Stephanie Rickard Democratic differences: electoral institutions and compliance with GATT/WTO agreements Article (Accepted version) (Refereed)

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Stephanie Rickard Democratic differences: electoral institutions and compliance with GATT/WTO agreements Article (Accepted version) (Refereed)"

Transcription

1 Stephanie Rickard Democratic differences: electoral institutions and compliance with GATT/WTO agreements Article (Accepted version) (Refereed) Original citation: Rickard, Stephanie (2010) Democratic differences: electoral institutions and compliance with GATT/WTO agreements. European journal of international relations, 16 (4). pp ISSN DOI: / European Consortium for Political Research, SAGE Publications This version available at: Available in LSE Research Online: April 2012 LSE has developed LSE Research Online so that users may access research output of the School. Copyright and Moral Rights for the papers on this site are retained by the individual authors and/or other copyright owners. Users may download and/or print one copy of any article(s) in LSE Research Online to facilitate their private study or for non-commercial research. You may not engage in further distribution of the material or use it for any profit-making activities or any commercial gain. You may freely distribute the URL ( of the LSE Research Online website. This document is the author s final manuscript accepted version of the journal article, incorporating any revisions agreed during the peer review process. Some differences between this version and the published version may remain. You are advised to consult the publisher s version if you wish to cite from it.

2 Democratic Differences: Electoral institutions and compliance with GATT/WTO agreements Stephanie J. Rickard London School of Economics A growing body of literature argues that democracies are more likely to comply with international agreements than authoritarian states. However, substantial variation exists in the compliance behaviour of democracies. How can this variation be explained? The same mechanism that links regime type to compliance, namely electoral competition, also explains variation in compliance amongst democracies. This is because the nature of electoral competition varies across democratic systems. An analysis of democratic GATT/WTO member countries from 1980 to 2003 reveals that countries with majoritarian electoral rules and/or single-member districts are more likely to violate GATT/WTO agreements than those with proportional electoral rules and/or multi-member districts. Keywords: GATT/WTO, electoral rules, democracy, compliance, international agreements [Accepted Version. April 7, Provided by author.] Forthcoming in European Journal of International Relations. Please cite the Published Version. 1

3 A growing body of literature argues that democracies are more likely to comply with international agreements than authoritarian states (e.g. Gaubatz, 1996; Mansfield, Milner and Rosendorff, 2002; Smith, 1996). Such arguments often point to the deterrent effect of democratic elections. Voters are believed to punish leaders who violate international agreements by voting against them in the next election. This makes it costly for democratically elected leaders to breach international agreements; doing so reduces their chance of staying in office (McGillivray and Smith, 2000). Electorally minded leaders in democratic states therefore comply with international agreements to maximize their chances of re-election, according to conventional wisdom. The implication is that democratic states violate international agreements less frequently than authoritarian states. However, significant variation in compliance behaviour exists amongst democracies. While some consistently comply with international agreements, others habitually violate them. In fact, the most frequent violators of agreements negotiated within the framework of the World Trade Organization (WTO) are high-functioning democracies with strong, credible opposition parties and regular competitive elections. This poses a puzzle for existing theories of democratic compliance, particularly those that place primary importance on the deterrent effects of competitive elections. If elections deter non-compliance, as conventional wisdom suggests, why do some democratically elected leaders violate international agreements more often than others? A possible explanation is the significant variation in electoral competition that exists amongst democratic states. This variation is a result of the different rules used to elect leaders. In majoritarian systems, politicians need 50 percent plus one of the votes in their electoral district to win (re)election; parties need to win a majority of the 2

4 districts to win control of the legislature. This engenders candidate-centred electoral competition where narrow interests have substantial political influence (e.g. Carey and Shugart, 1995; Persson & Tabellini, 2003). In contrast, proportional electoral rules (PR) engender party-centred competition. In these systems, parties work to maximize their share of the national vote because this determines the number of legislative seats the party will control. This variation in how democratic leaders are elected may help to explain why some democracies violate international agreements more often than others. Virtually all international agreements have distributive consequences that make some voters better off and others worse off (Tomz, 2002). For example, the World Trade Organization s Agreement on Subsidies and Countervailing Measures restrict the use of subsidies by member-country governments. Subsidies targeted to individual industries or firms are explicitly banned by Articles 1 through 9. i These restrictions are intended to increase economic efficiency and reduce costs to consumers. Consumers, who constitute a large segment of countries populations, benefit from compliance with these rules. In contrast, narrow segments of the population, like domestic producers, lose out from compliance. Producers including individual firms and industries would like to be able to earn rents from lucrative government subsidies. They would prefer that their national government violate these rules. Non-compliance with this international agreement benefits narrow producer groups; it serves their own self-interest. This is an important point one that has been largely overlooked in existing studies of international compliance. If voters preferences over compliance with an international agreement vary, the effect of democratic elections on compliance is ambiguous. The impact of democracy will depend critically on the electoral incentives 3

5 facing politicians and voter support for compliance. If, for example, compliance with an international agreement benefits broad-based groups, like consumers, then politicians in proportional rule countries have relatively greater electoral incentives to comply with the agreement. This is because the best electoral strategy for politicians and parties in proportional rule systems is to appeal to broad segments of the population in order to maximize the party s vote share (e.g. Carey and Shugart, 1995; Persson & Tabellini, 2003). Vote share determines the number of seats a party will control in the country s legislature. By maximizing its vote share, a party maximizes its power in the legislature and its chances of being in government. This implies that amongst democracies, those with proportional electoral rules are relatively more likely to comply with international agreements that benefit broad segments of a country s population, such as the GATT/WTO restrictions on narrow transfers. In contrast, democracies with plurality (or majoritarian) electoral rules are relatively more likely to violate GATT/WTO restrictions on narrow transfers. By providing narrow transfers, politicians can target benefits to constituents in their geographically-defined district thereby increasing their chances of re-election (e.g. Persson & Tabellini, 2003). Parties competing in two-party majoritarian systems can use narrow transfers to target benefits to key electoral districts. ii In this way, the provision of narrow transfers maximizes the chances of electoral success for parties and politicians competing in majoritarian systems. The implication is that democracies with majoritarian electoral rules are more likely to violate GATT/WTO restrictions on narrow transfers, as compared to proportional rule democracies. Instances of non-compliance with GATT/WTO restrictions on narrow transfers amongst democratic member countries from 1980 to 2003 are analyzed here to assess the empirical validity of this argument. Consistent with expectations, 4

6 majoritarian democracies are found to be more likely to violate GATT/WTO restrictions on narrow transfers, as compared to proportional rule democracies, holding all else equal. This finding is robust to the inclusion of numerous control variables and model specifications. The main theoretical implication of this research is that the effect of democracy on compliance with international agreements is conditional rather than direct. The consequences of democratic accountability depend critically on a country s electoral institutions and voters interests. Democracy makes compliance more likely when a state s electoral institutions privilege those voters that prefer compliance. In contrast, democracy makes compliance less likely when electoral institutions advantage voters that favour non-compliance. This provides a possible explanation for the previously unexplained variance in compliance behaviour amongst democratic states. The same mechanism that links regime type to compliance, namely electoral competition, also explains variation in compliance amongst democracies. This research has important theoretical implications for several of the key debates in International Relations including, for example, the degree to which the causes of international political and economic trends are to be found at the domestic or international level (Frieden and Lake, 2000). While some International Relations scholars rule out explanations of international phenomena by reference to internal characteristics of the nation-state (e.g. Waltz, 1979), others argue that national concerns can override global considerations. This research supports the latter view. A democratic state s compliance with international agreements depends critically on two key internal characteristics: electoral institutions and voters preferences over compliance. Both the state (i.e. political institutions) and society play a significant 5

7 role in countries foreign economic policies, international relations, and compliance with international agreements. The reminder of the paper is organized in six parts. Section 2 briefly discusses the GATT/WTO restrictions on narrowly targeted transfers. Sector 3 lays out the theoretical argument as to why some democracies violate international agreements more often than others. Section 4 describes the empirical tests of the theoretical expectations derived in the previous section. The results of the empirical tests are discussed in Section 5 and Section 6 concludes the paper. Context Restrictions on narrow transfers have long been the focus of multilateral negotiations because they are believed to cause significant economic distortions. As early as the Tokyo Round of 1979, narrowly targeted subsidies were regulated by GATT Articles VI, XVI and XXIII. iii Since then, restrictions on narrow transfers have been strengthened and expanded. The WTO Agreement on Subsidies and Countervailing Measures (Articles 1 through 9) explicitly bans government subsidies targeted exclusively to individual industries or firms. The use of narrowly targeted transfers is implicitly restricted by other GATT/WTO agreements that require general reductions in trade barriers and open market access. Under GATT/WTO agreements, member country governments are expected to refrain from privileging domestic producers via narrowly targeted transfers and/or trade barriers. Countries that choose to provide narrowly targeted transfers in violation of GATT/WTO rules risk being filed against at the WTO s Dispute Settlement Body. This entails potentially significant costs including international sanctions, the costs of participating in a GATT/WTO dispute, reputation costs, and the costs of compensating a plaintiff if ruled against by a Panel. Despite these costs, some 6

8 governments choose to provide narrow transfers in violation of GATT/WTO rules. For example, the United States government imposed 30 percent tariffs on steel imports in March Within a few days, the European Union lodged a formal complaint with the World Trade Organization alleging that such tariffs were illegal. In November 2003, the WTO ruled that the American tariffs were illegal. Subsequently China, the European Union, and Japan announced their intent to levy costly retaliatory sanctions against the United States (Mahncke, 2004). Why would a democratically elected government choose to violate GATT/WTO rules and risk costly international sanctions? Existing compliance theories provide little insight. Democratic governments are generally expected to comply with international agreements. Two key arguments are advanced in the literature for why this may be the case. First, democracies may comply with international legal obligations because they share an affinity with prevalent international legal processes and institutions (e.g. Dixon, 1993; Slaughter, 1995). Second, democracies may comply with international agreements because failure to do so entails costs for elected leaders (e.g. Leeds, 1999; McGillivray and Smith, 2000). This argument rests on the critical assumption that voters punish leaders for violating international agreements by voting against them in the next election. iv Given these arguments, how can the United States decision on steel tariffs be explained and, more generally, the variation in compliance behaviour amongst democratic states? Theory Democratically elected governments violate international agreements when the electoral benefits of doing so outweigh the domestic and international costs. The domestic costs of providing an illegal narrow transfer include the actual budgetary costs of the transfer, the opportunity costs of funding the transfer rather than some 7

9 other policy, and the potential economic distortions caused by the transfer. v The international costs of non-compliance include reputation costs and the potential costs of international sanctions. For example, extra duties (i.e. countervailing duties) can be imposed against illegally subsidized products. Such duties decrease the competitiveness of exports from defendant countries. Additionally, participation in the dispute settlement process entails resource costs, such as the financial, institutional, and human capital costs of litigating a dispute (Guzman and Simmons, 2005). Additionally, governments must consider the potential costs of compensating the plaintiff if ruled against by a GATT/WTO Panel. Governments implement WTO-inconsistent policies when the electoral benefits outweigh these costs. This is demonstrated by the United States steel tariffs. During the course of the US presidential election campaign in 2000, George W. Bush promised to help the steel industry in Ohio and West Virginia in an attempt to win votes in these key states. With the November 2002 midterm elections for the House of Representatives finely balanced, the Republicans needed to win the key steelproducing states of Ohio and Pennsylvania (Read, 2005: 135). The US tariffs on steel were an attempt by the Republican administration to win electoral support in key states (Read, 2005). The electoral benefits of providing this illegal narrow protection for the Republican Party appear to have outweighed the domestic and international costs of violating GATT/WTO rules. This illustrative example makes an important point; not all voters punish leaders for non-compliance with international agreements. Some voters will, in fact, reward leaders for violating international rules, as was the case in the key steelproducing states of Ohio and Pennsylvania. This point challenges a fundamental assumption in the domestic audience cost literature, namely that all voters value 8

10 compliance and therefore punish leaders who violate international agreements. When voters preferences over compliance vary, the expected effect of democratic elections on compliance is ambiguous. Democratically elected governments will provide illegal narrow transfers when the electoral benefits of doing so are substantial (i.e. when they outweigh the costs). The electoral benefits of providing an illegal narrow transfer are more likely to outweigh the costs when politicians compete for (re)election under majoritarian electoral rules in single-member districts. This is because of the unique nature of electoral competition in countries with these electoral institutions, as demonstrated formally by theoretical models of electoral competition (e.g. Lizzeri and Persico, 2001; Milesi-Ferreti et al., 2001; Persson and Tabellini, 1999, 2000, 2003). In such models, politicians and parties are assumed to be office-seeking. They want to maximize their chances of re-election and to this end work to provide benefits to those voters most critical to their re-election chances. The identity of these voters is determined by the country s electoral rules. In majoritarian systems, the most important voters for a politician s re-election chances are those in the politician s geographically-defined electoral district. Politicians need 50 percent plus one of the votes in their electoral district to win (re)election in majoritarian systems. To secure this outcome, politicians will work to provide narrowly targeted benefits those voters, firms, and industries located in their district (e.g. Lizzeri and Persico, 2001; Milesi- Ferreti et al., 2001; Persson and Tabellini, 1999, 2000, 2003). This incentive also exists for parties competing in two-party plurality rule systems with single-member districts. In these systems, parties win control of the legislature (and executive) district by district. To maximize their chances of winning control, strategic parties target narrow transfers to key electoral districts. Because 9

11 politicians and parties can use narrow transfers to target precisely those voters whose support they need to win re-election, these types of transfers are uniquely valuable in democracies with plurality electoral rules. vi Plurality electoral rules tend to be closely associated with single-member electoral districts. This empirical regularity provides further incentives for electorally minded politicians and parties to provide narrow transfers. Single member districts tend to be smaller than multimember districts (Powell and Vanberg, 2000). This increases the influence of narrow, particularistic groups over elected representatives (e.g. Alt and Gilligan, 1994; Magee et al., 1989; Mansfield and Busch, 1995; McGillivray, 2004; Rogowski, 1997). McGillivray (2004: 28) provides the following illustrative example: An industry with 100 employees represents 10 percent of the electorate in a district with 1,000 voters. The same industry represents only 0.1 percent of the electorate in a district of 100,000 voters. In the larger district, refusing to protect the industry is unlikely to affect the politician s re-election chances because the industry is only 0.1 percent of the representative s electorate. In a district of 100,000 voters, political representatives are forced to balance the interests of a greater variety of industry groups. Given this, politicians elected via the smaller districts that typically characterize countries with single-member districts have greater incentives to provide narrowly targeted transfers to their constituents. vii District size has been suggested as a possible explanation for the apparent protectionist bias in majoritarian countries. For example, Magee, Brock and Young (1989) argue that larger electoral districts minimize the electoral incentives to provide trade protection. viii Although the argument made here might be seen as a simple extension of existing arguments in the trade protection literature, a key question remains as to whether majoritarian democracies will provide WTO-inconsistent trade 10

12 protections. Governments can (and do) provide protection from international trade in ways that do not violate GATT/WTO rules. For example, many countries tariffs are set well below GATT/WTO limits. Governments interested in providing protection can do so by raising tariffs up to the agreed limit. Only by raising tariffs above this level do countries violate GATT/WTO agreements. Why would countries choose to provide illegal protection in violation of international agreements? This question is fundamentally distinct from the general question of why countries provide protection. The argument made here suggests that governments choose to provide illegal narrow transfers in violation of international agreements when the domestic electoral benefits of doing so outweigh the costs. This is more likely to occur in plurality rule democracies where narrow transfers provide unique and important electoral benefits to politicians facing competitive democratic elections. In proportional systems, politicians and parties have fewer electoral incentives to supply narrowly targeted transfers, even in the absence of international restrictions (e.g. Lizzeri and Persico, 2001; Persson and Tabellini, 2003; Rogowski, 1987, 1997). Parties competing under proportional electoral rules do not win elections district by district. In fact, no single district is critical to the electoral success of a party (McGillivray, 2004). Instead, parties work to maximize their aggregate vote share because this determines the number of legislative seats the party will control. ix By targeting transfers to broad segments of the electorate, such as consumers, parties are able to buy the electoral support of a wide range of voters dispersed across electoral districts. This is precisely the type of electoral support that is most beneficial to parties competing in multi-member districts under proportional rule. Because narrowly targeted transfers provide relatively fewer electoral benefits to politicians competing in proportional rule systems, PR democracies are less likely to violate 11

13 GATT/WTO rules on targeted transfers than plurality rule democracies, holding all else equal. The following section describes the empirical tests of this theoretical expectation. Data and methods Compliance with standing, substantive rules embodied in international agreements is difficult to measure. Using instances of non-compliance rather than compliance is a straightforward way to overcome this difficulty. x Complaints filed with the GATT/WTO Dispute Settlement Body over illegal narrow transfers are used to measure instances of non-compliance. xi The dependent variable is the cumulative number of complaints filed against a democratic GATT/WTO member country over illegal narrow transfers in a given year (Complaints). A vast majority of GATT/WTO complaints are filed in response to an illegal narrow transfer in the defendant country. xii This is confirmed by the fact that the majority of all cases decided by a GATT/WTO Panel yield a victory for the complainant country (Guzman and Simmons, 2005). Both developed and developing country complainants win approximately 90% of WTO cases (Guzman and Simmons, 2005). This suggests that the variable Complaints is a valid measure of noncompliance. In an attempt to further increase the validity of this measure, GATT/WTO complaints that are explicitly political in nature and do not have at issue an illegal narrow protection are systematically excluded from the sample. For example, the 1985 complaint filed by Nicaragua against the US in response to the trade embargo imposed by the Reagan Administration is excluded. Excluding these types of complaints increases the validity of this measure. Additional coding criteria and sample restrictions are discussed in the appendix. 12

14 Despite the restrictive coding criteria, it is possible that some complaints included in the sample were not filed in response to illegal narrow protection. These cases, if they exist, are false positives (i.e. a complaint is observed where no violation exists). This type of error will make it relatively more difficult to find evidence in support of the argument made here. This variable likely underestimates the frequency of non-compliant behaviour because not all instances of non-compliance engender a formal complaint. Filing a complaint entails costs for the plaintiff country. As a result, countries file complaints only in select cases. A vast literature examines when and under what circumstances countries chose to file a GATT/WTO complaint. For example, Davis and Shirato (2007) argue that the characteristics of the affected export industry in the complainant country determine when WTO complaints are filed. Davis and Bermeo (2007) show that the complainant country s domestic institutions and litigation experience play a critical role in the country s decision to file a WTO dispute. Bown (2005) shows that export stakes and retaliatory capacity account for much of the cross-national variation in dispute initiation. These studies and others suggest that the decision to file a complaint is not random. Although the decision is not random, it is unlikely to be influenced by a defendant country s electoral rules. Plaintiff countries are no more likely to file against a majoritarian country with an illegal protection than a proportional country with an illegal protection. xiii This is an important point. It suggests that any systematic relationship found between a country s electoral rules and the number of complaints filed against it is unlikely to be the result of selection bias. Given the discrete and non-negative properties of the dependent variable, it is appropriate to use an event count procedure to model the process underlying non- 13

15 compliance with GATT/WTO restrictions on narrow transfers. The negative binominal model is used here because the count variable is overdispersed. xiv The negative binomial model allows for this overdispersion and includes parameters for unobserved variance in the number of disputes across countries (King, 1989; Long, 1997). One might argue that the zero inflated negative binomial model may be more appropriate for this analysis given that the modal number of disputes in any given country in any given year is zero. However, the large number of zeros in the count variable may be the result of unobserved heterogeneity (Cameron and Trivedi, 1998; Long, 1997). Unobserved heterogeneity can cause both overdispersion and an increase in the proportion of zeros. The negative binominal model can account for the ovedispersion and the excess zeros in the raw data. The negative binominal model responds to the under prediction of zeros in the Poisson regression model by increasing the conditional variance without changing the conditional mean (Long, 1997). In contrast, zero modified count models change the mean structure to explicitly model the production of zero counts. This is done by assuming that zeros can be generated by a different process than positive counts. However, the theory advanced here does not suggest that the zeros are generated by a different process. Given this, it is difficult to justify theoretically the use of the zero inflated negative binomial model. Estimating a zero-inflated negative binominal model does not produce dramatically different results. xv In fact, no significant bias appears to be introduced by estimating the more theoretically sound negative binominal model rather than the zero-inflated model. The sample is an unbalanced panel of democratic GATT/WTO membercountries with yearly observations from 1980 to These data are used in a pooled 14

16 time-series cross-section analysis with country-years as observations. The causal mechanism specified in the theoretical argument makes monadic predictions; governments in countries with majoritarian electoral rules and/or single-member districts are more likely to implement WTO-inconsistent policies than governments in PR countries. As a result, majoritarian democracies are more likely to be named as defendants in GATT/WTO complaints than proportional rule democracies. The most appropriate unit of analysis for testing the empirical validity of this hypothesis is monadic country-years. xvi The WTO replaced GATT as the organization overseeing the multilateral trading system during the sample period (1995). Given this, a dummy variable coded one for years during the WTO regime and zero otherwise is included in all estimated models. xvii The base model also includes several addition control variables. xviii Countries with majoritarian electoral rules tend to have relatively larger economies, on average. If a defendant s market size influences a plaintiff s decisions to file a formal complaint, as suggested by Gruzman and Simmons (2005), then a spurious correlation between majoritarian rules and complaints may exist. To minimize concerns of a spurious correlation, defendant s market size measured by the country s GDP is included as a control variable in all estimated models. xix Plaintiff, a dichotomous variable coded 1 if the country filed a complaint with the GATT/WTO Dispute Settlement Body in the previous year and 0 otherwise, is included to account for the possibility that some complaints are filed in retaliation for previous complaints (Busch and Reinhardt, 2002). Exports, calculated as the amount of goods and services exported as a percent of GDP, is also included. International scrutiny of a country s compliance with multilateral trade agreements likely increases as a country s exports grows. xx 15

17 GDP per capita is included to account for the fact that developed countries have historically used the GATT/WTO dispute settlement procedures more often than developing countries. The yearly rate of economic growth (Economic growth) is included to account for the possibility that politicians in countries experiencing low or negative growth rates may face greater pressure to violate GATT/WTO rules. Violating international restrictions during times of adverse economic conditions may not entail the same reputation costs as doing so under normal economic conditions would (Drazen, 1997). Although these control variables are not unrelated, standard tests show acceptable levels of multicolinearity. xxi Their inclusion in a single model does not introduce undue bias. The results of the estimated models are reported in Table 1 and discussed in the following section. Results Amongst democracies, the variation in compliance with GATT/WTO agreements can be explained, in part, by electoral institutions. Electoral institutions are robust predictors of non-compliance, as reported in Table 1. xxii In Models 1 through 4, a country s electoral rule is measured using a simple dummy variable coded one if a majority or all of the seats in the lower (or only) legislative chamber are elected via xxiii plurality electoral rules and 0 otherwise. The effect of a country s mean district magnitude is estimated in Models 5 through 8. xxiv Given the close correspondence between electoral rules and district magnitude, the two variables are not included together in the same model. [Table 1 about here] Amongst high functioning democracies, xxv majoritarian electoral rules significantly increase the probability of violating GATT/WTO restrictions on narrow 16

18 transfers. Moving from a PR system to a majoritarian system increases the likelihood of non-compliance by nearly 7 percentage points in a single year. This effect is estimated using simulations via Clarify Software (King et al., 2000; Tomz et al., 2001). xxvi On average, the expected number of violations in majoritarian democracies is 300 percent higher than in proportional rule (PR) democracies. Democratic countries with single-member districts are also more likely to violate GATT/WTO rules regarding the provision of narrow transfers. Moving from an average sized multi-member district (i.e. one with 7 seats) to a single-member district system increases the probability of non-compliance by more than 6 percentage points in a single year. On average, the expected number of disputes in democratic countries with single-member districts is 186 percent higher than in multi-member districts. When the sample is expanded to include a broader group of democratic countries, xxvii majoritarian electoral rules remain a robust predictor of noncompliance, as reported in Models 3 and 4. Their estimated effect is slightly lower, however. Changing from a PR system to a majoritarian system increases the likelihood of non-compliance in a given year by nearly 4 percentage points. Mean district magnitude remains negatively related to non-compliance but no longer reaches conventional levels of statistical significance in the larger sample. Given the frequency with which the Unites States has been involved in GATT/WTO disputes, readers might be concerned that the results reported here are driven by the inclusion of the United States in the sample. However, this does not appear to be the case. When the United States is excluded, as in Model 2 Table 1, the estimated effect of Majoritarian actually increases slightly and remains statistically 17

19 significant at the 0.01 level. Mean District Magnitude also remains statistically significant but its effect is slightly smaller, as reported in Model 6 Table 1. Electoral institutions remain robust to a number of additional specifications. xxviii For example, both Majoritarian and Mean District Magnitude remain statistically significant when country size is measured using population rather than GDP. Alternative lag structures matter little for the estimated coefficients for Majoritarian and Mean District Magnitude. This is perhaps unsurprising given that these two variables change only very rarely over time. Several other interesting findings deserve mention here. The WTO indicator variable is positive and significant in 4 of the 8 models, namely those estimated using the larger sample. This finding is consistent with previous studies that point to an increase in the number of cases filed under the WTO regime (e.g. Petersmann, 1997). Country size and income are also statistically significant in the more inclusive sample of democracies. Larger countries and those with higher per capita income are relatively more likely to violate GATT/WTO rules, all else equal. This may be because larger, richer countries are less sensitive to the international costs of noncompliance. Alternatively, it may be that countries are more likely to file against big, rich defendants because there are relatively greater benefits to be gained from these cases (Gruzman and Simmons, 2005). This confirms the importance of controlling for country size. This is particularly important when estimating the effect of electoral rules on non-compliant behaviour. If large countries are more likely to be filed against and they are more likely to have majoritarian electoral rules, a spurious correlation between electoral rules and complaints may exist. However, by including measures of country size in all estimated models, the possibility of finding a spurious correlation is minimized. xxix 18

20 Conclusion Conventional wisdom suggests that democracies are more likely to comply with international agreements than autocracies. However, substantial variation in compliance behaviour exists amongst democracies. To date, this variation has gone largely unexplained. This article offers a possible account for the observed variance in compliance with GATT/WTO agreements among democracies. In a world where democracy is spreading, it is especially important to understand democratic states compliance with international agreements. Amongst democracies, variation in compliance with international agreements can be explained in part by electoral institutions. Democratic countries with majoritarian electoral rules violate GATT/WTO restrictions on the use of narrowly targeted transfers, such as industry-specific subsidies, more frequently than countries with proportional electoral systems. This is because majoritarian rules provide politicians with electoral incentives to supply transfers to narrow, select segments of the country s population. This incentive derives from the winner-takes-all characteristics of majoritarian electoral rules and the nature of electoral competition in single-member districts. In contrast, proportional electoral rules and multi-member districts generate incentives for politicians and parties to target benefits to broader segments of the electorate. As a result, governments elected via proportional rules are more likely to comply with GATT/WTO restrictions on narrowly targeted transfers as these restrictions tend to benefit consumers. Although this research focuses on compliance with a particular international agreement, the theoretical implications are relevant for virtually all international agreements. This is because virtually all international agreements have distributive consequences that make some voters better off and others worse off. Consider, for 19

21 example, an international environmental agreement. Although such an agreement generates benefits for many (perhaps all) citizens, it entails substantial costs for some. For example, producers using environmentally unfriendly technologies will find international environmental agreements costly. The theory advanced in this paper suggests that when such groups are critical to leaders electoral success, leaders will be less concerned with (and committed to) compliance with international environmental agreements. This may explain, for example, the United States refusal to ratify the Kyoto Protocol. Because virtually all international agreements have distributive consequences, some voters will prefer non-compliance. Democracy may therefore make compliance less likely. The effect of democracy on compliance depends critically on the political importance of voters that favour non-compliance. When a state s democratic institutions privilege non-compliance voters, violations of international agreements will be more likely. In contrast, when electoral institutions privilege those voters that favour compliance, democracy will make compliance more likely. In sum, the effect of democracy on compliance is conditional on a country s electoral institutions and the interests of voters. This provides a potential explanation for the observed variation in compliance behaviour amongst democracies. It also provides a possible reason for the mixed empirical evidence found to date on the effect of regime type on compliance. While some studies show that democracies honour their international commitments more regularly than authoritarian states (e.g. Mansfield, Milner and Rosendorff 2002), others find either a negative or a negligible correlation between democracy and compliance. For example, Remmer (1998) finds little evidence of a positive relationship between democracy and commercial cooperation. Simmons (2000) finds 20

22 that amongst those countries that joined the International Monetary Fund before 1980, democracies showed a greater tendency to violate international commitments. The theory advanced in this paper suggests a possible explanation for these mixed findings and an important avenue for future research. To better understand the effect of regime type on compliance with international agreements, we must develop and test theories about which voters prefer non-compliance and when they are likely to be electorally decisive. This research takes an important first step in this direction. This research makes several additional contributions. First, it demonstrates that WTO-inconsistent policies are neither random nor uniform across states. The supply of potential cases (i.e. WTO-inconsistent policies) is often taken as exogenous in studies of GATT/WTO disputes (e.g. Davis and Shirato 2007). xxx However, this research suggests that to fully understand the pattern of GATT/WTO disputes, one must account for the likelihood of a WTO-inconsistent policy in the defendant state. This depends in part on the country s electoral institutions. Second, this research confirms the increasingly common claim that majoritarian democracies are relatively more protectionist than proportional rule democracies (e.g. Evans, 2009; Grossman and Helpman, 2005). The novel result reported here is that governments in majoritarian systems are willing to protect domestic producers even when doing so violates their international obligations. The theoretical implication is that national electoral concerns can at times override international considerations. This speaks to the ongoing debate in International Relations over the degree to which the causes of international political and economic trends are to be found at the domestic or international level. This research demonstrates the importance of domestic politics for compliance with international agreements. It appears that the nation-state remains a powerful and independent actor 21

23 whose internal structures shape foreign economic policy and international relations, despite the dramatic increase in international interdependence and the proliferation of international agreements. Kindleberger s (1969) pronouncement that the nation-state is just about through as an economic unit appears to have been premature. 22

24 References Allee, Todd (2009) Going to Geneva? Trade Protection and Dispute Resolution Under the World Trade Organization, mimeo, University of Illinois at Urbana- Champaign. Allee, Todd and Jamie Scalera (2009) Getting there is Half the Fun: The Impact of WTO Accession on Trade. Paper prepared for the 67 th Annual Conference of the Midwest Political Science Association. Alt, James E. and Michael Gilligan (1994) The Political Economy of Trading States, Journal of Political Philosophy 2 (2): Ashworth, Scott and Ethan Bueno de Mesquita (2006) Delivering the Goods: Legislative Particularism in Different Electoral and Institutional Settings, Journal of Politics 68 (1): Beck, Thorsten, George Clarke, Alberto Groff, Philip Keefer, and Patrick Walsh (2001) New tools in Comparative Political Economy: The Database of Political Institutions, The World Bank Economic Review 15 (September): Boix, Carles (1999) Setting the Rules of the Game: The Choice of Electoral Systems in Advanced Democracies, American Political Science Review 93 (3): Bown, Chad P. (2005) Participation in WTO Dispute Settlement: Complainants, Interested Parties, and Free Riders, The World Bank Economic Review 19 (2): Busch, Marc L. and Eric Reinhardt (2002) Testing International Trade Law: Empirical Studies of GATT/WTO Dispute Settlement, in D. M. Kennedy and J. D. Southwick (eds) The Political Economy of International Trade Law: Essays in Honor of Robert Hudec, pp New York: Cambridge University Press. Cameron Colin A. and Pravin K. Trivedi (1998) Regression Analysis of Count Data. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Carey, John M. and Matthew Soberg Shugart (1995) Incentives to cultivate a personal vote: A rank ordering of electoral formulas, Electoral Studies 14 (4): Cox, Gary W. and Mathew D. McCubbins (1986) Electoral Politics as a Redistributive Game, The Journal of Politics 48 (2): Dai, Xinyuan (2006) Dyadic Myth and Monadic Advantage: Conceptualizing the Effect of Democratic Constraints on Trade, Journal of Theoretical Politics 18 (3): Davis, Christina L. (2008) The Democratic Propensity for Adjudication: An Analysis of GATT/WTO Dispute Settlement. Paper prepared for the 3 rd Annual Meeting of the International Political Economy Society. 23

25 Davis, Christina L. and Sara Bermeo (2008) Who Files? Developing country participation in WTO adjudication. Paper prepared for the 2 nd Annual Meeting of the International Political Economy Society. Davis, Christina L. and Yuki Shirato (2007) Firms, Governments and WTO Adjudication: Japan s Selection of WTO Disputes World Politics 59: Dixit, Avinash and John Londregan (1996) The Determinants of Success of Special Interests in Redistributive Politics, The Journal of Politics 58 (4): Dixon, William J. (1993) Democracy and the Management of International Conflict, The Journal of Conflict Resolution 37 (1): Drazen, Allan (1997) Policy Signalling in the Open Economy: A Re-Examination, National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No Evans, Carolyn L. (2009) A Protectionist Bias in Majoritarian Politics: An Empirical Investigation Economics and Politics. Fearon, James D. (1994) Domestic Political Audiences and the Escalation of International Disputes, The American Political Science Review 88 (3): Frieden, Jeffry and David A. Lake (2000) International Politics and International Economics, in J. Frieden and D. Lake (eds) International Political Economy. California: Wadsworth. Gaubatz, Kurt Taylor (1996) Democratic States and Commitment in International Relations, International Organization 50 (1): Grossman, Gene M. and Elhanan Helpman. (2005) A Protectionist Bias in Majoritarian Politics, The Quarterly Journal of Economics. 120 (4): Guzman, Andrew and Beth Simmons (2005) Power Plays and Capacity Constraints: The Selection of Defendants in WTO Disputes, Journal of Legal Studies 34 (2): Huber, Evelyne, Charles Ragin, and John D. Stephens (1993) Social Democracy, Christian Democracy, Constitutional Structure and the Welfare State, American Journal of Sociology 99: Hudec, Robert (1993) Enforcing International Trade Law: The Evolution of the Modern GATT Legal System. Salem, NH: Butterworth Legal Publishers. Johnson, Joel, and Jessica Wallack (2005) The Electoral Systems and the Personal Vote Database Karol, David (2007) Does Constituency Size Affect Elected Officials' Trade Policy Preferences?, The Journal of Politics 69:

26 Kindleberger, C. (1969) American Business Abroad. New Haven, Connecticut: Yale University Press. King, Gary (1989) Variance Specification in Event Count Models: From Restrictive Assumptions to a Generalized Estimator, American Journal of Political Science 33 (3): King, Gary, Michael Tomz, and Jason Wittenberg (2000) Making the Most of Statistical Analyses: Improving Interpretation and Presentation, American Journal of Political Science 44 (2): Leeds, Brett Ashley (2003) Alliance Reliability in Times of War: Explaining State Decisions to Violate Treaties, International Organization 57 (4): Lizzeri, Alessandro and Nicola Persico (2001) The Provision of Public Goods Under Alternative Electoral Incentives, American Economic Review 91 (1): Long, J. Scott (1997) Regression Models for Categorical and Limited Dependent Variables. Thousand Oaks, California: Sage Publications. Magee, Stephen P., William A. Brock, and Leslie Young (1989) Black Hole Tariffs and Endogenous Policy Theory: Political Economy in General Equilibrium. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Mahncke, Hans (2004) US Steel Tariffs and the WTO Dispute Resolution Mechanism, Leiden Journal of International Law 17 (3): Mansfield Edward D. and Marc Busch (1995) The Political Economy of Nontariff Barriers: A Crossnational Analysis, International Organization 49: Mansfield, Edward D., Helen V. Milner, and Peter B. Rosendorff (2002) Why Democracies Cooperate More: Electoral Control and International Trade Agreements, International Organization 56 (3): McGillivray, Fiona (2004) Privileging Industry: The Comparative Politics of Trade and Industrial Policy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. McGillivray, Fiona and Alastair Smith (2000) Trust and Cooperation Through Agent-Specific Punishments, International Organization 54 (4): Milesi-Ferretti, Gian Maria, Roberto Perotti, and Massimo Rostagno (2002) Electoral Systems and Public Spending, The Quarterly Journal of Economics 117 (2): Milner, Helen V. and Keiko Kubota (2005) Why the Move to Free Trade? Democracy and Trade Policy in the Developing Countries, International Organization 59 (1): Monroe, Burt L. and Amanda G. Rose (2002) Electoral Systems and Unimagined Consequences: Partisan Effects of Districted Proportional Representation, American Journal of Political Science 46 (1):

27 Petersmann, E. U. (1997) The GATT/WTO Dispute Settlement System: International Law, International Organizations and Dispute Settlement. Kluwer Law: London. Persson, Torsten and Guido Tabellini (1999) The Size and Scope of Government: Comparative Politics with Rational Politicians, European Economic Review 43: Persson, Torsten and Guido Tabellini (2000) Political Economics: Explaining Economic Policy. London: MIT Press. Persson, Torsten and Guido Tabellini (2003) The Economic Effects of Constitutions. Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press. Powell, G. Bingham and Georg S. Vanberg (2000) Election Laws, Disproportionality and Median Correspondence: Implications for Two Visions of Democracy, British Journal of Political Science 30: Read, R. (2005) The EU US WTO Steel Dispute: The Political Economy of Protection and the Efficacy of the WTO Dispute Settlement Understanding, in N. Perdikis, and R. Read (eds) The WTO and the Regulation of International Trade: Recent Trade Disputes between the European Union and the United States. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar. Reinhardt, Eric (1996) Posturing Parliaments: Ratification, Uncertainty, and International Bargaining, mimeo, Columbia University. Remmer, Karen L. (1998) Does Democracy Promote Interstate Cooperation? Lessons from the Mercosur Region, International Studies Quarterly 42 (1): Rogowski, Ronald (1987) Trade and the Variety of Democratic Institutions, International Organization 41 (2): Rogowski, Ronald (1997) Pork, Patronage, and Protection: How Geographic Concentration Affects Representation of Interests in Small-District Systems, mimeo, University of California, Los Angeles. Rokkan, Stein (1970) Citizens, Elections, Parties: Approaches to the Comparative Study of the Process of Development. Oslo: Univer- sitetsforlaget. Rose, Andrew K. (2008) GATT/WTO Membership and its Effect on Trade: Where Do We Stand? Working paper. Simmons, Beth A. (2000) International Law and State Behaviour: Commitment and Compliance in International Monetary Affairs, American Political Science Review 94 (4): Slaughter, Anne-Marie (1995) International Law in a World of Liberal States, European Journal of International Law 6 (1):

Democratic Differences: Electoral institutions and compliance with GATT/WTO agreements

Democratic Differences: Electoral institutions and compliance with GATT/WTO agreements Democratic Differences: Electoral institutions and compliance with GATT/WTO agreements Stephanie J. Rickard School of Law and Government Dublin City University Dublin, Ireland stephanie.rickard@dcu.ie

More information

Strategic targeting: The Effect of Institutions and Interests on Distributive Transfers

Strategic targeting: The Effect of Institutions and Interests on Distributive Transfers Strategic targeting: The Effect of Institutions and Interests on Distributive Transfers Stephanie J. Rickard School of Law and Government Dublin City University stephanie.rickard@dcu.ie Virtually every

More information

Electoral Systems and Trade

Electoral Systems and Trade Chapter 15 Electoral Systems and Trade Stephanie J. Rickard In democracies, politicians compete to win votes, and subsequently office, in free and fair elections. Elected representatives should therefore

More information

A Non-Tariff Protectionist Bias in Majoritarian Politics: Government Subsidies and Electoral Institutions 1

A Non-Tariff Protectionist Bias in Majoritarian Politics: Government Subsidies and Electoral Institutions 1 International Studies Quarterly (2012) 56, 777 785 A Non-Tariff Protectionist Bias in Majoritarian Politics: Government Subsidies and Electoral Institutions 1 Stephanie J. Rickard London School of Economics

More information

PS245 INTERNATIONAL POLITICAL ECONOMY

PS245 INTERNATIONAL POLITICAL ECONOMY University of California, San Diego Fall 2003 Monday 10:00-12:50 pm, SSB 104 http://weber.ucsd.edu/~jlbroz/courses/ps245 J. Lawrence Broz Assistant Professor of Political Science Office: SSB 389 Email:

More information

Particularism around the World

Particularism around the World Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized the world bank economic review, vol. 17, no. 1 133 143 Particularism around the World

More information

Does Lobbying Matter More than Corruption In Less Developed Countries?*

Does Lobbying Matter More than Corruption In Less Developed Countries?* Does Lobbying Matter More than Corruption In Less Developed Countries?* Nauro F. Campos University of Newcastle, University of Michigan Davidson Institute, and CEPR E-mail: n.f.campos@ncl.ac.uk Francesco

More information

Fall 2012 Political Institutions and International Political Economy: China and Beyond

Fall 2012 Political Institutions and International Political Economy: China and Beyond Fall 2012 Political Institutions and International Political Economy: China and Beyond Hans H. Tung August, 2012 Course Information Professor: Hans H. Tung ( htung@nccu.edu.tw) Time: Tuesdays, 15:10-18:00

More information

Determinants of Trade Protection in Contemporary Democracies: Whose interests do elected officials serve through trade protection?

Determinants of Trade Protection in Contemporary Democracies: Whose interests do elected officials serve through trade protection? Determinants of Trade Protection in Contemporary Democracies: Whose interests do elected officials serve through trade protection? Su-Hyun Lee 1. Introduction This dissertation aims to answer the determinants

More information

An Overview Across the New Political Economy Literature. Abstract

An Overview Across the New Political Economy Literature. Abstract An Overview Across the New Political Economy Literature Luca Murrau Ministry of Economy and Finance - Rome Abstract This work presents a review of the literature on political process formation and the

More information

1. The Relationship Between Party Control, Latino CVAP and the Passage of Bills Benefitting Immigrants

1. The Relationship Between Party Control, Latino CVAP and the Passage of Bills Benefitting Immigrants The Ideological and Electoral Determinants of Laws Targeting Undocumented Migrants in the U.S. States Online Appendix In this additional methodological appendix I present some alternative model specifications

More information

How do domestic political institutions affect the outcomes of international trade negotiations?

How do domestic political institutions affect the outcomes of international trade negotiations? American Political Science Review Vol. 96, No. 1 March 2002 Political Regimes and International Trade: The Democratic Difference Revisited XINYUAN DAI University of Illinois at Urbana Champaign How do

More information

Oxford Research Encyclopedia of Politics

Oxford Research Encyclopedia of Politics Oxford Research Encyclopedia of Politics Electoral Systems and Policy Outcomes Stephanie J. Rickard Subject: Policy, Administration, and Bureaucracy, Political Economy, Political Institutions Online Publication

More information

Political Economics II Spring Lectures 4-5 Part II Partisan Politics and Political Agency. Torsten Persson, IIES

Political Economics II Spring Lectures 4-5 Part II Partisan Politics and Political Agency. Torsten Persson, IIES Lectures 4-5_190213.pdf Political Economics II Spring 2019 Lectures 4-5 Part II Partisan Politics and Political Agency Torsten Persson, IIES 1 Introduction: Partisan Politics Aims continue exploring policy

More information

Leader Change and the World Trade Organization The Impact on Leader Turnover on the Onset and Resolution of International Trade Disputes

Leader Change and the World Trade Organization The Impact on Leader Turnover on the Onset and Resolution of International Trade Disputes Leader Change and the World Trade Organization The Impact on Leader Turnover on the Onset and Resolution of International Trade Disputes In international trade, the World Trade Organization governs agreements

More information

Table of contents TREATY ON THE EURASIAN ECONOMIC UNION PART I ESTABLISHMENT OF THE EURASIAN ECONOMIC UNION

Table of contents TREATY ON THE EURASIAN ECONOMIC UNION PART I ESTABLISHMENT OF THE EURASIAN ECONOMIC UNION TREATY ON THE EURASIAN ECONOMIC UNION PART I ESTABLISHMENT OF THE EURASIAN ECONOMIC UNION Article 1 Article 2 Section I GENERAL PROVISIONS Establishment of the Eurasian Economic Union. Legal Personality

More information

Supplementary Material for Preventing Civil War: How the potential for international intervention can deter conflict onset.

Supplementary Material for Preventing Civil War: How the potential for international intervention can deter conflict onset. Supplementary Material for Preventing Civil War: How the potential for international intervention can deter conflict onset. World Politics, vol. 68, no. 2, April 2016.* David E. Cunningham University of

More information

Compliance with WTO Dispute Rulings

Compliance with WTO Dispute Rulings Working Paper No 2011/25 July 2012 Compliance with WTO Dispute Rulings Gabriele Spilker, ETH Zurich Abstract Country pairs such as the US and the EU meet several times in front of the WTO dispute settlement

More information

Department of Economics Working Paper Series. Why Are So Many WTO Disputes Abandoned? Kara M. Reynolds. No June, 2007

Department of Economics Working Paper Series. Why Are So Many WTO Disputes Abandoned? Kara M. Reynolds. No June, 2007 Department of Economics Working Paper Series Why Are So Many WTO Disputes Abandoned? by Kara M. Reynolds No. 2007-05 June, 2007 http://www.american.edu/academic.depts/cas/econ/working papers/workpap.htm

More information

ArkPSA Arkansas Political Science Association

ArkPSA Arkansas Political Science Association ArkPSA Arkansas Political Science Association The Forgotten Disputes: Anti-Dumping and Trade Conflict at the WTO Author(s): Gregory C. Dixon Source: The Midsouth Political Science Review, Volume 14 (December

More information

CANNIMED THERAPEUTICS INC. (the Corporation ) COMPENSATION COMMITTEE CHARTER

CANNIMED THERAPEUTICS INC. (the Corporation ) COMPENSATION COMMITTEE CHARTER 1. POLICY STATEMENT CANNIMED THERAPEUTICS INC. (the Corporation ) COMPENSATION COMMITTEE CHARTER It is the policy of the Corporation to establish and maintain a Compensation Committee (the Committee )

More information

political budget cycles

political budget cycles P000346 Theoretical and empirical research on is surveyed and discussed. Significant are seen to be primarily a phenomenon of the first elections after the transition to a democratic electoral system.

More information

International Political Economy POLSC- AD 173

International Political Economy POLSC- AD 173 International Political Economy POLSC- AD 173 NYU AD: Spring, 2014 Professor Peter Rosendorff, Professor of Politics, NYUNY and NYUAD Office hours: 2-4pm Monday and Wednesday and by appointment Office:

More information

Research Statement. Jeffrey J. Harden. 2 Dissertation Research: The Dimensions of Representation

Research Statement. Jeffrey J. Harden. 2 Dissertation Research: The Dimensions of Representation Research Statement Jeffrey J. Harden 1 Introduction My research agenda includes work in both quantitative methodology and American politics. In methodology I am broadly interested in developing and evaluating

More information

An Electoral Rules Analysis of how Labor Unions Influence Trade Policy: A Comparative Study of 18 OECD Countries. Abstract

An Electoral Rules Analysis of how Labor Unions Influence Trade Policy: A Comparative Study of 18 OECD Countries. Abstract An Electoral Rules Analysis of how Labor Unions Influence Trade Policy: A Comparative Study of 18 OECD Countries Abstract This research attempts to determine whether, within democracies, variations in

More information

Preview. Chapter 9. The Cases for Free Trade. The Cases for Free Trade (cont.) The Political Economy of Trade Policy

Preview. Chapter 9. The Cases for Free Trade. The Cases for Free Trade (cont.) The Political Economy of Trade Policy Chapter 9 The Political Economy of Trade Policy Preview The cases for free trade The cases against free trade Political models of trade policy International negotiations of trade policy and the World Trade

More information

GLOBAL TRADE AND MARKETING

GLOBAL TRADE AND MARKETING GLOBAL TRADE AND MARKETING A Nepalese Perspective Bijendra Man Shakya Associate Professor (Economics) Shanker Dev Campus Tribhuvan University RATNA PUSTAK BHANDAR Kathmandu, Nepal CONTENTS List of Boxes

More information

A positive correlation between turnout and plurality does not refute the rational voter model

A positive correlation between turnout and plurality does not refute the rational voter model Quality & Quantity 26: 85-93, 1992. 85 O 1992 Kluwer Academic Publishers. Printed in the Netherlands. Note A positive correlation between turnout and plurality does not refute the rational voter model

More information

Domestic Institutions, Trade Disputes, and the Monitoring and Enforcement of International Law

Domestic Institutions, Trade Disputes, and the Monitoring and Enforcement of International Law International Interactions Empirical and Theoretical Research in International Relations ISSN: 0305-0629 (Print) 1547-7444 (Online) Journal homepage: http://www.tandfonline.com/loi/gini20 Domestic Institutions,

More information

Shopping for Protection: The Politics of Choosing Trade Instruments in a Partially Legalized World*

Shopping for Protection: The Politics of Choosing Trade Instruments in a Partially Legalized World* International Studies Quarterly (2009) 53, 421 444 Shopping for Protection: The Politics of Choosing Trade Instruments in a Partially Legalized World* Megumi Naoi University of California, San Diego This

More information

At the rare moments in history when a nation debates constitutional reform,

At the rare moments in history when a nation debates constitutional reform, Journal of Economic Perspectives Volume 18, Number 1 Winter 2004 Pages 75 98 Constitutions and Economic Policy Torsten Persson and Guido Tabellini At the rare moments in history when a nation debates constitutional

More information

Torsten Persson is Professor of Economics and Director of the Institute for International Economic

Torsten Persson is Professor of Economics and Director of the Institute for International Economic Constitutions and Economic Policy Torsten Persson and Guido Tabellini Torsten Persson is Professor of Economics and Director of the Institute for International Economic Studies, Stockholm University, Stockholm,

More information

POWER PLAYS & CAPACITY CONSTRAINTS: THE SELECTION OF DEFENDANTS IN WTO DISPUTES

POWER PLAYS & CAPACITY CONSTRAINTS: THE SELECTION OF DEFENDANTS IN WTO DISPUTES POWER PLAYS & CAPACITY CONSTRAINTS: THE SELECTION OF DEFENDANTS IN WTO DISPUTES Andrew T. Guzman Boalt Hall School of Law University of California at Berkeley guzman@law.berkeley.edu Beth A. Simmons Government

More information

Midterm Elections Used to Gauge President s Reelection Chances

Midterm Elections Used to Gauge President s Reelection Chances 90 Midterm Elections Used to Gauge President s Reelection Chances --Desmond Wallace-- Desmond Wallace is currently studying at Coastal Carolina University for a Bachelor s degree in both political science

More information

David Stasavage. Private investment and political institutions

David Stasavage. Private investment and political institutions LSE Research Online Article (refereed) David Stasavage Private investment and political institutions Originally published in Economics and politics, 14 (1). pp. 41-63 2002 Blackwell Publishing. You may

More information

Firms, Governments, and WTO Adjudication: Japan s Selection of WTO Disputes. Forthcoming in World Politics. Christina Davis

Firms, Governments, and WTO Adjudication: Japan s Selection of WTO Disputes. Forthcoming in World Politics. Christina Davis Firms, Governments, and WTO Adjudication: Japan s Selection of WTO Disputes Forthcoming in World Politics Christina Davis Princeton University, Department of Politics (cldavis@princeton.edu) and Yuki Shirato

More information

and Political Survival of the Democratic Leaders

and Political Survival of the Democratic Leaders Ohtsuki Formation of Preferential Trade Agreements and Political Survival of the Democratic Leaders Abstract Although existing literature shows economic explanations for the proliferation of PTAs and political

More information

1 Introduction. Cambridge University Press International Institutions and National Policies Xinyuan Dai Excerpt More information

1 Introduction. Cambridge University Press International Institutions and National Policies Xinyuan Dai Excerpt More information 1 Introduction Why do countries comply with international agreements? How do international institutions influence states compliance? These are central questions in international relations (IR) and arise

More information

Amendments The Clean Up. Amendments The Clean Up. Amendments Civil Rights. Amendments Civil Rights

Amendments The Clean Up. Amendments The Clean Up. Amendments Civil Rights. Amendments Civil Rights Amendments 11-12 The Clean Up Amendment XI - State Citizenship Date Ratified - Feb. 7, 1795 Date Passed by Congress - Mar. 4, 1794 What it does - Prohibits a citizen of another state or country from suing

More information

Forecasting the 2018 Midterm Election using National Polls and District Information

Forecasting the 2018 Midterm Election using National Polls and District Information Forecasting the 2018 Midterm Election using National Polls and District Information Joseph Bafumi, Dartmouth College Robert S. Erikson, Columbia University Christopher Wlezien, University of Texas at Austin

More information

The Political Logic of Dispute Settlement: Introduction. to the Special Issue

The Political Logic of Dispute Settlement: Introduction. to the Special Issue The Political Logic of Dispute Settlement: Introduction to the Special Issue Christina L. Davis Princeton University February 28, 2015 Christina Davis is Professor of Politics and International Affairs

More information

Testing Political Economy Models of Reform in the Laboratory

Testing Political Economy Models of Reform in the Laboratory Testing Political Economy Models of Reform in the Laboratory By TIMOTHY N. CASON AND VAI-LAM MUI* * Department of Economics, Krannert School of Management, Purdue University, West Lafayette, IN 47907-1310,

More information

BERKELEY UNIFIED SCHOOL DISTRICT BERKELEY SCHOOLS EXCELLENCE PROGRAM (BSEP) PLANNING & OVERSIGHT (P&O) COMMITTEE BYLAWS

BERKELEY UNIFIED SCHOOL DISTRICT BERKELEY SCHOOLS EXCELLENCE PROGRAM (BSEP) PLANNING & OVERSIGHT (P&O) COMMITTEE BYLAWS BERKELEY UNIFIED SCHOOL DISTRICT BERKELEY SCHOOLS EXCELLENCE PROGRAM (BSEP) PLANNING & OVERSIGHT (P&O) COMMITTEE BYLAWS I. Name of the Committee II. III. IV. Purpose Primary Responsibilities of the P&O

More information

DOMESTIC POLITICS AND INTERNATIONAL RELATIONS POLI 477, Spring 2003 M 1:30-4:30 PM, 114 Baker Hall

DOMESTIC POLITICS AND INTERNATIONAL RELATIONS POLI 477, Spring 2003 M 1:30-4:30 PM, 114 Baker Hall INSTRUCTOR: DOMESTIC POLITICS AND INTERNATIONAL RELATIONS POLI 477, Spring 2003 M 1:30-4:30 PM, 114 Baker Hall Professor Ashley Leeds 230 Baker Hall, (713) 348-3037 leeds@rice.edu www.ruf.rice.edu/~leeds

More information

Obstacles Facing Developing Countries in Antidumping Cases: The Path From Initial Filing to WTO Dispute Settlement

Obstacles Facing Developing Countries in Antidumping Cases: The Path From Initial Filing to WTO Dispute Settlement Obstacles Facing Developing Countries in Antidumping Cases: The Path From Initial Filing to WTO Dispute Settlement Chad P. Bown * Bernard Hoekman ** Caglar Ozden *** May 14, 2003 VERY PRELIMINARY: PLEASE

More information

ELECTING CANDIDATES WITH FAIR REPRESENTATION VOTING: RANKED CHOICE VOTING AND OTHER METHODS

ELECTING CANDIDATES WITH FAIR REPRESENTATION VOTING: RANKED CHOICE VOTING AND OTHER METHODS November 2013 ELECTING CANDIDATES WITH FAIR REPRESENTATION VOTING: RANKED CHOICE VOTING AND OTHER METHODS A voting system translates peoples' votes into seats. Because the same votes in different systems

More information

International Remittances and Brain Drain in Ghana

International Remittances and Brain Drain in Ghana Journal of Economics and Political Economy www.kspjournals.org Volume 3 June 2016 Issue 2 International Remittances and Brain Drain in Ghana By Isaac DADSON aa & Ryuta RAY KATO ab Abstract. This paper

More information

All s Well That Ends Well: A Reply to Oneal, Barbieri & Peters*

All s Well That Ends Well: A Reply to Oneal, Barbieri & Peters* 2003 Journal of Peace Research, vol. 40, no. 6, 2003, pp. 727 732 Sage Publications (London, Thousand Oaks, CA and New Delhi) www.sagepublications.com [0022-3433(200311)40:6; 727 732; 038292] All s Well

More information

Can the number of veto players measure policy stability?

Can the number of veto players measure policy stability? Can the number of veto players measure policy stability? Monika Nalepa and Ji Xue (The University of Chicago) February 22, 2018 Abstract Ever since the publication of George Tsebelis s Veto Players, political

More information

Doing Political Economy POL-UA Fall 2016 Monday & Wednesdays 3:30-4:45 pm 7 East 12 th Street, Room LL23

Doing Political Economy POL-UA Fall 2016 Monday & Wednesdays 3:30-4:45 pm 7 East 12 th Street, Room LL23 Doing Political Economy POL-UA 842-001 Fall 2016 Monday & Wednesdays 3:30-4:45 pm 7 East 12 th Street, Room LL23 Professor Nicole Simonelli nicole.simonelli@nyu.edu Phone: (212) 992-8084 Office: 19 West

More information

Democracy and economic growth: a perspective of cooperation

Democracy and economic growth: a perspective of cooperation Lingnan Journal of Banking, Finance and Economics Volume 4 2012/2013 Academic Year Issue Article 3 January 2013 Democracy and economic growth: a perspective of cooperation Menghan YANG Li ZHANG Follow

More information

Power Plays & Capacity Constraints: The Selection of Defendants in WTO Disputes. Forthcoming, Journal of Legal Studies, 2005

Power Plays & Capacity Constraints: The Selection of Defendants in WTO Disputes. Forthcoming, Journal of Legal Studies, 2005 Power Plays & Capacity Constraints: The Selection of Defendants in WTO Disputes Forthcoming, Journal of Legal Studies, 2005 Andrew T. Guzman Boalt Hall School of Law University of California at Berkeley

More information

The Textile, Apparel, and Footwear Act of 1990: Determinants of Congressional Voting

The Textile, Apparel, and Footwear Act of 1990: Determinants of Congressional Voting The Textile, Apparel, and Footwear Act of 1990: Determinants of Congressional Voting By: Stuart D. Allen and Amelia S. Hopkins Allen, S. and Hopkins, A. The Textile Bill of 1990: The Determinants of Congressional

More information

Conflicts in International Trade Law

Conflicts in International Trade Law EUROPEAN MONOGRAPHS Regulation of Subsidies and State Aids in WTO and EC Law Conflicts in International Trade Law Gustavo E. Luengo Hernandez de Madrid KLUWER LAW INTERNATIONAL Preface Acknowledgements

More information

Explaining Concessions in GATT/WTO Trade Disputes: The Role of Institutional Environments

Explaining Concessions in GATT/WTO Trade Disputes: The Role of Institutional Environments Explaining Concessions in GATT/WTO Trade Disputes: The Role of Institutional Environments Johannes Karreth Department of Political Science University of Colorado Boulder johannes.karreth@colorado.edu This

More information

The Provision of Public Goods Under Alternative. Electoral Incentives

The Provision of Public Goods Under Alternative. Electoral Incentives The Provision of Public Goods Under Alternative Electoral Incentives Alessandro Lizzeri and Nicola Persico March 10, 2000 American Economic Review, forthcoming ABSTRACT Politicians who care about the spoils

More information

WTO and Antidumping *

WTO and Antidumping * WTO and Antidumping * JeeHyeong Park Department of Economic Wayne State University April, 2001 The issues related antidumping are broad and complex. 1 In the following presentation, thus I will try to

More information

Guidelines for Comprehensive Exams in International Relations Department of Political Science Pennsylvania State University.

Guidelines for Comprehensive Exams in International Relations Department of Political Science Pennsylvania State University. Guidelines for Comprehensive Exams in International Relations Department of Political Science Pennsylvania State University Spring 2011 The International Relations comprehensive exam consists of two parts.

More information

Electoral Reform: Key Federal Policy Recommendations. Researched and written by CFUW National Office & CFUW Leaside East York and Etobicoke JULY 2016

Electoral Reform: Key Federal Policy Recommendations. Researched and written by CFUW National Office & CFUW Leaside East York and Etobicoke JULY 2016 Electoral Reform: Key Federal Policy Recommendations Researched and written by CFUW National Office & CFUW Leaside East York and Etobicoke JULY 2016 Page 1 About CFUW CFUW is a non-partisan, voluntary,

More information

The Trade Liberalization Effects of Regional Trade Agreements* Volker Nitsch Free University Berlin. Daniel M. Sturm. University of Munich

The Trade Liberalization Effects of Regional Trade Agreements* Volker Nitsch Free University Berlin. Daniel M. Sturm. University of Munich December 2, 2005 The Trade Liberalization Effects of Regional Trade Agreements* Volker Nitsch Free University Berlin Daniel M. Sturm University of Munich and CEPR Abstract Recent research suggests that

More information

Barbara Koremenos The continent of international law. Explaining agreement design. (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press)

Barbara Koremenos The continent of international law. Explaining agreement design. (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press) Rev Int Organ (2017) 12:647 651 DOI 10.1007/s11558-017-9274-3 BOOK REVIEW Barbara Koremenos. 2016. The continent of international law. Explaining agreement design. (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press)

More information

Political Economy. Pierre Boyer and Alessandro Riboni. École Polytechnique - CREST

Political Economy. Pierre Boyer and Alessandro Riboni. École Polytechnique - CREST Political Economy Pierre Boyer and Alessandro Riboni École Polytechnique - CREST Master in Economics Fall 2018 Schedule: Every Wednesday 08:30 to 11:45 Boyer and Riboni (École Polytechnique) Political

More information

International Political Economy: Politics and the Design of Commercial Agreements

International Political Economy: Politics and the Design of Commercial Agreements International Political Economy: Politics and the Design of Commercial Agreements Robert Gulotty Department of Political Science University of Chicago PKU-UChicago Summer Institute 2014 Outline of Talk

More information

Association Agreement between the European Union and its Member States and Ukraine

Association Agreement between the European Union and its Member States and Ukraine Association Agreement between the European Union and its Member States and Ukraine incorporating a Deep and Comprehensive Free Trade Area (DCFTA) Published in the Official Journal of the European Union

More information

SERBIA DRAFT AMENDMENTS TO THE CONSTITUTION OF THE REPUBLIC OF SERBIA. As submitted by the Ministry of Justice of Serbia on 12 October 2018

SERBIA DRAFT AMENDMENTS TO THE CONSTITUTION OF THE REPUBLIC OF SERBIA. As submitted by the Ministry of Justice of Serbia on 12 October 2018 Strasbourg, 12 October 2018 Opinion No. 921 / 2018 CDL-REF(2018)053 Eng.Only EUROPEAN COMMISSION FOR DEMOCRACY THROUGH LAW (VENICE COMMISSION) SERBIA DRAFT AMENDMENTS TO THE CONSTITUTION OF THE REPUBLIC

More information

Pork Barrel as a Signaling Tool: The Case of US Environmental Policy

Pork Barrel as a Signaling Tool: The Case of US Environmental Policy Pork Barrel as a Signaling Tool: The Case of US Environmental Policy Grantham Research Institute and LSE Cities, London School of Economics IAERE February 2016 Research question Is signaling a driving

More information

Tjalling C. Koopmans Research Institute

Tjalling C. Koopmans Research Institute Tjalling C. Koopmans Research Institute Tjalling C. Koopmans Research Institute Utrecht School of Economics Utrecht University Vredenburg 138 3511 BG Utrecht The Netherlands telephone +31 30 253 9800 fax

More information

Final Syllabus, January 27, (Subject to slight revisions.)

Final Syllabus, January 27, (Subject to slight revisions.) Final Syllabus, January 27, 2008. (Subject to slight revisions.) Politics 558. International Cooperation. Spring 2008. Professors Robert O. Keohane and Helen V. Milner Tuesdays, 1:30-4:20. Prerequisite:

More information

POL-GA Comparative Government and Institutions New York University Spring 2017

POL-GA Comparative Government and Institutions New York University Spring 2017 POL-GA.3501.004 Comparative Government and Institutions New York University Spring 2017 Professor: Hande Mutlu-Eren Class Time: Tuesday 2:00-3:50 PM Office: 303 Class Location: 435 Office hours: Tuesday

More information

Strengthening Protection of Labor Rights through Preferential Trade Agreements (PTAs)

Strengthening Protection of Labor Rights through Preferential Trade Agreements (PTAs) Strengthening Protection of Labor Rights through Preferential Trade Agreements (PTAs) Moonhawk Kim moonhawk@gmail.com Executive Summary Analysts have argued that the United States attempts to strengthen

More information

Fair Representation and the Voting Rights Act. Remedies for Racial Minority Vote Dilution Claims

Fair Representation and the Voting Rights Act. Remedies for Racial Minority Vote Dilution Claims Fair Representation and the Voting Rights Act Remedies for Racial Minority Vote Dilution Claims Introduction Fundamental to any representative democracy is the right to an effective vote. In the United

More information

FC5 (P7) Trade Mark Law Mark Scheme 2015

FC5 (P7) Trade Mark Law Mark Scheme 2015 (P7) Trade Mark Law PART A Question 1 a) Article1(2) Community trade mark CTMR provides that a CTM is unitary in character. What does that mean? 3 marks b) Explain by means of an example how that unitary

More information

POLITICAL SCIENCE 240/IRGN 254: International Relations Theory. The following books are available for purchase at the UCSD bookstore:

POLITICAL SCIENCE 240/IRGN 254: International Relations Theory. The following books are available for purchase at the UCSD bookstore: POLITICAL SCIENCE 240/IRGN 254: International Relations Theory Professors Miles Kahler and David A. Lake Winter Quarter 2002 Tuesdays, 1:30 PM 4:20 PM Course readings: The following books are available

More information

International Political Economy. Dr. Christina Fattore POLS 360

International Political Economy. Dr. Christina Fattore POLS 360 International Political Economy Instructor Information: Course Information: Dr. Christina Fattore POLS 360 306G Woodburn Hall TR 1:00-2:15PM Phone: 293-3811 Woodburn 102 E-mail: Christina.Fattore@mail.wvu.edu

More information

Like many international organizations, the World Trade

Like many international organizations, the World Trade Free Riding on Enforcement in the World Trade Organization Leslie Johns, University of California, Los Angeles Krzysztof J. Pelc, McGill University Many policies that appear to violate WTO rules remain

More information

Association Agreement

Association Agreement Association Agreement between the European Union and its Member States and Georgia incorporating a Deep and Comprehensive Free Trade Area (DCFTA) Published in the Official Journal of the European Union

More information

Following the Leader: The Impact of Presidential Campaign Visits on Legislative Support for the President's Policy Preferences

Following the Leader: The Impact of Presidential Campaign Visits on Legislative Support for the President's Policy Preferences University of Colorado, Boulder CU Scholar Undergraduate Honors Theses Honors Program Spring 2011 Following the Leader: The Impact of Presidential Campaign Visits on Legislative Support for the President's

More information

Contiguous States, Stable Borders and the Peace between Democracies

Contiguous States, Stable Borders and the Peace between Democracies Contiguous States, Stable Borders and the Peace between Democracies Douglas M. Gibler June 2013 Abstract Park and Colaresi argue that they could not replicate the results of my 2007 ISQ article, Bordering

More information

Corruption, Political Instability and Firm-Level Export Decisions. Kul Kapri 1 Rowan University. August 2018

Corruption, Political Instability and Firm-Level Export Decisions. Kul Kapri 1 Rowan University. August 2018 Corruption, Political Instability and Firm-Level Export Decisions Kul Kapri 1 Rowan University August 2018 Abstract In this paper I use South Asian firm-level data to examine whether the impact of corruption

More information

The Case of the Disappearing Bias: A 2014 Update to the Gerrymandering or Geography Debate

The Case of the Disappearing Bias: A 2014 Update to the Gerrymandering or Geography Debate The Case of the Disappearing Bias: A 2014 Update to the Gerrymandering or Geography Debate Nicholas Goedert Lafayette College goedertn@lafayette.edu May, 2015 ABSTRACT: This note observes that the pro-republican

More information

THE EFFECT OF EARLY VOTING AND THE LENGTH OF EARLY VOTING ON VOTER TURNOUT

THE EFFECT OF EARLY VOTING AND THE LENGTH OF EARLY VOTING ON VOTER TURNOUT THE EFFECT OF EARLY VOTING AND THE LENGTH OF EARLY VOTING ON VOTER TURNOUT Simona Altshuler University of Florida Email: simonaalt@ufl.edu Advisor: Dr. Lawrence Kenny Abstract This paper explores the effects

More information

Vote Buying and Clientelism

Vote Buying and Clientelism Vote Buying and Clientelism Dilip Mookherjee Boston University Lecture 18 DM (BU) Clientelism 2018 1 / 1 Clientelism and Vote-Buying: Introduction Pervasiveness of vote-buying and clientelistic machine

More information

A Summary of the Constitution of the United States of America

A Summary of the Constitution of the United States of America A Summary of the Constitution of the United States of America of the United States, in order to form a more perfect union, establish justice, insure domestic tranquility, provide for the common defense,

More information

Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation

Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation S. Roy*, Department of Economics, High Point University, High Point, NC - 27262, USA. Email: sroy@highpoint.edu Abstract We implement OLS,

More information

The political economy of public sector reforms: Redistributive promises, and transfers to special interests

The political economy of public sector reforms: Redistributive promises, and transfers to special interests Title: The political economy of public sector reforms: Redistributive promises, and transfers to special interests Author: Sanjay Jain University of Cambridge Short Abstract: Why is reform of the public

More information

Campaign Spending and Political Outcomes in Lombardy

Campaign Spending and Political Outcomes in Lombardy Campaign Spending and Political Outcomes in Lombardy Piergiorgio M. Carapella Università Cattolica del Sacro Cuore Preliminary Draft The question of how financing can affect politics has found great interest

More information

A Perpetuating Negative Cycle: The Effects of Economic Inequality on Voter Participation. By Jenine Saleh Advisor: Dr. Rudolph

A Perpetuating Negative Cycle: The Effects of Economic Inequality on Voter Participation. By Jenine Saleh Advisor: Dr. Rudolph A Perpetuating Negative Cycle: The Effects of Economic Inequality on Voter Participation By Jenine Saleh Advisor: Dr. Rudolph Thesis For the Degree of Bachelor of Arts in Liberal Arts and Sciences College

More information

Voters Interests in Campaign Finance Regulation: Formal Models

Voters Interests in Campaign Finance Regulation: Formal Models Voters Interests in Campaign Finance Regulation: Formal Models Scott Ashworth June 6, 2012 The Supreme Court s decision in Citizens United v. FEC significantly expands the scope for corporate- and union-financed

More information

TODD L. ALLEE. University of Maryland Web: Tydings Hall Phone: (W) College Park, MD 20742

TODD L. ALLEE. University of Maryland Web: Tydings Hall Phone: (W) College Park, MD 20742 TODD L. ALLEE Department of Government and Politics E-mail: tallee@umd.edu University of Maryland Web: www.gvpt.umd.edu/allee 3140 Tydings Hall Phone: 301-405-6753 (W) College Park, MD 20742 EMPLOYMENT

More information

CAN FAIR VOTING SYSTEMS REALLY MAKE A DIFFERENCE?

CAN FAIR VOTING SYSTEMS REALLY MAKE A DIFFERENCE? CAN FAIR VOTING SYSTEMS REALLY MAKE A DIFFERENCE? Facts and figures from Arend Lijphart s landmark study: Patterns of Democracy: Government Forms and Performance in Thirty-Six Countries Prepared by: Fair

More information

SEMINAR IN WORLD POLITICS PLSC 650 Spring 2015

SEMINAR IN WORLD POLITICS PLSC 650 Spring 2015 SEMINAR IN WORLD POLITICS PLSC 650 Spring 2015 Instructor: Benjamin O. Fordham E-mail: bfordham@binghamton.edu Office: LNG-58 Office Hours: Tuesdays and Thursdays, 1:00-2:30, and by appointment This course

More information

VOTING ON INCOME REDISTRIBUTION: HOW A LITTLE BIT OF ALTRUISM CREATES TRANSITIVITY DONALD WITTMAN ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA

VOTING ON INCOME REDISTRIBUTION: HOW A LITTLE BIT OF ALTRUISM CREATES TRANSITIVITY DONALD WITTMAN ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA 1 VOTING ON INCOME REDISTRIBUTION: HOW A LITTLE BIT OF ALTRUISM CREATES TRANSITIVITY DONALD WITTMAN ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA SANTA CRUZ wittman@ucsc.edu ABSTRACT We consider an election

More information

What historical events led to the Colonies declaring independence? What are the purposes of committees in Congress?

What historical events led to the Colonies declaring independence? What are the purposes of committees in Congress? EXAM FORMAT The exam will contain questions from Chapters 1 through 8. Each chapter s set of questions will be comprised of at least five Define/Identify questions and may contain a short essay. These

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES CONSEQUENCES OF CONSTITUTIONS. Torsten Persson. Working Paper

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES CONSEQUENCES OF CONSTITUTIONS. Torsten Persson. Working Paper NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES CONSEQUENCES OF CONSTITUTIONS Torsten Persson Working Paper 10170 http://www.nber.org/papers/w10170 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA

More information

Political Science 217/317 International Organization

Political Science 217/317 International Organization Phillip Y. Lipscy Spring, 2008 email: plipscy@stanford.edu Office Hours: Wed 10am-12pm or by appointment Encina Hall, Central 434 Course Description Political Science 217/317 International Organization

More information

Michigan Studies in International Political Economy

Michigan Studies in International Political Economy Monetary Divergence Michigan Studies in International Political Economy SERIES EDITORS: Edward Mansfield and Lisa Martin Michael J. Gilligan Empowering Exporters: Reciprocity, Delegation, and Collective

More information

The Amendments. Name: Date: Period:

The Amendments. Name: Date: Period: Name: Date: Period: The Amendments As you studied earlier, the path to amending the Constitution is a difficult one. Throughout the past 200 years, many, many amendments have been suggested in Congress.

More information

Curriculum Vitae Eric C.C. Chang

Curriculum Vitae Eric C.C. Chang August 2016 1 Curriculum Vitae Eric C.C. Chang Department of Political Science Michigan State University 368 Farm Lane, S303 East Lansing, MI 48824 Phone: (517)432-2047 Email: echang@msu.edu Academic Employment

More information

IT has become increasingly common to recognise that the strategic nature of

IT has become increasingly common to recognise that the strategic nature of STRATEGIC INTERACTION AND TRADE POLICYMAKING 507 Strategic Interaction and Trade Policymaking: Formal Analysis and Simulation William Roberts Clark 1, Erick Duchesne 2 and William L. Reed 3 1 University

More information

California's Rising Income Inequality: Causes and Concerns Deborah Reed, February 1999

California's Rising Income Inequality: Causes and Concerns Deborah Reed, February 1999 California's Rising Income Inequality: Causes and Concerns Deborah Reed, February 1999 Copyright 1999 Public Policy Institute of California, San Francisco, CA. All rights reserved. PPIC permits short sections

More information