Purchasing Protection? The Effect of Political Spending on U.S. Trade Policy. Political Research Quarterly, Vol. 57, No. 1. (Mar., 2004), pp

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Purchasing Protection? The Effect of Political Spending on U.S. Trade Policy. Political Research Quarterly, Vol. 57, No. 1. (Mar., 2004), pp"

Transcription

1 Purchasing Protection? The Effect of Political Spending on U.S. Trade Policy Jeffrey M. Drope; Wendy L. Hansen Political Research Quarterly, Vol. 57, No. 1. (Mar., 2004), pp Stable URL: Political Research Quarterly is currently published by University of Utah. Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use, available at JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use provides, in part, that unless you have obtained prior permission, you may not download an entire issue of a journal or multiple copies of articles, and you may use content in the JSTOR archive only for your personal, non-commercial use. Please contact the publisher regarding any further use of this work. Publisher contact information may be obtained at Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printed page of such transmission. The JSTOR Archive is a trusted digital repository providing for long-term preservation and access to leading academic journals and scholarly literature from around the world. The Archive is supported by libraries, scholarly societies, publishers, and foundations. It is an initiative of JSTOR, a not-for-profit organization with a mission to help the scholarly community take advantage of advances in technology. For more information regarding JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org. Sun Aug 19 22:44:

2 - Purchasing Protection? The Effect of Political Spending - -- on U.S. Trade Policy JEFFREY M. DROPE and WENDY L. HANSEN, UNIVERSITY OF NEW MEXICO The issue of whether or not money influences policymaking has been widely debated in American politics. While a direct link between money and policy outcomes has proven difficult to make, bureaucratic decisions on trade protection provide an opportunity to link politically active firms and industries to policy outcomes. The U.S. International Trade Commission (ITC) and the U.S. Department of Commerce both play a major role in making trade policy by administering several important trade laws, including the U.S. antidumping law. Firms can petition the ITC and Commerce for protection from foreign firms that are alleged to engage in the unfair practice of dumping their goods on the U.S. market. Evidence suggests, however, that firms use this law as a means of seeking protection from foreign competition, even when that competition is fair. As the stakes are high for both domestic and foreign firms, there is the potential for political influence. Focusing on lobbying activities and campaign contributions, we analyze the influence of domestic and foreign monies on bureaucratic decision making on trade policy The issue of whether or not money influences policymaking has been widely debated in American politics. While a direct link between money and policy outcomes has proven difficult to make, bureaucratic decisions on trade protection provide an opportunity to link politically active firms and industries to policy outcomes. In recent decades, increased global competition has led U.S. firms and industries to seek protection from foreign imports. One popular statute, the U.S. Antidumping Law, allows firms or industries to seek protection through the U.S. bureaucracy from the alleged practice of dumping, where dumping is defined as selling goods at below home market price or cost of production. We seek to determine the effect of domestic and foreign political spending on trade policy outcomes. By examining lobbying expenditures, soft money, and Political Action Committee (PAC) contributions of firms, industry associations, and other interested parties involved in a petition, we seek to determine whether or not such activities affect trade policy decisions. We are also interested in the role of foreign lobbying as a counter pressure to domestic interests. While it has been argued that foreign corporations are influential in U.S. politics (Choate 1990; Prestowitz 1988), very little systematic research has been done on policy impacts. Decisions under U.S. Antidumping Law involve two bureaucratic agencies. The International Trade Administration (ITA), an executive agency in the Department of Commerce, investigates dumping petitions and makes the decision on the unfair foreign practice of dumping. The International Trade Commission (ITC) is an independent NOTE: Wendy L. Hansen thanks the Joyce Foundation for prowding summer research support. Political Research Quarterly, Vol. 57, No. 1 (March 2004): pp regulatory agency with six politically appointed commissioners who make decisions, by majority vote, on the existence of injury to the U.S. industry by the alleged dumped imports. Affirmative decisions by both bodies result in the imposition of higher tariffs, as determined by the ITA, in order to counter the alleged dumping. Also, prior to a decision, a public hearing is held before the ITC on each petition in which both domestic and foreign parties may present their case before the commission. Evidence suggests that both agencies are susceptible to external political pressure (Baldwin 1985; Hansen 1990; Hansen and Park 1995; Hansen and Prusa 1996). Politically active firms andlor their associations may influence trade policy decisions in at least two ways. First, PAC contributions, soft money donations, and lobbying could be used to affect policy indirectly through the legislature. For example, the principal-agent and congressional dominance literatures as well as trade policy studies more specifically provide compelling evidence that members of the House and Senate have a stake in bureaucratic decisions and are active in influencing those decisions. In the case of trade policy, Senators and Representatives have attended public hearings held by the ITC to express their positions in favor of protection for a firm or industry Also, numerous hearings have been held in Congressional committees and subcommittees regarding the decisionmaking of the ITC and Commerce Department, and much legislation has been proposed and adopted, modifying the rules under which these bureaucracies operate in order to increase the likelihood that certain firms or industries will receive trade protection (e.g. see Hansen and Prusa 1996). Furthermore, public records exist of the contributions that firms give to specific congressional candidates, and firms must list in their lobby disclosure reports whether or not they are lobbying Congress directly and the reasons why. Thus a reasonable link may exist between firms' contributions and lobbylng efforts, and policy outcomes via Congress.

3 Second, firms or industry associations may directly lobby the executive branch or the bureaucracy to affect policy outcomes. Again, firms are supposed to disclose if and why they are lobbylng the executive andfor specific bureaucracies. Political appointees in the Commerce Department ultimately make decisions on unfair foreign practices. And ex- ITC commissioners (e.g. Paula Stern) have even become lobbyists for firms seeking protection. As profit-maximizers, firms and industry associations may spend time and money directly lobbying for favorable policy outcomes. In a case that neatly highlights the "politics" of antidumping disputes, state and federal-level politicians spoke publicly to the media and testified at hearings concerning alleged steel dumping by Japan (ITC case 731-TA- 807). Representatives Regula and Murtha and Senators Specter and Rockefeller testified before the ITC requesting punitive duties against Japanese steel exporters, while Senators Rockefeller, Byrd, and DeWine spoke out publicly to the media in favor of protection (Rushford 2000). Notably, among Senator Rockefeller's largest campaign contributors were five of the petitioners in this and several other steel cases: Bethlehem Steel, USX, Geneva Steel, Weirton, and the United Steelworkers of America. Additionally, at the time, the Senator was the third-ranking Democrat on the Senate Finance committee, which oversees the ITC. But politicians' relationships with industry constituents are more than just campaign contributions-simple shared interests also dominate their actions and interactions. While firms and industries promote their own health ultimately for maximization of profits, politicians care about the general welfare of their larger constituency because of the possibility of future support-either financial or more implicitly, in industries' voting employees. Shared interests happen on both sides of a policy debate. In a somewhat similar scenario, a firm opposed to protection was successful at securing a negative bureaucratic policy decision. In a set of three rubber cases (USITC Investigation numbers 731-TA-794, 731-TA-795, and 731-TA- 796), Michelin North America, a U.S. subsidiary of a French tire manufacturer, actively lobbied the executive, Congress, and the Department of Commerce ($167,000 in the year of the decision), successfully blocking protection against rubber imports from Brazil, Korea and Mexico. Unlike consumers who generally do not organize against protectionist policies, firms--domestic or foreign-that, for example, sell or use the imports as inputs into their production processes should have a stake in the policy outcome. The main purpose of this article is to build upon the literature that examines the behavior of the bureaucracy, while incorporating the theoretical logic and relevant empirical tests of the extensive literature that explores the relationship between political contributions and policy decisions. Moving beyond anecdotal evidence, we seek to examine systematically the political activities of firms and industry associations working both for and against the imposition of antidumping duties, in order to predict the impact of political contributions and expenditures on policy outcomes. The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. We begin with a brief discussion of the prior research, followed by a discussion of how it specifically relates to our theoretical framework and research design. Next, we highlight the general characteristics of antidumping cases, and outline the model and measures that we use to test these theoretical propositions. Finally, we summarize the main findings and the broader implications. There is still no definitive winner in the lively debate that explores if and how political contributions influence policymaking making. The evidence for and against the notion that "money matters" continues to accumulate on both sides of the debate. Researchers have tended to focus on PAC contributions in their search for a connection between money and influence. Much of this research explores the concept of "vote buying." Taking a different theoretical approach, research exploring lobbying influence has sought to identify causal mechanisms where analysts attempt to demonstrate whether or not lobbylng can increase access, and whether or not access actually leads to influence. Much of the early quantitative work suggests and tests for causal links between political contributions-particularly from PACs-and legislative results (Gopoian 1984; Saltzman 1987). More recently, Smith (2000: ) concurs that business "does exert some overt leverage over the outcomes of unifying issues," though he concludes that his empirical analysis suggests that this leverage is limited and that favorable public opinion and election outcomes are most important in determining legislative outcomes. Other scholarly efforts have avoided attempts to establish direct links between contributions and legislative outcomes, and have instead sought to establish links between patterns of giving and "access" to legislators. These approaches explore the notion that "access" is positively related to influence (e.g.langbein 1986; Wright 1990). While scholars have made important connections between political influence and both PAC spending and lobbymg, the theoretical and empirical literature, with some notable exceptions (Ansolabehere and Snyder 2000; Dwyre 1996; Magleby and Holt 1999), on the political influence of soft money is limited. Because the money goes from firms to the political parties and then specific candidates or causes, it is difficult to identify links accurately (Ansolabehere and Snyder 2000: 616). Nonetheless, soft money contributions are an important part of firms' overall political spending activities and we include them in our analysis. Other theoretical approaches emphasize the relationship between Congress and the bureaucracy The principal-agent model places central emphasis on major political institutions' (the principals) influence over public agencies (the agents). The model's ability to predict is predicated strongly upon the principal's control of the agent's resources (Wood 1988). Another major approach, the theory of congressional dominance, explores the regulatory process by focusing on

4 the indirect pressures that interest groups exert on the bureaucracy through Congress (Shepsle 1979; Shepsle and Weingast 1984; Weingast 1981). Scholars have refined this theory by hypothesizing that, in particular, congressional oversight committees-through control of agency budgets-play a critical intervening role in the relationships between interest groups and the bureaucracies (Seidman 1970; Weingast 1984; McCubbins and Schwartz 1984; Wood and Waterman 1991). We suggest that a combination of these approaches and theories will have the most utility in explaining the variation in bureaucratic decision making on trade policy Our objective, similar to Wright (1990: 417), "is to integrate lobbylng efforts and campaign contributions from coalitions of groups into an equation of group influence...." Furthermore, this research seeks to integrate the literature that explores empirically the impacts of different kinds of political spending on policy outcomes with theory that establishes links between politically active firms, members of congress, and the relevant bureaucracies. THEORETICAL ORIENTAT~ON AND RESEARCH DESIGN Recognizing Baumgartner and Leech's (1996a, 1996b) concern that analysts studylng the effects of contributions andlor lobbying on the political process have a propensity to make broad generalizations using narrow case studies, we propose that analyzing dozens of cases across one major bureaucracy allows for excellent variation on both the involved actors (i.e., different firms, industries, members of Congress, interest groups, etc.) and our substantive point of interest-the size of different types of political contributions and expenditures. We expect that firms will use some or all of the ways in their powers to influence government decisions that impact them. Thus, we look at the impact of all three spending measures, and also a combination of the three as a proxy for politically activity more generally. Furthermore, our study controls for other factors that could confound the results, including institutional and economic variables. In order to explore the relationships between the major actors-firms, congressional representatives, and the bureaucracies-it is necessary to identify ways to link both political spending and patterns of representation to the outcomes of these antidumping cases. Increased transparency and accessibility of political activity data can help to facilitate this task. First, in terms of PACs, we can track exact spending from specific firms to members of Congress. This information illuminates exactly who is giving, who is getting, and how much money is changing hands. Furthermore, in order to shed some light upon "why" firms are giving to Congressional members through their PACs, and consistent with principal-agent and congressional dominance theories, we can track amounts of PAC monies to the specific trade policy oversight committee members. While linking committees to specific policies or issues is not always straightforward (Romer and Snyder 1994: ), at least it is clear in the case of bureaucracies that implement trade policy that oversight lies with the House Ways and Means and Senate Finance Committees. Other research on trade policy has demonstrated the link between PAC spending, representation on oversight committees, and policy outcomes (Hansen and Prusa 1997; Moore 1992). Establishing reasonable links between firms' lobbying expenditures and Congress, the executive and relevant bureaucracies is also feasible using the data offered by lobbying disclosure reports (United States Senate 1999). For example, in 1999 (the only relevant year for which data are readily available), the reports indicate that in all but 1 of the 27 cases that involved lobbying (of a total of 34 cases that year), firms and associations in our sample explicitly cite international trade rules, domestic trade legislation, traderelated political appointees, import monitoring (the direct responsibility of the ITC), and import quotas as their reasons for lobbying.' Finally, taking advantage of a recent change in disclosure rules that compel every firm to describe more clearly in these reports to whom they lobby and how much they spend, we can actually begin to track the links directly. In 1999, firms disclosed in all but one of the 27 cases involving lobbying that they had lobbied all three of the executive branch, Congress and the Department of Commerce. Similarly, from ITC reports we have a record of all parties-firms, associations, lobbyists, expert witnesses, and members of Congress-that participated in each formal hearing. Generally, scholars have found that linking soft money to these outcomes is less straightforward particularly because of the circuitous route that money takes from the donor to the recipient. We do, however, have information on who gives soft money and how much they give. What is not known is to whom this money goes, and why. Nonetheless, because the firms and associations involved in our sample clearly participate in this type of political activity, we include it in the empirical analysis as a type of political spending. Finally, precisely because firms attempt to influence policy through different types of political spending, we argue that combining the different types of spending is also worthwhile. While previous literature has overwhelmingly emphasized the impacts of PAC spending, it is reasonable to expect that firms are using multi-faceted strategies that often rely on more than one type of political activity. Our data consist of 108 antidumping petitions filed between 1996 and We use 1996 as our starting date in order to take advantage of the new and better data afforded by the Lobbylng Disclosure Act of Among these cases, 59 percent of decisions were affirmative versus 41 percent ' Thus far, Congress has made these reports readlly available for only We cut off after 1999 because due to government information lags, a number of our key independent variables are not yet available for mclus~on.

5 negative. In our empirical analysis, we focus on the final outcome of a case, which in our sample is essentially the ITC's decision on injury, since in the time period of our study, only one of the 108 cases received a formal negative ITA decision on dumping. As the ITC has final veto power over the policy outcome (the ITC moves last in the decision process), its injury determination is the decisive factor in our ample.^ We incorporate the role of the ITA by using the degree of protection as an independent variable in predicting the final outcome (Devault 1993; Hansen and Prusa 1997). Our sample is ideally suited to an analysis of interest group influence. Scholars have demonstrated that campaign and PAC contributions appear to influence the policy process more when the issues are less visible (Jones and Keiser 1987; Morton and Cameron 1992; Schroedel 1986; Wright 1990). "Less visible" issues are thought to be more susceptible to interest group pressures. With only a few exceptions, the general public has very little knowledge of the activities of agencies like the ITC or ITA. Therefore, we should expect that these antidumping cases would be particularly vulnerable to this kind of pressure. Despite the relatively short time period, the institutional variation that might affect the policy outcomes is conspicuous. First, the composition of the commission changes dramatically from 1996 to Specifically, four new members (of a total of six) were appointed in this period. Additionally, because of vacancies on the commission andlor because commissioners sometimes recuse themselves, there are examples where, in only a one- or two-year span, entirely "different" commissions (i.e., different collections of commissioners) voted on separate cases.4 The composition of the commission also speaks to variation in presidential administrations-for nearly 40 percent of the cases in this study the ITC was comprised of a majority of commissioners appointed by a Republican administration. That being said, we anticipate that changes in presidential administrations do not necessarily make for differences in antidumping policy outputs. Scholars argue that presidents-regardless of ideology-due to their broader constituency and the need to implement effective foreign policy, are more interested in the widespread benefits of policies that favor free markets as opposed to the particularistic domestic benefits of protectionist policies (Keech and Pak, 1995; Lohmann and O'Halloran, 1994). Finally, though we do not have variation across control of congress by party, we do not expect partisan politics to be a significant issue. For example, bipartisan tension appears to dissolve as we witness Republican and Democratic members of Congress testifying at public hearings for the same side (e.g., USITC Investigation No. 731-TA-768, Atlantic salmon from Chile). ' The ITk recent propensity to rule that there is evidence of dumping contrasts somewhat with its pattern in 1980 to 1990 when they found dumping in 91 percent of cases (Hansen and Park 1995). Only two commissioners are required in order to enter a decision. Furthermore, a 50 percent split of voting commissioners by law goes to the affirmative (in favor of protection). Nevertheless, we collect and analyze appropriate political spending data on the two major parties in order to examine any possible relationship between dumping policy outcomes and congressional control. The general characteristics of the antidumping cases demonstrate both reasonable variation and several notable features and patterns. In terms of geographical representation across cases, almost every region of the globe is represented. The European Union countries are the most frequent targets, comprising nearly 15 percent of the cases. The majority of the remaining cases are spread relatively evenly among the NAFTA countries, Japan, China, Korea, the non-eu European nations, Taiwan, South America and the Southeast Asian countries. It is notable, however, that East Asia (China, Japan, Korea, and Taiwan) is a disproportionate target: they account for 41.7 percent of cases but roughly only one quarter of U.S imports during the time period of our study (United Nations ).5 In contrast, NAFTA products account for close to 30 percent of U.S. imports and only 11.1 percent of antidumping cases (UN ). This discrepancy, however, may be an indication that these countries typically resort to NAFTA mechanisms that address problems such as dumping. The nature of the industries involved in the antidumping cases also demonstrates both distinct patterns and variation. Overall, the 108 cases represent ten different broad industry categories. Each of construction products and steel products make up nearly a quarter of the antidumping petitions in the period of our study, while the plastics and chemical industry, and raw steel manufacturing combine for another quarter of the cases. The remainder of the cases is spread among the processed food sector, primary agricultural goods, electronics, textiles, minerals, and the auto/machinery sector. While many previous studies emphasize the large number of steel and steel-related cases, few pay sufficient attention to the heterogeneity of the traditional definition of "steel" when assigning each case to an industry category. While raw steel and steel products comprise 67 (62 percent) of the cases in this study, any overarching category of "steel" does not begin to capture the wide variation in production processes andlor the firms that produce these goods. Using the Harmonized Tariff Schedule of the U.S., the ITC reports make a clear distinction between 191 different steel and steel-related products in the antidumping cases in this time period. These cases involve dozens of domestic firms that vary considerably in size from small, highly technical and specialized manufacturing operations to multi-billion dollar conglomerates. Particularly relevant to this study, the distribution of political spending of the participating actors over the set of steel and related cases demonstrates tremendous variation with a range of $800 to over three million dollars. Also, 28 different countries are the targets of these petitions. It is important to note that the percentage of decisions involving these four countries in favor of protection is 63 percent, which is scarcely higher than the 59 percent of the overall sample.

6 Finally and most importantly, steel and steel-related cases do not appear to receive more favorable treatment than other industries-59 percent of steel cases received protection, which is identical to the larger sample. Nonetheless, we incorporate several different specifications of a steel dummy variable in the multivariate analysis to test for different treatment of that industry. There is also considerable variation across cases with regard to political spending more generally Overall, "politically active" firms participate in the ITC hearing process in 85 of the 108 cases in the sample. As Table 1 shows, on average, political contributions (either separately or as a sum of all three types of spending) by interests in favor of protection far outweigh contributions by interests opposed to protection. Much of the political spending opposed to protection comes from foreign firms. Though U.S. law does not constrain foreign corporations' lobbylng expenditures, there are prohibitions on PAC and soft money contributions; therefore we might expect opposition spending to be somewhat less. Interestingly, domestic firms opposed to protection, present in over 90 percent of the cases, are not as big of spenders as proponents of protection despite not having any of the constraints of their foreign allies and despite the potentially high stakes. Also interesting, the average total contributions by firms and industries in favor of protection are nearly twice as high in successful cases as it is for unsuccessful petitions. We seek to model bureaucratic decisions on trade policy. We expect that several key general factors-political and economic-will condition these policy outcomes. Politically, we anticipate that domestic factors like political spending and patterns of representation will affect decisions to protect. Economically, we predict that the economic merit of the case (the ITC explicitly considers measures of economic injury) and trade relations with the foreign countries will likely affect the provision of protection. Working from these factors, we hypothesize the following general model: Protection Decision = Po+ P, X (Domestic Political Factors) + P, X (Merits of Case) + P, X (Foreign Trade Relations) The dependent variable is dichotomous, indicating whether or not the petitioneds) was successful at receiving protection. We remove cases from the analysis that a firm has withdrawn with no explanation (a total of three cases). In the six cases where the Department of Commerce negotiated a settlement, we count the case as an affirmative decision because an agreement indicates that the firm or industry received enough favorable terms to suspend their request for protection (typically a price increase by the foreign party). We believe that such agreements result in a policy similar to an affirmative decision (Prusa 1992). Final Ruling Average PAC Contributions Affirmative-62 (59%) Negative-43 (41%) In Favor of Protection $ 780,829* $ 477,367 Average Lobbylng Expenditures Affirmative $1,056,831* Negative $ 515,842 Average Soft Money Contributions Affirmative Negative Average Total Political Contributions Affirmative Negative $ 143,624 $ 79,357 $1,981,284* $1,072,566 Opposed to Protection $ 40,497 $ 19,610 $218,798 $107,302 $ 28,791 $ 6,559 $288,086 $133,471 "Difference in means tests between affirmative and negative decisions within each spending category, p <.05. Domestic Political Factors One of the principal aims of this article is to incorporate direct measures of political pressure into the model. Previously, Hansen and Prusa (1996: 755) utilized industry-level PAC contributions as a crude measure of industry pressure. We refine this measure considerably by identifying the political contributions and lobbylng activities of every interested party-firm or association-involved in the petition during the year leading up to the final bureaucratic decisi~n.~ Because we believe that firms and associations employ various and varylng tactics to enhance their "access" to politicians, we explore the effects of each type of spending (PAC contributions, soft money contributions and lobbying expenditures) and also a composite measure of all three types of political spending to capture the overall impact of all spending activities. We have measures of firm and association spending for both "in favor of' and "in opposition to" implementing dumping duties for each type of political spending. We expect that higher contributions in favor of protection-regardless of the "type" of money-will increase the likelihood of an affirmative decision. By the same logic, we predict that the greater the contributions from firms opposed to the imposition of an antidumping duty, the more likely the decision will be negative. We use the year pnor to the final pollcy declslon for all of our data because the ITA and ITC typically take a minlmum of 280 days to produce a decision, and thls process can take up to 420 days

7 In an effort to explore more systematically the logic of theories of political spending that focus on Congress, we track PAC money from firms and associations to the members of the relevant congressional oversight committees- House Ways and Means and Senate Finance.' We seek to link political spending to specific, highly relevant members of Congress in order to examine how spending might influence their decision making. We anticipate that greater contributions by firms in favor of protection to oversight members will enhance the likelihood of an affirmative decision. Similarly, we expect that contributions to oversight members from those opposed to protection will increase the probability of a negative final case decision. The ability of firms or industries to influence policy outcomes might not be limited to the amount of money that they spend. Relationships with powerful and influential members of Congress can potentially serve their needs. Because congressional committees often have a more direct relationship with bureaucrats in government agencies due to their oversight responsibilities, we expect that the broad representation of the concerned industries in the constituencies of the appropriate House and Senate committee members will influence the outcome of petitions for protection. This relationship is consistent with the endogenous protection theory, and specifically the hypothesis that suggests industries enjoying broad political representation are more likely to receive favorable decisions to protect (Pincus 1975; Caves 1976). Furthermore, this relationship is also consistent with both principal-agent and congressional dominance theories. In our research, we are exploring specifically the breadth of representation of the affected industries on the appropriate oversight committees. Therefore, we use one measure to determine how many representatives from the House Ways and Means Trade Subcommittee have the specific industry in their district, and a similar measure to indicate how many senators from the Senate Finance Trade Subcommittee have the industry in their state. We predict that the greater the number of representatives or senators that have the industry in their district or state, the greater the likelihood that there will be an affirmative decision. We also want to test if money still matters when we control for representation. Finally, we utilize a measure of industry size to approximate interest group strength. We assume that larger industries, particularly because they tend to employ more people, will have more resources, and wield more political clout (Finger, Hall, and Nelson 1982). Therefore, we use employment as a measure representing industry size. We predict that industries that employ more people will be more likely to receive an affirmative decision. Merit of the Case By statute, the ITC is directed to take into account the overall economic health of the petitioning industry. Because quantitative, industry-level data ~rovide the commissioners with a reasonably good measure of the relative merit of a case, evidence of economic hardship should impact the decision making of the Commission. In order to capture this dynamic, we use the percentage change in capacity utilization. Similar to Hansen and Prusa (1996), we expect that a decrease in this measure will increase the likelihood of an affirmative decision. The overall pattern of import flows is another variable related to relative case merit and economic injury that previous studies have consistently found to influence an ITC decision (Baldwin and Steagall 1994; Hansen and Prusa 1997; Moore 1992). We assume that evidence of substantial dumping and injury will appear in the presence of major changes in import flows. Specifically, sudden increases in a country's share of U.S. imports in a particular sector may be evidence to suspect dumping and injury to the domestic industry. Therefore, we utilize the change in U.S.import share in the specific industry from the named country to represent this concept. This measure best reflects change that is not indicative of more general market shifts. Foreign Trade Relations While at the microeconomic level, the change in U.S. import share from the named country may affect bureaucratic decisions on injury reflecting the merit of a case, at a macroeconomic level, the broader trade relationship with the target country may also condition decision making on antidumping petitions. We use the U.S. trade deficit with the target country as a control measure of foreign trade relations. Though economists have yet to reach a consensus on the real effects of trade deficits, the public perception of these deficits tends to be negative. We expect that larger trade deficits will positively affect the probability of an affirmative decisi~n.~ ANALYSISAND RESULTS The results from our probit analyses, reported in Table 2, demonstrate some interesting general findings. From an economic perspective and consistent with our expectations, the measures of case merit are often significant in the models and always in the predicted direction. Also, the relationships between representation in the House and Senate oversight committees and the final decision to protect prove to be positive and statistically significant. Most importantly, even when controlling for economic merit of a case and congressional oversight, we find that there is a statistically significant positive relationship between petitioners' political activities and affirmative decisions on antidumping cases. We find that each individual measure of "political activity"-pac contributions, lobbying expenditures, and soft money donations-of firms andlor industry associations ' It is not possible to track either soft money or lobbying to specific members of Congress. Outside lobbying strategies may come into play here (see Kollman 1998).

8 = TABLE2 PROBITANALYSES OF U.S. ANTIDUMPING PETITIONS FOR PROTECTION, PAC LOBBY SOFT Combined To Oversight Model Model Model Model (PAC only) Coefficient Coefficient Coefficient Coefficient Coefficient Variable (S.E.) (S.E.) (S.E.) (S.E.) (S.E.) Constant -2.89** -2.56** -2.48** -2.67** -2.57** (0.72) (0.70) (0.69) (0.71) (0.70) Contributions in Favor of Protection 0.76** 0.47** 1.77* 0.28** 6.36* ($millions) (0.24) (0.17) (0.85) (0.10) (3.26) Contributions Opposed to Protection ($millions) Ways & Means Trade Subcommittee 0.25** 0.19* 0.17* 0.22** 0.19* Representation (0.08) (0.08) (0.08) (0.08) (0.08) Senate Finance Committee Representation 0.16** 0.16** 0.16** 0.15** 0.16** (0.05) (0.05) (0.05) (0.05) (0.05) Employment (thousands) % A Capacity Utilization % A Import Share Country Deficit ($billions) Number of Cases Number of Affirmative Cases Percent Affirmative Percent Correctly Predicted 81% 78% 74% 78% 73% seeking protection is positively related to affirmative deci- percent. In all models, the measure of political spending by sions for prote~tion.~ We also find that our combined meas- firms and/or associations in opposition to protection is posure of political spending of firms andfor associations seek- itive, which run contrary to expectation, though it is never ing protection is positive and statistically significant. The statistically significant.'' results suggest that, with all other variables held at their mean, one million dollars more in overall political spending lo In a separate effort to simplify the models, we replace the pair of spendincreases the likelihood of an affirmative decision by 10 ing-both "in favor of' and "opposed to" protection-variables with one measure that represents the difference between the two. In otherwise identical models, the new spending variables have positive coeffi- We also test for the possibility that a fourth type of political spendmg- cients that are similar in strength to the "in favor of protection" variable individual contributions to campaigns from firms' senior executives- in the original models; the soft money measure is significant at the.05 can affect the antidumping policy process. Using Dun & Bradstreet'sMil- level, while the other three measures are statistically significant at the 11on Dollar Directory (various years) to record the executives from the.o1 level. The models otherwise remain stable wherein all of the indepro- and anti-protection firms in our data set, we track their "personal" pendent variables demonstrate coefficients with the same direction and polit~cal spending using the Center for Respons~ve Politics' indivldual s~m~lar strength and stat~stical significance. We also try the spending donor search engine. When we run a model that replaces the spending variables as logged ratios of money in favor of money opposed to provariables with the new measures of indivldual contr~butions, we find that tectlon. Excluding the cases in each model where opposit~on money the indiwdual contribution coefficients are positive but not significant equals zero, we find that the new money ratio measures are positive and Furthermore, when we try adding these measures to the overall spend- significant at the 5 percent level. However, the house representation and ing measures, and re-run the model, we find only mlnute differences. change in capaclty utilization measures lose sign~ficance in both the Perhaps because the quantity of money involved in individual donations PAC and the overall models. S~milarly, if we replace zero opposition tends to be very small in comparison to firm or industry spending, the spending values wth a value of one dollar in order to include all cases, added contribution is minimal. the results are comparable

9 In order to examine the role of foreign lobbying as a counter pressure to domestic interests, we make a distinction between foreign and domestic monies opposed to protection. In this model, using overall political spending, we find as expected that foreign spending has a negative impact on the likelihood of protection, though it is not statistically significant. Similar to the measure of the overall opposition variable in our general model, the measure of domestic contributions opposed to protection is insignificant. Our two political measures that capture the breadth of representation in congressional oversight committees are both positive and statistically significant in all four models. Industries that operate in more districts/states of congressional oversight members enjoy a higher probability of trade protection. On the other hand, our general proxy measure for political power-the size of the industry-always has a negative coefficient, contrary to expectation but consistent with previous research (Hansen and Pmsa 1997), but the results are also statistically insignificant.ll As we predict, both measures of economic hardship are significant across the models, with the exception of the PAConly model where the measure for change in import share is not statistically significant. Generally however, an increase in capacity utilization means a petitioner is less likely to get protection, and if import share increases, the petitioners are more likely to get protection.12 From these results, it is reasonable to suggest that the bureaucracy does favor industries facing economic hardship, consistent with their mandate. In order to test the role that the ITA plays in the overall policy outcome, we include a measure that represents the tariff (antidumping duty) that will be collected on foreign imports in the case of an affirmative decision. Literature on the ITC suggests that the tariff rate, as an indicator of the severity of dumping and therefore, presumably, its relative overall merit as a genuine case of unfair trade or economic activity, may affect the final bureaucratic outcome (Hansen and Prusa 1997). This measure is positive but insignificant in all four models. We do not include this variable in our final model because we lose cases due to missing data. Our foreign trade relations variable, country deficit, is positive, consistent with our predictions, but the results are not statistically significant. In an alternative specification, we include three variables that test for other country effects. Historically, strong ties between Western Europe and the U.S. may lead to more favorable treatment, hence negative decisions; whereas cases against non-market economies, which typically rely on "constmcted value" measures of home market performance, may be more successful (see Tharakan for a discussion). Additionally, a recently contentious trade relationship with Japan suggests that it might be a more frequent target of protection. None of the dummy variables prove to be statistically significant.13 As reported in the last column of Table 2, in a more direct test of congressional dominance and principal-agent theories, we replace the total PAC spending measure with a measure of PAC contributions by firms or industry associations for or against protection only to the relevant congressional oversight committee members. Our results indicate that these more specific PAC measures behave similarly in the model when they replace the overall PAC measuresthey are both positive and the "in favor" money is statistically significant. All other coefficients are in the same direction as and are of similar strength to the overall PAC model. These results further buttress our theoretical contention that political contributions by these firms to congressional committee members and patterns of representation of these members related to the firms' industries can influence protection decisions. Because the Republicans control Congress during the time period of our sample, we test for party effects by separating the pro- and anti- protection PAC contributions to oversight committee members by political party Because contributions to Republicans and Democrats are highly correlated, it is not possible to include them in the same model. Instead we run separate models for each party Only the measure of contributions to Democrats in favor of protection is statistically significant. Since money to Democrats during li The results are the same ~f we use value of shipments as a measure of size Instead of employment. In other specifications, we lnclude a dummy variable to control for the fact that steel and steel related lndustnes represent the preponderance of cases. By vlrtue of its economic size, its employment base, and its tradition of successful labor organizing, it 1s possible that thls industry enjoys special treatment Though we expected a posltive relationship between steel industry involvement and affirmative decisions, no matter how we define steel (both wth and wthout manufactured products of steel), the dummy variable is not significant for any of the four models. Further, it is highly correlated with our measures of oversight. Similarly, because of the possibility of highly efficient organizational abilities, we control for the participation of unions. Like the steel dummy, the variable is signed positively, as expected, but is never significant. It is also highly correlated with our measures of political contributions. '* When we add percentage change in employment as an alternative measure of economic hardship to our models using 4 digit SIC level data (matched as closely as possible to the cases across the years of our study), the variable is never significant and our other results are virtually unaffected. l3 Despite the breadth of countnes involved, substantive evidence suggests that larger foreign pollcy goals do not have an impact on policy outcomes m our sample of cases. Unlike the Escape Clause law (e.g. most of the recent steel cases involving Europe), whlch Involves the president in the decision process and allows forelgn retaliation, the antidumping law is administered solely by the ITC and ITA, and does not, by law, allow foreign retaliation, and cannot be overturned by the president. While foreign policy considerations may play a larger role, particularly in the ITA decisions, which allege an unfair foreign trade practice, there is no variance in our sample because, as discussed above, in only one of the 108 cases did the ITA rule against U.S. firms. Though the NAFTA countries attempted to resolve other trade difficulties in either the Binational or Arbitral Panel processes, none of the 12 cases that involved either of the two NAFTA countnes-canada and Mexicc-became cases in these NAFTA dispute resolution mechanisms (we also controlled for participation of a NAFTA partner in separate specifications, and though the dummy variable IS always negative as expected, it is never significant). Similarly, while national governments are allowed to appeal U.S. decisions to the World Trade Organizationk Dispute Settlement Body, only one of the 108 cases was so appealed.

10 a Republican controlled Congress has a significant effect on protectionist decisions, one might expect similar patterns of influence during a Democrat-controlled time period.14 In the interest of exploring the stability of the effects of the independent variables in our overall model, we analyze two additional specifications of the dependent variable. First, we use an ordinary least squares model to analyze the percentage of commissioners voting in favor of trade protection. The direction and levels of significance of our independent variables do not change from the original models (Table 2). As a further test, we create a four-point quartile scale of the percentage vote in order to use ordered probit. These results are also similar to the original models. The nature of an antidumping decision suggests that selfselection could be a potential problem (Blonigen and Bown 2003; Hansen 1990). Since firms choose whether or not to petition the bureaucracy for protection, they may base that choice on what they perceive as their likelihood of success. We test for self-selection and find little effect on the overall results. Due to data constraints, resulting from the SIC to NAICS switch, we are only able to test for self-selection using 1998 and 1999 cases. Using STAT& Maximum-Likelihood Probit Model with Sample Selection we incorporate a model for a firm's decision of whether or not to apply for protection predicted by the percentage change in shipments and imports for each type of spending. While the models demonstrate self-selection, the decision stage yields coefficients of the same direction and similar levels of significance as our original probit models.'j Literature on the influence of political spending on policy outcomes is decidedly mixed. Typically, studies utilize congressional decisions, in some form, as the dependent variable, and PAC spending to operationalize political activity Perhaps, it is the complex nature of congressional decisions generally that has produced such inconsistent, " Also, particularly to test for party effects, we run the onginal models with year dummies. Only 1996, the year when more than half of the ITC commlssloners were appointed by a Republican adrn~n~stratlonthe "Bush" dummy-1s positive and significant at the 001 level, while other coeffic~ents are unaffected. l5 Though previous research nelther acknowledges nor treats the potentla1 for error correlat~on, we address thls by re-running each probit analysis uslng STAT.& "Cluster" technique. Specifically, cases filed by the same firm(s) against d~fferent countries but about the same set of products may share some of the same values across Independent vanables and are therefore assigned to the same cluster. The results for each model are similar to the "non-clustered" models In terms of the d~rect~on of the coefficients. However, In cases where the level of significance was at the 1 percent benchmark, the level drops to 5 percent. In the model that examlnes oversight monies, the level of s~gn~ficance of the measure of PAC spendlng to overs~ght members In favor of protection drops from the 5 percent level to the 10 percent level. Furthermore, because most clusters of cases Involve the steel Industry, our tests ulth the various specificat~ons of a steel dummy would also have p~cked up separately any error correlation difficulties. and sometimes contradictory, results. We argue that the specific characteristics of our set of cases and outcomes make it more suitable to explore the relationship between money and politics without succumbing to the confounding nature of the many variables that affect congressional decisions. It is also possible that analysts have often underreported political activity in previous studies because PAC activity only captures one part of overall political spending. While the literature has focused overwhelmingly on the influence of PAC contributions, we have extended the analysis to other types of spending including lobbylng and soft money. Moreover, by making a distinction between the different types of spending, we have begun to explore the causal relationships between the different types of money and policy outcomes. We also argue that our combined measure of spending-pac contributions, lobbying expenditures, and soft money-is extremely useful because it recognizes that firms and industry associations employ different kinds of strategies to obtain access and possibly influence. Finally, our study uses firm level rather than the typical industry level political spending data and includes relevant associational spending, a variable that analysts often overlook. Because most of the cases that we use in our study have a low public profile, we expect that firms and politicians have both incentives and opportunities to attempt to influence outcomes. Firms engage in political activities in a profit-maximizing manner to enhance their revenues and reduce their costs, while politicians have incentives to please important industrial constituents because of the potential for direct contributions and the votes of the industry's employees (Kollman 1998). Both parties recognize that low profile policy decisions are ideal because there are few observers to judge their activities. Simply, if a relationship between spending and policy outcomes exists, we would expect that it would show up in a set of cases such as requests to bureaucracies for protection. Thus, testing for this relationship in a "most likely" scenario suggests that subsequent research should strongly seek to identify a set of policy outcomes in "least likely" circumstances-testing for the relationship in a set of highly public cases where we expect behavior on both sides to be affected. The data demonstrate an unmistakable pattern across different types of political spending that the winners of antidumping cases tend to outspend the losers. Furthermore, the results indicate that industries that are located in more oversight committee members' districts or states enjoy a greater probability of favorable treatment from these regulatory agencies. Systematic analysis of policy outcomes suggests that, even when controlling for economic hardship, the more money that firms and associations that favor protection spend, and the more favorable the patterns of congressional representation, the more likely is it that they will enjoy an affirmative decision. Interestingly, spending-foreign and domestic-in opposition to protection is not significant. While it is not surprising that foreign money alone is not significant, considering that domestic firms or associations are listed in over

11 90 percent of the formal ITC petitions as opposing protection, the lack of significance of the opposition spending d l e s is surprising. There are several plausible explanations for the lack of significance of the findings for "opposition" monies. First, domestic industries that use the protected product may be able to rely on cheap goods from other sources. When a dumping case is filed and won against a particular country, higher tariffs may raise prices and reduce imports from that country, but other countries may pick up the slack with greater exports and lower prices. One of the major complaints about the usefulness of the antidumping law in protecting U.S. industries is the problem of other countries simply increasing their exports. Thus, when multiple countries export the product to the U.S., opponents of protection may not always face significant enough losses to justify large expenses to counteract thepolicy A second reasonable explanation lies more in the differences in the general characteristics of those parties lined up for and against protection. In all cases, the firms in favor of protection are seeking protection for a specific commodity that they produce-presumably the decision to protect will greatly and directly impact their competitor's price and therefore, most probably, the profits of both groups. In contrast it is possible that many of the firm-level actors opposed to protection use the soon-to-be protected item as one input in a much larger process, and therefore have less to gain from actively seeking to block protection. While protection will negatively affect their profits, the effects may be fewer ze!3maller in magnitude in many circumstances. Developing meaningful measures of the cost versus the benefits to e?ith firm opposed to protection is, unfortunately, far from straightforward. This challenge relates closely to another notable limitation of this and earlier research-the modelk measures of interest group strength and representation are really only representative of the parties in favor of protection. In other words, there are no measures of the inherent strength of the parties opposed to protection or their relationships to members of Congress. Unfortunately, because the interests lined up against protection tend to be considerably more varied (e.g. different industries using the same imported inputs), it is methodologically challenging to develop these corresponding measures. All that being said, precisely because opposition forces are potentially more fragmented and potentially have less at stake, we strongly suspect that these "missing" variables would have only minimal impacts on the overall results. Nonetheless, future research will have to attempt to address the complexities of developing better opposition measures in order to identify more definitively when, and how much, money "matters." Ansolabehere, Stephen, and James M. Snyder, Jr "Symposium: Law and Political Parties: Soft Money, Hard Money, Strong Parties." Columbia Law Review 100 (April): Baldwin, Robert E The Political Economy of U.S. lmport Policy. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Baldwin, Robert E., and Jeffrey W Steagall "An Analysis of United States International Trade Commission Decisions in Antidumping, Countervailing Duty and Safeguard Cases." Discussion Paper No Great Britain: Centre for Economic Policy Research. Barone, Michael, and Grant Ujifusa Almanac ofamerican Politics. Washington, DC: Times Mirror. Baumgartner, Frank R., and Beth L. Leech. 1996a. "The Multiple Ambiguities of Counteractive Lobbymg." American Journal of Political Science 40 (2): "Good Theories Deserve Good Data." American Journal ofpolitica1 Science 40 (2): Lobby Disclosure Data Set psu.edu~faculty/baumgartner/welcome.htm#research. Blonigen, Bruce A., and Chad E Bown "Antidumping and Retaliation Threats."Journal oflnternational Economics 60: Caves, kchard "Economic Models of Political Choice: Canada's Tariff Structure." CanadianJournal of Economics 9: Center for Responsive Politics Donor Lookup, Lobbying Data, Political Action Committees, and Soft Money Donor Search. Choate, Pat Agents of InfZuence: How Japan's Lobbyists in the United States Manipulate Americak Political and Economic System. New York: Knopf. Devault, James M "Economics and the International Trade Commission."Southern EconomicJournal 60 (2): Dun & Bradstreet Million Dollar Directory. Bethlehem, PA: Dun & Bradstreet. Dwyre, Diana "Spinning Straw into Gold: Soft Money and U.S. House Elections." Legdative Studies Quarterly 21 (3): Executive Office of the President of the United States North American Industry ClassiJication System-United States. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office. Federal Election Commission FEC Disclosure Reports-Political Action Committee. com/fecimg/index.html Finger, Michael J., H. Keith Hall, and Douglas Nelson "The Political Economy of Administered Protection." American Economic Review 72 (3): Gopoian, J. David "What Makes PACs Tick? An Analysis of the Allocation Patterns of Economic Interest Groups." AmericanJourna1 of Political Science 2 (2): Hansen, Wendy L "The International Trade Commission and the Politics of Protectionism." American Political Science Review 84 (1): Hansen, Wendy L., and Kee Ok Park "Nation-State and Pluralistic Decision-Making in Trade Policy: The Case of the International Trade Administration." lnternational Studies Quarterly 39: Hansen, Wendy L., and Thomas J. Prusa "Cumulation and ITC Decision Making: The Sum of the Parts is Greater than the Whole."Economic Inquiry 34 (October): "The Economics and Politics of Trade Policy: An Empirical Analysis of ITC Decision Making." Review of International Economics 5 (2): International Monetary Fund Direction of Trade Statistics Yearbook. Washington DC: International Monetary Fund. Jones, Woodrow Jr., and K. Robert Keiser "Issue Visibility and the Effects of PAC Money" Social Science Quarterly 68:

12 Keech, William R., and Kyoungsan Pak "Partisanship, Institutions, and Change in American Trade Politics." TheJoumal of Politics 57 (4): Kollman, Ken Outside Lobbying. New Jersey: Princeton University Press. Langbein, Laura I "Money and Access: Some Empirical Evidence." TheJoumal of Politics 48 (4): Lohmann, Susanne, and Sharyn O'Halloran "Divided Governments and U.S. Trade Policy: Theory and Evidence." International Organization 48: Magleby, David, and Marianne Holt "Soft Money and Issue Advocacy" Campaigns and Elections 20 (4): McCubbins, Matthew D., and Thomas Schwartz "Congressional Oversight Overlooked: Police Patrols Versus Fire Alarms." AmericanJoumal of Political Science 28: Moore, Michael "Rules or Politics? An Empirical Analysis of ITC Antidumping Decisions." Economic Inquiry July: Morton, Rebecca, and Charles Cameron "Elections and the Theory of Campaign Contributions: A Survey and Critical Analysis."Economics and Politics 4 (1): Pincus, J. J "Pressure Groups and the Pattern of Tariffs." Journal of Polit~cal Economy 83: Prestowitz, Clyde Trading Places. New York: Basic Books. Prusa, Thomas J "Why Are So Many Antidumping Petitions Withdrawn?"Journal oflnternational Economics 33: Roka, Fritz M "Estimating the Demand and Availability of Seasonal Agricultural Labor in the Southwest Florida Tomato Industry." Immokalee: Southwest Florida Research and Education Center. wwwimok.ufl.edu/veghort~pubs/workshop/roka. htm. Romer, Thomas, and James N. Snyder, Jr "An Emplrlcal Investigation of PAC Contribut~ons." AmericanJournal ojpolit1- cal Science 38 (3): Rushford, Greg "Tarlff Walls: Incentiv~zing Protectionism." The As~an Wall Streetlournal (October 20) Saltzman, Gregory M "Congressional Voting on Labor Issues: The Role of PACs." Industrial and Labor Relations Review 40 (2): Schroedel, J "Campaign Contributions and Legdative Outcomes " Western Political Science Quarterly 39: Seidman, Harold Politics, Position, and Power. New York: Oxford University Press. Shepsle, Kenneth A "Institutional Arrangements and Equilibrium in Multid~mensional Voting Models." American Journal of Political Science 23: Shepsle, Kenneth A., and Barry R. Weingast "Uncovered Sets and Sophisticated Voting Outcomes with Implications for Agenda Institutions." American Journal of Political Science 28: Smith, Mark A "Public Opinion, Elections, and Representation within a Market Economy: Does the Structural Power of Business Undermine Popular Sovereignty?" ArnericanJournal of Political Science 43, No. 3 (July): American Business and Political Power: Public Opinion, Elections, and Democracy. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Tharakan, P K. M "East European State Trading countries and Antidumping Undertakings." In P D. M. Tharakan, ed., Policy Implications of Antidumping Measures, pp Amsterdam: North Holland. United Nations International Trade Statistics Yearbook. Geneva: United Nations Press. U.S. Census Bureau Annual Survey of Manufacturers. www census.gov/prod/m/abs/industry.html U.S. Census Bureau Economic Census Summary Stat~stics for the United States. U.S. Census Bureau Table la-capacity Ut~lization Rates by Industry. U.S. Census of Agriculture and Cattle Calves-Sales 1992 and us-5l/usl-25.pdf U.S. Census of Aquaculture Census of Aquaculture. w w nass.usda,gov/census/census97/aquaculture/aquaculture.htm U.S. International Trade Commission, Dataweb. usitc.gov (Imports by Harmonized Tariff Schedule codes for ). U.S. International Trade Commission Invest~gat~ons (Antidumping) 731-TA-740 to 731 -TA-851. U.S. Senate-Office of Public Records Weingast, Barry R "Regulation, Reregulation, and Deregulation: The Polltical Foundations of Agency Clientele Relations." Law and Contemporary Problems 44: "The Congressional-Bureaucratic System: A Prlncipal-Agent Perspective with Applications to the SEC." Public Cholce 41: Wood, B. Dan "Principals, Bureaucrats, and Responsiveness in Clean Air Enforcements." Amencan Polltical Science Review 82 (1): Wood, B. Dan, and Richard W Waterman "The Dynamics of Political Control of the Bureaucracy" American Political Science Review 85, No. 3 (September): World Bank Indicators Table 6.6-Tarifl Barriers. www worldbank.org/data/wdi2ooo/pdfs/tab6_6.pdf Wright, John R "Contributions, Lobbying, and Committee Voting in the U.S. House of Representatives." Amencan Polltical Science Review 84 (2): Received: December 11, 2002 Accepted for Publication: March 4, 2003 jdrope@unm.edu wlhansen@unm.edu

The Textile, Apparel, and Footwear Act of 1990: Determinants of Congressional Voting

The Textile, Apparel, and Footwear Act of 1990: Determinants of Congressional Voting The Textile, Apparel, and Footwear Act of 1990: Determinants of Congressional Voting By: Stuart D. Allen and Amelia S. Hopkins Allen, S. and Hopkins, A. The Textile Bill of 1990: The Determinants of Congressional

More information

Economics and the International Trade Commission*

Economics and the International Trade Commission* Economics and the International Trade Commission* JAMES M. DEVAULT Lafayette College Easton, Pennsylvania I. Introduction U.S. trade policy over the last two decades has become increasingly reliant on

More information

1. The Relationship Between Party Control, Latino CVAP and the Passage of Bills Benefitting Immigrants

1. The Relationship Between Party Control, Latino CVAP and the Passage of Bills Benefitting Immigrants The Ideological and Electoral Determinants of Laws Targeting Undocumented Migrants in the U.S. States Online Appendix In this additional methodological appendix I present some alternative model specifications

More information

2017 CAMPAIGN FINANCE REPORT

2017 CAMPAIGN FINANCE REPORT 2017 CAMPAIGN FINANCE REPORT PRINCIPAL AUTHORS: LONNA RAE ATKESON PROFESSOR OF POLITICAL SCIENCE, DIRECTOR CENTER FOR THE STUDY OF VOTING, ELECTIONS AND DEMOCRACY, AND DIRECTOR INSTITUTE FOR SOCIAL RESEARCH,

More information

Obstacles Facing Developing Countries in Antidumping Cases: The Path From Initial Filing to WTO Dispute Settlement

Obstacles Facing Developing Countries in Antidumping Cases: The Path From Initial Filing to WTO Dispute Settlement Obstacles Facing Developing Countries in Antidumping Cases: The Path From Initial Filing to WTO Dispute Settlement Chad P. Bown * Bernard Hoekman ** Caglar Ozden *** May 14, 2003 VERY PRELIMINARY: PLEASE

More information

Codebook: International Trade Commission Antidumping and Countervailing Duties Cases

Codebook: International Trade Commission Antidumping and Countervailing Duties Cases Codebook: International Trade Commission Antidumping and Countervailing Duties Cases Variables 1. ITA No. Description: Code assigned to the case by the International Trade Administration in the Department

More information

Economy of U.S. Tariff Suspensions

Economy of U.S. Tariff Suspensions Protection for Free? The Political Economy of U.S. Tariff Suspensions Rodney Ludema, Georgetown University Anna Maria Mayda, Georgetown University and CEPR Prachi Mishra, International Monetary Fund Tariff

More information

Following the Leader: The Impact of Presidential Campaign Visits on Legislative Support for the President's Policy Preferences

Following the Leader: The Impact of Presidential Campaign Visits on Legislative Support for the President's Policy Preferences University of Colorado, Boulder CU Scholar Undergraduate Honors Theses Honors Program Spring 2011 Following the Leader: The Impact of Presidential Campaign Visits on Legislative Support for the President's

More information

Strengthening Protection of Labor Rights through Preferential Trade Agreements (PTAs)

Strengthening Protection of Labor Rights through Preferential Trade Agreements (PTAs) Strengthening Protection of Labor Rights through Preferential Trade Agreements (PTAs) Moonhawk Kim moonhawk@gmail.com Executive Summary Analysts have argued that the United States attempts to strengthen

More information

CRS Report for Congress Received through the CRS Web

CRS Report for Congress Received through the CRS Web Order Code RL30461 CRS Report for Congress Received through the CRS Web Trade Remedy Law Reform in the 107 th Congress Updated April 20, 2002 William H. Cooper Specialist In International Trade and Finance

More information

Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation

Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation S. Roy*, Department of Economics, High Point University, High Point, NC - 27262, USA. Email: sroy@highpoint.edu Abstract We implement OLS,

More information

SHOULD THE UNITED STATES WORRY ABOUT LARGE, FAST-GROWING ECONOMIES?

SHOULD THE UNITED STATES WORRY ABOUT LARGE, FAST-GROWING ECONOMIES? Chapter Six SHOULD THE UNITED STATES WORRY ABOUT LARGE, FAST-GROWING ECONOMIES? This report represents an initial investigation into the relationship between economic growth and military expenditures for

More information

GENDER EQUALITY IN THE LABOUR MARKET AND FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT

GENDER EQUALITY IN THE LABOUR MARKET AND FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT THE STUDENT ECONOMIC REVIEWVOL. XXIX GENDER EQUALITY IN THE LABOUR MARKET AND FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT CIÁN MC LEOD Senior Sophister With Southeast Asia attracting more foreign direct investment than

More information

Corruption, Political Instability and Firm-Level Export Decisions. Kul Kapri 1 Rowan University. August 2018

Corruption, Political Instability and Firm-Level Export Decisions. Kul Kapri 1 Rowan University. August 2018 Corruption, Political Instability and Firm-Level Export Decisions Kul Kapri 1 Rowan University August 2018 Abstract In this paper I use South Asian firm-level data to examine whether the impact of corruption

More information

Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US

Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US Ben Ost a and Eva Dziadula b a Department of Economics, University of Illinois at Chicago, 601 South Morgan UH718 M/C144 Chicago,

More information

Obama s Bold Economic Move on Chinese Tire Imports is Paying Off

Obama s Bold Economic Move on Chinese Tire Imports is Paying Off Obama s Bold Economic Move on Chinese Tire Imports is Paying Off September 1, 2010 Obama s Bold Economic Move on Chinese Tire Imports is Paying Off Initial Results Show Increased Domestic Production, Growth

More information

United States House Elections Post-Citizens United: The Influence of Unbridled Spending

United States House Elections Post-Citizens United: The Influence of Unbridled Spending Illinois Wesleyan University Digital Commons @ IWU Honors Projects Political Science Department 2012 United States House Elections Post-Citizens United: The Influence of Unbridled Spending Laura L. Gaffey

More information

Volume Title: The Political Economy of Trade Protection. Volume URL:

Volume Title: The Political Economy of Trade Protection. Volume URL: This PDF is a selection from an out-of-print volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: The Political Economy of Trade Protection Volume Author/Editor: Anne O. Krueger, Editor Volume

More information

THE year 2004 marked the centennial of anti-dumping (AD) policy, and the

THE year 2004 marked the centennial of anti-dumping (AD) policy, and the ANTI-DUMPING S HAPPY BIRTHDAY? 459 Anti-dumping s Happy Birthday? Jeffrey M. Drope 1 and Wendy L. Hansen 2 1 University of Miami and 2 University of New Mexico 1. INTRODUCTION THE year 2004 marked the

More information

Quiz # 12 Chapter 17 The Public Policy Process

Quiz # 12 Chapter 17 The Public Policy Process Quiz # 12 Chapter 17 The Public Policy Process 1. An interesting psychological characteristic associated with the concept of legitimacy is that most people a. accept what the government does as legitimate.

More information

Determinants of legislative success in House committees*

Determinants of legislative success in House committees* Public Choice 74: 233-243, 1992. 1992 Kluwer Academic Publishers. Printed in the Netherlands. Research note Determinants of legislative success in House committees* SCOTT J. THOMAS BERNARD GROFMAN School

More information

Ethnic networks and trade: Intensive vs. extensive margins

Ethnic networks and trade: Intensive vs. extensive margins MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Ethnic networks and trade: Intensive vs. extensive margins Cletus C Coughlin and Howard J. Wall 13. January 2011 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/30758/ MPRA

More information

WTO and Antidumping *

WTO and Antidumping * WTO and Antidumping * JeeHyeong Park Department of Economic Wayne State University April, 2001 The issues related antidumping are broad and complex. 1 In the following presentation, thus I will try to

More information

All s Well That Ends Well: A Reply to Oneal, Barbieri & Peters*

All s Well That Ends Well: A Reply to Oneal, Barbieri & Peters* 2003 Journal of Peace Research, vol. 40, no. 6, 2003, pp. 727 732 Sage Publications (London, Thousand Oaks, CA and New Delhi) www.sagepublications.com [0022-3433(200311)40:6; 727 732; 038292] All s Well

More information

Party Influence in a Bicameral Setting: U.S. Appropriations from

Party Influence in a Bicameral Setting: U.S. Appropriations from Party Influence in a Bicameral Setting: U.S. Appropriations from 1880-1947 June 24 2013 Mark Owens Bicameralism & Policy Outcomes 1. How valuable is bicameralism to the lawmaking process? 2. How different

More information

CRS Report for Congress Received through the CRS Web

CRS Report for Congress Received through the CRS Web Order Code RS21152 Updated May 30, 2002 CRS Report for Congress Received through the CRS Web Summary Steel: Key Issues for Congress Stephen Cooney Industry Analyst Resources, Science, and Industry Division

More information

Chapter Four Presidential and Congressional Constraints

Chapter Four Presidential and Congressional Constraints Chapter Four Presidential and Congressional Constraints The creation of independent regulatory commissions does not guarantee political independence. 1 This chapter briefly examines the role of presidential

More information

CRS-2 Production Sharing and U.S.-Mexico Trade When a good is manufactured by firms in more than one country, it is known as production sharing, an ar

CRS-2 Production Sharing and U.S.-Mexico Trade When a good is manufactured by firms in more than one country, it is known as production sharing, an ar CRS Report for Congress Received through the CRS Web 98-66 E January 27, 1998 Maquiladoras and NAFTA: The Economics of U.S.-Mexico Production Sharing and Trade J. F. Hornbeck Specialist in International

More information

Chapter 1. Introduction

Chapter 1. Introduction Chapter 1 Introduction 1 2 CHAPTER 1. INTRODUCTION This dissertation provides an analysis of some important consequences of multilevel governance. The concept of multilevel governance refers to the dispersion

More information

BEST PRACTICES IN REGULATION OF LOBBYING ACTIVITIES

BEST PRACTICES IN REGULATION OF LOBBYING ACTIVITIES BEST PRACTICES IN REGULATION OF LOBBYING ACTIVITIES QUERY Could you provide best practice examples on how to regulate lobbying activities? CONTENT 1. Lobbying, corruption risks and the need for regulation

More information

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr Abstract. The Asian experience of poverty reduction has varied widely. Over recent decades the economies of East and Southeast Asia

More information

Determinants of Outward FDI for Thai Firms

Determinants of Outward FDI for Thai Firms Southeast Asian Journal of Economics 3(2), December 2015: 43-59 Determinants of Outward FDI for Thai Firms Tanapong Potipiti Assistant professor, Faculty of Economics, Chulalongkorn University, Bangkok,

More information

The Effects of Political and Demographic Variables on Christian Coalition Scores

The Effects of Political and Demographic Variables on Christian Coalition Scores Res Publica - Journal of Undergraduate Research Volume 1 Issue 1 Article 6 1996 The Effects of Political and Demographic Variables on Christian Coalition Scores Tricia Dailey '96 Illinois Wesleyan University

More information

(a) Short title. This Act may be cited as the "Trade Promotion Authority Act of 2013". (b) Findings. The Congress makes the following findings:

(a) Short title. This Act may be cited as the Trade Promotion Authority Act of 2013. (b) Findings. The Congress makes the following findings: TRADE PROMOTION AUTHORITY ACT OF 2013 Section 1. Short title, findings and purpose (a) Short title. This Act may be cited as the "Trade Promotion Authority Act of 2013". (b) Findings. The Congress makes

More information

Lobbying in Washington DC

Lobbying in Washington DC Lobbying in Washington DC Frank R. Baumgartner Richard J. Richardson Distinguished Professor of Political Science, University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill, USA Frankb@unc.edu International Trends in

More information

Chapter 5. Resources and Trade: The Heckscher-Ohlin

Chapter 5. Resources and Trade: The Heckscher-Ohlin Chapter 5 Resources and Trade: The Heckscher-Ohlin Model Chapter Organization 1. Assumption 2. Domestic Market (1) Factor prices and goods prices (2) Factor levels and output levels 3. Trade in the Heckscher-Ohlin

More information

EXECUTIVE SUMMARY. Runaway Bureaucracy or Congressional Control?: Water Pollution Policies in the American States

EXECUTIVE SUMMARY. Runaway Bureaucracy or Congressional Control?: Water Pollution Policies in the American States EXECUTIVE SUMMARY Runaway Bureaucracy or Congressional Control?: Water Pollution Policies in the American States John A. Hoornbeek, 2004 University of Pittsburgh The Research Context: Over the last several

More information

Agency Design and Post-Legislative Influence over the Bureaucracy. Jan. 25, Prepared for Publication in Political Research Quarterly

Agency Design and Post-Legislative Influence over the Bureaucracy. Jan. 25, Prepared for Publication in Political Research Quarterly Agency Design and Post-Legislative Influence over the Bureaucracy Jan. 25, 2007 Prepared for Publication in Political Research Quarterly Jason A. MacDonald Department of Political Science Kent State University

More information

Chapter 6 Online Appendix. general these issues do not cause significant problems for our analysis in this chapter. One

Chapter 6 Online Appendix. general these issues do not cause significant problems for our analysis in this chapter. One Chapter 6 Online Appendix Potential shortcomings of SF-ratio analysis Using SF-ratios to understand strategic behavior is not without potential problems, but in general these issues do not cause significant

More information

THE FOLLOWING PUBLICATION DOES NOT IDENTIFY THE REQUESTER OF THE ADVISORY OPINION, WHICH IS NON PUBLIC DATA under Minn. Stat. 10A.02, subd.

THE FOLLOWING PUBLICATION DOES NOT IDENTIFY THE REQUESTER OF THE ADVISORY OPINION, WHICH IS NON PUBLIC DATA under Minn. Stat. 10A.02, subd. This document is made available electronically by the Minnesota Legislative Reference Library as part of an ongoing digital archiving project. http://www.leg.state.mn.us/lrl/lrl.asp Minnesota Campaign

More information

Segal and Howard also constructed a social liberalism score (see Segal & Howard 1999).

Segal and Howard also constructed a social liberalism score (see Segal & Howard 1999). APPENDIX A: Ideology Scores for Judicial Appointees For a very long time, a judge s own partisan affiliation 1 has been employed as a useful surrogate of ideology (Segal & Spaeth 1990). The approach treats

More information

Advocacy and influence: Lobbying and legislative outcomes in Wisconsin

Advocacy and influence: Lobbying and legislative outcomes in Wisconsin Siena College From the SelectedWorks of Daniel Lewis Summer 2013 Advocacy and influence: Lobbying and legislative outcomes in Wisconsin Daniel C. Lewis, Siena College Available at: https://works.bepress.com/daniel_lewis/8/

More information

The Spread of Antidumping Regimes and the Role of Retaliation in Filings*

The Spread of Antidumping Regimes and the Role of Retaliation in Filings* The Spread of Antidumping Regimes and the Role of Retaliation in Filings* Robert M. Feinberg and Kara Olson American University November 2004 Corresponding author: Prof. Robert M. Feinberg Department of

More information

Analyzing Non-tariff measures: collating evidence and setting research agenda. Emerging trends and issues in monitoring the use of NTMs

Analyzing Non-tariff measures: collating evidence and setting research agenda. Emerging trends and issues in monitoring the use of NTMs Analyzing Non-tariff measures: collating evidence and setting research agenda Emerging trends and issues in monitoring the use of NTMs 26-27 April, 2017 UNCC, Bangkok Cosimo Beverelli (World Trade Organization)

More information

Res Publica 29. Literature Review

Res Publica 29. Literature Review Res Publica 29 Greg Crowe and Elizabeth Ann Eberspacher Partisanship and Constituency Influences on Congressional Roll-Call Voting Behavior in the US House This research examines the factors that influence

More information

The Federal Advisory Committee Act: Analysis of Operations and Costs

The Federal Advisory Committee Act: Analysis of Operations and Costs The Federal Advisory Committee Act: Analysis of Operations and Costs Wendy Ginsberg Analyst in American National Government October 27, 2015 Congressional Research Service 7-5700 www.crs.gov R44248 Summary

More information

Chapter 11. Trade Policy in Developing Countries

Chapter 11. Trade Policy in Developing Countries Chapter 11 Trade Policy in Developing Countries Preview Import-substituting industrialization Trade liberalization since 1985 Trade and growth: Takeoff in Asia Copyright 2015 Pearson Education, Inc. All

More information

An Overview Across the New Political Economy Literature. Abstract

An Overview Across the New Political Economy Literature. Abstract An Overview Across the New Political Economy Literature Luca Murrau Ministry of Economy and Finance - Rome Abstract This work presents a review of the literature on political process formation and the

More information

The Effect of Institutional Characteristics. On Public Support for National Legislatures

The Effect of Institutional Characteristics. On Public Support for National Legislatures The Effect of Institutional Characteristics On Public Support for National Legislatures Stacy B. Gordon Fisher Associate Professor Katherine Carr Matthew Slagle Ani Zepeda-McMillan Elliot Malin Undergraduates

More information

Name: Class: Date: 5., a self-governing possession of the United States, is represented by a nonvoting resident commissioner.

Name: Class: Date: 5., a self-governing possession of the United States, is represented by a nonvoting resident commissioner. 1. A refers to a Congress consisting of two chambers. a. bicameral judiciary b. bicameral legislature c. bicameral cabinet d. bipartisan filibuster e. bipartisan caucus 2. In the context of the bicameral

More information

Inter- and Intra-Chamber Differences and the Distribution of Policy Benefits

Inter- and Intra-Chamber Differences and the Distribution of Policy Benefits Inter- and Intra-Chamber Differences and the Distribution of Policy Benefits Thomas M. Carsey Department of Political Science Florida State University Tallahassee, FL 32306 tcarsey@garnet.acns.fsu.edu

More information

Research Statement. Jeffrey J. Harden. 2 Dissertation Research: The Dimensions of Representation

Research Statement. Jeffrey J. Harden. 2 Dissertation Research: The Dimensions of Representation Research Statement Jeffrey J. Harden 1 Introduction My research agenda includes work in both quantitative methodology and American politics. In methodology I am broadly interested in developing and evaluating

More information

The Trade Liberalization Effects of Regional Trade Agreements* Volker Nitsch Free University Berlin. Daniel M. Sturm. University of Munich

The Trade Liberalization Effects of Regional Trade Agreements* Volker Nitsch Free University Berlin. Daniel M. Sturm. University of Munich December 2, 2005 The Trade Liberalization Effects of Regional Trade Agreements* Volker Nitsch Free University Berlin Daniel M. Sturm University of Munich and CEPR Abstract Recent research suggests that

More information

Final exam: Political Economy of Development. Question 2:

Final exam: Political Economy of Development. Question 2: Question 2: Since the 1970s the concept of the Third World has been widely criticized for not capturing the increasing differentiation among developing countries. Consider the figure below (Norman & Stiglitz

More information

Non-electoral Participation: Citizen-initiated Contact. and Collective Actions

Non-electoral Participation: Citizen-initiated Contact. and Collective Actions Asian Barometer Conference on Democracy and Citizen Politics in East Asia Co-organized by Institute of Political Science, Academia Sinica Taiwan Foundation for Democracy Program for East Asia Democratic

More information

Contiguous States, Stable Borders and the Peace between Democracies

Contiguous States, Stable Borders and the Peace between Democracies Contiguous States, Stable Borders and the Peace between Democracies Douglas M. Gibler June 2013 Abstract Park and Colaresi argue that they could not replicate the results of my 2007 ISQ article, Bordering

More information

ECON MACROECONOMIC PRINCIPLES Instructor: Dr. Juergen Jung Towson University. J.Jung Chapter 18 - Trade Towson University 1 / 42

ECON MACROECONOMIC PRINCIPLES Instructor: Dr. Juergen Jung Towson University. J.Jung Chapter 18 - Trade Towson University 1 / 42 ECON 202 - MACROECONOMIC PRINCIPLES Instructor: Dr. Juergen Jung Towson University J.Jung Chapter 18 - Trade Towson University 1 / 42 Disclaimer These lecture notes are customized for the Macroeconomics

More information

SERVICES, INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY AND THE MAJOR ISSUES OF THE URUGUAY ROUND

SERVICES, INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY AND THE MAJOR ISSUES OF THE URUGUAY ROUND 19891 SERVICES, INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY AND THE MAJOR ISSUES OF THE URUGUAY ROUND Claude E. Barfield* I am not going to talk services or U.S. competitiveness. I would really like to talk about the politics

More information

An Analysis of U.S. Congressional Support for the Affordable Care Act

An Analysis of U.S. Congressional Support for the Affordable Care Act Chatterji, Aaron, Listokin, Siona, Snyder, Jason, 2014, "An Analysis of U.S. Congressional Support for the Affordable Care Act", Health Management, Policy and Innovation, 2 (1): 1-9 An Analysis of U.S.

More information

Parliamentary Research Branch FREE TRADE IN NORTH AMERICA: THE MAQUILADORA FACTOR. Guy Beaumier Economics Division. December 1990

Parliamentary Research Branch FREE TRADE IN NORTH AMERICA: THE MAQUILADORA FACTOR. Guy Beaumier Economics Division. December 1990 Background Paper BP-247E FREE TRADE IN NORTH AMERICA: THE MAQUILADORA FACTOR Guy Beaumier Economics Division December 1990 Library of Parliament Bibliothèque du Parlement Parliamentary Research Branch

More information

The End of the Multi-fiber Arrangement on January 1, 2005

The End of the Multi-fiber Arrangement on January 1, 2005 On January 1 2005, the World Trade Organization agreement on textiles and clothing expired. All WTO members have unrestricted access to the American and European markets for their textiles exports. The

More information

Educated Preferences: Explaining Attitudes Toward Immigration In Europe. Jens Hainmueller and Michael J. Hiscox. Last revised: December 2005

Educated Preferences: Explaining Attitudes Toward Immigration In Europe. Jens Hainmueller and Michael J. Hiscox. Last revised: December 2005 Educated Preferences: Explaining Attitudes Toward Immigration In Jens Hainmueller and Michael J. Hiscox Last revised: December 2005 Supplement III: Detailed Results for Different Cutoff points of the Dependent

More information

FOREIGN FIRMS AND INDONESIAN MANUFACTURING WAGES: AN ANALYSIS WITH PANEL DATA

FOREIGN FIRMS AND INDONESIAN MANUFACTURING WAGES: AN ANALYSIS WITH PANEL DATA FOREIGN FIRMS AND INDONESIAN MANUFACTURING WAGES: AN ANALYSIS WITH PANEL DATA by Robert E. Lipsey & Fredrik Sjöholm Working Paper 166 December 2002 Postal address: P.O. Box 6501, S-113 83 Stockholm, Sweden.

More information

Non-Voted Ballots and Discrimination in Florida

Non-Voted Ballots and Discrimination in Florida Non-Voted Ballots and Discrimination in Florida John R. Lott, Jr. School of Law Yale University 127 Wall Street New Haven, CT 06511 (203) 432-2366 john.lott@yale.edu revised July 15, 2001 * This paper

More information

Has the Byrd Amendment affected U.S. Imports?

Has the Byrd Amendment affected U.S. Imports? Has the Byrd Amendment affected U.S. Imports? Philip G. Gayle Kansas State University Thitima Puttitanun San Diego State University May 2007 Abstract The Continued Dumping and Subsidy Offset Act (CDSOA),

More information

Online Appendix. December 6, Full-text Stimulus Articles

Online Appendix. December 6, Full-text Stimulus Articles Online Appendix Rune Slothuus and Claes H. de Vreese: Political Parties, Motivated Reasoning, and Issue Framing Effects Accepted for publication in Journal of Politics December 6, 2009 Full-text Stimulus

More information

Full clear download (no formatting errors) at:

Full clear download (no formatting errors) at: International Economics 7th Edition Gerber TEST BANK Full clear download (no formatting errors) at: https://testbankreal.com/download/international-economics-7th-editiongerber-test-bank/ International

More information

The Case of the Disappearing Bias: A 2014 Update to the Gerrymandering or Geography Debate

The Case of the Disappearing Bias: A 2014 Update to the Gerrymandering or Geography Debate The Case of the Disappearing Bias: A 2014 Update to the Gerrymandering or Geography Debate Nicholas Goedert Lafayette College goedertn@lafayette.edu May, 2015 ABSTRACT: This note observes that the pro-republican

More information

Unit 1 Introduction to Comparative Politics Test Multiple Choice 2 pts each

Unit 1 Introduction to Comparative Politics Test Multiple Choice 2 pts each Unit 1 Introduction to Comparative Politics Test Multiple Choice 2 pts each 1. Which of the following is NOT considered to be an aspect of globalization? A. Increased speed and magnitude of cross-border

More information

Article XIX. Emergency Action on Imports of Particular Products

Article XIX. Emergency Action on Imports of Particular Products 1 ARTICLE XIX... 1 1.1 Text of Article XIX... 1 1.2 General... 2 1.2.1 Application of Article XIX... 2 1.2.2 Standard of review... 4 1.3 Article XIX:1: "as a result of unforeseen developments"... 4 1.3.1

More information

Empirical Analyses of U.S. Congressional Voting on Recent FTA Bills

Empirical Analyses of U.S. Congressional Voting on Recent FTA Bills KIEP Working Paper 08-08 Empirical Analyses of U.S. Congressional Voting on Recent FTA Bills Hyejoon Im and Hankyoung Sung KIEP Working Paper 08-08 Empirical Analyses of U.S. Congressional Voting on Recent

More information

Money In Politics: A little or a lot? During the summer of 2018, I spent 8 weeks interning at The Morning Group, a political

Money In Politics: A little or a lot? During the summer of 2018, I spent 8 weeks interning at The Morning Group, a political Marlene Artov John Brademas Center NYU Summer 2018 Money In Politics: A little or a lot? During the summer of 2018, I spent 8 weeks interning at The Morning Group, a political fundraising firm in Washington

More information

Trends in Campaign Financing, Report for the Campaign Finance Task Force October 12 th, 2017 Zachary Albert

Trends in Campaign Financing, Report for the Campaign Finance Task Force October 12 th, 2017 Zachary Albert 1 Trends in Campaign Financing, 198-216 Report for the Campaign Finance Task Force October 12 th, 217 Zachary Albert 2 Executive Summary:! The total amount of money in elections including both direct contributions

More information

Judicial Elections and Their Implications in North Carolina. By Samantha Hovaniec

Judicial Elections and Their Implications in North Carolina. By Samantha Hovaniec Judicial Elections and Their Implications in North Carolina By Samantha Hovaniec A Thesis submitted to the faculty of the University of North Carolina in partial fulfillment of the requirements of a degree

More information

Working Paper Series: No. 89

Working Paper Series: No. 89 A Comparative Survey of DEMOCRACY, GOVERNANCE AND DEVELOPMENT Working Paper Series: No. 89 Jointly Published by Non-electoral Participation: Citizen-initiated Contactand Collective Actions Yu-Sung Su Associate

More information

Wisconsin Economic Scorecard

Wisconsin Economic Scorecard RESEARCH PAPER> May 2012 Wisconsin Economic Scorecard Analysis: Determinants of Individual Opinion about the State Economy Joseph Cera Researcher Survey Center Manager The Wisconsin Economic Scorecard

More information

TPP and Exchange Rates

TPP and Exchange Rates TPP and Exchange Rates 20 C. FRED BERGSTEN AND JEFFREY J. SCHOTT The Trans-Pacific Partnership (TPP) has achieved an important distinction in the history of trade policy. It is the first ever free trade

More information

UNIT 1: Parliamentary Committees in Democracies

UNIT 1: Parliamentary Committees in Democracies UNIT 1: Parliamentary Committees in Democracies Learning Objectives How do parliamentary committees contribute to governance? After studying this unit you should: Have a better understanding of the functions

More information

to demonstrate financial strength and noteworthy success in adapting to the more stringent

to demonstrate financial strength and noteworthy success in adapting to the more stringent Party Fundraising Success Continues Through Mid-Year The Brookings Institution, August 2, 2004 Anthony Corrado, Visiting Fellow, Governance Studies With only a few months remaining before the 2004 elections,

More information

Randall S. Kroszner Graduate School of Business University of Chicago Chicago, IL and N.B.E.R. and

Randall S. Kroszner Graduate School of Business University of Chicago Chicago, IL and N.B.E.R. and DOES POLITICAL AMBIGUITY PAY? CORPORATE CAMPAIGN CONTRIBUTIONS AND THE REWARDS TO LEGISLATOR REPUTATION* Randall S. Kroszner Graduate School of Business University of Chicago Chicago, IL 60637 and N.B.E.R.

More information

1. States must meet certain requirements in drawing district boundaries. Identify one of these requirements.

1. States must meet certain requirements in drawing district boundaries. Identify one of these requirements. Multiple Choice 1. States must meet certain requirements in drawing district boundaries. Identify one of these requirements. a. A person's vote in the largest district of a state must have only half the

More information

CRS Report for Congress Received through the CRS Web

CRS Report for Congress Received through the CRS Web CRS Report for Congress Received through the CRS Web 97-1040 GOV Updated June 14, 1999 Campaign Financing: Highlights and Chronology of Current Federal Law Summary Joseph E. Cantor Specialist in American

More information

Lobbying and Policy Change in

Lobbying and Policy Change in Lobbying and Policy Change in Washington Presentation to class November 12, 2008 Prof. Baumgartner PLSC 083T Power in Washington Penn State t University it A Collaborative Project Frank Baumgartner, Penn

More information

Buying Elections in a Post-Citizens United World: The Effect of Campaign Spending in House Elections Since 2010

Buying Elections in a Post-Citizens United World: The Effect of Campaign Spending in House Elections Since 2010 Buying Elections in a Post-Citizens United World: The Effect of Campaign Spending in House Elections Since 2010 Malcom Fox Political Science Advisor Al Montero Abstract To what extent does campaign spending

More information

Volume 35, Issue 1. An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach

Volume 35, Issue 1. An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach Volume 35, Issue 1 An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach Brian Hibbs Indiana University South Bend Gihoon Hong Indiana University South Bend Abstract This

More information

Advocates and Interest Representation in Policy Debates

Advocates and Interest Representation in Policy Debates Advocates and Interest Representation in Policy Debates Marie Hojnacki Penn State University marieh@psu.edu Kathleen Marchetti Penn State University kathleen.maeve@gmail.com Frank R. Baumgartner University

More information

Author(s) Title Date Dataset(s) Abstract

Author(s) Title Date Dataset(s) Abstract Author(s): Traugott, Michael Title: Memo to Pilot Study Committee: Understanding Campaign Effects on Candidate Recall and Recognition Date: February 22, 1990 Dataset(s): 1988 National Election Study, 1989

More information

Imagine Canada s Sector Monitor

Imagine Canada s Sector Monitor Imagine Canada s Sector Monitor David Lasby, Director, Research & Evaluation Emily Cordeaux, Coordinator, Research & Evaluation IN THIS REPORT Introduction... 1 Highlights... 2 How many charities engage

More information

Organized Interests, Legislators, and Bureaucratic Structure

Organized Interests, Legislators, and Bureaucratic Structure Organized Interests, Legislators, and Bureaucratic Structure Stuart V. Jordan and Stéphane Lavertu Preliminary, Incomplete, Possibly not even Spellchecked. Please don t cite or circulate. Abstract Most

More information

Private sector fundraising and partnerships

Private sector fundraising and partnerships Executive Committee of the High Commissioner s Programme Distr.: Restricted 31 August 2018 English Original: English and French Standing Committee 73 rd meeting Private sector fundraising and partnerships

More information

title, Routledge, September 2008: 234x156:

title, Routledge, September 2008: 234x156: Trade Policy, Inequality and Performance in Indian Manufacturing Kunal Sen IDPM, University of Manchester Presentation based on my book of the same title, Routledge, September 2008: 234x156: 198pp, Hb:

More information

Preview. Chapter 9. The Cases for Free Trade. The Cases for Free Trade (cont.) The Political Economy of Trade Policy

Preview. Chapter 9. The Cases for Free Trade. The Cases for Free Trade (cont.) The Political Economy of Trade Policy Chapter 9 The Political Economy of Trade Policy Preview The cases for free trade The cases against free trade Political models of trade policy International negotiations of trade policy and the World Trade

More information

LESSON Money and Politics

LESSON Money and Politics LESSON 22 157-168 Money and Politics 1 EFFORTS TO REFORM Strategies to prevent abuse in political contributions Imposing limitations on giving, receiving, and spending political money Requiring public

More information

Chapter 7: Legislatures

Chapter 7: Legislatures Chapter 7: Legislatures Objectives Explain the role and activities of the legislature. Discuss how the legislatures are organized and how they operate. Identify the characteristics of the state legislators.

More information

Strategic Partisanship: Party Priorities, Agenda Control and the Decline of Bipartisan Cooperation in the House

Strategic Partisanship: Party Priorities, Agenda Control and the Decline of Bipartisan Cooperation in the House Strategic Partisanship: Party Priorities, Agenda Control and the Decline of Bipartisan Cooperation in the House Laurel Harbridge Assistant Professor, Department of Political Science Faculty Fellow, Institute

More information

Summary During 2007, both the House and Senate established new earmark transparency procedures for their separate chambers. They provide for public di

Summary During 2007, both the House and Senate established new earmark transparency procedures for their separate chambers. They provide for public di House and Senate Procedural Rules Concerning Earmark Disclosure Sandy Streeter Analyst on Congress and the Legislative Process November 18, 2009 Congressional Research Service CRS Report for Congress Prepared

More information

Abdurohman Ali Hussien,,et.al.,Int. J. Eco. Res., 2012, v3i3, 44-51

Abdurohman Ali Hussien,,et.al.,Int. J. Eco. Res., 2012, v3i3, 44-51 THE IMPACT OF TRADE LIBERALIZATION ON TRADE SHARE AND PER CAPITA GDP: EVIDENCE FROM SUB SAHARAN AFRICA Abdurohman Ali Hussien, Terrasserne 14, 2-256, Brønshøj 2700; Denmark ; abdurohman.ali.hussien@gmail.com

More information

2011 National Opinion Poll: Canadian Views on Asia

2011 National Opinion Poll: Canadian Views on Asia 2011 National Opinion Poll: Canadian Views on Asia Table of Contents Methodology Key Findings Section 1: Canadians Mental Maps Section 2: Views of Canada-Asia Economic Relations Section 3: Perceptions

More information

NATIONAL OPINION POLL: CANADIAN VIEWS ON ASIA

NATIONAL OPINION POLL: CANADIAN VIEWS ON ASIA NATIONAL OPINION POLL: CANADIAN VIEWS ON ASIA Copyright 2014 Asia Pacific Foundation of Canada TABLE OF CONTENTS ABOUT THE ASIA PACIFIC FOUNDATION OF CANADA 2 ABOUT THE NATIONAL OPINION POLL: CANADIAN

More information

Julie Lenggenhager. The "Ideal" Female Candidate

Julie Lenggenhager. The Ideal Female Candidate Julie Lenggenhager The "Ideal" Female Candidate Why are there so few women elected to positions in both gubernatorial and senatorial contests? Since the ratification of the nineteenth amendment in 1920

More information