaney (2008) shows that a decrease in fixed costs of exporting increases the number of exporters (extensive margin), whereas a reduction in variable costs also increases the volume exported by each exporting firm (intensive margin). Empirical contributions using firm-level data focus on various aspects influencing costs of exporting (like spillover effects of nearby firms (Sinani and Hobdari, 2010; Silvente and Geménez, 2007) or financial factors (Berman and Héricourt, 2010)), but leave out the issue of migration. I combine detailed information coming from a questionnaire conducted among 8,300 firms on the export behavior to different countries with regional data on migration from the European Labor Force Survey (LFS). I find evidence that both the propensity to export and to a much smaller extent the volume of sales of exporting firms to a particular destination is higher for firms located in regions with a larger number of immigrants from that country. I conclude that migrants mainly reduce fixed costs of exporting. Keywords: Firm-level data; Export destinations; Immigrants; Margins of trade JEL classification: D21; F22; F1; R12 1. Introduction and Related Literature It has been quite a while since Ravenstein (1885) has formulated seven laws of migration to explain patterns of migration flows on the eve of the 19 th century. While various causes and consequences of migration have been analyzed ever since, it, however, took more than a century that the issue of migration has been linked to foreign trade. Gould (1994) was the first who analyzed this relationship and introduced costs associated with gaining information on foreign markets in a gravity equation explaining trade flows. In his model, it is costly to get information on foreign markets. These information costs have to be paid in addition to the well-known costs of trade, namely tariffs and transportation costs. Gould (1994) links the costs of getting information of a particular country with the number of immigrants from that country and argues that immigrants can reduce trade costs to their home countries due to their language skills, their information about home country preferences and their ties to the home country that facilitates the development of trust. In an empirical application of his model Gould (1994) analyzes trade 1 This working paper has also been published in the WIFO Working Paper Series, No. 405 (2011); much of the research was conducted while the author with a Visiting Scholar in REAL. 2 Dr. Dieter Pennerstorfer, Austrian Institute of Economic Research (WIFO), Arsenal, Objekt 20, A-1030 Vienna, Austria. dieter.pennerstorfer@wifo.ac.at; Tel.: ; Fax:

3 Export, Migration, and Costs of Market Entry: Evidence from Central European Firms 2 flows between the U.S. and 47 trading partners and shows that the number of immigrants from a particular country has a positive impact on the volume of trade. He finds that exports are more heavily influenced than imports and consumer goods are more strongly affected than producer goods. Gould s (1994) article was followed by a large number of empirical articles investigating the links between trade patterns and immigration. Peri and Requena-Silvente (2010) offer a detailed literature review and show that despite using different data and methods all of the most important empirical articles investigating this relationship find a positive impact of immigration on exports, although the export elasticities with respect to immigration 3 differ considerably and range from 0.07 to Peri and Requena-Silvente (2010) themselves analyze trade flows between Spanish regions to 77 destination countries between 1995 and They find an export elasticity of immigrants of (in their preferred specification) and attribute the largest part (0.082) to a change in the number of transactions and only a small share (0.028) to a change in the average volume per transaction. All articles dealing with immigration and trade use country- and regional-level data. At the firm level to my knowledge no empirical contribution examining the influence of migrants on firms export decisions exists. This is not surprising, as one cannot deduct hypotheses from Gould s (1994) model to explain firm behavior directly: In his gravity model, the production function deals with industries only, but not with firms. Recent theoretical contributions by Melitz (2003) and Chaney (2008) encourage analyzing firm behavior, as they extend the Krugman (1980) gravity model on trade by introducing firm heterogeneity with respect to productivity and distinguish between fixed and variable costs of exporting. Both articles follow Krugman (1980) in assuming monopolistic competition and increasing returns to scale. Their approach to derive trade flows between two countries is different from Gould (1994), as they start with individual firms that are characterized by different productivity levels and derive a threshold productivity level for exporting to a particular country. All firms below this threshold productivity refrain from exporting to this country. Aggregate trade flows are derived by adding up the export volumes of all exporting firms. Chaney s (2008) model is more general than the model endorsed by Melitz (2003), as he allows for asymmetric trading partners. Chaney (2008) analyzes the export decisions of firms depending on the size, remoteness and trade barriers (variable and fixed costs of exporting) of the destination country. He shows that fixed costs influence the decision of firms to start exporting, but it does not affect the export volumes of exporting firms. Variable export costs influence both, the export propensity and the export volumes. An increase in the export volume due to a reduction in export costs can stem from an increase in export volumes of firms that already exported before the reduction in trade costs (the intensive margin ) and/or 3 The export elasticity of immigration is defined as the relative change of export volumes over the relative change of the number of immigrants.

4 Export, Migration, and Costs of Market Entry: Evidence from Central European Firms 3 from new exporters (the extensive margin ). The corresponding elasticities coming from a reduction in variable trade costs τ!" or fixed trade costs f!" between the exporting country i and the importing country j can be split in an intensive and an extensive margin elasticity and stated as: d ln X!" d ln τ!" = γ = σ 1!"#$"%&'$!"#$%&!"#$%&'&%( d ln X!" d ln f!" = + γ σ 1!"#$%&'($!"#$%&!"#$%&'&%( γ σ 1 1 = 0 +!"#$"%&'$!"#$%&!"#$%&'&%( γ σ 1 1!"#$%&'!"!"#$%&!"#$%&'&%( (1) (2) X!" denotes the trade volumes from country i to j. σ indicates the elasticity of substitution between two varieties of goods of the same sectors and γ describes the heterogeneity of firms with respect to productivity. 4 This line of literature spurred research using firm-level data on the export propensity (extensive margin) and the export volume of exporting firms (intensive margin), using different variables indicating export costs. Koenig et al. (2010) investigate the impact of spillover effects on the export decisions of French firms. They analyze a panel data set of more than 8,000 firms for different destination countries at the product level and argue that spillover effects reduce trade costs. They find evidence for positive spillover effects from other firms in the same area if they export the same product or if they export to the same destination country on the probability to start exporting. The spillover effects are strongest from firms that export the same product to the same destination. The authors do not find evidence of spillover effects on the export volumes. 5 They interpret this as a first evidence of export spillovers acting through the fixed rather than the variable cost (p. 622). Berman and Héricourt (2010) analyze around 5,000 firms in 9 developing countries and investigate the impact of financial constraints on entering the export market, but do not distinguish between different destination countries. They find that financial constraints reduce the propensity of becoming an exporter, but do not impact the probability of a firm remaining an exporter, nor influence the export volume. The export volume is measured by the value of exports (sales) and by the share of exports over total sales. The authors interpret these results as evidence of the existence of 4 Chaney (2008) assumes that the productivity of firms is distributed Pareto over the interval 1, + with the shape! parameter γ. He estimates the ratio 2 using data on US firms. Eaton et al. (2008) find a smaller value!!! (around 1.5) for this ratio using the export propensity of French firms. 5 Koening et al. (2010) use export volumes (in tons) rather than export values (sales).

5 Export, Migration, and Costs of Market Entry: Evidence from Central European Firms 4 large sunk costs when entering the export market. The fixed costs of exporting that have to be paid each period might be dramatically lower than the fixed costs for starting to export. In this article I investigate the export decision of firms with respect to the regional stock of immigrants. I evaluate whether an increase in export activities of firms due to a large number of migrants stems from a reduction in fixed or variable costs of exporting. I contribute to the existing literature, as to my knowledge I am the first who explains the export decision of firms by the (regional) stock of migrants. All empirical articles investigating the export behavior using firm-level data leave out the issue of migration. The articles analyzing the link between trade and migration use regional data. One is, however, unable to assess whether migrants affect fixed and/or variable costs of exporting when analyzing regional trade data. 6 The data used in this article include information on the export behavior of 8,300 firms located in four Central European countries (Austria, Czech Republic, Slovakia and Hungary) for different destination countries. In the empirical analysis the export propensity (extensive margin) and the export volume (intensive margin) is estimated. I am therefore able to infer whether an increase in export activity due to a large number of immigrants comes from a reduction in fixed and/or variable costs of exporting. In contrast to most other empirical articles I do not restrict the analysis to firms located in a single country, but analyze the export decisions of firms located in adjacent, but economically and historically very different countries. The remainder of the article is structured as follows: The next section 2 describes the data. In section 3 I present the empirical model and discuss econometric issues. The results of the model estimating the export propensity and the export volume are described in section 4 and section 5 provides different model specifications to demonstrate the robustness of the results. Section 6 concludes. 2. Data The main data source is a survey conducted among 8,299 firms located in Austria, the Czech Republic, Hungary and Slovakia. The survey was carried out between September and November 2010, but firms reported information of In this survey firms were asked whether they make sales abroad and if so, they reported their export behavior for a predetermined set of destination countries. The number of 6 Peri and Requena-Silvente (2010) despite using regional trade data decompose the trade effect of immigrants in its impact on the number of transaction (shipments) and on the change in the average volume of a transaction and denote these effects as extensive and intensive margins, respectively. They use transactions rather than firms to distinguish between these two effects as they cannot identify the exporting firm (only the exporting province). Their estimated effect of immigration on the extensive margin is therefore overestimated at the expense of the intensive margin (when applying the definition used in Chaney, 2008), because an increase in the number of trading partners or in the frequency of transactions between existing trading partners by one firm is (misleadingly) attributed to the extensive margin rather than to the intensive margin.

6 Export, Migration, and Costs of Market Entry: Evidence from Central European Firms 5 destinations ranges between 8 to 16 countries, depending on the country the firm is located. The number of observations for all combinations of countries of origin and destinations is summarized in Table 1. The data collected within the survey also include total sales, volume of sales the firm makes abroad, and the share of export turnover attained in a certain destination country. Based on this information the volume of sales in each destination as well as the share of export turnover in a target country among total sales can be calculated. The data include information on the age and the size (number of employees) of the firm, on ownership and firm structure, on the location of the firm (at the district level) and on the industry the firm belongs to (at the one-digit NACE level). The data set was supplemented by data on GDP and GDP per capita and on population density of the NUTS-2 region, where the firm is located, and on the on GDP and GDP per capita of the destination country. This information comes from Eurostat. 7 Data for the home region are from 2007 (to avoid concerns about endogeneity, see below) and from 2009 for the destination countries. Based on the district of the firm and the capital of the destination country the Euclidean distance is calculated. Data on migration was provided by European Labour Force Survey (LFS) on a regional level (NUTS-2) from < Table 1 around here > Table 2 shows a detailed description of the variables used in the regression analysis. The export propensity is a binary variable and takes the value 1 if a firm exports to a particular destination country. Whereas 1,120 (13,5%) out of 8,299 firms export to at least one of the predetermined destination countries, only 2,575 observations (2,9%) out of more than 87,000 firm-destination pairs report export activity. This low figure can be explained by the data sample that contains mainly small and medium sized enterprises. Note that nearly 40 percent of the firms have less than 10, and more than 80 percent have less than 100 employees. 8 The number of observations for the volume and the share of sales drops to 1,056, as only exporting firms are included in estimating the intensive margin and as firms are more reluctant in reporting their sales. As the survey includes information on total sales, on the volume of sales abroad and on the share of sales abroad (over total sales), observations where the figures reported to these questions were inconsistent are excluded from the sample. To estimate the volume of sales I use the absolute export volume (in million Euros, denoted as Sales ) and the relative export volume (share of sales in a particular destination country over total sales, denoted as Share ). The export value of firms exporting to a particular country averages 2.2 million Euros or 14.9 percent of total sales. Note the large variation, especially when considering the absolute volume of sales. 7 Information on GDP and GDP per capita of Russia, Ukraine and Serbia are not published by Eurostat and come from the IMF. 8 Although most firms in the sample are small and medium sized enterprises, large firms are slightly overrepresented.

7 Export, Migration, and Costs of Market Entry: Evidence from Central European Firms 6 < Table 2 around here > The variable on immigration is calculated as the share of immigrants from a particular country over all residents in each NUTS-2 region. The geographic area, where all firms are located (Austria, Czech Republic, Hungary and Slovakia) includes 28 NUTS-2 regions. I take the share rather than the absolute number to account for differences in size of the regions. The average share of immigrants is 0.25 percent and ranges from 0 to 3.5 percent. I expect that the share of immigrants increases the export propensity, but have no clear prediction on the intensive margin, as immigrants might reduce fixed costs of exports only. Personal ties of migrants to their home country might be important to build trust among trading partners abroad to start export relations, but might have little influence afterwards. Language skills, on the other hand, will not only facilitate to set up export relations, but also to maintain export relation and to expand the export volume in a particular country. The distance between the firm and the (capital of the) destination country is expected to decrease the intensive and the extensive margin. Sharing a common border and speaking the same or a similar language 9 in the home and in the destination country should reduce trade costs and therefore increase the export activities to these countries. I expect to find a similar effect if the destination country is (like all home countries) a member of the European Union (EU). The size of the market in the destination country (GDP and GDP per capita) is expected to increase export propensity and export volume, whereas economic theory does not provide clear predictions on the effect of the size of the home region market. A larger home market could be associated with less need for expanding business abroad. Economic theory predicts a positive impact of a higher population density in the home region, as agglomeration is usually associated with higher productivity (see e.g. Rice et al., 2006), which should increase export participation as well as export volume. I expect that firm size, age, international ownership and belonging to a corporate group increases international activities due to higher productivity and better access to financial resources. Figure 1 gives a first glance on the relationship between the export probability and the share of immigrants. The share of immigrants in a region from a destination country is plotted against the share of firms in the region that export to this particular country. The first (left) figure uses all destination countries, whereas the second (right) figure focuses on the countries where the firms are located (Austria, Czech Republic, Hungary and Slovakia) as export destinations. Both variables are in logarithmic terms. 9 Within the term same or similar language Austria, Germany and Switzerland as well as the Czech Republic and Slovakia are pooled together, although German is the main language only in parts of Switzerland and the Czech and the Slovakian languages are slightly different.

8 Export, Migration, and Costs of Market Entry: Evidence from Central European Firms 7 The figures give a first hint on the positive relationship between immigration and export activities of firms. < Figure 1 around here > 3. Empirical Model and Econometric Concerns To investigate the impact of migration on the export behavior of firms I estimate the influence of migration on the propensity of being an exporter and on the export volume (of exporting firms). Based on Chaney s (2008) terminology the first (second) effect is referred to as the extensive (intensive) margin. Based on the parameter estimates (presented in section 4) I will infer in section 5, whether migrants affect the export decision of firms due to reducing fixed and/or variable costs of exporting. Export Propensity The profit function of firms depending on their export behavior is unobservable, but the sample provides information whether a firm exports to a particular country. I therefore have to deal with a binary endogenous variable, which gives rise to a probit specification: P X!"# > 0 = 1 if α + β ln IMM!" + Ω!" κ + Γ! δ + Ψ! λ + Υ! θ + η! + μ! + ε!"# > 0 0 otherwise (3) The probability of firm f located in region r exporting to destination country d (and therefore X!"# > 0) depends on a constant term, on the share of immigrants (among all residents) from country d settled in region r (IMM rd ), and on other variables depending on both home region r and destination country d (distance, common border, same language), summarized in Ω!". Γ! includes home region specific variables, Ψ! variables varying over destination countries, and Υ! summarizes firm specific effects. α, β, κ, δ, λ and θ are the corresponding parameters to be estimated. η! and μ! are firm-specific and destination country specific fixed effects, to control for unobserved firm or destination country characteristics. 10 ε!"# are the IID disturbances. All variables (except dummy variables) are included in a logarithmic functional form. Obviously, I cannot identify all effects in equation (3), as the firm-level fixed effects wipe out the firm specific variables (Υ! ) and the home region characteristics (Γ! ). The impact of the destination specific 10 I use destination-industry fixed effects (instead of fixed destination effects) in the empirical analysis, but neglect this information in equation (3) to keep the notation as simple as possible. Some empirical specifications include region-specific fixed effects (instead of fixed firm effects), which is also left out in equation (3) for convenience.

9 Export, Migration, and Costs of Market Entry: Evidence from Central European Firms 8 variables (Ψ! ) cannot be identified when destination country fixed effects are present. As the fixed effects control for unobserved variables that might influence both migration and export behavior (and may lead to biased parameter estimates), firm- and destination-fixed effects are included in one model specification. η! and/or μ! are, however, left out in alternative model configurations to be able to estimate the corresponding parameters on firm, region and destination characteristics and to demonstrate the robustness of the main findings. Export Volume To estimate the intensive margin the binary dependent variable from equation (3) is replaced by the logarithmic value of the volume of sales (ln X!"# ), and only those firms that actually export to a particular destination country are considered (if X!"# > 0). The linear relationship can be stated as follows: ln X!"# = ρ + φ ln IMM!" + Ω!" φ + Γ! ω + Ψ! π + Υ! ν + η! + μ! + ε!"# if X!"# > 0 (4) The variables included in equation (4) are the same as in the regression estimating the export propensity. The corresponding parameters are ρ, φ, φ, ω, π and ν. All variables except dummy variables are included in logarithmic terms. Due to the linear character of the model the estimated coefficients can be directly interpreted as elasticities. 11 The model structure with respect to including or excluding fixed firm and/or destination country effects is the same as in the probit model: The preferred model again includes both firm and destination fixed effects. If I exclude firm-level fixed effects, η! is included as a random individual (firm) effect with η! ~IID 0, σ!!. ε!"# is the remainder error with ε!"# ~IID 0, σ!!. Elasticities The extensive margin elasticity, θ, is defined as the relative change in the probability of exporting to a particular destination, associated with a relative change in the stock of immigrants (coming from that country) in the region, where the firm is located. The intensive margin elasticity, ζ, is the relative change in the volume of sales over the relative change in the stock of immigrants. Both elasticities can be summarized as follows: θ P X!"# > 0 IMM!" IMM!" P X!"# > 0 = P X!"# > 0 1 ln IMM!" P X!"# > 0 (5) 11 The parameters of the dummy variables are semi-elasticities.

10 Export, Migration, and Costs of Market Entry: Evidence from Central European Firms 9 ζ X!"# IMM!" IMM!" X!"# = ln X!"# ln IMM!" = φ (6) As the variable on immigration is incorporated in logarithmic terms, the parameter estimates of the regressions on the volume of sales can be directly interpreted as the intensive margin elasticity (ζ = φ). This is not the case in the probit model due to its non-linear character. Based on the regression results I calculate the marginal effect for the average firm (!"!!"#!!!!"!""!" ) and use the marginal effect and the estimated probability of exporting to a particular country (for the average firm) to calculate the extensive margin elasticity (θ). Note that in the probit model the elasticity of the average firm will in general not equal the average elasticity (as in the panel estimation on the volume of sales). 12 Econometric Issues The data sample can be described as an unbalanced panel with firms and destination countries as the two dimensions. As the sample is restricted to one time period, I cannot identify the effect of migration on export behavior over time. The identification stems from the variation of the variable IMM rd over the home regions of the firms and over destination countries. Basically, the variable on migration can be split into a constant (immigration averaged over all regions and all destination countries), into a region-specific deviation from that average (some regions attract more immigrants than others), into a destination country-specific effect (there are more migrants from some countries than from others), and into a part that indicates the deviation of the variable IMM rd from the sum of the constant, and the region- and the destination-specific deviations. In one model specification I include firm and destination-industry fixed effects into the estimation equation. Therefore, the identification of the effect of migrants on the export decision of firms comes from variations of this variables controlling for region and destination effects. Excluding either the firm-level or the destination fixed effects allows for more variation in the data (as differences between regions and/or destination countries matter), but fails to control for unobserved effects, which might lead to biased results. I show that the results of the models are rather robust with respect to the inclusion (or exclusion) of different types of fixed effects. Besides IMM rd, the other variables indicating region and destination characteristics take the expected signs in most model specifications. 12 The definition of the extensive margin elasticity is slightly different to Chaney (2008). He defines the extensive margin as the contribution of the export volumes by firms that start exporting (due to a reduction in fixed or variable export costs). I estimate the impact of a reduction in export costs on the probability of firms to export, but do not take their export volumes into account.

11 Export, Migration, and Costs of Market Entry: Evidence from Central European Firms 10 There are great concerns on the endogeneity of the firm specific variables in the data, especially firm size (number of employees) and age. Bernard and Jensen (1999) not only find that larger firms are more likely to become exporters, but also that employment growth and the probability of survival are higher for exporting firms. The causality between export behavior and these explanatory variables is therefore unclear and the corresponding coefficients might be biased. Articles applying panel data usually take the lagged values of some or all explanatory variables (e.g. Berman and Hèricourt, 2010; Koening et al., 2010), which is not possible using cross-sectional data only. Therefore, all firm-specific variables are left out of the regressions in the preferred specifications in section 4. To test for robustness I include these variables in the regression equation but use these variables only as controls for firm heterogeneity and do not interpret the parameter values and the significance levels of the respective variables. Parameter values and significance levels of migration are hardly affected by the inclusion of firm-specific variables. When using fixed firm effects, these variables drop out of the equation. There might be similar concerns about reverse causality and simultaneity of the estimated effect of the variable on immigration, as foreign activities of a firm might attract migrants from the destination countries either directly or indirectly (as exporting firms are more successful and contribute to a prospering regional economy). Both the direct and the indirect effect caused by a single firm are negligibly small, as the migration variable is calculated on a regional level. Additionally, I lag the migration variable by two years and take the stock of migrants from As the export intensity of firms in a region influences economic variables positively and besides external migration might also lead to population growth due to internal migration I also lag the region-specific variables (GDP, GDP per capita and the population density) by two years. There might be omitted variables that influence both, immigration and export behavior. For example, Meltiz and Ottaviano (2008) show in a theoretical model that agglomeration (bigger markets) leads to (on average) larger and more productive firms. Marshallian externalities might be another reason why firms might be more productive and, therefore, more likely to be exporters in regions with a high firm density. Studies on the location choice of migrants (see, e.g., Nowotny and Pennerstorfer, 2011) find that more agglomerated regions (with respect to population and economic activities) are preferred destinations by new migrants. I address this issue by including the population density of the region where the firm is located as a proxy for agglomeration as well as GDP per capita of that region (both variables lagged by two years) and in some model specifications region-specific (more precisely: region-industry-specific) fixed effects. In- or exclusion of this type of fixed effects does not alter the main findings.

12 Export, Migration, and Costs of Market Entry: Evidence from Central European Firms 11 Another econometric concern arises as export decisions of firms for different destination countries (87,393 observations) are explained by variables that vary only between (28) home regions, (18) destination countries or as the variable on migration between (321) combinations of home regions and destination countries. As described in Moulton (1990) this might lead to standard errors that are biased downwards. I address this issue by clustering the residuals with respect to each home region-destination country combination in the probit models (estimating the export probability) and by using heteroscedasticity consistent estimates of the covariance matrix (White, 1980) in the random effects models (estimating export volumes). When estimating the export volumes, only observations that report export activity are included in the analysis. As the selection of this sample is likely to be a non-random selection of all observations, I correct for the potentially biasing non-random sample selection using a Heckman (1976) type two-stage procedure as a robustness check. In the first stage I estimate a probit model whether a firm exports to a particular country and reports the respective export volume. In this estimation all exogenous variables from the second stage regression and a large number of combinations of fixed region, destination and industry effects are used as regressors. From the results of the probit model I calculate the inverse Mills ratio and include this ratio as an additional explanatory variable in the second stage regression. 13 Last, the selection of firms included in the survey is non-random, but the data sample is stratified with respect to industry, home region and firm size (number of employees). I control for industry effects by including respective dummy variables in each regression. In some model I consider fixed home region or firm effects or the potentially endogenous number of employees. Including home region fixed effects or the firm size does not alter the main findings, which serves as evidence that the effect of immigrants on the export decisions of firms is similar between regions and independent of firm size. 4. Results The extensive margin elasticity The results of the probit models estimating the probability of exporting to a particular country are summarized in Table 3. I find a positive and statistically significant effect of the share of immigrants of a particular country on the probability of a firm to export to this destination throughout all model specifications. 13 The inverse Mills ratio is the ratio between the standard normal probability distribution function and standard normal cumulative distribution function, evaluated for each observation at the linear prediction of the probit model (Wooldridge, 2002).

13 Export, Migration, and Costs of Market Entry: Evidence from Central European Firms 12 The model specifications differ on the type of fixed effects included in the regressions. Specification [1] includes dummy variables for industries, model [2] for region-industry combinations, specification [3] for destination-industry and column [4] for both region-industry and destination-industry combinations. Specification [5] controls for fixed firm effects and model [6] also for destination-industry fixed effects. Note that the number of observations drops sharply to about 10 percent of the total sample in specification [5] and [6]. Due to including fixed firm effects, the export decisions of a firm have to vary across different destination countries. All firms that do not export to one of the destination countries drop out of the regression, as their behavior is perfectly predicted by the fixed firm effects. 14 Different types of fixed effects control for various unobserved variables and reduce the variation of the immigration variable (necessary for identifying its influence on the export propensity) to variation between different destinations countries (model [2] and [5]) or between different regions (model [3]). In specification [4] and [6] identification comes from deviations from the region and the destination mean only. Region- (destination-) specific variables drop out of the equation when including region- (destination-) fixed effects due to multicollinearity. Irrespective of the model specification I find a positive coefficient for immigration that is statistically significant at the one percent level. In specification [1] to [4] the parameter estimates vary between and The estimated coefficient is higher in specification [5] (0.314) and [6] (0.334). The parameter estimates on the distance between the districts, where the firms are located, and the capital of the destination countries take the expected negative signs, but are significantly different from zero only if destination-specific fixed effects are excluded. Contrary to the effect of immigrants the variation between the geographic areas, where all firms are located, is not strong enough to ensure a statistically significant negative relationship. This result might also be a consequence of the fact that the measure of distance used in the analysis is not very accurate, as the distance to the capital of a country might be a poor proxy of the (relevant) distance to trading partners, especially if the destination country is large (e.g. Russia) or the economic centers of a country are far away from the capital (e.g. Germany). The dummy variables whether home and destination country share a common border or speak the same language take a positive sign and are significantly different from zero in most model specifications, as expected. The regression analysis does not provide statistically significant results for the relationship between the GDP in the home region and export propensity, a larger GDP per capita however dampens export activities. It seems that a wealthier home market induces less need to expand business abroad. The 14 All firms that export to all destinations also have to be dropped. These are, however, only 29 firms that account for less than 0.4 percent of the entire sample.

14 Export, Migration, and Costs of Market Entry: Evidence from Central European Firms 13 parameter estimate on the population density is, however, not significantly different from zero. Surprisingly, whether the trading partner is (also) a member of the European Union (EU) does not influence the export propensity. One reason for this result might be that there are only a few destination countries that are not members of the EU (namely Switzerland, Serbia, Croatia, Ukraine and Russia) that are probably very heterogeneous with respect to their trade barriers. The market size of the destination country (GDP and GDP per capita), however, takes the expected positive sign and is significantly different from zero throughout all model specifications. < Table 3 around here > The marginal effects and the extensive margin elasticities are reported in Table 4 and are calculated at means. I follow Koenig et al. (2010) and Berman and Héricourt (2010) and denote the impact on the probability of a firm to export (or to start exporting) as the extensive margin of trade. Note that the elasticities reported in Table 4 are slightly different compared to the extensive margin elasticity defined by Chaney (2008). In his model, the extensive margin elasticity is the (relative) increase in trade volume coming from additional exporters. The elasticities presented in Table 4 are the (relative) increase in the number of exporters. As export propensity and export volume (see below) are positively correlated with firm size, it is likely that new exporters (due to a reduction in trade costs) are smaller and (therefore) export less compared to the average of the firms already exporting. The elasticities derived in Table 4 therefore overestimate the extensive margin elasticity. Nevertheless, the elasticities are useful to compare the size of the impact of immigration on the export propensity to its effect on export volume. Note that the export probability of the average firm-destination combination differs considerably between the models. The export propensity when including fixed firm effects (model [5] and [6]) is about 14 percent, compared to roughly 2 percent otherwise, as all firms that do not export to any of the potential destination countries are left out in these specifications. But as most marginal effects increase even more strongly than the export probability, the elasticities tend to be higher (in absolute values) when controlling for unobserved firm effects (specifications [5] and [6]). The extensive margin elasticity of immigration is (model [5]) and (model [6]) if fixed firm effects are included and takes values between and if they are left out. 15 The calculated elasticities with respect to distance are about 0.3 when destination-dummies are excluded and insignificant otherwise. As the common border and the same language are binary variables the elasticities reported in Table 4 are semi-elasticities. Sharing a common border increases the export probability of a firm by 35.4 to 51.0 percent, except in model specification [4], where the elasticity is only 15 Note that I do not multiply the elasticities by 1 as Chaney (2008).

15 Export, Migration, and Costs of Market Entry: Evidence from Central European Firms percent and not significantly different from zero. The semi-elasticity on the same language is far more volatile and takes values between and The GDP per capita of the home region has a strong negative impact on the export propensity (ranging between and 0.276). The strong positive impact of the market size of the destination country is also reflected by the corresponding elasticities: A one percent increase in the GDP and the GDP per capita of the destination country increases the export probability roughly by one half (GDP per capita) and one fourth (GDP) of a percent. < Table 4 around here > The intensive margin elasticity The parameter estimates for the intensive margins are summarized in Table 5 and Table 6. Both tables report the same specifications of the model (with respect to controlling for various fixed effects) for estimating the intensive margin as for estimating the export probabilities (see Table 3). The (logarithm of the) absolute export volume (volume of sales, Table 5) is the preferred endogenous variable, as this figure is more closely related to the theoretical model proposed by Chaney (2008) than the (logarithm of the) relative export volume (share of sales in a destination country over total sales, summarized in Table 6). The regression results on the relative export volume show the robustness of the main findings. As the endogenous and all but binary explanatory variables are included in logarithmic values the parameter estimates can be interpreted as elasticities directly. 16 The parameter estimates of immigration on the export volume take values between and and are significantly different from zero (at least) at the ten percent level in five models and at the five percent level in two out of six specifications. Comparing the intensive margin elasticity to the extensive margin elasticity shows a much smaller effect on the export volume than on the export propensity. The distance to the destination country is again sensitive to the inclusion of destination fixed effects, but is not statistically significant (at the five percent level) in any model. The parameter estimates on sharing a common border and on speaking the same language always take a positive sign, but the impact of speaking the same language is rather small and not significantly different from zero. Sharing a common border with the destination country increases export volumes (of exporting firms) between 24.8 and 40.4 percent. The variables describing the size and the agglomeration of the home region has no effect on the intensive margin, nor does the membership of the destination country to the EU. The size of the destination country plays an important role for the export volume: An increase in the GDP by 1 percent 16 The parameter estimates of the binary variables are semi-elasticities.

16 Export, Migration, and Costs of Market Entry: Evidence from Central European Firms 15 increases the export volume of exporting firms by roughly 0.15 percent. The influence of GDP per capita is even stronger in size, but not significantly different from zero. < Table 5 around here > Table 6 reports the parameter estimates of the relative export volumes to a particular destination country (sales to this country over total sales, denoted as SHARE). The results of the models including fixed firm effects are not reported, as the parameter estimates except for the intercept are identical to the parameter estimates on the absolute export volume (specification [5] and [6] in Table 5), as!"#$!!" ln SHARE!" = ln = ln SALES!"!#$!"#$!!" ln TOTAL SALES! and as ln TOTAL SALES! is! controlled for by fixed firm effects. The parameters on immigration are significantly different from zero at the five percent level in three out of four specifications. The estimated elasticities range between and and are therefore very similar to the results obtained from the absolute export values. Again, the distance to the destination country and whether home region and destination country speak the same language has no impact on the export volume. Sharing a common border significantly increases the relative export volume in specification [3] and [4], but is insignificant in the other specifications. The negative influence of GDP per capita is more pronounced as in the regressions on the absolute export volume and significantly different from zero. Whether the destination country is a member of the EU or not has no influence on the relative export volume, whereas the market size of the destination (measured by GDP) increases volumes with elasticities slightly below The influence of the GDP per capita is again large in size, but not significantly different from zero. < Table 6 around here > I conclude that the influence of the share of immigrants on the (absolute and relative) export volume is much smaller than on the export propensity. While all parameter estimates take a positive sign, as expected, only five (out of ten) parameters are significant at the five percent level. In three specifications the coefficients are only significantly different from zero at the ten percent level, while the parameter estimates are not statistically significant at all in two models. In most specifications the parameter estimates on the number of immigrants are at the edge of passing the five percent significance threshold. 5. Robustness In Table 7 to 9, I re-estimate the export propensity and the export volume, but include firm-specific variables like firm size (number of employees), age, whether the firms are fully or partly owned by

17 Export, Migration, and Costs of Market Entry: Evidence from Central European Firms 16 foreigners and whether the firm is an individual enterprise, the headquarter or the subsidiary of a corporate group. The results on the export probability (Table 7) are hardly affected by the inclusion of firms-specific variables. Due to endogeneity concerns, I refrain from interpreting the parameter estimates, but use the respective variables as additional controls. Not a single parameter estimates drops below or passes the five percent significance level due to including these firm-specific regressors. < Table 7 around here > The parameter estimates of the variable on immigration increases slightly when estimating the absolute (Table 8) or the relative export volume (Table 9). As the estimated coefficients are only slightly below significance levels without including firm-specific variables (Table 5 and 6), the respective parameter estimates despite a rather small increase in size pass the five percent significance level in seven out of eight model specifications. Although the difference of the parameter estimates between the basic specifications and the robustness checks is still small, it is more pronounced compared to robustness checks on the export propensity. Note that the increase in the explanatory power of the regressions due to including firm-specific variables is larger when estimating the absolute rather than the relative export volume. < Tables 8, 9 around here > Table 10 summarizes the results of the second stage regression using a two stage Heckman procedure. In the first stage, I estimate a probit model (selection equation). The endogenous variable is binary and takes the value 1 if the firm exports to a particular destination and reports its export volume. I use regionindustry, destination-industry and region-destination fixed effects and the distance to the destination country as regressors in the first stage probit regression. All exogenous variables (despite distance) from the second stage regression vary with respect to home region, destination country or region-destination combinations and drop out of the equation. 17 Due to the large number of fixed effects (and the subsequent perfect prediction of the export probabilities of some observations) the number of observations in the first stage regression is reduced to 44,490. Including a large number of variables in the first stage probit model is nonetheless reasonable, as it increases the explanatory power of the selection equation. 17 The distance is calculated as the distance between the district, where the firm is located, and the capital of the destination country and can therefore be included in the first stage probit regression.

18 Export, Migration, and Costs of Market Entry: Evidence from Central European Firms 17 From the selection equation I calculate the inverse Mills ration and include this variable as an additional regressor in the second stage equation. 18 This variable is significant in two specifications (SALES [11] and [13]), indicating biased parameter estimates due to a non-random selection of observations (for the second stage regression). In these two specifications I do not control region-specific fixed effects in the second stage and the size of the parameter estimates drops significantly by one third (compared to SALES [1] and [3] in Table 5) and is not statistically significant from zero anymore. The Mills ratio is insignificant in specification [12] and [14] and the parameter estimates on immigration are (therefore) hardly affected due to correcting for the sample selection. Nevertheless, the coefficients on migration in the four model specifications summarized in Table 10 are insignificant in two models and significantly different from zero only at the ten percent level in the other two specifications, enriching doubts on the robustness of the effect of immigration on the export volume. < Table 10 around here > 6. Summary and Conclusions In this article I investigate empirically the link between exports and migration at the firm level. I use survey data that comprise detailed information on export behavior of firms located in four Central European countries (Austria, Hungary, Czech Republic and Slovakia) for different destination countries. The variable on immigration is calculated for each source country (and potential export destination) for each NUTS-2 region. I find a positive, statistically significant and economically meaningful effect of the share of immigrants from a particular country on the export propensity of firms located in that region to export to that particular destination (extensive margin elasticity). The effect of immigrants on the (absolute and relative) export volume (intensive margin elasticity), despite being positive in all models, is smaller in size and statistically insignificant in some specifications. Arguments put forward by Gould (1994) language skills, knowledge about preferences in and ties to their home country can explain the causal relationship between export behavior of firms and the stock of immigrants residing in the region the firm is located. As I do not estimate the productivity distribution of firms or the elasticity of substitution between different varieties of a good (see equation (1) and (2)), I cannot assess directly, whether immigrants reduce mainly fixed or variable costs. If immigrants reduce variable trade costs only, than the ratio between the intensive and the extensive margin elasticity based on estimates on!!!! by Chaney (2008) 18 I report the results applying the Heckman method only for estimating absolute (rather than relative) export volumes, as this is the preferred measure to estimate the intensive margin elasticity. Estimates on the relative export volumes are very similar and are available from the author upon request.

The Trade Creation Effect of Immigrants: Testing the Theory on the Remarkable Case of Spain

The Trade Creation Effect of Immigrants: Testing the Theory on the Remarkable Case of Spain The Trade Creation Effect of Immigrants: Testing the Theory on the Remarkable Case of Spain Giovanni Peri (UC Davis, CESifo and NBER) Francisco Requena (Universitat de Valencia) June, 2009 Abstract There

More information

Table A.2 reports the complete set of estimates of equation (1). We distinguish between personal

Table A.2 reports the complete set of estimates of equation (1). We distinguish between personal Akay, Bargain and Zimmermann Online Appendix 40 A. Online Appendix A.1. Descriptive Statistics Figure A.1 about here Table A.1 about here A.2. Detailed SWB Estimates Table A.2 reports the complete set

More information

Migration and Tourism Flows to New Zealand

Migration and Tourism Flows to New Zealand Migration and Tourism Flows to New Zealand Murat Genç University of Otago, Dunedin, New Zealand Email address for correspondence: murat.genc@otago.ac.nz 30 April 2010 PRELIMINARY WORK IN PROGRESS NOT FOR

More information

Immigration, Information, and Trade Margins

Immigration, Information, and Trade Margins Immigration, Information, and Trade Margins Shan Jiang November 7, 2007 Abstract Recent theories suggest that better information in destination countries could reduce firm s fixed export costs, lower uncertainty

More information

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr Abstract. The Asian experience of poverty reduction has varied widely. Over recent decades the economies of East and Southeast Asia

More information

How Foreign-born Workers Foster Exports

How Foreign-born Workers Foster Exports How Foreign-born Workers Foster Exports Léa Marchal Clément Nedoncelle February 2, 2017 Abstract We investigate the export-enhancing effect of foreign workers at the firm level. We first develop a theoretical

More information

Immigration and Internal Mobility in Canada Appendices A and B. Appendix A: Two-step Instrumentation strategy: Procedure and detailed results

Immigration and Internal Mobility in Canada Appendices A and B. Appendix A: Two-step Instrumentation strategy: Procedure and detailed results Immigration and Internal Mobility in Canada Appendices A and B by Michel Beine and Serge Coulombe This version: February 2016 Appendix A: Two-step Instrumentation strategy: Procedure and detailed results

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE TRADE CREATION EFFECT OF IMMIGRANTS: EVIDENCE FROM THE REMARKABLE CASE OF SPAIN. Giovanni Peri Francisco Requena

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE TRADE CREATION EFFECT OF IMMIGRANTS: EVIDENCE FROM THE REMARKABLE CASE OF SPAIN. Giovanni Peri Francisco Requena NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE TRADE CREATION EFFECT OF IMMIGRANTS: EVIDENCE FROM THE REMARKABLE CASE OF SPAIN Giovanni Peri Francisco Requena Working Paper 15625 http://www.nber.org/papers/w15625 NATIONAL

More information

Is Corruption Anti Labor?

Is Corruption Anti Labor? Is Corruption Anti Labor? Suryadipta Roy Lawrence University Department of Economics PO Box- 599, Appleton, WI- 54911. Abstract This paper investigates the effect of corruption on trade openness in low-income

More information

The Trade Liberalization Effects of Regional Trade Agreements* Volker Nitsch Free University Berlin. Daniel M. Sturm. University of Munich

The Trade Liberalization Effects of Regional Trade Agreements* Volker Nitsch Free University Berlin. Daniel M. Sturm. University of Munich December 2, 2005 The Trade Liberalization Effects of Regional Trade Agreements* Volker Nitsch Free University Berlin Daniel M. Sturm University of Munich and CEPR Abstract Recent research suggests that

More information

Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation

Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation S. Roy*, Department of Economics, High Point University, High Point, NC - 27262, USA. Email: sroy@highpoint.edu Abstract We implement OLS,

More information

Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US

Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US Ben Ost a and Eva Dziadula b a Department of Economics, University of Illinois at Chicago, 601 South Morgan UH718 M/C144 Chicago,

More information

Skill Classification Does Matter: Estimating the Relationship Between Trade Flows and Wage Inequality

Skill Classification Does Matter: Estimating the Relationship Between Trade Flows and Wage Inequality Skill Classification Does Matter: Estimating the Relationship Between Trade Flows and Wage Inequality By Kristin Forbes* M.I.T.-Sloan School of Management and NBER First version: April 1998 This version:

More information

Working Papers in Economics

Working Papers in Economics University of Innsbruck Working Papers in Economics Foreign Direct Investment and European Integration in the 90 s Peter Egger and Michael Pfaffermayr 2002/2 Institute of Economic Theory, Economic Policy

More information

Trade and Inequality: From Theory to Estimation

Trade and Inequality: From Theory to Estimation Trade and Inequality: From Theory to Estimation Elhanan Helpman, Harvard and CIFAR Oleg Itskhoki, Princeton Marc Muendler, UCSD Stephen Redding, Princeton December 2012 HIMR (Harvard, Princeton, UCSD and

More information

Remittances and the Brain Drain: Evidence from Microdata for Sub-Saharan Africa

Remittances and the Brain Drain: Evidence from Microdata for Sub-Saharan Africa Remittances and the Brain Drain: Evidence from Microdata for Sub-Saharan Africa Julia Bredtmann 1, Fernanda Martinez Flores 1,2, and Sebastian Otten 1,2,3 1 RWI, Rheinisch-Westfälisches Institut für Wirtschaftsforschung

More information

Corruption, Political Instability and Firm-Level Export Decisions. Kul Kapri 1 Rowan University. August 2018

Corruption, Political Instability and Firm-Level Export Decisions. Kul Kapri 1 Rowan University. August 2018 Corruption, Political Instability and Firm-Level Export Decisions Kul Kapri 1 Rowan University August 2018 Abstract In this paper I use South Asian firm-level data to examine whether the impact of corruption

More information

Does the G7/G8 Promote Trade? Volker Nitsch Freie Universität Berlin

Does the G7/G8 Promote Trade? Volker Nitsch Freie Universität Berlin February 20, 2006 Does the G7/G8 Promote Trade? Volker Nitsch Freie Universität Berlin Abstract The Group of Eight (G8) is an unofficial forum of the heads of state of the eight leading industrialized

More information

Determinants of Export Performance: Comparison of Central European and Baltic Firms*

Determinants of Export Performance: Comparison of Central European and Baltic Firms* JEL Classification: F14, P33 Keywords: Baltic states, Central Europe, export activity, heterogeneity of firms, new EU member states Determinants of Export Performance: Comparison of Central European and

More information

Migrant Wages, Human Capital Accumulation and Return Migration

Migrant Wages, Human Capital Accumulation and Return Migration Migrant Wages, Human Capital Accumulation and Return Migration Jérôme Adda Christian Dustmann Joseph-Simon Görlach February 14, 2014 PRELIMINARY and VERY INCOMPLETE Abstract This paper analyses the wage

More information

Self-Selection and the Earnings of Immigrants

Self-Selection and the Earnings of Immigrants Self-Selection and the Earnings of Immigrants George Borjas (1987) Omid Ghaderi & Ali Yadegari April 7, 2018 George Borjas (1987) GSME, Applied Economics Seminars April 7, 2018 1 / 24 Abstract The age-earnings

More information

The Costs of Remoteness, Evidence From German Division and Reunification by Redding and Sturm (AER, 2008)

The Costs of Remoteness, Evidence From German Division and Reunification by Redding and Sturm (AER, 2008) The Costs of Remoteness, Evidence From German Division and Reunification by Redding and Sturm (AER, 2008) MIT Spatial Economics Reading Group Presentation Adam Guren May 13, 2010 Testing the New Economic

More information

Do (naturalized) immigrants affect employment and wages of natives? Evidence from Germany

Do (naturalized) immigrants affect employment and wages of natives? Evidence from Germany Do (naturalized) immigrants affect employment and wages of natives? Evidence from Germany Carsten Pohl 1 15 September, 2008 Extended Abstract Since the beginning of the 1990s Germany has experienced a

More information

Appendix to Sectoral Economies

Appendix to Sectoral Economies Appendix to Sectoral Economies Rafaela Dancygier and Michael Donnelly June 18, 2012 1. Details About the Sectoral Data used in this Article Table A1: Availability of NACE classifications by country of

More information

CENTRO STUDI LUCA D AGLIANO DEVELOPMENT STUDIES WORKING PAPERS N May 2002

CENTRO STUDI LUCA D AGLIANO DEVELOPMENT STUDIES WORKING PAPERS N May 2002 CENTRO STUDI LUCA D AGLIANO DEVELOPMENT STUDIES WORKING PAPERS N. 161 May 2002 Foreign Direct Investment in Central and Eastern Europe: Employment Effects in the EU Henrik Braconier * Karolina Ekholm **

More information

IMMIGRATION REFORM, JOB SELECTION AND WAGES IN THE U.S. FARM LABOR MARKET

IMMIGRATION REFORM, JOB SELECTION AND WAGES IN THE U.S. FARM LABOR MARKET IMMIGRATION REFORM, JOB SELECTION AND WAGES IN THE U.S. FARM LABOR MARKET Lurleen M. Walters International Agricultural Trade & Policy Center Food and Resource Economics Department P.O. Box 040, University

More information

CENTRO STUDI LUCA D AGLIANO DEVELOPMENT STUDIES WORKING PAPERS N April Export Growth and Firm Survival

CENTRO STUDI LUCA D AGLIANO DEVELOPMENT STUDIES WORKING PAPERS N April Export Growth and Firm Survival WWW.DAGLIANO.UNIMI.IT CENTRO STUDI LUCA D AGLIANO DEVELOPMENT STUDIES WORKING PAPERS N. 350 April 2013 Export Growth and Firm Survival Julian Emami Namini* Giovanni Facchini** Ricardo A. López*** * Erasmus

More information

An Empirical Analysis of Pakistan s Bilateral Trade: A Gravity Model Approach

An Empirical Analysis of Pakistan s Bilateral Trade: A Gravity Model Approach 103 An Empirical Analysis of Pakistan s Bilateral Trade: A Gravity Model Approach Shaista Khan 1 Ihtisham ul Haq 2 Dilawar Khan 3 This study aimed to investigate Pakistan s bilateral trade flows with major

More information

Unreported Trade Flows and Gravity Equation. Estimation

Unreported Trade Flows and Gravity Equation. Estimation Unreported Trade Flows and Gravity Equation Estimation Thomas Baranga May 15, 2009 Abstract Some widely used trade databases do not distinguish between zero and unreported trade flows. The number of unreported

More information

A Global Economy-Climate Model with High Regional Resolution

A Global Economy-Climate Model with High Regional Resolution A Global Economy-Climate Model with High Regional Resolution Per Krusell Institute for International Economic Studies, CEPR, NBER Anthony A. Smith, Jr. Yale University, NBER February 6, 2015 The project

More information

GEORG-AUGUST-UNIVERSITÄT GÖTTINGEN

GEORG-AUGUST-UNIVERSITÄT GÖTTINGEN GEORG-AUGUST-UNIVERSITÄT GÖTTINGEN FACULTY OF ECONOMIC SCIENCES CHAIR OF MACROECONOMICS AND DEVELOPMENT Bachelor Seminar Economics of the very long run: Economics of Islam Summer semester 2017 Does Secular

More information

Individual attitudes towards migration: a reexamination of the evidence

Individual attitudes towards migration: a reexamination of the evidence Individual attitudes towards migration: a reexamination of the evidence Tobias Müller and Silvio H. T. Tai May 17, 2010 PRELIMINARY VERSION Abstract Recent economic research has highlighted the importance

More information

Benefit levels and US immigrants welfare receipts

Benefit levels and US immigrants welfare receipts 1 Benefit levels and US immigrants welfare receipts 1970 1990 by Joakim Ruist Department of Economics University of Gothenburg Box 640 40530 Gothenburg, Sweden joakim.ruist@economics.gu.se telephone: +46

More information

School Quality and Returns to Education of U.S. Immigrants. Bernt Bratsberg. and. Dek Terrell* RRH: BRATSBERG & TERRELL:

School Quality and Returns to Education of U.S. Immigrants. Bernt Bratsberg. and. Dek Terrell* RRH: BRATSBERG & TERRELL: Forthcoming, Economic Inquiry School Quality and Returns to Education of U.S. Immigrants Bernt Bratsberg and Dek Terrell* RRH: BRATSBERG & TERRELL: SCHOOL QUALITY AND EDUCATION RETURNS OF IMMIGRANTS JEL

More information

Remittances and Poverty. in Guatemala* Richard H. Adams, Jr. Development Research Group (DECRG) MSN MC World Bank.

Remittances and Poverty. in Guatemala* Richard H. Adams, Jr. Development Research Group (DECRG) MSN MC World Bank. Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Remittances and Poverty in Guatemala* Richard H. Adams, Jr. Development Research Group

More information

Determinants and Dynamics of Migration to OECD Countries in a Three-Dimensional Panel Framework

Determinants and Dynamics of Migration to OECD Countries in a Three-Dimensional Panel Framework Determinants and Dynamics of Migration to OECD Countries in a Three-Dimensional Panel Framework Ilse Ruyssen, Gerdie Everaert, and Glenn Rayp SHERPPA, Ghent University Preliminary, May 2012 Abstract This

More information

Trade Flows and Migration to New Zealand

Trade Flows and Migration to New Zealand Trade Flows and Migration to New Zealand David Law and John Bryant N EW Z EALAND T REASURY W ORKING P APER 04/## J UNE 2004 Treasury:625092v1 [473620-1] NZ TREASURY WORKING PAPER 04/## Trade Flows and

More information

Immigration, Trade and Productivity in Services: Evidence from U.K. Firms

Immigration, Trade and Productivity in Services: Evidence from U.K. Firms Immigration, Trade and Productivity in Services: Evidence from U.K. Firms Gianmarco I.P. Ottaviano (LSE) Giovanni Peri (UC Davis) Greg C. Wright (UC Merced) August 18, 2014 Abstract This paper explores

More information

DANMARKS NATIONALBANK

DANMARKS NATIONALBANK ANALYSIS DANMARKS NATIONALBANK 10 JANUARY 2019 NO. 1 Intra-EU labour mobility dampens cyclical pressures EU labour mobility dampens labour market pressures Eastern enlargements increase access to EU labour

More information

Computerization and Immigration: Theory and Evidence from the United States 1

Computerization and Immigration: Theory and Evidence from the United States 1 Computerization and Immigration: Theory and Evidence from the United States 1 Gaetano Basso (Banca d Italia), Giovanni Peri (UC Davis and NBER), Ahmed Rahman (USNA) BdI-CEPR Conference, Roma - March 16th,

More information

WhyHasUrbanInequalityIncreased?

WhyHasUrbanInequalityIncreased? WhyHasUrbanInequalityIncreased? Nathaniel Baum-Snow, Brown University Matthew Freedman, Cornell University Ronni Pavan, Royal Holloway-University of London June, 2014 Abstract The increase in wage inequality

More information

3 Wage adjustment and employment in Europe: some results from the Wage Dynamics Network Survey

3 Wage adjustment and employment in Europe: some results from the Wage Dynamics Network Survey 3 Wage adjustment and in Europe: some results from the Wage Dynamics Network Survey This box examines the link between collective bargaining arrangements, downward wage rigidities and. Several past studies

More information

On the Determinants of Global Bilateral Migration Flows

On the Determinants of Global Bilateral Migration Flows On the Determinants of Global Bilateral Migration Flows Jesus Crespo Cuaresma Mathias Moser Anna Raggl Preliminary Draft, May 2013 Abstract We present a method aimed at estimating global bilateral migration

More information

On Estimating The Effects of Legalization: Do Agricultural Workers Really Benefit?

On Estimating The Effects of Legalization: Do Agricultural Workers Really Benefit? On Estimating The Effects of Legalization: Do Agricultural Workers Really Benefit? Breno Sampaio Universidade Federal de Pernambuco, Department of Economics, Professor, Recife, PE, Brazil brenosampaio@hotmail.com

More information

Study. Importance of the German Economy for Europe. A vbw study, prepared by Prognos AG Last update: February 2018

Study. Importance of the German Economy for Europe. A vbw study, prepared by Prognos AG Last update: February 2018 Study Importance of the German Economy for Europe A vbw study, prepared by Prognos AG Last update: February 2018 www.vbw-bayern.de vbw Study February 2018 Preface A strong German economy creates added

More information

Determinants of Highly-Skilled Migration Taiwan s Experiences

Determinants of Highly-Skilled Migration Taiwan s Experiences Working Paper Series No.2007-1 Determinants of Highly-Skilled Migration Taiwan s Experiences by Lee-in Chen Chiu and Jen-yi Hou July 2007 Chung-Hua Institution for Economic Research 75 Chang-Hsing Street,

More information

The Determinants and the Selection. of Mexico-US Migrations

The Determinants and the Selection. of Mexico-US Migrations The Determinants and the Selection of Mexico-US Migrations J. William Ambrosini (UC, Davis) Giovanni Peri, (UC, Davis and NBER) This draft March 2011 Abstract Using data from the Mexican Family Life Survey

More information

Investigating the Effects of Migration on Economic Growth in Aging OECD Countries from

Investigating the Effects of Migration on Economic Growth in Aging OECD Countries from Bowdoin College Bowdoin Digital Commons Honors Projects Student Scholarship and Creative Work 5-2017 Investigating the Effects of Migration on Economic Growth in Aging OECD Countries from 1975-2015 Michael

More information

The Impact of Having a Job at Migration on Settlement Decisions: Ethnic Enclaves as Job Search Networks

The Impact of Having a Job at Migration on Settlement Decisions: Ethnic Enclaves as Job Search Networks The Impact of Having a Job at Migration on Settlement Decisions: Ethnic Enclaves as Job Search Networks Lee Tucker Boston University This version: October 15, 2014 Abstract Observational evidence has shown

More information

Accounting for the role of occupational change on earnings in Europe and Central Asia Maurizio Bussolo, Iván Torre and Hernan Winkler (World Bank)

Accounting for the role of occupational change on earnings in Europe and Central Asia Maurizio Bussolo, Iván Torre and Hernan Winkler (World Bank) Accounting for the role of occupational change on earnings in Europe and Central Asia Maurizio Bussolo, Iván Torre and Hernan Winkler (World Bank) [This draft: May 24, 2018] This paper analyzes the process

More information

Commuting and Minimum wages in Decentralized Era Case Study from Java Island. Raden M Purnagunawan

Commuting and Minimum wages in Decentralized Era Case Study from Java Island. Raden M Purnagunawan Commuting and Minimum wages in Decentralized Era Case Study from Java Island Raden M Purnagunawan Outline 1. Introduction 2. Brief Literature review 3. Data Source and Construction 4. The aggregate commuting

More information

Determinants of Outward FDI for Thai Firms

Determinants of Outward FDI for Thai Firms Southeast Asian Journal of Economics 3(2), December 2015: 43-59 Determinants of Outward FDI for Thai Firms Tanapong Potipiti Assistant professor, Faculty of Economics, Chulalongkorn University, Bangkok,

More information

The Flow Model of Exports: An Introduction

The Flow Model of Exports: An Introduction MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive The Flow Model of Exports: An Introduction Jiri Mazurek School of Business Administration in Karviná 13. January 2014 Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/52920/

More information

International Migration:

International Migration: International Migration: A Panel Data Analysis of Economic and Non-Economic Determinants Anna Maria Mayda March 2004 Preliminary and Incomplete Comments Welcome Abstract In this paper I empirically investigate

More information

EU enlargement and the race to the bottom of welfare states

EU enlargement and the race to the bottom of welfare states Skupnik IZA Journal of Migration 2014, 3:15 ORIGINAL ARTICLE Open Access EU enlargement and the race to the bottom of welfare states Christoph Skupnik Correspondence: christoph.skupnik@fu-berlin.de School

More information

Remittances and the Wage Impact of Immigration

Remittances and the Wage Impact of Immigration Remittances and the Wage Impact of Immigration William W. Olney 1 First Draft: November 2011 Revised: June 2012 Abstract This paper examines the impact of immigrant remittances on the wages of native workers

More information

Impact of the EU Enlargement on the Agricultural Income. Components in the Member States

Impact of the EU Enlargement on the Agricultural Income. Components in the Member States Impact of the EU Enlargement on the Agricultural Income Paweł Kobus, PhD, email: pawel_kobus@sggw.pl. Department of Agricultural Economics and International Economic Relations Warsaw University of Life

More information

The Effect of Immigration on Native Workers: Evidence from the US Construction Sector

The Effect of Immigration on Native Workers: Evidence from the US Construction Sector The Effect of Immigration on Native Workers: Evidence from the US Construction Sector Pierre Mérel and Zach Rutledge July 7, 2017 Abstract This paper provides new estimates of the short-run impacts of

More information

LABOUR-MARKET INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS IN OECD-COUNTRIES: WHAT EXPLANATIONS FIT THE DATA?

LABOUR-MARKET INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS IN OECD-COUNTRIES: WHAT EXPLANATIONS FIT THE DATA? LABOUR-MARKET INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS IN OECD-COUNTRIES: WHAT EXPLANATIONS FIT THE DATA? By Andreas Bergh (PhD) Associate Professor in Economics at Lund University and the Research Institute of Industrial

More information

Being a Good Samaritan or just a politician? Empirical evidence of disaster assistance. Jeroen Klomp

Being a Good Samaritan or just a politician? Empirical evidence of disaster assistance. Jeroen Klomp Being a Good Samaritan or just a politician? Empirical evidence of disaster assistance Jeroen Klomp Netherlands Defence Academy & Wageningen University and Research The Netherlands Introduction Since 1970

More information

Explaining the Deteriorating Entry Earnings of Canada s Immigrant Cohorts:

Explaining the Deteriorating Entry Earnings of Canada s Immigrant Cohorts: Explaining the Deteriorating Entry Earnings of Canada s Immigrant Cohorts: 1966-2000 Abdurrahman Aydemir Family and Labour Studies Division Statistics Canada aydeabd@statcan.ca 613-951-3821 and Mikal Skuterud

More information

The trade creation effect of immigrants: evidence from the remarkable case of Spain

The trade creation effect of immigrants: evidence from the remarkable case of Spain The trade creation effect of immigrants: evidence from the remarkable case of Spain Giovanni Peri Department of Economics, UC Davis Francisco Requena-Silvente Department of Applied Economics II, Universitat

More information

Wage Differences Between Immigrants and Natives in Austria: The Role of Literacy Skills

Wage Differences Between Immigrants and Natives in Austria: The Role of Literacy Skills Working Paper No. 12 11/2017 Michael Christl, Monika Köppl-Turyna, Phillipp Gnan Wage Differences Between Immigrants and Natives in Austria: The Role of Literacy Skills Abstract This paper analyzes wage

More information

Volume 35, Issue 1. An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach

Volume 35, Issue 1. An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach Volume 35, Issue 1 An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach Brian Hibbs Indiana University South Bend Gihoon Hong Indiana University South Bend Abstract This

More information

Immigration, Worker-Firm Matching, and. Inequality

Immigration, Worker-Firm Matching, and. Inequality Immigration, Worker-Firm Matching, and Inequality Jaerim Choi* University of Hawaii at Manoa Jihyun Park** KISDI August 2, 2018 Abstract This paper develops a novel framework of worker-firm matching to

More information

1. Introduction. The Stock Adjustment Model of Migration: The Scottish Experience

1. Introduction. The Stock Adjustment Model of Migration: The Scottish Experience The Stock Adjustment Model of Migration: The Scottish Experience Baayah Baba, Universiti Teknologi MARA, Malaysia Abstract: In the many studies of migration of labor, migrants are usually considered to

More information

Measuring EU Trade Integration within the Gravity Framework

Measuring EU Trade Integration within the Gravity Framework Measuring EU Trade Integration within the Gravity Framework Andrea Molinari INTRODUCTION... 2 CHAPTER I. ECONOMIC HISTORY AND TRADE STYLISED FACTS... 4 CHAPTER II. TRADE INTEGRATION AND GRAVITY MODELS:

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE CAUSES AND EFFECTS OF INTERNATIONAL MIGRATIONS: EVIDENCE FROM OECD COUNTRIES Francesc Ortega Giovanni Peri

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE CAUSES AND EFFECTS OF INTERNATIONAL MIGRATIONS: EVIDENCE FROM OECD COUNTRIES Francesc Ortega Giovanni Peri NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE CAUSES AND EFFECTS OF INTERNATIONAL MIGRATIONS: EVIDENCE FROM OECD COUNTRIES 1980-2005 Francesc Ortega Giovanni Peri Working Paper 14833 http://www.nber.org/papers/w14833

More information

Supplementary information for the article:

Supplementary information for the article: Supplementary information for the article: Happy moves? Assessing the link between life satisfaction and emigration intentions Artjoms Ivlevs Contents 1. Summary statistics of variables p. 2 2. Country

More information

Emigration and source countries; Brain drain and brain gain; Remittances.

Emigration and source countries; Brain drain and brain gain; Remittances. Emigration and source countries; Brain drain and brain gain; Remittances. Mariola Pytliková CERGE-EI and VŠB-Technical University Ostrava, CReAM, IZA, CCP and CELSI Info about lectures: https://home.cerge-ei.cz/pytlikova/laborspring16/

More information

Neil T. N. Ferguson. Determinants and Dynamics of Forced Migration: Evidence from Flows and Stocks in Europe

Neil T. N. Ferguson. Determinants and Dynamics of Forced Migration: Evidence from Flows and Stocks in Europe Determinants and Dynamics of Forced Migration: Evidence from Flows and Stocks in Europe Neil T. N. Ferguson Responding to Crises Conference 26 September 2016 UNU Wider - Helsinki Outline 1. Motivation

More information

Trade and Inequality: Educational and Occupational Choices Matter

Trade and Inequality: Educational and Occupational Choices Matter Trade and Inequality: Educational and Occupational Choices Matter Arthur V. Smith Boston University December 16, 2018 Latest version available here. Abstract How does trade affect inequality? Using recent

More information

ENHANCING TRADE THROUGH MIGRATION. A GRAVITY MODEL OF THE NETWORK EFFECT.

ENHANCING TRADE THROUGH MIGRATION. A GRAVITY MODEL OF THE NETWORK EFFECT. ENHANCING TRADE THROUGH MIGRATION. A GRAVITY MODEL OF THE NETWORK EFFECT. Laura Casi ISLA-Bocconi, Milan (Italy) Abstract: While trade liberalization has always been the core of common policies, only in

More information

Family Ties, Labor Mobility and Interregional Wage Differentials*

Family Ties, Labor Mobility and Interregional Wage Differentials* Family Ties, Labor Mobility and Interregional Wage Differentials* TODD L. CHERRY, Ph.D.** Department of Economics and Finance University of Wyoming Laramie WY 82071-3985 PETE T. TSOURNOS, Ph.D. Pacific

More information

Rethinking the Area Approach: Immigrants and the Labor Market in California,

Rethinking the Area Approach: Immigrants and the Labor Market in California, Rethinking the Area Approach: Immigrants and the Labor Market in California, 1960-2005. Giovanni Peri, (University of California Davis, CESifo and NBER) October, 2009 Abstract A recent series of influential

More information

DETERMINANTS OF INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION: A SURVEY ON TRANSITION ECONOMIES AND TURKEY. Pınar Narin Emirhan 1. Preliminary Draft (ETSG 2008-Warsaw)

DETERMINANTS OF INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION: A SURVEY ON TRANSITION ECONOMIES AND TURKEY. Pınar Narin Emirhan 1. Preliminary Draft (ETSG 2008-Warsaw) DETERMINANTS OF INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION: A SURVEY ON TRANSITION ECONOMIES AND TURKEY Pınar Narin Emirhan 1 Preliminary Draft (ETSG 2008-Warsaw) Abstract This paper aims to test the determinants of international

More information

Immigrant-native wage gaps in time series: Complementarities or composition effects?

Immigrant-native wage gaps in time series: Complementarities or composition effects? Immigrant-native wage gaps in time series: Complementarities or composition effects? Joakim Ruist Department of Economics University of Gothenburg Box 640 405 30 Gothenburg, Sweden joakim.ruist@economics.gu.se

More information

Wage Trends among Disadvantaged Minorities

Wage Trends among Disadvantaged Minorities National Poverty Center Working Paper Series #05-12 August 2005 Wage Trends among Disadvantaged Minorities George J. Borjas Harvard University This paper is available online at the National Poverty Center

More information

Exploring the Impact of Democratic Capital on Prosperity

Exploring the Impact of Democratic Capital on Prosperity Exploring the Impact of Democratic Capital on Prosperity Lisa L. Verdon * SUMMARY Capital accumulation has long been considered one of the driving forces behind economic growth. The idea that democratic

More information

The Great Mexican Emigration

The Great Mexican Emigration The Great Mexican Emigration Gordon H. Hanson University of California, San Diego and NBER Craig McIntosh University of California, San Diego August 2008 Abstract. In this paper, we examine net emigration

More information

Statistical Modeling of Migration Attractiveness of the EU Member States

Statistical Modeling of Migration Attractiveness of the EU Member States Journal of Modern Applied Statistical Methods Volume 14 Issue 2 Article 19 11-1-2015 Statistical Modeling of Migration Attractiveness of the EU Member States Tatiana Tikhomirova Plekhanov Russian University

More information

Firm Dynamics and Immigration: The Case of High-Skilled Immigration

Firm Dynamics and Immigration: The Case of High-Skilled Immigration Firm Dynamics and Immigration: The Case of High-Skilled Immigration Michael E. Waugh New York University, NBER April 28, 2017 0/43 Big Picture... How does immigration affect relative wages, output, and

More information

ON ESTIMATING THE EFFECTS OF IMMIGRANT LEGALIZATION: DO U.S. AGRICULTURAL WORKERS REALLY BENEFIT?

ON ESTIMATING THE EFFECTS OF IMMIGRANT LEGALIZATION: DO U.S. AGRICULTURAL WORKERS REALLY BENEFIT? ON ESTIMATING THE EFFECTS OF IMMIGRANT LEGALIZATION: DO U.S. AGRICULTURAL WORKERS REALLY BENEFIT? BRENO SAMPAIO, GUSTAVO RAMOS SAMPAIO, AND YONY SAMPAIO The question of whether legalization affects immigrants

More information

Immigration and property prices: Evidence from England and Wales

Immigration and property prices: Evidence from England and Wales MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Immigration and property prices: Evidence from England and Wales Nils Braakmann Newcastle University 29. August 2013 Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/49423/ MPRA

More information

ECON 450 Development Economics

ECON 450 Development Economics ECON 450 Development Economics Long-Run Causes of Comparative Economic Development Institutions University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign Summer 2017 Outline 1 Introduction 2 3 The Korean Case The Korean

More information

The Wage Performance of Immigrant Women: Full-Time Jobs, Part-Time Jobs, and the Role of Selection

The Wage Performance of Immigrant Women: Full-Time Jobs, Part-Time Jobs, and the Role of Selection The Wage Performance of Immigrant Women: Full-Time Jobs, Part-Time Jobs, and the Role of Selection Christian Dustmann University College London, iza (Bonn) and cepr (London) and Christoph M. Schmidt University

More information

Do foreign workers reduce trade barriers? Microeconomic evidence

Do foreign workers reduce trade barriers? Microeconomic evidence Do foreign workers reduce trade barriers? Microeconomic evidence Martyn Andrews University of Manchester Thorsten Schank Johannes Gutenberg Universität Mainz Richard Upward University of Nottingham October

More information

Direction of trade and wage inequality

Direction of trade and wage inequality This article was downloaded by: [California State University Fullerton], [Sherif Khalifa] On: 15 May 2014, At: 17:25 Publisher: Routledge Informa Ltd Registered in England and Wales Registered Number:

More information

Presence of language-learning opportunities abroad and migration to Germany

Presence of language-learning opportunities abroad and migration to Germany Presence of language-learning opportunities abroad and migration to Germany Early draft (Do not cite!) Matthias Huber University of Jena Silke Uebelmesser University of Jena and CESifo June 21, 2017 Abstract

More information

Quantitative Analysis of Migration and Development in South Asia

Quantitative Analysis of Migration and Development in South Asia 87 Quantitative Analysis of Migration and Development in South Asia Teppei NAGAI and Sho SAKUMA Tokyo University of Foreign Studies 1. Introduction Asia is a region of high emigrant. In 2010, 5 of the

More information

GLOBALISATION AND WAGE INEQUALITIES,

GLOBALISATION AND WAGE INEQUALITIES, GLOBALISATION AND WAGE INEQUALITIES, 1870 1970 IDS WORKING PAPER 73 Edward Anderson SUMMARY This paper studies the impact of globalisation on wage inequality in eight now-developed countries during the

More information

The Effects of the Free Movement of Persons on the Distribution of Wages in Switzerland

The Effects of the Free Movement of Persons on the Distribution of Wages in Switzerland The Effects of the Free Movement of Persons on the Distribution of Wages in Switzerland Tobias Müller and Roman Graf Preliminary draft November 2014 Abstract This paper combines a wage decomposition method

More information

Do Foreign Workers Reduce Trade Barriers? Microeconomic Evidence

Do Foreign Workers Reduce Trade Barriers? Microeconomic Evidence DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 9437 Do Foreign Workers Reduce Trade Barriers? Microeconomic Evidence Martyn Andrews Thorsten Schank Richard Upward October 2015 Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit

More information

The Effect of Ethnic Residential Segregation on Wages of Migrant Workers in Australia

The Effect of Ethnic Residential Segregation on Wages of Migrant Workers in Australia The Effect of Ethnic Residential Segregation on Wages of Migrant Workers in Australia Mathias G. Sinning Australian National University and IZA Bonn Matthias Vorell RWI Essen March 2009 PRELIMINARY DO

More information

How do rigid labor markets absorb immigration? Evidence from France

How do rigid labor markets absorb immigration? Evidence from France Edo IZA Journal of Migration (2016) 5:7 DOI 10.1186/s40176-016-0055-1 ORIGINAL ARTICLE Open Access How do rigid labor markets absorb immigration? Evidence from France Anthony Edo Correspondence: anthony.edo@

More information

Statistical Analysis of Endorsement Experiments: Measuring Support for Militant Groups in Pakistan

Statistical Analysis of Endorsement Experiments: Measuring Support for Militant Groups in Pakistan Statistical Analysis of Endorsement Experiments: Measuring Support for Militant Groups in Pakistan Kosuke Imai Department of Politics Princeton University Joint work with Will Bullock and Jacob Shapiro

More information

TITLE: AUTHORS: MARTIN GUZI (SUBMITTER), ZHONG ZHAO, KLAUS F. ZIMMERMANN KEYWORDS: SOCIAL NETWORKS, WAGE, MIGRANTS, CHINA

TITLE: AUTHORS: MARTIN GUZI (SUBMITTER), ZHONG ZHAO, KLAUS F. ZIMMERMANN KEYWORDS: SOCIAL NETWORKS, WAGE, MIGRANTS, CHINA TITLE: SOCIAL NETWORKS AND THE LABOUR MARKET OUTCOMES OF RURAL TO URBAN MIGRANTS IN CHINA AUTHORS: CORRADO GIULIETTI, MARTIN GUZI (SUBMITTER), ZHONG ZHAO, KLAUS F. ZIMMERMANN KEYWORDS: SOCIAL NETWORKS,

More information

FOREIGN FIRMS AND INDONESIAN MANUFACTURING WAGES: AN ANALYSIS WITH PANEL DATA

FOREIGN FIRMS AND INDONESIAN MANUFACTURING WAGES: AN ANALYSIS WITH PANEL DATA FOREIGN FIRMS AND INDONESIAN MANUFACTURING WAGES: AN ANALYSIS WITH PANEL DATA by Robert E. Lipsey & Fredrik Sjöholm Working Paper 166 December 2002 Postal address: P.O. Box 6501, S-113 83 Stockholm, Sweden.

More information

Ethnic networks and trade: Intensive vs. extensive margins

Ethnic networks and trade: Intensive vs. extensive margins MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Ethnic networks and trade: Intensive vs. extensive margins Cletus C Coughlin and Howard J. Wall 13. January 2011 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/30758/ MPRA

More information

Does government decentralization reduce domestic terror? An empirical test

Does government decentralization reduce domestic terror? An empirical test Does government decentralization reduce domestic terror? An empirical test Axel Dreher a Justina A. V. Fischer b November 2010 Economics Letters, forthcoming Abstract Using a country panel of domestic

More information