Exogenous Shocks or Endogenous Constructions? The Meanings of Wars and Crises

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Exogenous Shocks or Endogenous Constructions? The Meanings of Wars and Crises"

Transcription

1 International Studies Quarterly (2007) 51, Exogenous Shocks or Endogenous Constructions? The Meanings of Wars and Crises Wesley W. Widmaier St. Joseph s University Mark Blyth Johns Hopkins University Leonard Seabrooke Copenhagen Business School and The Australian National University This symposium addresses the role of wars and crises as mechanisms of international change. Over the past two decades, the international system has undergone a number of remarkable transformations, from the end of the Cold War to the emergence of an ongoing War on Terror, and from the collapse of statist development models to the emergence of a contested if evolving neoliberal Washington Consensus. This volatility exceeds any underlying shifts in economic structures or the distribution of capabilities, and raises important questions regarding the roles of agency, uncertainty, and ideas in advancing change. In this introduction we examine the role of wars and economic crises as socially constructed openings for change. We attempt three things: to critique materialist approaches in the security and political economy issue areas, to outline the distinctive contribution that an agent-centered constructivist understanding of such events offers, and to offer a framework for the study of such events, one which highlights an expanded range of elite-mass interactions One scarcely need identify the events to which these dates refer. One knows them when one sees them as turning points when old orders ended and new ones began to emerge. Over the past several years, the importance of such events has been examined by a range of international relations scholars offering either materialist analyses of international relations after victory and in the context of hard times, or more constructivist analyses of constitutive wars and the importance of socialpolitik. 1 Such Author s note: For their comments and criticisms of this effort, we thank Lisa Baglione, Jacqueline Best, Bruce Cronin, Colin Hay, Ronald Krebs, Jennifer Lobasz, the late Steve Poe, and Alexander Wendt. The usual disclaimers apply. 1 For example, see Gilpin (1981); Gourevitch (1986); Ruggie (1993); Hay (1996); Bially-Mattern (2001); Ikenberry (2001); Blyth (2002); Hall (2003); Widmaier (2003a); Isacoff (2004); Frederking (2003); Seabrooke (2006). On socialpolitik, see Alkopher (2005). Ó 2007 International Studies Association. Published by Blackwell Publishing, 350 Main Street, Malden, MA 02148, USA, and 9600 Garsington Road, Oxford OX4 2DQ, UK.

2 748 Exogenous Shocks or Endogenous Constructions approaches have definite value, but they also have limits. From the materialist vantage, scholars stress the effect of major wars and economic crises on the balance of power or economic production possibilities. Ikenberry (2001:3) has argued that hegemonic wars ratify shifts in the balance of power and spur the emergence of new systemic arrangements, as historical junctures come at dramatic moments of upheaval when the old order has been destroyed by war and newly powerful states try to reestablish basic organizing principles. Similarly, Gourevitch (1986:20 21) has stressed the effects of economic crises, defined as encompassing major downturn(s) in the business cycle which rearrange the placement of social actors in the economy and shape subsequent policy choices. There are two key problems with such approaches. First, as constructivists have consistently argued, they obscure the influence of intersubjective understandings on agents interpretations of material incentives. As Blyth (2001, 2003) has argued, structures do not come with an instruction sheet, and even exogenous shocks must be interpreted. Neither wars nor crises can be defined simply in terms of their effects on military or economic capabilities. Second, materialist approaches obscure the full scope of agency, limiting it to strategic interaction or adaptation, suggesting that agents rather automatically and unproblematically respond to material shifts in easily predicable ways. However, the range of what agents can do is not exhausted by adaptation to structural constraints or material incentives. Rather, this symposium investigates how agents can also engage in efforts at strategic social construction (Finnemore and Sikkink 1998:888) to shape shared meanings and interpretations of events. In this light, this symposium offers a constructivist analysis of wars and crises, which we define as events which agents intersubjectively interpret as necessitating change. 2 We claim that wars or crises cannot be defined simply in terms of their material effects, but that agents intersubjective understandings must first give meaning to such material changes. In short, agents act upon such understandings rather than their materially telegraphed interests. Neither state nor societal agents can react to material changes until they have interpreted them through diverse frameworks of understanding. Such frameworks do not simply condition subjective perceptions of so-called objective phenomena such as the balance of power. Instead, they render concerns for such things as the balance of power contentious, as when varied ideological, nationalist, or religious ties independently drive foreign policy choices. As such, wars and crises occur in meaningful contexts, as in the Cold War struggle over ways of life or the implications of the Global War on Terror for the United States deepest beliefs. 3 Had those ways of life or deepest beliefs been constructed differently at the particular historical moment they occurred, then the outcomes associated with these struggles would likewise have varied. 4 For example, the fact that the domestic price level of the U.S. fell off a cliff in 1929, or that the Germans took back the Rhineland in 1936, does not telegraph to agents on the ground in 1929 or 1936 what such events mean and what (obviously) has to be done about it. While policy requires politics 2 The notion of socially constructed crisis cannot be reduced to a Kuhnian paradigm shift driven by unambiguous policy failure (Hall 1989); For example, Sikkink (1991: ) questions whether the dramatic failure of past policies combined with initial success of the new is always the best explanation for policy change. She argues instead that the people may be persuaded only if they perceive that old models have suffered dramatic failure or if the new offers stunning success (emphasis added). 3 President Harry S. Truman s Address before a Joint Session of Congress, March 12, 1947; 3 state.gov/usa/infousa/facts/funddocs/truman.txt; George W. Bush, Second Inaugural Address January 20, Indeed, even apparently minor wars and crises can carry disproportionate lessons, as when the 1970s stagflation undermined support for Keynesianism, or when the post-cold War Black Hawk Down incident in Somalia prompted an isolationist backlash against creeping multilateralism (Halberstam 2001).

3 Wesley W. Widmaier, Mark Blyth, and Leonard Seabrooke 749 (Gourevitch 1986:17), politics cannot be reduced to who gets what, when, and how. Politics, at its core, involves arguments over the meaning of events, and such acts of interpretation tell agents who they are and what they want. 5 This is why such moments are often called critical junctures or tipping points (Collier and Collier 1991; Finnemore and Sikkink 1998). They are moments when, as Katznelson (2003:274) has put it, [S]tructurally induced unsettled times can provoke possibilities for particularly consequential purposive action. Such moments alter material incentives precisely because the event is interpreted differently by agents. To get inside the processes of persuasion that help us understand how both elites and the mass public interpret wars and crises differently, we stress the importance of not reading interests as materially telegraphed from structural positions. We also emphasize the need to see the limitations of extant constructivist work that assumes that agents are constituted as subjects by the prevailing systemic culture. While we do not disagree with such approaches per se, our aim is to develop a more agent-centered constructivism addressing the unsettled times at which agents persuasive practices come to the fore. In doing so we wish to understand how elite agents constructions of wars and crises as turning points for policy change is particularly effective when there is a sufficient intersubjective consensus about the legitimacy of change among the broader population. In the first section of this introductory piece, we critique materialist treatments of such events on the grounds that even exogenous shocks must be endogenously interpreted. 6 In each issue-area, we highlight the importance of intersubjective contexts which both give meaning to and can be reshaped by wars and crises. In the second section, we distinguish structural and agent-centered versions of constructivism, arguing for a wider focus on the persuasive practices that agents employ to give meaning to events. We stress here that war and crises ignite processes of persuasion between elites, from elites to the mass public, and from the mass public to elites. In making persuasion rather than socialization the causal mechanism of interest, we can more easily identify how various agents frame what should be done and, in doing so, further an agent-centered constructivism. Developing these arguments, in the third section, we outline elements of a research agenda into the construction of wars and crises, the components of which are highlighted in the individual symposium contributions. While each article is grounded in a basic concern for the meaning of critical events, each also varyingly stresses the elite, mass public, or institutional forces that shape interpretations of crises. In the first article, Mark Blyth examines shifting American understandings of monopoly and elite interactions, arguing that they gave meaning to economic crisis during the first New Deal. In the second article, Wesley Widmaier examines the interplay of an American liberal tradition and presidential rhetoric in reshaping U.S. interests, arguing that presidential constructions of the Cold War and the War on Terror legitimated parallel shifts to crusading foreign policies. In the final effort, Leonard Seabrooke traces evolving mass attitudes in interwar Britain, arguing that these provided the foundation for the ostensibly elite-driven Keynesian Revolution. Taken together, these contributions highlight the importance of persuasive struggles to the construction of crises that transform state and societal interests alike. 5 Even something as obvious as capitalists preferences for rising or falling wages cannot be abstracted from a social context. While some capitalists may prefer higher wages to raise demand, others may prefer falling wages to reduce labor costs. In advocating Keynesian or classical policies, equally capitalist agents can differ over which interpretations of events serve their interests (Widmaier 2004). 6 For example, World War II did not cause the Bretton Woods agreements. Rather, what agents thought caused World War II caused the Bretton Woods Agreements to take their particular form.

4 750 Exogenous Shocks or Endogenous Constructions Contrasting Materialist and Constructivist Assumptions Concerning Agency Materialist approaches share a common view of agents as collectively making efficient use of available information, so that while individuals may commit subjective errors, aggregate efficiency via selection pressures ensures that global trends will coincide with the predictions of the relevant economic [or international relations] theory (Muth 1961:316). 7 For example, shifts in the distribution of power may lead to the appropriate balancing to prevent the emergence of a dominant power, and shifts in economic resources may similarly spur the rise or demise of particular economic orders. However, such approaches obscure the importance of the interpretive context and lead to a somewhat impoverished view of agency (Hay 2004:52 53). This is logically the case given that if there are underlying incentive structures that guide rational choices, we should expect the variation in politically relevant outcomes to be quite limited. The fact that it is not surely tells us something of interest. Constructivism stresses how intersubjective understandings, sustained through interaction, give meaning to incentives and interests. These understandings are termed inter subjective because they transcend individual beliefs and possess instead a collective permanence. 8 Constructivists argue that intersubjective understandings matter because agents cannot efficiently employ all available information in forming their strategies. Instead, agents face a fundamental uncertainty in forming expectations. This uncertainty is not limited to the ability to make a probabilistic calculation regarding the likelihood of some event, such as a shift in the balance of power or a market downturn. Rather, it is a more pervasive constraint, one which limits the ability of agents to form any meaningful estimate of future trends. 9 In the face of such uncertainty, agents rely on intersubjective understandings to make sense of events and define their interests, or beliefs about how to meet needs (Wendt 1999:130; Blyth 2002, 2006). Constructivists further assume that such understandings must be sustained and or transformed through interaction, via explicitly expressive, communicative, or rhetorical practices. Such an approach opens up the possibility of understanding the variation in outcomes that we see in international politics, as it eschews the notion that there is an efficient outcome that agents are socialized disciplined into. Rather, it stresses the contingent nature of outcomes by examining how agents frame such uncertain moments to make persuasive claims concerning the need for change, while also recognizing that frames can take on lives of their own in generating future uncertainty. The remainder of this section juxtaposes materialist views of wars and crises as exogenous shocks with a constructivist stress on their endogenous, social foundations. 7 It is worth drawing a distinction here between economists use of the term rationality as used by rationalchoice pioneer John Muth (1961: ) and recent discussions in the IR literature. Muth defines rational choices as those made on the basis of all available information, conforming to the predictions of the relevant economic theory. This differs from IR scholars more casual conflation (Finnemore and Sikkink 1998; Fearon and 4Wendt 2002) of rational with strategic choices. To assume that agents are strategic is simply to suggest that they have consistent preferences and make choices which advance those preferences, not that they can collectively employ all available information. Given this distinction, while constructivist frameworks cannot at base be reconciled with rationalist assumptions, they can be reconciled with approaches that posit agents make strategic choices, given some social context. 8 For example, the belief that independent central banks lead to lower inflation is institutionalized within the community of central bankers, irrespective of the beliefs on any individual banker. 9 Keynes (1973 [1937]: ) argued that the fact that our knowledge of the future is fluctuating, vague and uncertain, renders wealth a peculiarly unsuitable subject for the methods of the classical economic theory. Blyth (2002), Widmaier (2003b), and Seabrooke (2007c) further address the implications of uncertainty for economic constructivism.

5 Wesley W. Widmaier, Mark Blyth, and Leonard Seabrooke 751 Materialist and Constructivist Approaches to War and Change International relations scholars have long noted the association between major wars, postwar settlements, and change in international orders. Perhaps most prominently, Robert Gilpin has argued that hegemonic war serves as the principal mechanism of change throughout history. In this view, periodic hegemonic conflicts determine which state or states will be dominant and govern the system (Gilpin 1981:15). One might ask, however, how a victorious hegemon might define its interests, in a benign or a more predatory fashion? 10 One solution, adopted by scholars favoring a second image reversed perspective, offers a supplemental stress on domestic preferences. For example, scholars like Ikenberry (2001:5) accord primary focus to the systemic distribution of capabilities, but then highlight the intervening role of domestic institutions in shaping postwar orders, arguing that democratic states have greater capacities to enter into binding institutions and can establish more stable arrangements. Similarly, scholars like Snyder (1991:2) stress the role of economic sectors and state bureaucracies that manipulate constructions of conflicts to justify their self-serving policies in terms of a broader public interest. Such arguments remain wanting, however, to the extent that major asymmetries in the balance of power cannot be abstracted from the social context of, for example, rivalry or friendship between states. While states identifying as rivals may shift to prevent any competitor from attaining dominance, states identified as friends may downplay the importance of the distribution of power in mutual interactions. Second, the very meaning of institutional arrangements is subject to interpretation. For example, definitions of democracy itself may be a source of conflict, or they may in fact be altered to justify conflict as Oren (1995) has argued concerning scholarship and U.S. foreign policy during World War I. Third, societal agents may have no determinate a priori interests in systemic arrangements. Capitalists may oppose expansionistic foreign policies out of a fear of an aggrandized state, or they may favor expansion as a means to securing export markets and access to raw materials. In short, intersubjective frameworks give meaning to systemic, state, and societal incentives. In this light, constructivists have stressed the need to more directly examine debates over the meaning of wars. They cast power politics as a social and historical product, suggesting that wars can acquire new meanings and functions in different settings (Alkopher 2005:719). For example, Ruggie (1993:157, ) argues that the emergence of the sovereign state system can itself be seen as having reflected a transformation in social epistemology. He highlights a change in the epistemes of the pre-westphalian era and the mental equipment that people drew upon in imagining and symbolizing forms of political community. Ruggie argues that pre-westphalian views were challenged in and hammered home through constitutive wars, which established the notion of sovereignty, and set the stage for more strategic and tactical configurative and positional wars. Similarly, Bukovansky (2002:2; ) stresses how shifting notions of legitimate political authority drove the shift from dynasticism to popular sovereignty. She argues that even though dynastic monarchy seemed to have been victorious, the Napoleonic Wars paradoxically prompted an acceleration of nationalism. In this view, it is not only shifts in power, but also tensions over prevailing understandings that drive war and change in world politics. 10 Gilpin himself makes an ad hoc concession to the importance of ideology, acknowledging that every dominant state promotes a religion or ideology that justifies its domination (Gilpin 1981:30).

6 752 Exogenous Shocks or Endogenous Constructions Materialist and Constructivist Views of Economic Crisis and Change Paralleling these views of wars as manifesting shifts in the distribution of power, materialist scholars with an IPE focus cast exogenous material shocks as reshaping economic orders. Hegemonic stability theorists such as Robert Gilpin cast the rise and fall of great powers as the most important factor in explaining systemic stability. However, Gilpin (1987:88) concedes the role of ideology and stresses the need for a dominant liberal power to enable economic cooperation. As in the security realm, materialist scholars have increasingly recognized the indeterminacy of systemic incentives and argued for a greater stress on domestic politics and actors interests. For example, Ikenberry (1992:291) highlights the supplemental role of policy specialists and economists in establishing the post-world War II economic order, while Gourevitch (1986:21) argues that economic effects of the crises of the 1920s and the 1930s on the relative position of capital and labor explain variation in policy choices. Despite their merits, such analyses remain wanting for the same reasons as in the security realm, reflecting uncertainty regarding systemic, institutional, and societal incentives. First, the effects of the distribution of capabilities in abstraction from the social context are indeterminate. Where states share a sense of the common interest, as in the case of the European Union, no hegemonic capabilities may be needed to maintain macroeconomic stability. Conversely, where such positive identification is lacking, no level of capabilities may be sufficient to guarantee stability, as in the counter case of ASEAN (Katzenstein 2005: ). Secondly, institutional incentives are likewise subject to interpretation. Consider that the rise of independent central banks might lead to lower inflation only if central bankers define their institutional interests in those terms (Widmaier 2007). Third, and finally, for all types of social actors, neither firms, nor unions, nor representatives of civil society can identify their true interests in abstraction from some intersubjective setting (Blyth 2002). For example, the deflation caused by the Great Depression impacted states in a common way, yet promoted vastly different responses, the variance of which went well beyond domestic material differences. The U.S., Sweden, and Germany all deflated, but the choice of cartelization, fascism, or social democracy as an institutional resolution was not given by the material context (Berman 2006). Ruggie s work has also played a key role in developing constructivist arguments in the area of IPE, as reflected in his stress on not only power but also social purpose in explaining the rise of the Bretton Woods system. Building upon Ruggie s insights, Blyth (2002:7 8) rejects frameworks that treat international political development as progressing through a series of selfapparent exogenous shocks. Attempting to deal with the indeterminacy of materialist arguments and to pay greater attention to how the social context shapes outcomes, Blyth suggests that ideas play differing roles as weapons in distributional struggles, blueprints for new institutions, and as conventions for the coordination of behavior. From Structural to Agent-Centered Constructivism Such arguments have important implications for the ability of constructivism to address not only stability and cooperation, but also change and conflict. Recognizing the need to address such concerns, constructivists have, in recent years, increasingly shifted from a focus on structural continuities and their effects on agents via socialization, to a focus on what agents do and how they frame their actions. Indeed, over its first decade, constructivist scholarship was

7 Wesley W. Widmaier, Mark Blyth, and Leonard Seabrooke 753 often highly structural. 11 Perhaps the clearest illustration of this was the Katzenstein (1996) edited volume on security cultures, which, as contributors Kowert and Legro (1996: ) noted, examined the consequences of behavioral norms and identities, but not the issue of Where do the norms themselves come from? Reacting to this limitation, a growing recognition emerged in the mid 1990s that constructivists should [bring] agency back in (Checkel 1998: ) in order to highlight the sources of contingency and change in world politics. 12 In the context of this concern for agency, scholars like Finnemore and Sikkink (1998) and Adler (2005 [1997]) have emphasized the ways in which members of epistemic communities and norm entrepreneurs have acted as agents of change. In an influential piece, Finnemore and Sikkink (1998: ) highlight the role of norm entrepreneurs who attempt to convince a critical mass of states (norm leaders) to embrace new norms. These entrepreneurs engage in framing practices that call attention to issues or even create issues by using language that names, interprets, and dramatizes them. Their efforts succeed when a first stage of norm emergence passes a tipping point into a second stage of norm cascade, facilitated by social pressure for conformity, desire to enhance international legitimation, and the desire of state leaders to enhance their self-esteem. When norm leaders are successful, such actions resonate with broader public understandings and are adopted as new ways of talking about and understanding issues. In a broadly similar way, Adler (2005 [1997]:111) stresses the role of scientific and policy elites in not simply reshaping policy frameworks, but even engendering the transformation of identities and interests. For example, to explain the establishment of the Bretton Woods institutions, Adler (2005 [1991]:83) stresses its origins in the minds of a small group of key U.S. [and U.K.] economists as the agreements were negotiated twice: first, in the domestic game of coalitional politics and second, in the international game of economic diplomacy. While such frameworks highlight important types of agency, we argue in this symposium for the need to build on them by employing a wider focus on the role of persuasion not only among elites, but from elites to the mass public, and from the mass public to elites. To do so we require an analytical framework that is also sensitive to institutional contexts and the practices involved in the construction of crises. Toward an Agent-Centered Constructivism: Turning Points, Persuasion, and Elite Mass Interactions Building on the prior efforts of constructivist theorists, we outline here a set of propositions regarding the social construction of wars and crises as reconstitutive events. In doing so, we suggest paying attention to how moments of change are framed. In such moments the politics of persuasion comes to the fore, and consequently a focus upon who is persuading whom becomes salient. We suggest that a focus on persuasion can provide more analytical purchase than a focus on socialization as the dominant mechanism driving normative change (Finnemore and Sikkink 1998:902). This is the case given that wars and crises provide openings for change where a range of social agents can interpret events to push for policy innovations. Furthermore, as war and crises are interpreted 11 This was in part a function of the need to engage contemporary rivals like neorealism and neoliberal institutionalism. 12 To paraphrase Hay (2004), just as a rational choice can be seen as no choice, so taken to extremes is a socialized choice. The emergence of an over-socialized, structural constructivism would risk obscuring the practices by which intersubjective structures evolve and change.

8 754 Exogenous Shocks or Endogenous Constructions not only by elites, but also by the mass public, such events center around the persuasiveness of claims concerning the necessity of change. Whereas more structural versions of constructivism often view persuasion as a part of socialization, and existing agent-centered constructivist accounts tend to focus on elite elite interactions (epistemic communities with bureaucrats, norm entrepreneurs with politicians), we suggest the need for a greater focus on persuasion as intersubjective contestation among both elite and mass public agents. To understand how mechanisms of persuasion operate, we identify four specific concerns as analytical foci: (1) the interplay of intersubjective tensions and interpretive struggles, (2) institutional and rhetorical norms which guide efforts to frame particular events, (3) mass elite persuasive interactions, and (4) subsequent debates over the lessons of history a concern beyond the focus of the articles in this symposium. First, intersubjective understandings possess such an enduring mass presence that it should at least be questioned as to whether they can be easily reshaped by elites. While there has been great conceptual progress in explaining persuasion as normative suasion, especially in shifting an agent s internalization of a norm from a logic of consequences to a logic of appropriateness (Risse, Ropp, and Sikkink 1999; Checkel 2005: ), we wonder to what extent the internalization of either logic depletes an agent s ability to buck the system (see also Sending 2002). We take a slightly different tack on the extant literature by viewing persuasion not so much as a part of socialization, but as an ongoing process in which the legitimacy of claims about what is to be done is open to contestation between elites, and between elites and mass publics. Importantly, this reminds us that when elites struggle over what ideas should be given priority in a time of crisis, they must consider what ideas will be persuasive and establish institutional and political support for ideas to translate into policy action. For example, in the first symposium piece, Blyth offers an analysis of varied American notions of monopoly power as a product of market forces or state policy, as a benign or malignant force, and as an aid or an impediment to recovery from the Depression. Blyth s concern is not to establish that one of these views is correct, as no economic theory is a correspondence theory of the way the world works (Blyth 2002, 2003). Rather his point is to detail how competing versions of what monopoly is came to be instantiated in policy as a function of persuasive struggles, rather than as some functional response to an exogenously given and preinterpretive economic crisis. By examining the so-called first New Deal under Roosevelt, Blyth shows how competing U.S. notions of monopoly set boundaries on the types of institutions and coalitions the American state attempted to construct in the period Second, to the extent that intersubjective understandings are sustained in particular settings, it is often necessary to ask a second set of questions regarding the institutional contexts of social construction. This can entail, as suggested above, a focus on both the formal structures that shape debate and the more diffuse norms that encourage particular types of rhetoric. In this vein, the article by Widmaier seeks to explain the instability of definitions of U.S. national interests with reference to intersubjective structures and institutionalized practices. In terms of intersubjective influences, Widmaier argues that an American liberal tradition has been constitutive of three shifting definitions of the national interest: an exceptionalist isolationism, a pragmatic realism, and an absolutist or crusading internationalism. With respect to institutionalized practices, he argues further that liberalism s instability is exacerbated by reliance on a rhetorical presidency to focus debate (Tulis 1987). He then applies this framework to show how presidential rhetoric shaped constructions of events in 1947 and 2001 to accomplish strikingly parallel visions of the Cold War and the War on Terror. In each setting, crisis discourses, advanced in mass public contexts via

9 Wesley W. Widmaier, Mark Blyth, and Leonard Seabrooke 755 the use of presidential rhetoric, took on lives of their own as they reshaped prevailing notions of the national interest and engendered more crusading policies. This analysis shows how presidential interpretations cannot be imposed by fiat, that persuasion is never a one-way street, and that institutional contexts can exert their own influence on the form and frequency of crisis constructions. Third, the success of any elite group engaged in persuasion is often less related to their analytic skills than to the broad mass intuitions of the moment, which will favor one movement to the exclusion of others. In this light, it is often necessary to examine mass political views to explain the manner in which specific elites can actually influence policy discourses. Such everyday politics can matter more than elite debates, as elite victories often reflect a base accord with broader intuitions (Hobson and Seabrooke 2007; Seabrooke 2007a). In this light, Leonard Seabrooke examines the widening cleavages between elite and mass policy beliefs in Britain in the 1920s and details how elite ideas about the need for austerity clashed with mass ideas about economic justice, as well as new economic and social conventions. Despite elite views that economic policy was largely a technical matter, the increasing legitimacy gap between elite policy proclamations and mass public expectations opened the door to later Keynesian thinking and a demand-side emphasis on promoting income equality as a means to recovery (Seabrooke 2007b). Absent such legitimacy contests, the emergence of Keynesianism in Britain, in the particular form that it assumed, becomes difficult to explain. In short, mass expectations about how the economy should work set limits on ostensible elite policy makers. In this sense, while dominant constructivist work on socialization and persuasion stresses the need for new norms to resonate with the larger public (Finnemore and Sikkink 1998:897), we raise the threshold for resonance by highlighting the capacity for mass publics to reject elites attempts to legitimate or naturalize changes made during periods of crisis (Hopf 2002). 13 Finally, in a context that exceeds the scope of these three articles (Figure 1, above, provides an overview of their emphases), we suggest that a research focus on the construction of crises would allow analysts to better recognize the importance of expressive struggles over the lessons of history, as intensified debate over the meaning of contemporary events often fosters reinterpretations of past wars and crises. For example, in the context of debates over the stagflations of the 1970s, the lessons of the Great Depression came under new discussion. Keynesian market failure constructions, which had dominated discourses from the 1930s onward with their stress on the endogenous instability of market expectations, increasingly yielded to more classical state-failure constructions which cast macroeconomic interventions as inherently destabilizing (Blyth 2002; Widmaier 2004). Similarly, in the security realm, debates over the lessons of history have had a recurring effect on foreign policy determination. In the case of Israel, for example, Isacoff (2004) attributes variation in foreign policy by tracing the arguments of traditional and new Israeli historians and how they construct contending images of Arab and Palestinian roles in different phases of their conflict. In this sense, even when a particular crisis-construction has apparently triumphed, constructivists should resist temptations to reify the resulting social facts, as any conventional wisdom can always be reconstructed. To the extent that debates over the lessons of history are themselves constitutive of future 13 To the extent that mass attitudes shift, so may the foundations of international accords, necessitating a greater focus on deliberative deficits and legitimacy gaps in undermining elite consensus and policy practices. There are both domestic and international effects here. Consider, for example, how the framing of the project of European Union has shifted from prevent war with the ECSA agreement of 1951 to prevent inflation under EMU at century s end. The evaluation of what the EU is for necessarily impacts what the EU as actor can and cannot do. Similarly, the IMFs informal practices are some distance from its formal mandate and encourage a legitimacy gap between itself, its member states, and their mass publics (see Seabrooke 2007b).

10 756 Exogenous Shocks or Endogenous Constructions Turning point 1) Uncertainty over intersubjective context: 2) Context of expressive struggle: 3) Constitutive effects on state and societal interests: U.S. Debates over First New Deal 1930s (Blyth) Uncertainty over classical economics and nature of monopoly State and business and labor discourse Constitution of aggregate or macro interests U.K. Debates over adjustment and depression 1920s- 1930s (Seabrooke) Uncertainty over Victorian/Edwardian values, classical economics, and gold standard Elite and mass discourses Constitution of new conventions support elite Keynesian demand-side economics U.S. redefinitions of national interest: post-wwii; post- 9/11 (Widmaier) Uncertainty over U.S. national interest and isolationistpragmatist policies Presidential rhetoric Constitution of crusading definition of national interest FIG. 1. International Turning Points: The Effects of Wars and Crises on State and Societal Interests. understandings and interests, the construction of crises involves ongoing persuasion in mass and elite settings alike. Conclusions This introductory piece has offered a constructivist analysis of wars and crises as mechanisms of change, highlighting theoretical insights that transcend ostensible IPE-security divides and so breaking down the artificial borders that divide disciplinary subfields. We have argued that intersubjective contexts not only give meaning to wars and crises, but also that how agents interpret these events as necessitating change leads to different strategies of persuasion among both elites and mass publics. The persuasiveness of a change enabled by crisis-construction cannot, in our view, be read off of materially telegraphed interests, just as it cannot be attributed to elites automatic capacity to socialize mass publics into normative frameworks. In terms of subsequent research design, our agent-centered constructivist approach to war and crisis inverts materialist frameworks that begin with questions about the distribution of capabilities or economic resources and treat ideas as mere focal points. Instead, this symposium proposes a research agenda focused on wars and crises as moments where elite and mass public agents attempt to persuade each other over who they are and what they want. This approach casts political struggles as arguments over the meaning of events, over how they should be framed and interpreted within various institutional contexts. In terms of ongoing debates, there is a strong link here between our use of persuasion and that of legitimacy, if the latter is understood as a process by which the governing and governed make, and confer or reject, claims concerning the fairness and rightfulness of policy change. The concept of legitimacy has received renewed attention in international relations (Clark 2005; Jackson 2006; Hurd 2007), and our wish is to bolster the development of this work with a strong agent-centered constructivism. For this to occur, our notion of legitimacy must not focus exclusively on elites proclamations and rhetorical battles, but also recognize that those on the receiving end of persuasion often have the capacity to influence policy outcomes (Seabrooke 2006:40 42). An agent-centered constructivism therefore requires us to investigate the means by which a broader range of social actors provide impulses for intersubjective change. It asks

11 Wesley W. Widmaier, Mark Blyth, and Leonard Seabrooke 757 us to qualify how war and crises act as effective turning points not because of changes in material structures per se, but because of transformations in broader intersubjective understandings. Finally, this approach has the added merit of highlighting the most important aspect of constructivism; a stress upon contingency and the ability to highlight unappreciated social possibilities. From Wendt s seminal argument that anarchy is what states make of it, to Adler s work on cognitive evolution and learning, to Finnemore and Sikkink s emphasis on the agency of norm entrepreneurs, and onto the arguments in this symposium, a central concern of constructivists has been to stress that constraints on policy are socially constructed. Whether in seeking to transcend the security dilemma, the impossible trinity, or restrictive notions of sovereignty, an awareness of the socially constructed nature of systemic constraints is essential to the ability of scholars to highlight unappreciated possibilities. No less than anarchy itself, wars and crises cannot be reduced to material forces or socialization, but are what agents make of them. References Adler, Emanuel. (2005 [1991]) Cognitive Evolution: A Dynamic Approach for the Study of International Relations and Their Progress. In Progress in Postwar International Relations, edited by E. Adler and B. Crawford. New York: Columbia University Press. Adler, Emanuel. (2005 [1997]) Seizing the Middle Ground: Constructivism in World Politics. In Communitarian International Relations: The Epistemic Foundations of International Relations, edited by 1 Emanuel Adler. New York: Routledge. Alkopher, Tal Dingott. (2005) The Social (and Religious) Meanings that Constitute War: The Crusades as Realpolitik vs. Socialpolitik. International Studies Quarterly 49(4): Berman, Sheri. (2006) The Primacy of Politics: Social Democracy and the Making of Europe s Twentieth Century. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Bially-Mattern, Janice. (2001) The Power Politics of Identity. European Journal of International Relations 7(3): Blyth, Mark. (2001) The Transformation of the Swedish Model: Economic Ideas, Distributional Conflict and Institutional Change. World Politics 54(1): Blyth, Mark. (2002) Great Transformations: Economic Ideas and Institutional Change in the Twentieth Century. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Blyth, Mark. (2003) Structures Do Not Come with an Instruction Sheet: Interests, Ideas and Progress in Political Science. Perspectives on Politics 1(4): Blyth, Mark. (2006) Great Punctuations: Prediction, Randomness, and the Evolution of Comparative Political Science. American Political Science Review 100(4): Bukovansky, Mlada. (2002) Legitimacy and Power Politics: The American and French Revolutions in International Political Culture. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Checkel, Jeffrey T. (1998) The Constructivist Turn in International Relations Theory. World Politics 50(2): Checkel, Jeffrey T. (2005) International Institutions and Socialization in Europe: Introduction and Framework. International Organization 59(4): Clark, Ian. (2005) Legitimacy in International Society. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Collier, Ruth Berins, and David Collier. (1991) Shaping the Political Arena: Critical Junctures, the Labor Movement and Regime Dynamics in Latin America. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Fearon, James, and Alexander Wendt. (2002) Rationalism v. Constructivism: A Skeptical View. In Handbook of International Relations, edited by W. Carlsnaes, T. Risse and B. A. Simmons. London: Sage Publications. Finnemore, Martha, and Kathryn Sikkink. (1998) International Norm Dynamics and Political Change. International Organization 52(4): Frederking, Brian. (2003) Constructing Post-Cold War Collective Security. American Political Science Review 97(3): Gilpin, Robert. (1981) War and Change in World Politics. New York: Cambridge University Press. Gilpin, Robert. (1987) The Political Economy of International Relations. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

12 758 Exogenous Shocks or Endogenous Constructions Gourevitch, Peter. (1986) Politics in Hard Times: Comparative Responses to International Economic Crises. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press. Halberstam, David. (2001) War in a Time of Peace. New York: Scribner. Hall, Peter, eds. (1989) The Political Power of Economic Ideas. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Hall, Rodney Bruce. (2003) The Discursive Demolition of the Asian Development Model. International Studies Quarterly 47(4): Hay, Colin. (1996) Narrating Crisis: The Discursive Construction of the Winter of Discontent. Sociology 30(2): Hay, Colin. (2004) Theory, Stylized Heuristic or Self-Fulfilling Prophecy? The Status of Rational Choice Theory in Public Administration. Public Administration 82(1): Hobson, John M, and Leonard Seabrooke, eds. (2007) Everyday Politics of the World Economy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Hopf, Ted. (2002) Making the Future Inevitable: Legitimizing, Naturalizing and Stabilizing. The Transition in Estonia, Ukraine and Uzbekistan. European Journal of International Relations 8(3): Hurd, Ian. (2007) After Anarchy: Legitimacy and Power at the United Nations Security Council. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Ikenberry, G. John. (1992) A World Economy Restored: Expert Consensus and the Anglo-American Postwar Settlement. International Organization 46(1): Ikenberry, G. John. (2001) After Victory: Institutions, Strategic Restraint and the Rebuilding of Order after Major Wars. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Isacoff, Jonathan. (2004) Writing the Arab-Israeli Conflict: Historical Bias and the Use of History in Political Science. Perspectives on Politics 3(1): Jackson, Patrick Thaddeus. (2006) Civilizing the Enemy: German Reconstruction and the Invention of the West. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press. Katzenstein, Peter J, eds. (1996) The Culture of National Security: Norms and Identity in World Politics. New York: Columbia. Katzenstein, Peter J. (2005) A World of Regions: Asia and Europe in the American Imperium. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press. Katznelson, Ira. (2003) Periodization and Preferences: Reflections of Purposive Action in Comparative Historical Social Science. In Comparative Historical Analysis in the Social Sciences, edited by J. Mahoney and D. Rueschemeyer. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Keynes, John Maynard. (1973 [1937]) The General Theory of Employment. In The Collected Writings of John Maynard Keynes: The General Theory and After, edited by D. Moggridge. London: MacMillan. Kowert, Paul, and Jeffrey Legro. (1996) Norms, Identity, and Their Limits: A Theoretical Reprise. In The Culture of National Security, edited by P. Katzenstein. New York: Columbia University Press. Muth, John F. (1961) Rational Expectations and the Theory of Price Movements. Econometrica 29(3): Oren, Ido. (1995) The Subjectivity of the Democratic Peace: Changing U.S. Perceptions of Imperial Germany. International Security 20(2): Risse, Thomas, Stephen Ropp, and Kathryn Sikkink, eds. (1999) The Power of Human Rights: International Norms and Domestic Change. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Ruggie, John Gerard. (1993) Territoriality and Beyond: Problematizing Modernity in International Relations. International Organization 47(3): Seabrooke, Leonard. (2006) The Social Sources of Financial Power: Domestic Legitimacy and International Financial Orders. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press. Seabrooke, Leonard. (2007a) Everyday Legitimacy and International Financial Orders: The Social Sources of Imperialism and Hegemony in Global Finance. New Political Economy 12(1): Seabrooke, Leonard. (2007b) Legitimacy Gaps in the World Economy: Explaining the Sources of the IMFs Legitimacy Crisis. International Politics 44(2-3): Seabrooke, Leonard. (2007c) Varieties of Economic Constructivism in Political Economy: Uncertain Times Call for Disparate Measures. Review of International Political Economy 14(2): Sending, Ole Jacob. (2002) Constitution, Choice and Change: Problems with the Logic of Appropriateness and Its Use in Constructivist Theory. European Journal of International Relations 8(4): Sikkink, Kathryn. (1991) Ideas and Institutions: Developmentalism in Argentina and Brazil. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.

13 Wesley W. Widmaier, Mark Blyth, and Leonard Seabrooke 759 Snyder, Jack. (1991) Myths of Empire: Domestic Politics and International Ambition. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press. Tulis, Jeffrey. (1987) The Rhetorical Presidency. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Wendt, Alexander. (1999) Social Theory of International Politics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Widmaier, Wesley W. (2003a) Constructing Monetary Crises: New Keynesian Understandings and Monetary Cooperation in the 1990s. Review of International Studies 29(1): Widmaier, Wesley W. (2003b) Keynesianism as a Constructivist Theory of the International Political Economy. Millennium: Journal of International Studies 32(1): Widmaier, Wesley W. (2004) The Social Construction of the Impossible Trinity : The Intersubjective Bases of Monetary Cooperation. International Studies Quarterly 48(2): Widmaier, Wesley W. (2007) Where You Stand Depends on How You Think: Economic Ideas, the Decline of the Council of Economic Advisers, and the Rise of the Federal Reserve. New Political Economy 12(1):

Economic Ideas and the Political Construction of Financial Crisis and Reform 1

Economic Ideas and the Political Construction of Financial Crisis and Reform 1 ECPR Joint Sessions Antwerp 2012 Proposal for Workshop Economic Ideas and the Political Construction of Financial Crisis and Reform 1 Dr Andrew Baker, School of Politics, International Studies and Philosophy,

More information

Graduate Seminar on International Relations Political Science (PSCI) 5013/7013 Spring 2007

Graduate Seminar on International Relations Political Science (PSCI) 5013/7013 Spring 2007 Graduate Seminar on International Relations Political Science (PSCI) 5013/7013 Spring 2007 Instructor: Moonhawk Kim Office: Ketchum 122A E-mail: moonhawk.kim@colorado.edu Phone: (303) 492 8601 Office Hours:

More information

Social Constructivism and International Relations

Social Constructivism and International Relations Social Constructivism and International Relations Philosophy and the Social Sciences Jack Jenkins jtjenkins919@gmail.com Explain and critique constructivist approaches to the study of international relations.

More information

Peter Katzenstein, ed. The Culture of National Security: Norms and Identity in World Politics

Peter Katzenstein, ed. The Culture of National Security: Norms and Identity in World Politics Peter Katzenstein, ed. The Culture of National Security: Norms and Identity in World Politics Peter Katzenstein, Introduction: Alternative Perspectives on National Security Most studies of international

More information

International Relations Theory Political Science 440 Northwestern University Winter 2010 Thursday 2-5pm, Ripton Room, Scott Hall

International Relations Theory Political Science 440 Northwestern University Winter 2010 Thursday 2-5pm, Ripton Room, Scott Hall International Relations Theory Political Science 440 Northwestern University Winter 2010 Thursday 2-5pm, Ripton Room, Scott Hall Jonathan Caverley j-caverley@northwestern.edu 404 Scott Office Hours: Tuesday

More information

Exam Questions By Year IR 214. How important was soft power in ending the Cold War?

Exam Questions By Year IR 214. How important was soft power in ending the Cold War? Exam Questions By Year IR 214 2005 How important was soft power in ending the Cold War? What does the concept of an international society add to neo-realist or neo-liberal approaches to international relations?

More information

FOREIGN POLICY ANALYSIS

FOREIGN POLICY ANALYSIS I IBIIIUUI t A/553920 SAGE LIBRARY OF INTERNATIONAL RELATIONS FOREIGN POLICY ANALYSIS VOLUME I Edited by Walter Carlsnaes and Stefano Guzzini (S)SAGE Los Angeles London New Delhi Singapore Washington DC

More information

Chapter One Introduction Finland s security policy is not based on historical or cultural ties and affinities or shared values, but on an unsentimenta

Chapter One Introduction Finland s security policy is not based on historical or cultural ties and affinities or shared values, but on an unsentimenta Chapter One Introduction Finland s security policy is not based on historical or cultural ties and affinities or shared values, but on an unsentimental calculation of the national interest. (Jakobson 1980,

More information

changes in the global environment, whether a shifting distribution of power (Zakaria

changes in the global environment, whether a shifting distribution of power (Zakaria Legitimacy dilemmas in global governance Review by Edward A. Fogarty, Department of Political Science, Colgate University World Rule: Accountability, Legitimacy, and the Design of Global Governance. By

More information

POLITICAL SCIENCE 240/IRGN 254: International Relations Theory. The following books are available for purchase at the UCSD bookstore:

POLITICAL SCIENCE 240/IRGN 254: International Relations Theory. The following books are available for purchase at the UCSD bookstore: POLITICAL SCIENCE 240/IRGN 254: International Relations Theory Professors Miles Kahler and David A. Lake Winter Quarter 2002 Tuesdays, 1:30 PM 4:20 PM Course readings: The following books are available

More information

POL 3: Introduction to International Relations Fall Course Website:

POL 3: Introduction to International Relations Fall Course Website: POL 3: Introduction to International Relations Fall 2011 Professor Zeev Maoz (zmaoz@ucdavis.edu) TR: 10:30-11:50 Office Hours: T,R 3:00-4:00 Office: 674 Kerr Hall Course Website: http://psfaculty.ucdavis.edu/zmaoz/international_relations.htm.

More information

Introduction to International Relations Political Science S1601Q Columbia University Summer 2013

Introduction to International Relations Political Science S1601Q Columbia University Summer 2013 Introduction to International Relations Political Science S1601Q Columbia University Summer 2013 Instructor: Sara Bjerg Moller Email: sbm2145@columbia.edu Office Hours: Prior to each class or by appointment.

More information

SS: Social Sciences. SS 131 General Psychology 3 credits; 3 lecture hours

SS: Social Sciences. SS 131 General Psychology 3 credits; 3 lecture hours SS: Social Sciences SS 131 General Psychology Principles of psychology and their application to general behavior are presented. Stresses the scientific method in understanding learning, perception, motivation,

More information

Critical Theory and Constructivism

Critical Theory and Constructivism Chapter 7 Pedigree of the Critical Theory Paradigm Critical Theory and Ø Distinguishing characteristics: p The critical theory is a kind of reflectivism, comparative with rationalism, or problem-solving

More information

ADVANCED POLITICAL ANALYSIS

ADVANCED POLITICAL ANALYSIS ADVANCED POLITICAL ANALYSIS Professor: Colin HAY Academic Year 2018/2019: Common core curriculum Fall semester MODULE CONTENT The analysis of politics is, like its subject matter, highly contested. This

More information

GOVT 2060 International Relations: Theories and Approaches Fall 2017

GOVT 2060 International Relations: Theories and Approaches Fall 2017 THE UNIVERSITY OF THE WEST INDIES ST. AUGUSTINE FACULTY OF SOCIAL SCIENCES DEPARTMENT OF POLITICAL SCIENCE GOVT 2060 International Relations: Theories and Approaches Fall 2017 Topic 9 Constructivism In

More information

SS: Social Sciences. SS 131 General Psychology 3 credits; 3 lecture hours

SS: Social Sciences. SS 131 General Psychology 3 credits; 3 lecture hours SS: Social Sciences SS 131 General Psychology Principles of psychology and their application to general behavior are presented. Stresses the scientific method in understanding learning, perception, motivation,

More information

DIPL 6000: Section AA International Relations Theory

DIPL 6000: Section AA International Relations Theory 1 DIPL 6000: Section AA International Relations Theory Professor Martin S. Edwards E-Mail: edwardmb@shu.edu Office: 106 McQuaid Office Phone: (973) 275-2507 Office Hours: By Appointment This is a graduate

More information

GOVERNMENT 426 CONFLICT & COOPERATION IN WORLD POLITICS Spring 1996 Tuesday 2:15-4:05 p.m. Healy 106

GOVERNMENT 426 CONFLICT & COOPERATION IN WORLD POLITICS Spring 1996 Tuesday 2:15-4:05 p.m. Healy 106 GOVERNMENT 426 CONFLICT & COOPERATION IN WORLD POLITICS Spring 1996 Tuesday 2:15-4:05 p.m. Healy 106 Professor Joseph Lepgold Professor George Shambaugh ICC 665 ICC 674A phone: 687-5635 phone: 687-2979

More information

Geopolitical Economy: After US Hegemony, Globalization and Empire. The Future of World Capitalism

Geopolitical Economy: After US Hegemony, Globalization and Empire. The Future of World Capitalism Radhika Desai Geopolitical Economy: After US Hegemony, Globalization and Empire. The Future of World Capitalism 2013. London: Pluto Press, and Halifax: Fernwood Publishing. Pages: 313. ISBN 978-0745329925.

More information

440 IR Theory Fall 2011

440 IR Theory Fall 2011 440 IR Theory Fall 2011 Ian Hurd ianhurd@northwestern.edu Scott Hall Class meetings: Monday, 9 to 12:00, Ripton Room Office hours Tuesday, 12:30 to 2:30 This seminar examines the main theoretical and methodological

More information

B.A. Study in English International Relations Global and Regional Perspective

B.A. Study in English International Relations Global and Regional Perspective B.A. Study in English Global and Regional Perspective Title Introduction to Political Science History of Public Law European Integration Diplomatic and Consular Geopolitics Course description The aim of

More information

REVIEW THE SOCIAL THEORY OF INTERNATIONAL POLITICS

REVIEW THE SOCIAL THEORY OF INTERNATIONAL POLITICS REVIEW THE SOCIAL THEORY OF INTERNATIONAL POLITICS Author: Alexander Wendt Polirom Publishing House, 2011 Oana Dumitrescu [1] The social theory of international politics by Alexander Wendt, was originally

More information

Essentials of International Relations Eighth Edition Chapter 3: International Relations Theories LECTURE SLIDES

Essentials of International Relations Eighth Edition Chapter 3: International Relations Theories LECTURE SLIDES Essentials of International Relations Eighth Edition Chapter 3: International Relations Theories LECTURE SLIDES Copyright 2018 W. W. Norton & Company Learning Objectives Explain the value of studying international

More information

MA International Relations Module Catalogue (September 2017)

MA International Relations Module Catalogue (September 2017) MA International Relations Module Catalogue (September 2017) This document is meant to give students and potential applicants a better insight into the curriculum of the program. Note that where information

More information

Power in Concert, by Jennifer Mitzen. Chicago and London: University of Chicago Press, pp. Paperback. ISBN-13:

Power in Concert, by Jennifer Mitzen. Chicago and London: University of Chicago Press, pp. Paperback. ISBN-13: Remembrance of Things Past Review by Edward A. Fogarty Department of Political Science, Colgate University Power in Concert, by Jennifer Mitzen. Chicago and London: University of Chicago Press, 2013. 264

More information

Introduction. Part One

Introduction. Part One Part One Introduction in this web service 1 Owning development: creating policy norms in the IMF and the World Bank Susan Park and Antje Vetterlein Introduction How are policies devised by the International

More information

POSITIVIST AND POST-POSITIVIST THEORIES

POSITIVIST AND POST-POSITIVIST THEORIES A theory of international relations is a set of ideas that explains how the international system works. Unlike an ideology, a theory of international relations is (at least in principle) backed up with

More information

Final Syllabus, January 27, (Subject to slight revisions.)

Final Syllabus, January 27, (Subject to slight revisions.) Final Syllabus, January 27, 2008. (Subject to slight revisions.) Politics 558. International Cooperation. Spring 2008. Professors Robert O. Keohane and Helen V. Milner Tuesdays, 1:30-4:20. Prerequisite:

More information

The Politics of Egalitarian Capitalism; Rethinking the Trade-off between Equality and Efficiency

The Politics of Egalitarian Capitalism; Rethinking the Trade-off between Equality and Efficiency The Politics of Egalitarian Capitalism; Rethinking the Trade-off between Equality and Efficiency Week 3 Aidan Regan Democratic politics is about distributive conflict tempered by a common interest in economic

More information

Ideology COLIN J. BECK

Ideology COLIN J. BECK Ideology COLIN J. BECK Ideology is an important aspect of social and political movements. The most basic and commonly held view of ideology is that it is a system of multiple beliefs, ideas, values, principles,

More information

POLI 359 Public Policy Making

POLI 359 Public Policy Making POLI 359 Public Policy Making Session 10-Policy Change Lecturer: Dr. Kuyini Abdulai Mohammed, Dept. of Political Science Contact Information: akmohammed@ug.edu.gh College of Education School of Continuing

More information

CHAPTER 2: Historical Context and the Future of U.S. Global Power

CHAPTER 2: Historical Context and the Future of U.S. Global Power CHAPTER 2: Historical Context and the Future of U.S. Global Power MULTIPLE CHOICE 1. European powers were heavily involved in the American Revolutionary war because a. of the wars implications for the

More information

International Relations. Policy Analysis

International Relations. Policy Analysis 128 International Relations and Foreign Policy Analysis WALTER CARLSNAES Although foreign policy analysis (FPA) has traditionally been one of the major sub-fields within the study of international relations

More information

440 IR Theory Winter 2014

440 IR Theory Winter 2014 440 IR Theory Winter 2014 Ian Hurd ianhurd@northwestern.edu rm 306, Scott Hall Seminar meetings: Friday 9 to 12, Ripton Room Office hours Wednesday 10 to 12. All discussion of international politics rests

More information

International Political Economy in Context Individual Choices, Global Effects

International Political Economy in Context Individual Choices, Global Effects International Political Economy in Context Individual Choices, Global Effects Andrew C. Sobel Los Angeles London New Delhi Singapore Washington DC CQPRESS Detailed Contents Figures, Tables, and Maps. xviii

More information

Power Politics Economics Independence. Unit 10:The World Divides 8 days (block) Unit Title Pacing. Unit Overview

Power Politics Economics Independence. Unit 10:The World Divides 8 days (block) Unit Title Pacing. Unit Overview WS/FCS Unit Planning Organizer Subject(s) Social Studies Conceptual Lenses Grade/Course 9 th Grade Unit of Study Post World War II (7.4, 7.5, 7.6, 8.1, 8.2, 8.3, 8.7) Unit Title Pacing Unit 10:The World

More information

CONSTRUCTIVISM AS THE FRAMEWORK FOR INTERNATIONAL ORDERS

CONSTRUCTIVISM AS THE FRAMEWORK FOR INTERNATIONAL ORDERS AIR COMMAND AND STAFF COLLEGE AIR UNIVERSITY CONSTRUCTIVISM AS THE FRAMEWORK FOR INTERNATIONAL ORDERS by Charles Stretch, Major, USAF A Research Paper Submitted to the Faculty In Partial Fulfillment of

More information

Chapter 1: Theoretical Approaches to Global Politics

Chapter 1: Theoretical Approaches to Global Politics Chapter 1: Theoretical Approaches to Global Politics I. Introduction A. What is theory and why do we need it? B. Many theories, many meanings C. Levels of analysis D. The Great Debates: an introduction

More information

CONTEMPORARY GLOBAL ISSUES. Assoc. Prof. Dr Andrey Baykov. Shortened Syllabus. Spring 2018

CONTEMPORARY GLOBAL ISSUES. Assoc. Prof. Dr Andrey Baykov. Shortened Syllabus. Spring 2018 Purpose of the Course CONTEMPORARY GLOBAL ISSUES Assoc. Prof. Dr Andrey Baykov Shortened Syllabus Spring 2018 This course provides students with an introduction to what is known as the Contemporary Global

More information

Marxism and Constructivism

Marxism and Constructivism Theories of International Political Economy II: Marxism and Constructivism Min Shu Waseda University 2018/5/8 International Political Economy 1 An outline of the lecture The basics of Marxism Marxist IPE

More information

POLITICS AND INTERNATIONAL RELATIONS

POLITICS AND INTERNATIONAL RELATIONS POLITICS AND INTERNATIONAL RELATIONS 2013-2014 Catalog POLITICS MAJOR 11 courses distributed as follows: POLI 100 Issues in Politics MATH 215 Statistical Analysis POLI 400 Research Methods POLI 497 Senior

More information

Political Opposition and Authoritarian Rule: State-Society Relations in the Middle East and North Africa

Political Opposition and Authoritarian Rule: State-Society Relations in the Middle East and North Africa European University Institute Robert Schuman Centre for Advanced Studies Workshop 5 Political Opposition and Authoritarian Rule: State-Society Relations in the Middle East and North Africa directed by

More information

Regional policy in Croatia in search for domestic policy and institutional change

Regional policy in Croatia in search for domestic policy and institutional change Regional policy in Croatia in search for domestic policy and institutional change Aida Liha, Faculty of Political Science, University of Zagreb, Croatia PhD Workshop, IPSA 2013 Conference Europeanization

More information

The uses and abuses of evolutionary theory in political science: a reply to Allan McConnell and Keith Dowding

The uses and abuses of evolutionary theory in political science: a reply to Allan McConnell and Keith Dowding British Journal of Politics and International Relations, Vol. 2, No. 1, April 2000, pp. 89 94 The uses and abuses of evolutionary theory in political science: a reply to Allan McConnell and Keith Dowding

More information

The Western Heritage Since 1300 Kagan, Revised, 11 th Edition AP Edition, 2016

The Western Heritage Since 1300 Kagan, Revised, 11 th Edition AP Edition, 2016 A Correlation of The Western Heritage Since 1300 Kagan, Revised, 11 th Edition AP Edition, 2016 To the AP European History Curriculum Framework AP is a trademark registered and/or owned by the College

More information

Power in World Politics

Power in World Politics University of Göttingen Faculty of Social Sciences Department of Political Science B.Pol.4 Power in World Politics Winter semester 2014/15 Prof. Dr. Tobias Lenz Email tobias.lenz@sowi.uni-goettingen.de

More information

Rise and Decline of Nations. Olson s Implications

Rise and Decline of Nations. Olson s Implications Rise and Decline of Nations Olson s Implications 1.) A society that would achieve efficiency through comprehensive bargaining is out of the question. Q. Why? Some groups (e.g. consumers, tax payers, unemployed,

More information

White Rose Research Online URL for this paper:

White Rose Research Online URL for this paper: This is an author produced version of Mahoney, J and K.Thelen (Eds) (2010) Explaining institutional change: agency, ambiguity and power, Cambridge: CUP [Book review]. White Rose Research Online URL for

More information

SNU/GSIS : Understanding International Cooperation Fall 2017 Tuesday 9:30am-12:20pm Building 140-1, Room 101

SNU/GSIS : Understanding International Cooperation Fall 2017 Tuesday 9:30am-12:20pm Building 140-1, Room 101 SNU/GSIS 875.520: Understanding International Cooperation Fall 2017 Tuesday 9:30am-12:20pm Building 140-1, Room 101 Instructor: Jiyeoun Song Office: Building 140-1, Room 614 Phone: 02-880-4174 Email: jiyeoun.song@snu.ac.kr

More information

ASSET FUNGIBILITY AND ORGANIZATIONAL ADAPTABILITY: THE EU AND NATO S APPROACHES TO MANAGING AND REGULATING CYBER THREATS

ASSET FUNGIBILITY AND ORGANIZATIONAL ADAPTABILITY: THE EU AND NATO S APPROACHES TO MANAGING AND REGULATING CYBER THREATS ASSET FUNGIBILITY AND ORGANIZATIONAL ADAPTABILITY: THE EU AND NATO S Abstract: APPROACHES TO MANAGING AND REGULATING CYBER THREATS In the last decade the NATO and the European Union (EU) have paid close

More information

GOVT 2060 International Relations: Theories and Approaches Fall 2017

GOVT 2060 International Relations: Theories and Approaches Fall 2017 THE UNIVERSITY OF THE WEST INDIES ST. AUGUSTINE FACULTY OF SOCIAL SCIENCES DEPARTMENT OF POLITICAL SCIENCE GOVT 2060 International Relations: Theories and Approaches Fall 2017 Topic 4 Neorealism The end

More information

BA International Studies Leiden University Year Two Semester Two

BA International Studies Leiden University Year Two Semester Two BA International Studies Leiden University Year Two Semester Two NOTE: All these courses were prepared for planning purposes. The new course descriptions will be published next academic year. Overview

More information

Course Schedule Spring 2009

Course Schedule Spring 2009 SPRING 2009 COURSE DESCRIPTIONS Ph.D. Program in Political Science Course Schedule Spring 2009 Decemberr 12, 2008 American Politics :: Comparative Politics International Relations :: Political Theory ::

More information

Yale University Department of Political Science

Yale University Department of Political Science Yale University Department of Political Science THE BALANCE OF POWER: THEORY AND PRACTICE Global Affairs S287 Political Science S126 Summer 2018 Session A Syllabus Version date: March 15, 2018 Professor

More information

THINKING AND WORKING POLITICALLY THROUGH APPLIED POLITICAL ECONOMY ANALYSIS (PEA)

THINKING AND WORKING POLITICALLY THROUGH APPLIED POLITICAL ECONOMY ANALYSIS (PEA) THINKING AND WORKING POLITICALLY THROUGH APPLIED POLITICAL ECONOMY ANALYSIS (PEA) Applied PEA Framework: Guidance on Questions for Analysis at the Country, Sector and Issue/Problem Levels This resource

More information

INTRODUCTION EB434 ENTERPRISE + GOVERNANCE

INTRODUCTION EB434 ENTERPRISE + GOVERNANCE INTRODUCTION EB434 ENTERPRISE + GOVERNANCE why study the company? Corporations play a leading role in most societies Recent corporate failures have had a major social impact and highlighted the importance

More information

1) Is the "Clash of Civilizations" too broad of a conceptualization to be of use? Why or why not?

1) Is the Clash of Civilizations too broad of a conceptualization to be of use? Why or why not? 1) Is the "Clash of Civilizations" too broad of a conceptualization to be of use? Why or why not? Huntington makes good points about the clash of civilizations and ideologies being a cause of conflict

More information

Public Policy 429 FOUNDATIONS OF INTERNATIONAL POLITICAL ECONOMY

Public Policy 429 FOUNDATIONS OF INTERNATIONAL POLITICAL ECONOMY Public Policy 429 FOUNDATIONS OF INTERNATIONAL POLITICAL ECONOMY Harris School of Public Policy Studies The University of Chicago Winter 2006 Tuesdays 3:30-6:20pm (Room 140A) Professor Lloyd Gruber Office:

More information

TAKING STOCK: The Constructivist Research Program in International Relations and Comparative Politics

TAKING STOCK: The Constructivist Research Program in International Relations and Comparative Politics Annu. Rev. Polit. Sci. 2001. 4:391 416 Copyright c 2001 by Annual Reviews. All rights reserved TAKING STOCK: The Constructivist Research Program in International Relations and Comparative Politics Martha

More information

Which statement to you agree with most?

Which statement to you agree with most? Which statement to you agree with most? Globalization is generally positive: it increases efficiency, global growth, and therefore global welfare Globalization is generally negative: it destroys indigenous

More information

Discipline and Diversity

Discipline and Diversity SUB Hamburg Discipline and Diversity THIRD EDITION Edited by Tim Dunne, Milja Kurki, and Steve Smith OXFORD UNIVERSITY PRESS Detailed Contents Preface Acknowledgements Brief Contents About the Contributors

More information

Monetary Theory and Central Banking By Allan H. Meltzer * Carnegie Mellon University and The American Enterprise Institute

Monetary Theory and Central Banking By Allan H. Meltzer * Carnegie Mellon University and The American Enterprise Institute Monetary Theory and Central Banking By Allan H. Meltzer * Carnegie Mellon University and The American Enterprise Institute It is a privilege to present these comments at a symposium that honors Otmar Issing.

More information

The Theory of Hegemonic Stability and Embedded Liberalism. The Case of the Bretton Woods System

The Theory of Hegemonic Stability and Embedded Liberalism. The Case of the Bretton Woods System The Theory of Hegemonic Stability and Embedded Liberalism The Case of the Bretton Woods System Clicker quiz: Why the effort to restore Free Trade after WW II? A. Because corporations wanted to restore

More information

POLITICAL SCIENCE (POLI)

POLITICAL SCIENCE (POLI) POLITICAL SCIENCE (POLI) This is a list of the Political Science (POLI) courses available at KPU. For information about transfer of credit amongst institutions in B.C. and to see how individual courses

More information

POLI 5140 Politics & Religion 3 cr.

POLI 5140 Politics & Religion 3 cr. Ph.D. in Political Science Course Descriptions POLI 5140 Politics & Religion 3 cr. This course will examine how religion and religious institutions affect political outcomes and vice versa. Emphasis will

More information

Essentials of International Relations

Essentials of International Relations Chapter 3 INTERNATIONAL RELATIONS THEORIES Essentials of International Relations SEVENTH EDITION L E CTURE S L IDES Copyright 2016, W.W. Norton & Co., Inc Learning Objectives Explain the value of studying

More information

SEMINAR IN WORLD POLITICS PLSC 650 Spring 2015

SEMINAR IN WORLD POLITICS PLSC 650 Spring 2015 SEMINAR IN WORLD POLITICS PLSC 650 Spring 2015 Instructor: Benjamin O. Fordham E-mail: bfordham@binghamton.edu Office: LNG-58 Office Hours: Tuesdays and Thursdays, 1:00-2:30, and by appointment This course

More information

TOWARD A SYLLABUS FOR FALL 99-8/27/98

TOWARD A SYLLABUS FOR FALL 99-8/27/98 Professor Bruce Moon INTERNATIONAL RELATIONS 125 International Political Economy Lehigh University 208 Maginnes (758-3387) Fall term 1998 Office Hours: Tu/Th 10:45-11:45 BM05@Lehigh.EDU TOWARD A SYLLABUS

More information

POLI 111: INTRODUCTION TO THE STUDY OF POLITICAL SCIENCE

POLI 111: INTRODUCTION TO THE STUDY OF POLITICAL SCIENCE POLI 111: INTRODUCTION TO THE STUDY OF POLITICAL SCIENCE SESSION 4 NATURE AND SCOPE OF POLITICAL SCIENCE Lecturer: Dr. Evans Aggrey-Darkoh, Department of Political Science Contact Information: aggreydarkoh@ug.edu.gh

More information

Unit Three: Thinking Liberally - Diversity and Hegemony in IPE. Dr. Russell Williams

Unit Three: Thinking Liberally - Diversity and Hegemony in IPE. Dr. Russell Williams Unit Three: Thinking Liberally - Diversity and Hegemony in IPE Dr. Russell Williams Required Reading: Cohn, Ch. 4. Class Discussion Reading: Outline: Eric Helleiner, Economic Liberalism and Its Critics:

More information

Analysing the relationship between democracy and development: Basic concepts and key linkages Alina Rocha Menocal

Analysing the relationship between democracy and development: Basic concepts and key linkages Alina Rocha Menocal Analysing the relationship between democracy and development: Basic concepts and key linkages Alina Rocha Menocal Team Building Week Governance and Institutional Development Division (GIDD) Commonwealth

More information

M. Taylor Fravel Statement of Research (September 2011)

M. Taylor Fravel Statement of Research (September 2011) M. Taylor Fravel Statement of Research (September 2011) I study international security with an empirical focus on China. By focusing on China, my work seeks to explain the foreign policy and security behavior

More information

Political Science 217/317 International Organization

Political Science 217/317 International Organization Phillip Y. Lipscy Spring, 2008 email: plipscy@stanford.edu Office Hours: Wed 10am-12pm or by appointment Encina Hall, Central 434 Course Description Political Science 217/317 International Organization

More information

T05P07 / International Administrative Governance: Studying the Policy Impact of International Public Administrations

T05P07 / International Administrative Governance: Studying the Policy Impact of International Public Administrations T05P07 / International Administrative Governance: Studying the Policy Impact of International Public Administrations Topic : T05 / Policy Formulation, Administration and Policymakers Chair : Jörn Ege -

More information

POST COLD WAR U.S. POLICY TOWARD ASIA

POST COLD WAR U.S. POLICY TOWARD ASIA POST COLD WAR U.S. POLICY TOWARD ASIA Eric Her INTRODUCTION There is an ongoing debate among American scholars and politicians on the United States foreign policy and its changing role in East Asia. This

More information

REALISM INTRODUCTION NEED OF THEORY OF INTERNATIONAL RELATIONS

REALISM INTRODUCTION NEED OF THEORY OF INTERNATIONAL RELATIONS REALISM INTRODUCTION NEED OF THEORY OF INTERNATIONAL RELATIONS We need theories of International Relations to:- a. Understand subject-matter of IR. b. Know important, less important and not important matter

More information

Global Governance - EU and India s contribution to a contested concept in theory and practice

Global Governance - EU and India s contribution to a contested concept in theory and practice Global Governance - EU and India s contribution to a contested concept in theory and practice Lara Klossek Global India European Training Network Institut Barcelona de Estudis Internationals Literature

More information

GOVT 102 Introduction to International Politics Spring 2011 Section 01: Tues/Thurs 9:30-10:45am Section 02: Tues/Thurs 11:00am-12:15pm Kirby 107

GOVT 102 Introduction to International Politics Spring 2011 Section 01: Tues/Thurs 9:30-10:45am Section 02: Tues/Thurs 11:00am-12:15pm Kirby 107 GOVT 102 Introduction to International Politics Spring 2011 Section 01: Tues/Thurs 9:30-10:45am Section 02: Tues/Thurs 11:00am-12:15pm Kirby 107 Professor Seo-Hyun Park Office: Kirby 102 Phone: (610) 330-5412

More information

ALEXANDER GAMERDINGER INTERNATIONAL BUSINESS POLITICS FINAL EXAM International Political Economy Final Exam 2016

ALEXANDER GAMERDINGER INTERNATIONAL BUSINESS POLITICS FINAL EXAM International Political Economy Final Exam 2016 International Political Economy Final Exam 2016 IDEAS VS. INTERESTS Alexander Gamerdinger XXXXXX-XXXX 19.12.2016 Bsc. International Business and Politics Copenhagen Business School, Tutorial Class: XX

More information

Content Map For Social Studies

Content Map For Social Studies World Geography SS-WG-1 Describe population distribution, density, and what factors contribute to these. SS-WG-2 SS-WG-3 SS-WG-4 SS-WG-5 SS-WG-6 Describe how major religions impact cultures. Describe government

More information

Guidelines for Comprehensive Exams in International Relations Department of Political Science Pennsylvania State University.

Guidelines for Comprehensive Exams in International Relations Department of Political Science Pennsylvania State University. Guidelines for Comprehensive Exams in International Relations Department of Political Science Pennsylvania State University Spring 2011 The International Relations comprehensive exam consists of two parts.

More information

Period 1: Period 2:

Period 1: Period 2: Period 1: 1491 1607 Period 2: 1607 1754 2014 - #2: Explain how intellectual and religious movements impacted the development of colonial North America from 1607 to 1776. 2013 - #2: Explain how trans-atlantic

More information

Course Requirements: Arcadia University The College of Global Studies 1

Course Requirements: Arcadia University The College of Global Studies 1 Course Title: Political Economy of the EU: Crisis & Change Course Code: GREA ECMO 380 (cross listed as PSMO 380) Subject: Economics, Political Economics, Political Science Credits: 3 Semester/Term: Semester

More information

Status and the Challenge of Rising Powers by Steven Ward

Status and the Challenge of Rising Powers by Steven Ward Book Review: Status and the Challenge of Rising Powers by Steven Ward Rising Powers Quarterly Volume 3, Issue 3, 2018, 239-243 Book Review Status and the Challenge of Rising Powers by Steven Ward Cambridge:

More information

2. Realism is important to study because it continues to guide much thought regarding international relations.

2. Realism is important to study because it continues to guide much thought regarding international relations. Chapter 2: Theories of World Politics TRUE/FALSE 1. A theory is an example, model, or essential pattern that structures thought about an area of inquiry. F DIF: High REF: 30 2. Realism is important to

More information

Theories of International Political Economy II: Marxism and Constructivism

Theories of International Political Economy II: Marxism and Constructivism Theories of International Political Economy II: Marxism and Constructivism Min Shu Waseda University 17 April 2017 International Political Economy 1 An outline of the lecture The basics of Marxism Marxist

More information

Lahore University of Management Sciences. POL 131 Introduction to International Relations Fall

Lahore University of Management Sciences. POL 131 Introduction to International Relations Fall POL 131 Introduction to Fall 2017-18 Instructor Room No. Email Shahab Ahmad Course Basics Credit Hours 4 Course Distribution Core Elective Open for Student Category POL/ Econ&Pol COURSE DESCRIPTION The

More information

The Invention of Decolonization: The Algerian War and the Remaking of France. Todd Shepard.

The Invention of Decolonization: The Algerian War and the Remaking of France. Todd Shepard. 1 The Invention of Decolonization: The Algerian War and the Remaking of France. Todd Shepard. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, 2006. ISBN: 9780801474545 When the French government recognized the independence

More information

Cyber War and Competition in the China-U.S. Relationship 1 James A. Lewis May 2010

Cyber War and Competition in the China-U.S. Relationship 1 James A. Lewis May 2010 Cyber War and Competition in the China-U.S. Relationship 1 James A. Lewis May 2010 The U.S. and China are in the process of redefining their bilateral relationship, as China s new strengths means it has

More information

We the Stakeholders: The Power of Representation beyond Borders? Clara Brandi

We the Stakeholders: The Power of Representation beyond Borders? Clara Brandi REVIEW Clara Brandi We the Stakeholders: The Power of Representation beyond Borders? Terry Macdonald, Global Stakeholder Democracy. Power and Representation Beyond Liberal States, Oxford, Oxford University

More information

The quest for legitimacy in world politics international organizations selflegitimations

The quest for legitimacy in world politics international organizations selflegitimations The quest for legitimacy in world politics international organizations selflegitimations Outline of the topic International organizations (IOs) take increasing interest in their legitimacy. They employ

More information

War in International Society (POL. 2 Module)

War in International Society (POL. 2 Module) War in International Society (POL. 2 Module) Lectures by Dr. Stefano Recchia NOTE: These lectures are given as a required module for Pol 2 International Society, a firstyear undergraduate paper taught

More information

Economic Assistance to Russia: Ineffectual, Politicized, and Corrupt?

Economic Assistance to Russia: Ineffectual, Politicized, and Corrupt? Economic Assistance to Russia: Ineffectual, Politicized, and Corrupt? Yoshiko April 2000 PONARS Policy Memo 136 Harvard University While it is easy to critique reform programs after the fact--and therefore

More information

NATO in Central Asia: In Search of Regional Harmony

NATO in Central Asia: In Search of Regional Harmony NATO in Central Asia: In Search of Regional Harmony The events in Andijon in May 2005 precipitated a significant deterioration of relations between Central Asian republics and the West, while at the same

More information

Transnational social movements JACKIE SMITH

Transnational social movements JACKIE SMITH Transnational social movements JACKIE SMITH Modern social movements, generally thought of as political, emerged in tandem with modern nation states, as groups of people organized to alternately resist

More information

By Benn Steil Senior Fellow and Director of International Economics, Council on Foreign Relations

By Benn Steil Senior Fellow and Director of International Economics, Council on Foreign Relations Teaching Notes The Battle of Bretton Woods: John Maynard Keynes, Harry Dexter White, and the Making of a New World Order By Benn Steil Senior Fellow and Director of International Economics, Council on

More information

GOVT 102 Introduction to International Politics Spring 2010 MW 11:00am-12:15pm Kirby 204

GOVT 102 Introduction to International Politics Spring 2010 MW 11:00am-12:15pm Kirby 204 GOVT 102 Introduction to International Politics Spring 2010 MW 11:00am-12:15pm Kirby 204 Professor Seo-Hyun Park Office: Kirby 102 Phone: (610) 330-5412 Email: parksh@lafayette.edu Office hours: MW 1:00-3:00pm

More information

Lahore University of Management Sciences. POL 131 Introduction to International Relations Fall

Lahore University of Management Sciences. POL 131 Introduction to International Relations Fall POL 131 Introduction to International Relations Fall 2015 16 Instructor SHAZA FATIMA KHAWAJA Room No. 210 Email Shaza.fatima@lums.edu.pk Course Basics Credit Hours 4 Course Distribution Core Elective Open

More information

International Political Economy

International Political Economy Quiz #3 Which theory predicts a state will export goods that make intensive use of the resources they have in abundance?: a.) Stolper-Samuelson, b.) Ricardo-Viner, c.) Heckscher-Olin, d.) Watson-Crick.

More information