Does the Rule of Law Matter? The WTO and US Antidumping Investigations

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Does the Rule of Law Matter? The WTO and US Antidumping Investigations"

Transcription

1 Does the Rule of Law Matter? The WTO and US Antidumping Investigations Marc L. Busch School of Foreign Service Georgetown University 37th and O Streets, NW Washington, DC mlb66@georgetown.edu Rafal Raciborski Department of Political Science Emory University Atlanta, GA rafal.raciborski@emory.edu Eric Reinhardt Department of Political Science Emory University Atlanta, GA erein@emory.edu Version: May 22, 2008

2 Abstract Are states constrained by international law? Recent studies suggest that the legal regime of the World Trade Organization (WTO), in particular, has no independent effect on members trade policies. We argue, in contrast, that the WTO s rule of law is likely to deter protectionist practices against other members, including those lacking the ability to retaliate. The WTO accomplishes this by clarifying policy standards and providing for enforcement through judicial review. We test these competing hypotheses using a dataset of 921 United States (US) antidumping (AD) investigations and 2,539 potential cases which were never initiated, from 1978 through We find that the US is less likely to investigate and impose AD duties against countries that are members of the WTO. The WTO legal regime deters protectionist practices against fellow members, especially against those unable to credibly threaten retaliation.

3 I. Introduction Are states constrained by international law? The power-oriented perspective says that, absent a central authority to enforce it, international law is largely a guise for strong states to have their way. Looking at the global trade regime, in particular, recent studies lend some weight to this view, suggesting that the World Trade Organization (WTO) is of little consequence (Rose 2003, 2004), or that its effectiveness depends on member countries having sufficient market power to retaliate for transgressions (Gowa and Kim 2005; Bagwell and Staiger 2002; Mavroidis 2000). We dissent from this view, arguing that the WTO raises the costs of protectionism by defining standards for acceptable practices and providing for enforcement through judicial review. Elaborating this rules-oriented perspective, we hypothesize that the WTO should deter protectionism against other members, including those that lack the market power to retaliate. This argument is not novel. Yet, despite the longstanding debate over the merits of the power- and rules-oriented views of international law, the field has not offered evidence that can adequately discriminate between these perspectives. The challenge is that, as Finlayson and Zacher (1981, 599) claim, [i]t is impossible to know how many protectionist actions have not been undertaken because of the existence of GATT obligations. This is because such actions do not typically surface in the empirical record. Consequently, studies of international trade agreements have only examined the association between membership and observed levels of trade or protection. But these studies may be biased by the fact that countries join the legal regime because they are ready to cooperate, rather than the other way around. So far, it has proven difficult to falsify this skeptical interpretation of such correlational evidence. For this reason, Simmons (1998, 89) cautions that, while it can be shown that much international 1

4 behavior is consistent with international law (italics added), it has been far more difficult, however, to show any causal link between legal commitments and behavior. Our paper aims to overcome this challenge by using direct evidence on non-cases. We utilize a research design not previously brought to bear on this question, focusing on the political economy of United States (US) antidumping (AD) policy. Specifically, we look at a broad pool of comparable opportunities for the US to impose new protectionism against other countries, including cases in which the government, as well as firms beforehand, decided not to request or impose AD duties. We thus avoid overstating the effects of international law and sidestep concerns about selection bias by scrutinizing identifiable instances of protection that did not happen, as well as those that did. We construct a dataset of 921 US antidumping (AD) investigations, supplemented by 2,539 potential cases that were not initiated, from 1978 through We then use this set of cases and controls to test our hypothesis against the expectations of the power-oriented perspective. Our analysis takes account of a variety of other determinants of the demand for, and supply of, antidumping protection, including we hasten to emphasize the actual import price and volume for the product in question. We find that the US is less likely to investigate and impose new AD duties against members of the WTO, even those lacking market power with which to retaliate. In particular, the probabilities of being named in a US antidumping petition, and having duties imposed, are about 25 percent lower for an average member of the WTO (or its predecessor, the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade, or GATT) than for a non-member. Moreover, if anything, the deterrent impact of the WTO is greater, not weaker, for members of the trade regime that cannot retaliate. The implication, of course, is that international law has a concrete, independent effect on states trade policies. Those countries that are unable to hit back 2

5 with trade sanctions can still effectively use the law to guard against adverse behavior by the strongest state in the trading system. This paper provides some of the first direct evidence of this point, lending clear support to the rules-oriented perspective. Our methodology further allows us to do what many scholars have presumed impossible: that is, estimate how many protectionist actions were prevented by the global trade regime. Specifically, between 1978 and 2001, the GATT/WTO deterred 143 [118, 167] 1 impositions of antidumping duties by the US. To put this in perspective, the actual number of observed duties imposed by the US during this period was 413, with the average AD action directly affecting $175 million of annual imports (in 1995 prices). In short, the GATT/WTO has substantially curtailed US AD actions, including against those members least capable of fighting back on their own. The paper proceeds as follows. Section II sets out the rules-oriented perspective on international law, and grounds our empirical project in the literature. Section III elaborates our hypothesis, as applied to the domain of US antidumping decisions. Sections IV and V describe our empirical research design and results, respectively. Section VI concludes by highlighting some implications of our findings for debates about the impact of international law. II. The Literature The rules-oriented perspective on international law enjoys a long theoretical tradition, centered on the idea that codified rules constrain state behavior. Scholars in this tradition have emphasized a number of complementary causal mechanisms. Chief among these is the idea that the existence of mutually accepted rules clarifies each parties obligations, limiting the prospects for spirals of retaliation and counter-retaliation by reducing uncertainty (Finlayson and Zacher 1 Figures in square brackets here and elsewhere in this paper denote 95 percent confidence interval bounds. 3

6 1981; Keohane 1984). Robust dispute settlement provisions, and judicial review in particular, can make noncompliance costly as well (Keohane, Moravcsik, and Slaughter 2000). What ties these claims together is their implication that adherence to the law is not merely a function of coincidence of interests or of market power relationships among states. Our argument takes its cues from this theoretical tradition. However, this paper s main contribution is empirical rather than theoretical. The motivation is simple: the view that law matters has long been taken as an article of faith, and we wish to subject it to empirical scrutiny. 2 To date, the literature has turned up decidedly inconclusive results. For example, Simmons (2000) looks at why governments commit to, and comply with, monetary rules set out by the International Monetary Fund. She finds that states generally do comply, and concludes that legalization strengthens commitment. In a similar vein, Davis (2004) examines whether trade negotiations under the GATT/WTO enable governments to credibly link issues and roll back agricultural protection. At least in the case of Japanese and European negotiations with the US, the answer is yes. Using comparable methods, however, others find largely negative results. For instance, Hathaway (2002) observes that countries that ratify human rights treaties are no more likely to uphold those rights than countries that do not ratify. Likewise, Rose (2003, 2004) reveals that members of the GATT/WTO regime do not trade more with each other or liberalize their trade policies more than non-members. Putting aside their differing conclusions, studies of this sort are open to criticisms of selection bias, which, as Simmons (1998, 89-90) explains, is the single biggest hurdle for studies of international institutions. The concern, as explained by Downs, Rocke and Barsoom (1996, 2 E.g., to quote an assumption made by Sykes (1991, ), GATT signatories regard their commitments as binding and are unwilling simply to abrogate them. 4

7 380), is that compliant behavior might be traceable to a harmony of interests, rather than to the independent constraints imposed by international law. This presents an almost insurmountable problem for empirical research because individual opportunities for compliance or noncompliance are hard to observe. 3 Hence few studies are able to define an appropriate and comparable population of potential cases of noncompliance, from which all actual cases of defection are selected. Our methodology allows us to do precisely this. US Antidumping Procedures The process by which AD duties are awarded is important in framing the paper s empirical research design. Antidumping cases are initiated by a domestic producer who alleges that a foreign firm is selling at less-than-normal-value (usually, below its home-market price) in the US. The goal is to obtain a duty that offsets the margin of dumping, or the difference between a normal price and the one being charged. For our purposes, the key is how petitions of this sort are vetted by the two agencies charged with overseeing US AD decisions. First, a domestic producer(s) decides whether to file a petition with the International Trade Administration in the Department of Commerce (DOC). Second, if there is a filing, the US International Trade Commission (USITC) can either reject the petition (given insufficient evidence, for example), in which case it issues a negative preliminary ruling, or send the case on to the DOC after rendering a positive preliminary ruling. Third, the DOC then investigates, issues a preliminary ruling of its own as to whether dumping is occurring, which, if positive, will trigger provisional antidumping duties. Finally, the USITC must decide whether the dumping (as decided by the DOC) is causing material injury to the domestic producer(s). If so, it issues 3 For a study that attempts to correct for this problem explicitly in its estimation strategy, see Ringquist and Kostadinova s (2005) examination of the impact of the 1985 Helsinki Protocol on pollution emissions. 5

8 a positive final decision, and the DOC imposes a final antidumping duty order based on the assessed dumping margin (see USITC 2005, II-23). The order technically applies to imports from only the particular foreign firms found to be dumping in the investigation. In practice, however, these firms account for the vast bulk of imports of the affected product(s) from the targeted supplier country, so we speak interchangeably of country and firm targets. Given the ease of obtaining AD protection in the US (as elsewhere), the puzzle is why so few investigations occur. Indeed, of the many foreign countries supplying a significant share of the imports of a typical product, why are only a small number ever named in petitions? Scholars agree that the answer does not lie in the economic merits of the case. Such merits are scarce in general, and US legal standards are so permissive that high duties can be imposed even on foreign firms making a profit in fact, even on those selling abroad for higher prices than at home (Blonigen and Prusa 2003). In practice, as several former Commerce Department employees attest, the US authorities engage in margin shopping, or looking at different ways to calculate an importer s costs or prices and choosing the one that helps fatten the prospective [dumping] margin to a desirably high level (Washington Post, July 13, 2003, F1). Observers thus agree that the antidumping decisions are not mechanical products of legalistic reasoning or the economic facts alone. Rather, the authorities have latitude to exercise discretion; consequently, their decisions are affected by political context. For those trained to think in strictly economic or legal terms, this assumption can be hard to accept. However, we strongly emphasize that this assumption is the same used, and empirically validated, in a long list of excellent studies of the political economy of unfair trade actions (Finger, Hall, and Nelson 1982; Rehbein and Lenway 1994; Rosendorff 1996; Gilligan 1997; Unah 1997; Rosendorff and 6

9 Milner 2001; Drope and Hansen 2004). 4 This literature highlights how various political pressures from Congress, the Presidency, well-funded industry associations, and unions influence determinations by the US AD authorities. The point is that, even though the facts and legal standards applied in two cases may be identical, an affirmative outcome is more likely for the petition backed by stronger political pressures. For political scientists, at least, such a proposition is hardly surprising. After all, if the decisions of independent, life-tenured US federal judges are heavily influenced by political ideology and context (e.g., Segal and Spaeth 2002; Epstein and Knight 1998), why would those of the USITC be any different? One aspect of political context that might influence US antidumping decisions is the threat of foreign retaliation. For this threat to be credible, though, US industry must export a sizable amount to the target country. If not, such threats are likely to be superfluous. This is in keeping with the broader claim made by Gowa and Kim (2005) that the GATT institution has only been successful in promoting trade among its most powerful members. 5 Countries lacking market power are unable to shape the trade regime s structure of reciprocal trade liberalization to their own advantage (Bagwell and Staiger 2006). The problem with the empirical literature on antidumping, however, is that it fails to examine the independent deterrent impact of membership in the WTO, which goes to the heart of the debate between the power- and rules-oriented perspectives. Indeed, these studies ignore the 4 To be sure, there have been a few studies downplaying the influence of politics on ITC decisions (e.g., DeVault 2002). However in contrast to our paper such studies look at only the antidumping decision, not the industry s initial decision over whether to file a petition; as our later findings testify, that omission leads to significant selection bias. Further, those studies focus only on domestic political pressures, especially those arising from industry lobbying or Congress; they do not examine the impact of the threat of foreign retaliation or WTO litigation, as we do. Regardless, even a skeptic like DeVault (2002, 18-19) concedes that the evidence shows that Congress attempts to influence the atmosphere in which ITC decisions are made (through commissioner appointments and legislation) and that the preferences of certain congressional oversight committee members affect ITC decisions, concluding that political factors influence ITC decisions, even if statutory considerations also matter greatly. 5 See also Blonigen and Bown (2003). 7

10 fundamental point, emphasized by a number of scholars (Rosendorff 2005; Kucik and Reinhardt forthcoming; Sykes 1991), that the trade regime limits unilateral retaliation even while it facilitates multilaterally-authorized sanctions. That is, targeted countries that are not GATT/WTO members may actually have a freer hand in retaliating, given that the trade regime requires members to exhaust dispute settlement before suspending concessions (i.e., retaliating). Our point is that, if the rule of law matters, it should matter for the GATT/WTO membership as a whole, not just those members with sufficient market power to credibly threaten retaliation. III. The Argument Adopting the rules-oriented perspective, we argue that the WTO regime makes it more costly for members to impose antidumping protection against imports from other members, as compared to non-members. It does so by defining standards for acceptable practices and providing for enforcement of those standards through judicial review. The WTO regulates the use of antidumping protection in the Anti-Dumping Agreement (ADA). 6 The ADA requires that a country conduct a formal investigation demonstrating that (a) the target firm(s) sold the product at less than normal value, customarily treated as the home market price; and (b) the imports caused material injury to a domestic industry. The Agreement also stipulates how an investigation may derive reference prices (Art. 2), calculate the level of injury (Art. 3), prove causation (Arts ), and certify a petitioner with standing 6 The full name of this text is the Agreement on Implementation of Article VI of the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade Prior to 1995, the GATT regime also restricted antidumping explicitly, in the 1979 Tokyo Round Antidumping Code, whose parties included the major users of antidumping (including, of course, the United States). The 1979 agreement regulated the use of antidumping along much the same lines as the ADA, albeit with a lesser level of detail on certain points (Trebilcock and Howse 1999, 168-9). The general legal constraints on protection, at the core of the original GATT regime, also significantly constrained the use of antidumping by the US and other users from the start. Indeed, nearly one out of ten formal GATT disputes (i.e., at least 33 cases) from 1948 through 1994 concerned antidumping measures (e.g., see Hudec 1993). Hence we do not anticipate that the GATT differs much from the WTO in its success in deterring antidumping actions by one member against another. 8

11 as a domestic industry (Art. 4), for example. It also contains pages of procedural requirements regulating how investigations should be conducted and how duty orders must be imposed and reviewed over time. Finally, the Agreement requires that members notify the WTO at each step in the process for every AD investigation and order. Given the clarity of the WTO s well-defined standards regarding antidumping, memberstates have strong incentives to comply. Not doing so risks disturbing investor confidence, which thrives on the stable expectations fostered by the WTO s strong rule of law (Abbott 2000; Simmons 2000). The WTO s clear rules regarding antidumping, in particular, give leaders a device to tie their hands and resist petitions for import relief when the institution s standards are not met (see Goldstein 1996). For instance, after the WTO ruled against the US practice of awarding AD duty revenues to the petitioning firms (the Byrd amendment), despite predictions from many critics and pundits that Congress would never repeal the Byrd amendment, it did so in a close vote in late Besides detailing the standards for acceptable use of antidumping, the multilateral trade regime also provides a well-established mechanism for enforcement of those standards through procedures for judicial review. One member-state, the complainant, can file a formal dispute against another member-state, the defendant, alleging violation or merely nullification or impairment of the complainant s rights under the treaty. If the complainant is not satisfied after WTO-sponsored bilateral consultations, it may request a judgment by an ad hoc WTO judicial body, or panel, whose ruling may then be appealed to the Appellate Body (AB). These rulings have binding legal force and may instruct the defendant to bring its AD actions into compliance 7 Vice President Dick Cheney cast the tie-breaking vote in the Senate. Washington Post, 22 December 2005, D1. Pekkanen (2001) similarly argues that the Japanese government bureaucracy was able to sustain certain liberalization proposals in the face of legislative and interest group pressure precisely because of the clarity and bindingness of the relevant WTO standards. 9

12 with WTO rules. In the event of noncompliance, the WTO may legally authorize the complainant to raise its own tariffs against the defendant up to a stipulated (and often arbitrated) level, although such action is explicitly proscribed in the absence of multilateral authorization. From 1995 through July 2007, 61 formal disputes were filed over antidumping actions by one member against another. 8 In 29 of these cases, WTO judicial bodies ( panels ) issued legal rulings, 15 of which were appealed. The result is a total of 12,751 pages of WTO jurisprudence on antidumping matters. This adds up to a staggering amount of international law regulating every conceivable aspect of this particular protectionist instrument. The WTO makes it costly for its members to decide in favor of any particular antidumping petition in other ways as well. Specifically, many WTO complaints against antidumping have targeted key aspects of the defendant s domestic antidumping statutes and procedures, rather than any specific instance of their use (e.g., the previously mentioned Byrd Amendment dispute, as well as in cases over Antidump 1916, zeroing, and oil country tubular goods sunset review). Members thus have an additional incentive to comply with the rules on antidumping to forestall challenges that would bring into question their overall antidumping mechanisms, which provide flexibility that is vital in maintaining domestic support for liberalization more broadly (Kucik and Reinhardt forthcoming; Finger and Nogues 2005). Legal scholars agree that this case law, built up in successive WTO rulings over antidumping matters, carries great force (Palmeter and Mavroidis 2004, 56). While it is true that, formally speaking, there is no binding precedent in international law, the fact is that the acquis of WTO case law works much the same way, leading observers to talk about a de facto stare decisis (Bhala 1999; Steinberg 2004). AD rulings, in particular, are often densely packed with citations 8 Measures by the US were the target of 46 of these complaints. Data in this paragraph was obtained from the WTO website and online document search facility. 10

13 to prior GATT/WTO rulings and have a substantial impact on subsequent practice. According to one legal expert, for example, rulings against the US practice of zeroing (i.e., not counting higher-priced goods in assessments of the less than normal value pricing margin), which has enjoyed strong bipartisan support, have virtually eliminated this procedure, and forced Washington to make further adjustments to its broader AD regulations (McGivern 2007). Indeed, in a recent dispute brought by Mexico that also implicated zeroing, the US did not even offer a defense of this practice. Our point is that it is appropriate to talk about a cumulative body of GATT/WTO jurisprudence on antidumping, and to see this case law as having a real influence on future WTO legal rulings, and member-state behavior, and not merely because an aggrieved complainant (like Europe in US Antidump 1916) can ask for WTO authorization to retaliate. A realist perspective would discount even such a commonly-used and legally reliable enforcement device, presuming that only countries able to credibly impose trade sanctions in the end would find it effective (Gowa and Kim 2005; Bagwell and Staiger 2006). We argue, in contrast, that members are reluctant to routinely break the rules, not chiefly due to pressure from a powerful complainant, but rather because they do not want to erode the standards constraining AD actions by the many other member-states in the system, or set a bad precedent or (Busch 2007). Noncompliance in cases that would not pass muster before the WTO also raises the problem of dirty hands i.e., one country is afoul of the same legal provision that it accuses another of violating which complicates the state s ability to get others to settle trade disputes on favorable terms. Yet another deterrent to an unmerited AD award is the prospect of having to mount a legal defense in the WTO judicial process, which involves nontrivial costs and staff time, especially because litigation commonly draws the participation of other interested parties 11

14 (i.e., third party governments) in the dispute (Busch and Reinhardt 2006), and often entails successive rounds of appeal, compliance assessments, and arbitration. By anticipation, then, the fact that the home country of a firm targeted in an AD petition may have recourse to WTO dispute settlement changes the incentives for the US authorities, making an affirmative decision more costly. This tends to deter positive AD determinations as a result, all else equal. Note that we are not arguing that there is a two-track legal process for US antidumping decisions one for WTO members and another for non-members. Rather, our point is that external political considerations, in this case arising from the WTO regime, weigh on the minds of the DOC and USITC authorities. That political factors play a role in such decisions is not controversial; an extensive literature speaks to these influences, and the premise of margin shopping testifies to its importance. We have simply added a new variable to the list of such factors WTO membership and given it voice to speak for itself, as distinct from having the market power to retaliate. We submit that proof of the influence of WTO law on member-states behavior can be found in financial markets. For instance, stock prices for Korea s Hynix Semiconductor rose 7.5 percent in the wake of a WTO Appellate Body ruling condemning Japan s duty on computer chip imports. 9 Shares in Chiquita, which imports bananas into Europe, jumped over 9 percent after the WTO ruled in favor of a complaint by Ecuador against the European Union s banana tariffs. 10 Desai and Hines (2008) and Jensen (2007) demonstrate similar stock price effects of WTO dispute settlement in other disputes as well. Examples like these show that investors are willing to stake large amounts of money on the belief that member states tend to comply with 9 From the CNBC website: as posted on November 28, From Reuters: as posted on December 4,

15 WTO rulings, even in disputes in which complainants appear to have lesser market power than defendants. 11 So far we have discussed the role of the post-1994 WTO institution. The predecessor institution, GATT, offered largely the same standards regarding antidumping and dispute settlement procedures (the chief exception being that defendants possessed a hypothetical veto over the formation of a panel, and the validation of any panel ruling under GATT). Judicial review was thus not mandatory in the GATT period, technically speaking, although reforms in 1989 corrected that limitation of the regime. Still, in practice, as the empirical literature on GATT disputes widely recognizes (Hudec 1993; Hudec 1999; Busch and Reinhardt 2003), the defendant s unilateral veto over panel formation was used in only a handful of occasions, in part because it came at great cost to the defendant s GATT litigation as a complainant, due the dirty hands phenomenon noted earlier. In fact, a greater proportion of complaints over antidumping went to panels in the GATT era than in the WTO era. Patterns of settlement of disputes across the two periods are largely similar, thus leading empirical studies to conclude that the two dispute settlement systems operated with roughly equivalent degrees of efficacy (Busch and Reinhardt 2003b). While we expect the two regimes to function similarly in terms of deterrence of AD activity, we nonetheless test for any differences across these institutions in our empirical analyses. We thus expect that GATT/WTO membership will deter US AD investigations and duties, even on the part of those countries lacking the market power to retaliate. This, we contend, is a far more direct test of the efficacy of law than what the literature has offered to 11 For an examination of the impact of dispute settlement provisions on international trade flows more generally, see Kono (2007). 13

16 date, both because we are able to get around the selection bias critique, and because we give full voice to both the power- and rules-oriented perspectives. The implication of the rules-oriented perspective is clear enough with respect to the decision by the US authorities, who can expect WTO members to potentially invoke dispute settlement procedures against an AD order. The petitioning industry s decision about which countries to name, however, is not directly tied to consequences flowing from WTO dispute proceedings. Nevertheless, as the economics literature on antidumping agrees (e.g., Blonigen and Prusa 2003), there are nontrivial costs to filing a petition which can in some cases outweigh the benefits of doing so. Hence, by simple backward induction, the industry should build the government s anticipated response to the target s WTO membership into its petitioning decision. If the legal regime deters an affirmative finding, it should thus, beforehand, deter the naming of a member country in the petition. To test for the independent impact of law, we focus on formal membership in the GATT/WTO. Formal, rather than informal, membership is the best indicator, because informal members do not have access to dispute settlement. Our hypothesis, tailored to our empirical focus on US AD policies, is thus as follows: Hypothesis: If a country is a GATT/WTO member, it is less likely to be targeted in US AD investigations and duty orders, controlling for its market power. IV. Research design We model both the demand for as well as the supply of antidumping protection. Specifically, we examine how GATT/WTO membership affects two dependent variables: (a) whether a given supplier country is named by private industry in a US AD petition; and (b) 14

17 whether the US authorities issue an affirmative decision on that petition, ending in the imposition of AD duties. The Dataset We start with a list of all US AD investigations begun from 1978 through This initial list has 921 observations, one per country named in each petition. 13 We group related investigations into families prompted by the same petition; they share the same date and products. For example, a pair of November 26, 2001 investigations against China and South Africa over ferrovanadium imports fits into one family, constituting two observations. The average petition has 2.3 country targets and, thus, investigations. For each petition, we then construct a list of control observations, one for every non-named country supplying three percent or more of US imports of any one of the products named in that petition in the year it was filed. 14 Because Canada, Belgium, Austria, and the Czech Republic all supplied sufficient amounts of ferrovanadium to the US in the case above, for example, they enter our dataset as this petition s controls. The file has 2,539 controls, or about 2.8 per case. The result is a complete dataset totaling 3,460 cases and controls. 12 We thank Bruce Blonigen for providing the core list of investigations used in Blonigen and Bown (2003). We would also like to thank Tom Prusa, who provided the product codes addressed in all of the pre-1994 cases. We ourselves updated case outcomes and the products petitioned in a number of the more recent cases in the list, following Blonigen and Bown s (2003) sources. Identification of products relies upon 5- or 7-digit TSUSA codes for the period; 8-digit Harmonized System codes for the period; and 4-, 5-, 6-, 8-, and 10- digit codes in the period, as they are named in the petition. This paper s data on product- and countrylevel import and export volumes by year is from Feenstra, Romalis, and Schott (2002) for and the USITC ( for From a complete set of 1,043 investigations we omit 122 due to missing data on one or more of the covariates used in our analysis. 14 In the preliminary determination phase of a US AD investigation, the Department of Commerce terminates cases in which the targeted country supplies less than 3 percent of total US imports of that product, though there are exceptions (USITC 2005, II-39). Such potential cases are thus unlikely to be filed in the first place, so we apply this sampling cutoff following Blonigen and Bown (2003, 260-1, 265). There would be about 8400 more controls if we did not apply the three percent cutoff. 15

18 Remarkably, 43 percent of the controls actually exported more of the product in question to the US than at least one of the countries named in the associated petition; 23 percent exported more than the largest supplier named. Similarly, in 42 percent of the control observations, the supplier s product-specific imports were priced lower than the comparable imports of at least one of the countries named in the petition; 27 percent were priced lower than the imports of that product from all of the named suppliers. Indeed, fully 16 percent of these controls supplied more of the product in question, at a lower price, than all suppliers actually targeted in the investigation. Why were these controls not also named, given that they constituted at least as severe a competitive threat to US producers? The point is that the controls in the sample constitute a legitimate reference point for comparison in terms of indicators relevant to the dominant statutory and political criteria (i.e., import price and volumes, respectively) that shape US antidumping decisions in practice. Dependent Variables Our first dependent variable, Petition, is 1 if the country was named in that petition, 0 otherwise, thereby classifying observations as cases or controls. Our second dependent variable, Affirmative, is 1 if the US authorities ultimately imposed AD duties on the target country. Affirmative is zero for all other types of case outcomes, including negative determinations as well as withdrawn or terminated investigations. Needless to say, we do not observe the investigation s outcome if no petition was ever filed. Affirmative is one in 45 percent of the 921 decisions. Two features of the dependent variables are worth highlighting. First, the economics literature on antidumping emphasizes the fact that the investigation itself, particularly when it 16

19 results in a positive preliminary determination, imposes costs on the foreign supplier (Staiger and Wolak 1994), even if the final determination is negative. Thus, if we only looked at final decisions, we would miss much of the action. Moreover, the legal teams conducting domestic AD litigation are certainly sophisticated enough to induce the likely impact of GATT/WTO law on the final decisions of US authorities. They should accordingly factor this into the decision over whether to bring the case in the first place. If so, only looking at final AD actions would fail to reveal any anticipatory effect that the GATT/WTO might have on the petition choice itself. Doing so might also cause selection bias for inferences about the role of GATT/WTO in decisions themselves. The dependent variable at this stage is thus at least as important as the final decision. Second, our coding of Affirmative does not distinguish among the various alternative ways an investigation might end. 15 For our purposes, the key issue is how different outcomes affect the foreign supplier s welfare. As Prusa (1992) demonstrates, AD investigations that are withdrawn or terminated early are certainly trade-restricting, but they tend to reflect collusive settlements among the petitioning and targeted firms. Such settlements may be profitable to the targets, just as foreign firms prefer voluntary quota restrictions over tariffs. Hence, given that an investigation is underway and has proceeded past a positive preliminary determination (a key point, as noted above), from the targeted country s perspective, the most negative outcomes occur only when duties are imposed, i.e., when Affirmative equals one. Independent Variables Regime Membership. Our chief explanatory variable is dichotomous: GATT/WTO, coded 1 if the potential target country was a formal member of the trade regime in the year of the 17

20 petition, and 0 otherwise. Of the 88 countries in our dataset, 23 were non-members at some point in the file. Non-members include China, Taiwan, Thailand, Mexico, Russia, Vietnam, Venezuela, Saudi Arabia, El Salvador, Panama, Guatemala, Ecuador, among others. 433 observations (12.5 percent) are of non-members 16, though a disproportionate 19.2 percent of the filed cases were against non-wto targets. We expect GATT/WTO to have a negative coefficient in both dependent variables equations. Market Power. The target country s credible capacity to retaliate using trade sanctions is derived from its position as a large and price-sensitive importer of products from the United States. Such consumption increases the target s price-setting market power, such that its actions can lower the world price of overall US exports. We measure this capacity in the variable US Export Dependence, which is the volume of total US exports to the target country, in the petition year, as a percent of US gross domestic product. 17 The median observation s country imported about 0.15 percent of US GDP annually. US bilateral exports exceeded 0.5 percent of US GDP at some point for only 3 of the 88 countries in our dataset (Canada, Japan and Mexico). US Export Dependence should have a negative association with the filing of AD petitions and affirmative AD decisions. Import Price and Volume. The main statutory criterion affecting antidumping decisions by the US authorities is the price of the imported products under investigation. As we shall see in the regression results below, this indeed proves to be a powerful predictor of antidumping 16 We emphasize that the non-member observations do not disproportionately involve China, which is actually second behind Taiwan in volume of exports of affected products and in its frequency in our dataset. To confirm that our findings are not being driven by any unique aspects of China as an AD target, we conduct a number of additional tests reported in the results section below. 17 It should be obvious that, should the target choose to retaliate, it has the practical freedom to do so on any product, not simply the products the US is considering imposing a duty on. The relevant numerator here, from the state s perspective, is thus total US exports to the target country. Further, note that we could alternatively normalize this measure by US exports to the world, rather than US GDP. The two versions are virtually identical, however, with a 0.89 correlation. Not surprisingly, our findings are the same regardless of which formulation of US Export Dependence is used. 18

21 petitions and affirmative decisions. If GATT/WTO members happen to supply higher-priced exports, then they would not be as liable to antidumping actions due to spurious considerations, rather than to the impact of the trade law regime. Hence we construct a variable, Product Relative Price, which indexes the per-unit product-specific price of imports from a given supplier, relative to a reference price (the per-unit average price of imports into the US from all suppliers of the product in question in that same year). 18 In particular, Product Relative Price is the natural log of the supplier s price as a percent of this reference price. Its sample median unsurprisingly corresponds to 102 percent. Product Relative Price exhibits only a small correlation (0.13) with GATT/WTO, but even this modest association disappears once we take per capita income into account, since rich countries exports are more expensive, and rich countries are more likely to be in the WTO. 19 We include Product Relative Price in both equations in the analysis. However, to head off any later misinterpretations of our findings about GATT/WTO, we also wish to emphasize this critical point: GATT/WTO members exports of the products named in US antidumping petitions are not more expensive than comparable exports from countries not in GATT/WTO. So far as assessments of dumping are based on the market price of the product in question which they must be, as noted earlier, since the calculations of fair value have wide latitude to achieve politically desired results then GATT/WTO members by this measure dump no less frequently than non-members. Relatedly, as prior studies demonstrate, AD duties are more likely when the volume of imports in question is larger. Therefore, we include the variable Log Product Imports, or US imports of the affected product(s) in the year of the petition, expressed in logged constant We calculated this using raw data, at the appropriate disaggregated product level, from Feenstra, Romalis, and Schott (2002). 19 An ordinary regression of Product Relative Price on GATT/WTO and Log Per Capita Income, for our 3460 observations, yields a coefficient on GATT/WTO of 0.074, with a two-tailed p-value greater than

22 US dollars. For the purposes of explaining which countries get named in the petition, this variable counts all products ultimately addressed in any of the investigations resulting from that petition. For our analysis of the outcomes of cases once filed, Log Product Imports counts only those particular products named in the investigation against the specific target country. There is little difference, in practice, however. The average investigation concerned $175 million (1995 prices) of annual imports, though that figure varies widely depending on the product at issue. Other Controls. Several other attributes of a potential case are also important. Our analysis takes account of the overall amount of US imports from the potential target country in the year of the petition, as a percentage of US GDP, in the variable US Import Penetration. This has little bearing on the legal features of US antidumping proceedings. However, high levels of imports may make any US protectionist pressures against the source country more politically salient in that year, regardless of the value of imports of the product in question (e.g., Irwin 2005, 9-10). Total imports from the potentially targeted country are just over one-fifth of a percent of US GDP in the median observation. The DOC designates certain countries as Non-Market Economies (NMEs) for the purposes of its assessment of less-than-normal-value pricing. In such cases, it bases its normal value figure on the cost of the relevant factor inputs in market economies of comparable levels of development, which also produce the goods in question. This use of substitute data tends to make the case easier to prove. 20 We accordingly add a dichotomous control variable, Non- Market Economy, to flag such country targets countries are NMEs at some point in our dataset, constituting 4 percent of the control observations and 15 percent of the investigations. It is important to note that the terms of China s WTO accession agreement allow the US to 20 As one observer put it, in such cases, with respect to the DOC s estimate of the dumping margin, Basically, you can come up with any dang number you want to (Washington Post, 13 July 2003, F1). 21 We thank Tim Truman of the US International Trade Administration for these data. 20

23 continue treating it as an NME, for AD purposes, for 15 years afterwards. That means China counts as an NME in all cases and controls in our dataset. If there is any change over time in petitioning and affirmative rates in US AD cases against China, it is not because of a change in its NME status. Another idiosyncratic, yet widely appreciated, feature of US antidumping politics is that the steel industry files a disproportionately large number of cases. We use Standard Industrial Classification (revision 3, 1987) code 3312 to mark the steel observations (constituting our dichotomous variable Steel), which make up 31 percent of our dataset as a whole, and 36 percent of the investigations themselves. We also control for the logged per capita real GDP of the potential target country, in Log Per Capita Income. This variable speaks to the competitive threat posed to import-competing US firms from labor- (rather than capital-) abundant countries (i.e., those with low per capita incomes). If this simple extrapolation from the Heckscher-Ohlin trade model is correct, then higher per capita income should decrease the probability of US AD duties. Our analysis controls for four variables capturing the closeness of the US foreign policy relationship with the potential target country. It is possible that government responsiveness to petitions would be lower if the US were concurrently seeking to support or avoid alienating foreign governments deemed important for national security reasons. The reinstatement of US nonreciprocal trade preferences for Pakistani exports at the time of the invasion of Afghanistan illustrates this potential dynamic. In any case, we simply wish to control for this possibility. We do so using dichotomous variables flagging countries fighting alongside the US in an armed conflict (Conflict Coalition Member, 1 in 7 % of the observations), countries in a formal alliance with the US (Ally, 1 in 70 %), and countries with whom the US maintains a free trade agreement 21

24 (PTA, 1 in 6 %), all measured in the year of the petition. We also add the Polity IV score measuring how democratic the target country is in that year, to ensure that any GATT/WTO effect is not merely an artifact of the prevalence of democracies in its membership. 22 Finally, we include a variable, GSP Fraction, which measures the proportion of the potential target s total exports to the United States that fell under the Generalized System of Preferences (GSP) program. Imports through GSP face zero tariffs, in contrast to the typical nonzero rates faced by non-gsp suppliers. As Özden and Reinhardt (2005) have argued, however, GSP benefits lie outside of the GATT/WTO regime and can be (and have often been) unilaterally removed by the US. Hence, the more a country s exports depend on GSP benefits, the more vulnerable it is to any (never explicit) threat to remove those benefits. It is thus possible though the issue has never before been tested that GSP-dependent countries would be more reluctant to retaliate against any single AD action by the US, in the form of either unilateral measures or use of GATT/WTO dispute settlement. US firms and US authorities may consequently be less deterred from initiating AD actions against targets whose exports are more vulnerable to the removal of GSP benefits. Identification of Petition Equation. The variables that shape the final decision by US authorities on antidumping investigations should similarly figure, by anticipation, in decisions by US industry associations about which suppliers to name in the petition to begin with. However, the logic of such industry decisions is shaped by other considerations as well, which do not bear on the goals of the US antidumping authorities. To this end, we construct the variable, Log US Product Export Share, which is based on the value of US exports to the potential target country, as a percent of US exports to the world, all in terms of just the specific product(s) in question. 22 Sources: PRIO s Armed Conflict Dataset, version 3.0 (Gleditsch et al. 2002); Mansfield and Reinhardt (2003); Jaggers and Gurr (1995). 22

25 (Specifically, the variable, as measured, is the natural log of one plus that percentage, to deal with the multiple cases with zero exports.) It answers the question: how dependent are the exports of the specific petitioning US industry to retaliation from the potential target state s market? The fear of potential retaliation on the part of the US government, however, must necessarily take all industries into account, not just the petitioning firm(s); this motivation is captured in the variable mentioned earlier, US Export Dependence. Hence we include Log US Product Export Share in just the Petition equation below, not the Affirmative equation as well. The Statistical Model We jointly estimate two equations, one for each of our dichotomous dependent variables, Petition and Affirmative, using a Heckman-like probit selection model. The model corrects for the failure to observe values of Affirmative in the unfiled observations. The equations are: Pr( Petition i β P + = 1) = F + β P3 β P ( GATT WTOi ) + β P ( US Export Dependencei ) ( ) 1 2 Log US Product Export Sharei + κ iλ P + ei 0 / and i ( β + β ( GATT WTO ) + β ( US Export Dependence ) + κ u ) Pr( Affirmativ e = 1) = F λ + A A / 0 1 where κ i is a vector of the all the above control variables for observation i; i A2 i λ A and i A λ P are vectors of equation-specific coefficients for those variables; and F is the standard normal cumulative density function. The estimation allows ρ Corr( e i, u ) 0. Note that the Petition = i equation is identified to the extent that, as previous research strongly indicates, Log US Product Export Share is a powerful predictor of petitioning behavior. i 23

Obstacles Facing Developing Countries in Antidumping Cases: The Path From Initial Filing to WTO Dispute Settlement

Obstacles Facing Developing Countries in Antidumping Cases: The Path From Initial Filing to WTO Dispute Settlement Obstacles Facing Developing Countries in Antidumping Cases: The Path From Initial Filing to WTO Dispute Settlement Chad P. Bown * Bernard Hoekman ** Caglar Ozden *** May 14, 2003 VERY PRELIMINARY: PLEASE

More information

Does Legal Capacity Matter? Explaining Patterns of Protection in the Shadow of WTO Litigation

Does Legal Capacity Matter? Explaining Patterns of Protection in the Shadow of WTO Litigation University of Minnesota-Twin Cities From the SelectedWorks of Gregory C Shaffer 2008 Does Legal Capacity Matter? Explaining Patterns of Protection in the Shadow of WTO Litigation Gregory C Shaffer, Loyola

More information

WTO and Antidumping *

WTO and Antidumping * WTO and Antidumping * JeeHyeong Park Department of Economic Wayne State University April, 2001 The issues related antidumping are broad and complex. 1 In the following presentation, thus I will try to

More information

Leader Change and the World Trade Organization The Impact on Leader Turnover on the Onset and Resolution of International Trade Disputes

Leader Change and the World Trade Organization The Impact on Leader Turnover on the Onset and Resolution of International Trade Disputes Leader Change and the World Trade Organization The Impact on Leader Turnover on the Onset and Resolution of International Trade Disputes In international trade, the World Trade Organization governs agreements

More information

Department of Economics Working Paper Series. Why Are So Many WTO Disputes Abandoned? Kara M. Reynolds. No June, 2007

Department of Economics Working Paper Series. Why Are So Many WTO Disputes Abandoned? Kara M. Reynolds. No June, 2007 Department of Economics Working Paper Series Why Are So Many WTO Disputes Abandoned? by Kara M. Reynolds No. 2007-05 June, 2007 http://www.american.edu/academic.depts/cas/econ/working papers/workpap.htm

More information

Explaining Concessions in GATT/WTO Trade Disputes: The Role of Institutional Environments

Explaining Concessions in GATT/WTO Trade Disputes: The Role of Institutional Environments Explaining Concessions in GATT/WTO Trade Disputes: The Role of Institutional Environments Johannes Karreth Department of Political Science University of Colorado Boulder johannes.karreth@colorado.edu This

More information

Article XX. Schedule of Specific Commitments

Article XX. Schedule of Specific Commitments 1 ARTICLE XX... 1 1.1 Text of Article XX... 1 1.2 Article XX:1... 2 1.2.1 General... 2 1.2.1.1 Structure of the GATS... 2 1.2.1.2 The words "None" and "Unbound" in GATS Schedules... 2 1.2.1.3 Nature of

More information

CRS Report for Congress Received through the CRS Web

CRS Report for Congress Received through the CRS Web Order Code RL30461 CRS Report for Congress Received through the CRS Web Trade Remedy Law Reform in the 107 th Congress Updated April 20, 2002 William H. Cooper Specialist In International Trade and Finance

More information

Tariff Bindings, Tariff Overhang, and Trade Remedies: Policy Flexibility at the WTO in Tough Political Times

Tariff Bindings, Tariff Overhang, and Trade Remedies: Policy Flexibility at the WTO in Tough Political Times Tariff Bindings, Tariff Overhang, and Trade Remedies: Policy Flexibility at the WTO in Tough Political Times Marc L. Busch and Krzysztof J. Pelc The GATT/WTO s main accomplishment since the Uruguay Round

More information

Article XVI. Miscellaneous Provisions

Article XVI. Miscellaneous Provisions 1 ARTICLE XVI... 1 1.1 Text of Article XVI... 1 1.2 Article XVI:1... 2 1.2.1 "the WTO shall be guided by the decisions, procedures and customary practices followed by the CONTRACTING PARTIES to GATT 1947"...

More information

Article 1. Coverage and Application

Article 1. Coverage and Application 1 ARTICLE 1 AND APPENDIX 1 AND 2... 1 1.1 Text of Article 1... 1 1.2 Article 1.1: "covered agreements"... 2 1.2.1 Text of Appendix 1... 2 1.2.2 General... 2 1.2.3 The DSU... 3 1.2.4 Bilateral agreements...

More information

SECTION THREE BENEFITS OF THE JSEPA

SECTION THREE BENEFITS OF THE JSEPA SECTION THREE BENEFITS OF THE JSEPA 1. Section Two described the possible scope of the JSEPA and elaborated on the benefits that could be derived from the proposed initiatives under the JSEPA. This section

More information

Article XIX. Emergency Action on Imports of Particular Products

Article XIX. Emergency Action on Imports of Particular Products 1 ARTICLE XIX... 1 1.1 Text of Article XIX... 1 1.2 General... 2 1.2.1 Application of Article XIX... 2 1.2.2 Standard of review... 4 1.3 Article XIX:1: "as a result of unforeseen developments"... 4 1.3.1

More information

Jagdish Bhagwati University Professor, Columbia University & Andrew Meyer Senior Fellow Council on Foreign Relations

Jagdish Bhagwati University Professor, Columbia University & Andrew Meyer Senior Fellow Council on Foreign Relations Final The Byrd Amendment Is WTO-Illegal: But We must Kill the Byrd with the Right Stone Jagdish Bhagwati University Professor, Columbia University & Andrew Meyer Senior Fellow Council on Foreign Relations

More information

Economics and the International Trade Commission*

Economics and the International Trade Commission* Economics and the International Trade Commission* JAMES M. DEVAULT Lafayette College Easton, Pennsylvania I. Introduction U.S. trade policy over the last two decades has become increasingly reliant on

More information

WORLD TRADE ORGANIZATION

WORLD TRADE ORGANIZATION WORLD TRADE ORGANIZATION WT/DS184/13 19 February 2002 (02-0823) UNITED STATES ANTI-DUMPING MEASURES ON CERTAIN HOT-ROLLED STEEL PRODUCTS FROM JAPAN Arbitration under Article 21.3(c) of the Understanding

More information

Corruption, Political Instability and Firm-Level Export Decisions. Kul Kapri 1 Rowan University. August 2018

Corruption, Political Instability and Firm-Level Export Decisions. Kul Kapri 1 Rowan University. August 2018 Corruption, Political Instability and Firm-Level Export Decisions Kul Kapri 1 Rowan University August 2018 Abstract In this paper I use South Asian firm-level data to examine whether the impact of corruption

More information

UNITED STATES CERTAIN METHODOLOGIES AND THEIR APPLICATION TO ANTI-DUMPING PROCEEDINGS INVOLVING CHINA

UNITED STATES CERTAIN METHODOLOGIES AND THEIR APPLICATION TO ANTI-DUMPING PROCEEDINGS INVOLVING CHINA * 19 January 2018 (18-0485) Page: 1/28 Original: English UNITED STATES CERTAIN METHODOLOGIES AND THEIR APPLICATION TO ANTI-DUMPING PROCEEDINGS INVOLVING CHINA Arbitration under Article 21.3(c) of the Understanding

More information

ArkPSA Arkansas Political Science Association

ArkPSA Arkansas Political Science Association ArkPSA Arkansas Political Science Association The Forgotten Disputes: Anti-Dumping and Trade Conflict at the WTO Author(s): Gregory C. Dixon Source: The Midsouth Political Science Review, Volume 14 (December

More information

Research Statement. Jeffrey J. Harden. 2 Dissertation Research: The Dimensions of Representation

Research Statement. Jeffrey J. Harden. 2 Dissertation Research: The Dimensions of Representation Research Statement Jeffrey J. Harden 1 Introduction My research agenda includes work in both quantitative methodology and American politics. In methodology I am broadly interested in developing and evaluating

More information

Article 11. Initiation and Subsequent Investigation

Article 11. Initiation and Subsequent Investigation 1 ARTICLE 11... 1 1.1 Text of Article 11... 1 1.2 General... 3 1.2.1 Anti-Dumping Agreement... 3 1.3 Article 11.2... 3 1.3.1 "caused by subsidized imports"... 3 1.3.2 "sufficient evidence"... 4 1.3.3 Relationship

More information

Developing Countries and DSU Reform

Developing Countries and DSU Reform Developing Countries and DSU Reform Marc L. Busch and Petros C. Mavroidis There has long been a desire to help developing countries make more of dispute settlement at the WTO. Ever since the subject of

More information

Revisiting Procedure and Precedent in the WTO: An Analysis of US Countervailing and Anti-Dumping Measures (China)

Revisiting Procedure and Precedent in the WTO: An Analysis of US Countervailing and Anti-Dumping Measures (China) World Trade Review, Page 1 of 21 Mostafa Beshkar and Adam S. Chilton doi:10.1017/s1474745615000683 Revisiting Procedure and Precedent in the WTO: An Analysis of US Countervailing and Anti-Dumping Measures

More information

WORLD TRADE ORGANIZATION

WORLD TRADE ORGANIZATION WORLD TRADE ORGANIZATION WT/DS269/13 20 February 2006 (06-0702) Original: English EUROPEAN COMMUNITIES CUSTOMS CLASSIFICATION OF FROZEN BONELESS CHICKEN CUTS ARB-2005-4/21 Arbitration under Article 21.3(c)

More information

AGRICULTURAL POLICIES, TRADE AGREEMENTS AND DISPUTE SETTLEMENT. Michael N. Gifford

AGRICULTURAL POLICIES, TRADE AGREEMENTS AND DISPUTE SETTLEMENT. Michael N. Gifford AGRICULTURAL POLICIES, TRADE AGREEMENTS AND DISPUTE SETTLEMENT Michael N. Gifford INTRODUCTION The purpose of this paper is to examine how dispute settlement mechanisms in trade agreements have evolved

More information

MFN and the Third-Party Economic Interests of Developing Countries in GATT/WTO Dispute Settlement

MFN and the Third-Party Economic Interests of Developing Countries in GATT/WTO Dispute Settlement MFN and the Third-Party Economic Interests of Developing Countries in GATT/WTO Dispute Settlement Chad P. Bown Department of Economics & International Business School Brandeis University Prepared for the

More information

U.S.-Latin America Trade: Recent Trends

U.S.-Latin America Trade: Recent Trends Order Code 98-840 Updated May 18, 2007 U.S.-Latin America Trade: Recent Trends Summary J. F. Hornbeck Specialist in International Trade and Finance Foreign Affairs, Defense, and Trade Division Since congressional

More information

Trade theory and regional integration

Trade theory and regional integration Trade theory and regional integration Dr. Mia Mikic mia.mikic@un.org Myanmar Capacity Building Programme Training Workshop on Regional Cooperation and Integration 9-11 May 2016, Yangon Outline of this

More information

Revisiting Procedure and Precedent in the WTO: An Analysis of US-Countervailing and Anti- Dumping Measure (China)

Revisiting Procedure and Precedent in the WTO: An Analysis of US-Countervailing and Anti- Dumping Measure (China) University of Chicago Law School Chicago Unbound Coase-Sandor Working Paper Series in Law and Economics Coase-Sandor Institute for Law and Economics 2015 Revisiting Procedure and Precedent in the WTO:

More information

Participation of Developing Countries in the World Trade Organizations Dispute Settlement System

Participation of Developing Countries in the World Trade Organizations Dispute Settlement System Participation of Developing Countries in the World Trade Organizations Dispute Settlement System Name: Anna Jüngen (36489) University: Erasmus University Rotterdam, Department of Public Administration

More information

Strengthening Protection of Labor Rights through Preferential Trade Agreements (PTAs)

Strengthening Protection of Labor Rights through Preferential Trade Agreements (PTAs) Strengthening Protection of Labor Rights through Preferential Trade Agreements (PTAs) Moonhawk Kim moonhawk@gmail.com Executive Summary Analysts have argued that the United States attempts to strengthen

More information

Saudi Arabia s Role as Third Party in WTO Anti-Dumping Conflicts

Saudi Arabia s Role as Third Party in WTO Anti-Dumping Conflicts International Journal of Business and Social Science Volume 8 Number 6 June 2017 Saudi Arabia s Role as Third Party in WTO Anti-Dumping Conflicts Abstract 72 Mohammed Alamri PhD Candidate of Law Stirling

More information

WORLD TRADE ORGANIZATION

WORLD TRADE ORGANIZATION WORLD TRADE ORGANIZATION WT/DS136/11 28 February 2001 (01-0980) UNITED STATES ANTI-DUMPING ACT OF 1916 Arbitration under Article 21.3(c) of the Understanding on Rules and Procedures Governing the Settlement

More information

The Trade Liberalization Effects of Regional Trade Agreements* Volker Nitsch Free University Berlin. Daniel M. Sturm. University of Munich

The Trade Liberalization Effects of Regional Trade Agreements* Volker Nitsch Free University Berlin. Daniel M. Sturm. University of Munich December 2, 2005 The Trade Liberalization Effects of Regional Trade Agreements* Volker Nitsch Free University Berlin Daniel M. Sturm University of Munich and CEPR Abstract Recent research suggests that

More information

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr Abstract. The Asian experience of poverty reduction has varied widely. Over recent decades the economies of East and Southeast Asia

More information

(a) Short title. This Act may be cited as the "Trade Promotion Authority Act of 2013". (b) Findings. The Congress makes the following findings:

(a) Short title. This Act may be cited as the Trade Promotion Authority Act of 2013. (b) Findings. The Congress makes the following findings: TRADE PROMOTION AUTHORITY ACT OF 2013 Section 1. Short title, findings and purpose (a) Short title. This Act may be cited as the "Trade Promotion Authority Act of 2013". (b) Findings. The Congress makes

More information

Benefit levels and US immigrants welfare receipts

Benefit levels and US immigrants welfare receipts 1 Benefit levels and US immigrants welfare receipts 1970 1990 by Joakim Ruist Department of Economics University of Gothenburg Box 640 40530 Gothenburg, Sweden joakim.ruist@economics.gu.se telephone: +46

More information

A COMPARISON BETWEEN TWO DATASETS

A COMPARISON BETWEEN TWO DATASETS A COMPARISON BETWEEN TWO DATASETS Bachelor Thesis by S.F. Simmelink s1143611 sophiesimmelink@live.nl Internationale Betrekkingen en Organisaties Universiteit Leiden 9 June 2016 Prof. dr. G.A. Irwin Word

More information

10 common misunderstandings about the WTO

10 common misunderstandings about the WTO 10 common misunderstandings about the WTO The debate will probably never end. People have different views of the pros and cons of the WTO s multilateral trading system. Indeed, one of the most important

More information

Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US

Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US Ben Ost a and Eva Dziadula b a Department of Economics, University of Illinois at Chicago, 601 South Morgan UH718 M/C144 Chicago,

More information

Bachelorproject 2 The Complexity of Compliance: Why do member states fail to comply with EU directives?

Bachelorproject 2 The Complexity of Compliance: Why do member states fail to comply with EU directives? Bachelorproject 2 The Complexity of Compliance: Why do member states fail to comply with EU directives? Authors: Garth Vissers & Simone Zwiers University of Utrecht, 2009 Introduction The European Union

More information

The Spread of Antidumping Regimes and the Role of Retaliation in Filings

The Spread of Antidumping Regimes and the Role of Retaliation in Filings 1 The Spread of Antidumping Regimes and the Role of Retaliation in Filings Robert M. Feinberg * and Kara M. Reynolds + * Corresponding author: American University and U.S. International Trade Commission

More information

CLAIMANTS' REPLY TO UNITED STATES' ANSWERS TO THE TRIBUNAL'S ADDITIONAL QUESTIONS IN RELATION TO THE BYRD AMENDMENT

CLAIMANTS' REPLY TO UNITED STATES' ANSWERS TO THE TRIBUNAL'S ADDITIONAL QUESTIONS IN RELATION TO THE BYRD AMENDMENT UNDER THE UNCITRAL ARBITRATION RULES AND SECTION B OF CHAPTER 11 OF THE NORTH AMERICAN FREE TRADE AGREEMENT CANFOR CORPORATION and TERMINAL FOREST PRODUCTS LTD. Investors (Claimants) v. UNITED STATES OF

More information

LABOUR-MARKET INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS IN OECD-COUNTRIES: WHAT EXPLANATIONS FIT THE DATA?

LABOUR-MARKET INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS IN OECD-COUNTRIES: WHAT EXPLANATIONS FIT THE DATA? LABOUR-MARKET INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS IN OECD-COUNTRIES: WHAT EXPLANATIONS FIT THE DATA? By Andreas Bergh (PhD) Associate Professor in Economics at Lund University and the Research Institute of Industrial

More information

ANNEX E EXECUTIVE SUMMARIES OF THE SECOND WRITTEN SUBMISSIONS OF THE PARTIES

ANNEX E EXECUTIVE SUMMARIES OF THE SECOND WRITTEN SUBMISSIONS OF THE PARTIES Page E-1 ANNEX E EXECUTIVE SUMMARIES OF THE SECOND WRITTEN SUBMISSIONS OF THE PARTIES Annex E-1 Annex E-2 Contents Executive Summary of the Second Written Submission of Viet Nam Executive Summary of the

More information

Balancing Law and Politics: Judicial Incentives in WTO Dispute Settlement

Balancing Law and Politics: Judicial Incentives in WTO Dispute Settlement Balancing Law and Politics: Judicial Incentives in WTO Dispute Settlement Ryan Brutger & Julia Morse 5 January 2013 Abstract: Can international courts ever be independent of state influence? If not, how

More information

China - Measures Affecting Imports of Automobile Parts

China - Measures Affecting Imports of Automobile Parts Chicago-Kent College of Law Scholarly Commons @ IIT Chicago-Kent College of Law All Faculty Scholarship Faculty Scholarship January 2008 China - Measures Affecting Imports of Automobile Parts Sungjoon

More information

TRADE REMEDIES. Side-by-Side Chart Trade Remedies

TRADE REMEDIES. Side-by-Side Chart Trade Remedies 3 July 2013 TRADE REMEDIES EU KOREA Safeguard Measures Application Article 3.1 - Application of a Bilateral Safeguard Measure 1. If, as a result of the reduction or elimination of a customs duty under

More information

POWER PLAYS & CAPACITY CONSTRAINTS: THE SELECTION OF DEFENDANTS IN WTO DISPUTES

POWER PLAYS & CAPACITY CONSTRAINTS: THE SELECTION OF DEFENDANTS IN WTO DISPUTES POWER PLAYS & CAPACITY CONSTRAINTS: THE SELECTION OF DEFENDANTS IN WTO DISPUTES Andrew T. Guzman Boalt Hall School of Law University of California at Berkeley guzman@law.berkeley.edu Beth A. Simmons Government

More information

Growth and Migration to a Third Country: The Case of Korean Migrants in Latin America

Growth and Migration to a Third Country: The Case of Korean Migrants in Latin America JOURNAL OF INTERNATIONAL AND AREA STUDIES Volume 23, Number 2, 2016, pp.77-87 77 Growth and Migration to a Third Country: The Case of Korean Migrants in Latin America Chong-Sup Kim and Eunsuk Lee* This

More information

International Regulation: Lessons from the IP Experience for the Internet

International Regulation: Lessons from the IP Experience for the Internet International Regulation: Lessons from the IP Experience for the Internet THE MARKET FOR REGULATION IN THE INTERNET OF THINGS January 11, 2019 Judith Goldstein Department of Political Science Can there

More information

Does government decentralization reduce domestic terror? An empirical test

Does government decentralization reduce domestic terror? An empirical test Does government decentralization reduce domestic terror? An empirical test Axel Dreher a Justina A. V. Fischer b November 2010 Economics Letters, forthcoming Abstract Using a country panel of domestic

More information

Understanding Taiwan Independence and Its Policy Implications

Understanding Taiwan Independence and Its Policy Implications Understanding Taiwan Independence and Its Policy Implications January 30, 2004 Emerson M. S. Niou Department of Political Science Duke University niou@duke.edu 1. Introduction Ever since the establishment

More information

Institutions and Outcomes: The GATT/WTO and Postwar Trade. Joanne Gowa. Department of Politics. Princeton University.

Institutions and Outcomes: The GATT/WTO and Postwar Trade. Joanne Gowa. Department of Politics. Princeton University. Institutions and Outcomes: The GATT/WTO and Postwar Trade Joanne Gowa Department of Politics Princeton University jgowa@princeton.edu Preliminary. Please do not cite or circulate. Institutions and Outcomes:

More information

WORLD TRADE ORGANIZATION

WORLD TRADE ORGANIZATION WORLD TRADE ORGANIZATION 10 common misunderstandings about the WTO Is it a dictatorial tool of the rich and powerful? Does it destroy jobs? Does it ignore the concerns of health, the environment and development?

More information

Table A.2 reports the complete set of estimates of equation (1). We distinguish between personal

Table A.2 reports the complete set of estimates of equation (1). We distinguish between personal Akay, Bargain and Zimmermann Online Appendix 40 A. Online Appendix A.1. Descriptive Statistics Figure A.1 about here Table A.1 about here A.2. Detailed SWB Estimates Table A.2 reports the complete set

More information

Comments and observations received from Governments

Comments and observations received from Governments Extract from the Yearbook of the International Law Commission:- 1997,vol. II(1) Document:- A/CN.4/481 and Add.1 Comments and observations received from Governments Topic: International liability for injurious

More information

General Interpretative Note to Annex 1A

General Interpretative Note to Annex 1A WTO ANALYTICAL INDEX GATT 1994 General (Jurisprudence) 1 GENERAL... 1 1.1 Relationship between GATT 1994 and other Annex 1A agreements... 1 1.1.1 Text of the General Interpretative Note... 1 1.1.2 The

More information

Economic Growth, Foreign Investments and Economic Freedom: A Case of Transition Economy Kaja Lutsoja

Economic Growth, Foreign Investments and Economic Freedom: A Case of Transition Economy Kaja Lutsoja Economic Growth, Foreign Investments and Economic Freedom: A Case of Transition Economy Kaja Lutsoja Tallinn School of Economics and Business Administration of Tallinn University of Technology The main

More information

RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN ARTICLE XIX OF GATT 1994 AND AGREEMENT ON SAFEGUARD

RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN ARTICLE XIX OF GATT 1994 AND AGREEMENT ON SAFEGUARD LAW MANTRA THINK BEYOND OTHERS (I.S.S.N 2321-6417 (Online) Ph: +918255090897 Website: journal.lawmantra.co.in E-mail: info@lawmantra.co.in contact@lawmantra.co.in RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN ARTICLE XIX OF GATT

More information

GENDER EQUALITY IN THE LABOUR MARKET AND FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT

GENDER EQUALITY IN THE LABOUR MARKET AND FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT THE STUDENT ECONOMIC REVIEWVOL. XXIX GENDER EQUALITY IN THE LABOUR MARKET AND FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT CIÁN MC LEOD Senior Sophister With Southeast Asia attracting more foreign direct investment than

More information

Deterring Disputes: WTO Dispute Settlement as a Tool for Conflict Management

Deterring Disputes: WTO Dispute Settlement as a Tool for Conflict Management Deterring Disputes: WTO Dispute Settlement as a Tool for Conflict Management Christina L. Davis November 10, 2016 Prepared for presentation to the Annual Meeting of the International Political Economy

More information

The Spread of Antidumping Regimes and the Role of Retaliation in Filings*

The Spread of Antidumping Regimes and the Role of Retaliation in Filings* The Spread of Antidumping Regimes and the Role of Retaliation in Filings* Robert M. Feinberg and Kara Olson American University November 2004 Corresponding author: Prof. Robert M. Feinberg Department of

More information

INTERNATIONAL TRADE AND DOMESTIC POLITICS: THE DOMESTIC SOURCES OF INTERNATIONAL TRADE AGREEMENTS AND INSTITUTIONS.

INTERNATIONAL TRADE AND DOMESTIC POLITICS: THE DOMESTIC SOURCES OF INTERNATIONAL TRADE AGREEMENTS AND INSTITUTIONS. INTERNATIONAL TRADE AND DOMESTIC POLITICS: THE DOMESTIC SOURCES OF INTERNATIONAL TRADE AGREEMENTS AND INSTITUTIONS. BY Helen V. Milner Department of Political Science Columbia University NY NY 10027 Hvm1@columbia.edu

More information

Amended proposal for a REGULATION OF THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND OF THE COUNCIL

Amended proposal for a REGULATION OF THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND OF THE COUNCIL EUROPEAN COMMISSION Brussels, 4.7.2017 COM(2017) 361 final 2014/0175 (COD) Amended proposal for a REGULATION OF THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND OF THE COUNCIL on additional customs duties on imports of certain

More information

THE WTO S EMPHASIS ON ADJUDICATED DISPUTE SETTLEMENT MAY BE MORE DRAG THAN LIFT. John D. Greenwald & Lynn Fischer Fox

THE WTO S EMPHASIS ON ADJUDICATED DISPUTE SETTLEMENT MAY BE MORE DRAG THAN LIFT. John D. Greenwald & Lynn Fischer Fox THE WTO S EMPHASIS ON ADJUDICATED DISPUTE SETTLEMENT MAY BE MORE DRAG THAN LIFT John D. Greenwald & Lynn Fischer Fox With its emphasis on adjudicated dispute resolution, the World Trade Organization (WTO)

More information

2017 NATIONAL OPINION POLL

2017 NATIONAL OPINION POLL 2017 NATIONAL OPINION POLL Canadian Views on Engagement with China 2017 NATIONAL OPINION POLL I 1 2017 NATIONAL OPINION POLL 2 TABLE OF CONTENTS EXECUTIVE SUMMARY ABOUT THE ASIA PACIFIC FOUNDATION OF CANADA

More information

Non-tariff barriers. Yuliya Chernykh

Non-tariff barriers. Yuliya Chernykh Non-tariff barriers Yuliya Chernykh Non-tariff measures/non-tariff barriers All government imposed and sponsored actions or omissions that act as prohibitions or restrictions on trade, other than ordinary

More information

Segal and Howard also constructed a social liberalism score (see Segal & Howard 1999).

Segal and Howard also constructed a social liberalism score (see Segal & Howard 1999). APPENDIX A: Ideology Scores for Judicial Appointees For a very long time, a judge s own partisan affiliation 1 has been employed as a useful surrogate of ideology (Segal & Spaeth 1990). The approach treats

More information

The World Trade Organization and the future of multilateralism Note Key principles behind GATT general principle rules based not results based

The World Trade Organization and the future of multilateralism Note Key principles behind GATT general principle rules based not results based The World Trade Organization and the future of multilateralism By Richard Baldwin, Journal of Economic perspectives, Winter 2016 The GATT (General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade) was established in unusual

More information

11 Legally binding versus nonlegally binding instruments

11 Legally binding versus nonlegally binding instruments 11 Legally binding versus nonlegally binding instruments Arizona State University Although it now appears settled that the Paris agreement will be a treaty within the definition of the Vienna Convention

More information

Corruption and quality of public institutions: evidence from Generalized Method of Moment

Corruption and quality of public institutions: evidence from Generalized Method of Moment Document de travail de la série Etudes et Documents E 2008.13 Corruption and quality of public institutions: evidence from Generalized Method of Moment Gbewopo Attila 1 University Clermont I, CERDI-CNRS

More information

The Textile, Apparel, and Footwear Act of 1990: Determinants of Congressional Voting

The Textile, Apparel, and Footwear Act of 1990: Determinants of Congressional Voting The Textile, Apparel, and Footwear Act of 1990: Determinants of Congressional Voting By: Stuart D. Allen and Amelia S. Hopkins Allen, S. and Hopkins, A. The Textile Bill of 1990: The Determinants of Congressional

More information

RULES OF ORIGIN CHAPTER 10 A. OVERVIEW OF RULES 1. BACKGROUND OF RULES. Chapter 10: Rules of Origin

RULES OF ORIGIN CHAPTER 10 A. OVERVIEW OF RULES 1. BACKGROUND OF RULES. Chapter 10: Rules of Origin CHAPTER 10 Chapter 10: Rules of Origin RULES OF ORIGIN A. OVERVIEW OF RULES 1. BACKGROUND OF RULES Rules of origin are used to determine the nationality of goods traded in international commerce. Yet,

More information

Shopping for Protection: The Politics of Choosing Trade Instruments in a Partially Legalized World*

Shopping for Protection: The Politics of Choosing Trade Instruments in a Partially Legalized World* International Studies Quarterly (2009) 53, 421 444 Shopping for Protection: The Politics of Choosing Trade Instruments in a Partially Legalized World* Megumi Naoi University of California, San Diego This

More information

WORLD TRADE ORGANIZATION

WORLD TRADE ORGANIZATION WORLD TRADE ORGANIZATION WT/DS34/AB/R 22 October 1999 (99-4546) Original: English TURKEY RESTRICTIONS ON IMPORTS OF TEXTILE AND CLOTHING PRODUCTS AB-1999-5 Report of the Appellate Body Page i I. Introduction...

More information

GENERAL AGREEMENT ON TARIFFS AND TRADE The General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade 1994 ("GATT 1994") shall consist of:

GENERAL AGREEMENT ON TARIFFS AND TRADE The General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade 1994 (GATT 1994) shall consist of: Page 23 GENERAL AGREEMENT ON TARIFFS AND TRADE 1994 1. The General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade 1994 ("GATT 1994") shall consist of: (a) the provisions in the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade,

More information

International Business 7e

International Business 7e International Business 7e by Charles W.L. Hill (adapted for LIUC09 by R.Helg) McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright 2009 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. Chapter 6 The Political Economy of

More information

THE FUTURE OF THE WTO

THE FUTURE OF THE WTO INTRODUCTION THE FUTURE OF THE WTO Daniel T. Griswold A Crucial Moment in U.S. Trade Policy Once an obscure international body tucked away in Geneva, Switzerland, the World Trade Organization (WTO) has

More information

R ESEARCHERS T EST Q UESTION P APER. By Dr. Nicolas Lamp Assistant Professor, Faculty of Law, Queen s University

R ESEARCHERS T EST Q UESTION P APER. By Dr. Nicolas Lamp Assistant Professor, Faculty of Law, Queen s University RESEARCHERS TEST By Dr. Nicolas Lamp Assistant Professor, Faculty of Law, Queen s University INSTRUCTIONS FOR PARTICIPANTS: The duration of this test is 90 minutes. There are 30 questions, so you have

More information

BACKGROUND NOTE PROPOSAL TO PERMANENTLY EXCLUDE NON-VIOLATION AND SITUATION COMPLAINTS FROM THE WTO TRIPS AGREEMENT. 20 September

BACKGROUND NOTE PROPOSAL TO PERMANENTLY EXCLUDE NON-VIOLATION AND SITUATION COMPLAINTS FROM THE WTO TRIPS AGREEMENT. 20 September Development, Innovation and Intellectual Property Programme BACKGROUND NOTE PROPOSAL TO PERMANENTLY EXCLUDE NON-VIOLATION AND SITUATION COMPLAINTS FROM THE WTO TRIPS AGREEMENT 20 September 2017 1. Background

More information

Firms, Governments, and WTO Adjudication: Japan s Selection of WTO Disputes. Forthcoming in World Politics. Christina Davis

Firms, Governments, and WTO Adjudication: Japan s Selection of WTO Disputes. Forthcoming in World Politics. Christina Davis Firms, Governments, and WTO Adjudication: Japan s Selection of WTO Disputes Forthcoming in World Politics Christina Davis Princeton University, Department of Politics (cldavis@princeton.edu) and Yuki Shirato

More information

States have long sought to have their conflicts adjudicated by institutions. Nowhere is

States have long sought to have their conflicts adjudicated by institutions. Nowhere is JOURNAL Busch / PANELING OF CONFLICT OF DISPUTES RESOLUTION UNDER GATT Democracy, Consultation, and the Paneling of Disputes under GATT MARC L. BUSCH Queen s School of Business Studies of the General Agreement

More information

TPP and Exchange Rates

TPP and Exchange Rates TPP and Exchange Rates 20 C. FRED BERGSTEN AND JEFFREY J. SCHOTT The Trans-Pacific Partnership (TPP) has achieved an important distinction in the history of trade policy. It is the first ever free trade

More information

Trade Deflection arising from U.S. Antidumping Duties on Imported Shrimp

Trade Deflection arising from U.S. Antidumping Duties on Imported Shrimp Trade Deflection arising from U.S. Antidumping Duties on Imported Shrimp Xiaojin Wang, PhD candidate Department of Agricultural Economics, University of Kentucky 312 Charles E. Barnhart Bldg. Lexington,

More information

Economy of U.S. Tariff Suspensions

Economy of U.S. Tariff Suspensions Protection for Free? The Political Economy of U.S. Tariff Suspensions Rodney Ludema, Georgetown University Anna Maria Mayda, Georgetown University and CEPR Prachi Mishra, International Monetary Fund Tariff

More information

COMMUNICATION FROM THE COMMISSION TO THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT, THE COUNCIL, THE EUROPEAN ECONOMIC AND SOCIAL COMMITTEE AND THE COMMITTEE OF THE REGIONS

COMMUNICATION FROM THE COMMISSION TO THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT, THE COUNCIL, THE EUROPEAN ECONOMIC AND SOCIAL COMMITTEE AND THE COMMITTEE OF THE REGIONS EUROPEAN COMMISSION Brussels, 13.9.2017 COM(2017) 492 final COMMUNICATION FROM THE COMMISSION TO THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT, THE COUNCIL, THE EUROPEAN ECONOMIC AND SOCIAL COMMITTEE AND THE COMMITTEE OF THE

More information

EMU, Switzerland? Marie-Christine Luijckx and Luke Threinen Public Policy 542 April 10, 2006

EMU, Switzerland? Marie-Christine Luijckx and Luke Threinen Public Policy 542 April 10, 2006 EMU, Switzerland? Marie-Christine Luijckx and Luke Threinen Public Policy 542 April 10, 2006 Introduction While Switzerland is the EU s closest geographic, cultural, and economic ally, it is not a member

More information

Assessing the impact of the Sentencing Council s Burglary offences definitive guideline

Assessing the impact of the Sentencing Council s Burglary offences definitive guideline Assessing the impact of the Sentencing Council s Burglary offences definitive guideline Summary An initial assessment of the Sentencing Council s burglary offences definitive guideline indicated there

More information

Skill Classification Does Matter: Estimating the Relationship Between Trade Flows and Wage Inequality

Skill Classification Does Matter: Estimating the Relationship Between Trade Flows and Wage Inequality Skill Classification Does Matter: Estimating the Relationship Between Trade Flows and Wage Inequality By Kristin Forbes* M.I.T.-Sloan School of Management and NBER First version: April 1998 This version:

More information

Power Plays & Capacity Constraints: The Selection of Defendants in WTO Disputes. Forthcoming, Journal of Legal Studies, 2005

Power Plays & Capacity Constraints: The Selection of Defendants in WTO Disputes. Forthcoming, Journal of Legal Studies, 2005 Power Plays & Capacity Constraints: The Selection of Defendants in WTO Disputes Forthcoming, Journal of Legal Studies, 2005 Andrew T. Guzman Boalt Hall School of Law University of California at Berkeley

More information

Policy Uncertainty, Trade and Welfare: Theory and Evidence for China and the U.S.

Policy Uncertainty, Trade and Welfare: Theory and Evidence for China and the U.S. Policy Uncertainty, Trade and Welfare: Theory and Evidence for China and the U.S. by Kyle Handley and Nuno Limao Discussion by Anna Maria Mayda Georgetown University and CEPR Exploring the Price of Policy

More information

1 Introduction. Cambridge University Press International Institutions and National Policies Xinyuan Dai Excerpt More information

1 Introduction. Cambridge University Press International Institutions and National Policies Xinyuan Dai Excerpt More information 1 Introduction Why do countries comply with international agreements? How do international institutions influence states compliance? These are central questions in international relations (IR) and arise

More information

NOTE. 3. Annexed is the Chapter from the WTO Analytical Index, 3 rd edition (2012) providing information on the Agreement on Textiles and Clothing.

NOTE. 3. Annexed is the Chapter from the WTO Analytical Index, 3 rd edition (2012) providing information on the Agreement on Textiles and Clothing. NOTE 1. The Agreement on Textiles and Clothing (ATC) was negotiated in the Uruguay Round of Trade Negotiations. It replaced the Arrangement Regarding International Trade in Textiles (MFA, or Multi-Fibre

More information

ANNEX D. Oral Statements, First and Second Panel meetings

ANNEX D. Oral Statements, First and Second Panel meetings Page D-1 ANNEX D Oral Statements, First and Second Panel meetings Content Page Annex D-1 Executive Summary of the Oral Statement of Japan First meeting D-2 Annex D-2 Executive Summary of the Oral Statement

More information

TRADE POLICY REVIEW OF SOUTH AFRICA 1-2 JUNE GATT Council's Evaluation

TRADE POLICY REVIEW OF SOUTH AFRICA 1-2 JUNE GATT Council's Evaluation CENTRE WILLIAM-RAPPARD, RUE DE LAUSANNE 154, 1211 GENÈVE 21, TÉL. 022 73951 11 TRADE POLICY REVIEW OF SOUTH AFRICA 1-2 JUNE 1993 GATT Council's Evaluation GATT/1583 3 June 1993 The GATT Council conducted

More information

The Economic and Strategic Motives for Antidumping Filings. Susan Skeath* January 14, 2002

The Economic and Strategic Motives for Antidumping Filings. Susan Skeath* January 14, 2002 The Economic and Strategic Motives for Antidumping Filings Thomas J. Prusa Rutgers University and NBER prusa@econ.rutgers.edu Susan Skeath* Wellesley College sskeath@wellesley.edu January 14, 2002 CONTENTS

More information

WORLD TRADE ORGANIZATION

WORLD TRADE ORGANIZATION WORLD TRADE ORGANIZATION WT/DS282/AB/R 2 November 2005 (05-5145) Original: English UNITED STATES ANTI-DUMPING MEASURES ON OIL COUNTRY TUBULAR GOODS (OCTG) FROM MEXICO AB-2005-7 Report of the Appellate

More information

Supplementary Material for Preventing Civil War: How the potential for international intervention can deter conflict onset.

Supplementary Material for Preventing Civil War: How the potential for international intervention can deter conflict onset. Supplementary Material for Preventing Civil War: How the potential for international intervention can deter conflict onset. World Politics, vol. 68, no. 2, April 2016.* David E. Cunningham University of

More information

An Empirical Analysis of Pakistan s Bilateral Trade: A Gravity Model Approach

An Empirical Analysis of Pakistan s Bilateral Trade: A Gravity Model Approach 103 An Empirical Analysis of Pakistan s Bilateral Trade: A Gravity Model Approach Shaista Khan 1 Ihtisham ul Haq 2 Dilawar Khan 3 This study aimed to investigate Pakistan s bilateral trade flows with major

More information