One Tick and You re Out: The Effects of the. Master Lever on Senator Positions

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "One Tick and You re Out: The Effects of the. Master Lever on Senator Positions"

Transcription

1 One Tick and You re Out: The Effects of the Master Lever on Senator Positions Olga Gorelkina University of Liverpool, Liverpool Ioanna Grypari Max Planck Institute, Bonn This Version: October 2016 Abstract This paper accounts for the effects of the master lever (ML), aka the straight-ticket voting option, on elected US senators from 1960 till The ML, still present in some states, allows voters to select a specific party for all elections listed on a ballot, as opposed to filling out each office individually. Introducing it leads to an increase in the number of partisan votes, and thus changes the groups of voters targeted by parties and shifts the positions of senatorial candidates. Theoretically, we examine this change in tradeoffs by building a model of multidimensional pre-election competition. Empirically, we identify the effect of the ML by using a triple difference estimator to account for selection into treatment. Controlling for party trends, we find that it leads to a right-wing shift of senatorial positions, an effect that is larger for the Republican party. We use the theory to explain how the political climate, as observed by the data, implies the specific result. Keywords: Ballot Design, Elections, Political Positions, U.S. Senate - JEL: D72, K16, N42 The authors thank Ying Chen, Paola Conconi, Mira Frick, Martin Hellwig, Johannes Hörner, Anna Kochanova, Rida Laraki, Derek Stemple, Stan Veuger, Maurizio Zanardi and participants of the CRETE and EEA conferences and the MPI workshop; as well as Darya Babushkina and Georg Treuter for excellent research assistance, and the Cowles Foundation at Yale University for hosting Gorelkina in University of Liverpool Management School, Chatham Street, Liverpool L69 7ZH, UK, olga@liv.ac.uk. Max Planck Institute for Research on Collective Goods, Bonn 53113, Germany, grypari@coll.mpg.de. 1

2 1 Introduction The Senate is one of the two chambers of the legislative branch in the US. Each state is represented by two senators, regardless of population, who serve staggered six-year terms. In other words, in every midterm or general (Presidential) election, at most one seat is up for election. The master lever, also known as the straight ticket voting option is a box at the top of a ballot that offers voters the possibility to vote for one party for all offices listed. The existence of a master level has been heavily debated and the number of states that offer the option has been decreasing over time. The main argument used against the master lever is that since in its presence voters are more likely to vote by the partisanship of the candidate as opposed to by her positions this leads to less informed voters and a lack of accountability for the politicians. However, another side to this issue is that the presence of the master lever shifts the groups of voters targeted by politicians. If introducing the master lever leads to more voters voting according to their partisanship, the parties will now have less incentive to target these partisan and put forth candidates with positions that will satisfy other groups of voters. In this paper, we provide a theory of multi-dimensional pre-election competition that models the incentives described above and which we estimate using data from the US Senate from 1960 till We find that the effects of the master lever on how moderate or extreme politicians are in their positions depends on the partisanship of the state (which party voters prefer), the average preferred voter position in each issue and the covariance between the two, the likelihood that a socially conservative voter is a republican partisan for example. This paper contributes to the literature on pre-election competition by studying the way a change in the ballot affects the game politicians play and thus offering a novel insight on the interaction of partisanship, policy positions and voting technology. 2

3 It also contributes to the growing empirical literature that studies the polarization of congressional positions, by introducing a so-far overlooked aspect, namely an important difference in ballots across US states. 1 Understanding these incentives is also a first step towards making policy recommendations with respect to the presence of the master lever by considering its effect on senator positions and thus congressional gridlock. We build a static model of parties and voters in a multi-dimensional issue space. Parties select which senatorial candidate to put forth by effectively picking their positions in each issue and voters vote for the candidate that they prefer. 2 Parties maximize their vote share in the election which they discount by the distance of their candidate s position from the party bliss point. The latter represents the party s willingness to be united in order to be able to pass more policies, or one can think of this as an incentive to maintain ideological purity and consistency over time. We find that equilibrium politician positions in each issue depend on the average partisanship of voters in the state, the average bliss point of voters and the covariance between the two. 3 In particular, introducing the master lever shifts the parties targeted group of voters away from weak partisans, i.e. those who could still vote by position but with the introduction of the master lever are more likely to vote by party. 4 If a party is the strong majority in the state, then the master lever will allow that party to put forth politicians closer to the party bliss point (since they will win the state anyway). If, however, we are in a weak partisan or non-partisan state by shifting the focus away from weak partisans both parties will have to target non-partisan voters or partisans of the other party. The positions they use to do this 1 We do not however claim that the master lever is enough to account for the evolution of senatorial positions over time. 2 For a discussion of primary elections and the senator already in power please see the theory section 3 Note that we separate between partisanship and positions and allow for liberals to be Republican for example. 4 The strong partisans will vote by party anyway. 3

4 depends on the covariance between voter partisanship and their bliss points. If for example we are in a non-partisan state where swing voters are more likely conservative, relative to the state s average, the introduction of the master lever will lead to both parties putting forth more conservative candidates (to try to appeal to swing voters). We use data from 1960 to 2010 to estimate the model. Voter-level data from Enns and Koch (2013) which use opinion polls to create state-level voter opinion data in two dimensions. For senatorial positions, we use the Poole and Rosenthal (2015) dataset which is estimated using the history of a senators roll call votes. 5 We build our own data set on the history of the master lever in each state as well as on senator characteristics, including their political history. In order to identify the treatment effect we employ the methodology of Ravallion et al. (2005) to account for the selection bias into having a master lever in the state. We separate the states into three groups 1. participant stayers (ML always), 2. participant leavers (ML, then no ML) and 3. non-participants. We construct a difference-in-difference (DD) estimator for stayers over non-participants and another one for leavers over non-participants and then take the difference between the two. This way we account for the effect of the ML as long as three things are satisfied: the selection is time-invariant, there is not selection into abolishing the ML and no lasting effects on winning senatorial positions after it is removed. We verify all three in section 4.6. We find that the master lever is a significant determinant of senator positions and our results fit the predictions of the model. We observe an asymmetry between the effects depending on whether the senator is a Democrat or a Republican, which we are able to explain using the empirical relationship between partisanship and preferred positions in the electorate. Overall, due to the parameter constellations, 5 The Yay or Nay when a bill is up for a vote. 4

5 the gradual removal of the master lever has in fact worked against the increasing political polarization of the Senate. The purpose of this paper is to account for the tradeoffs senators, and the parties behind them, face in the presence of a straight ticket voting option on the ballots. Theoretically, we model the way both the positions and share of votes of senatorial candidates are affected by a ML introduction and empirically we document the significance and direction of these changes for elected senators in the US. We observe that progressively more states are removing their option from their ballots and find that this change has negatively affected the number of Republican senators elected. Moreover, the parameter constellation in the data is such that postremoval Republican senators became more moderate and Democratic senators more extreme. This has direct implications for the composition of positions and parties in the Congress. This paper is organized as follows: section 2 presents the model and theoretical results, section 3 the data set, estimation and results, section 4 concludes. 2 Related Literature In this paper we account for the tradeoffs that senators, and the parties behind them, face in the presence of a straight ticket voting option, and document empirically the effects of the gradual removal of the ML across the US on the party and positions of elected senators. As this has direct implications on the composition of Congress, our paper relates to the literature on political polarization. 6 Political polarization is defined as the gap between Democratic and Republican parties at the mass and/or elite-level in some issue or ideological space. There is general agreement that political elites in the US are polarized. McCarty et al. (2006) 6 To be clear, we do not aim to explain the increasing Congress polarization. Instead, we examine the importance of a common ballot characteristic on the type of senators that get elected. 5

6 show that the difference in mean positions between the two parties has continued to grow since the 1940s in both the House of Representatives and the Senate and that this increase is driven more by the Republican Party. 7 There is an extensive literature on the causes of this phenomenon, 8 with a strong focus on the role of the voters. At the national level, there is no evidence of mass polarization and changes in the Congress composition have not been following changes in voter ideology, overall and across issues. 9 At the district-level, there is conflicting evidence on the importance of the electorate s preferences in predicting legislative behavior. Krasa and Polborn (2014) find that there is a stronger effect from politicians to voters, as opposed to the other way around, whereas Kirkland (2014) and McCarty et al. (2015) show that within state or district heterogeneity does lead to more extreme politicians. Harden and Carsey (2012) show that voter preferences can predict senatorial positions only in homogeneous states and that the voters party affiliation is a much more important determinant of political polarization. In fact, there is a growing literature on the importance of party sorting (the increased correlation between voter positions and their party affiliation) and within-state party strength in determining Congress members positions, with the direction of causality debated. 10 McCarty et al. (2006) and Garand (2010), among others, have examined the importance of income inequality in determining political polarization. In general periods of higher income inequality are associated with more extreme legislatures, that are also more right-leaning (Voorheis et al. (2015)). A lot of attention has also been given to the interaction of mass media with the electorate. 11 Campante and Hojman (2013) show that broadcast TV has led to more extreme Congress members, but Prior 7 Note that we use their dataset on senatorial positions. 8 See Barber and McCarty (2015) for a review. 9 E.g. Abramowitz (2010), Ansolabehere et al. (2006), Bafumi and Herron (2010), Fiorina et al. (2005), Fiorina and Abrams (2008), Tausanovitch and Warshaw (2013). 10 See Krasa and Polborn (2014), Layman and Carsey (2002) and Levendusky (2009), among others. 11 See Strömberg (2015) for a review of the literature. 6

7 (2013) finds no significant evidence of partisan media, in particular, influencing voter preferences. On the other hand, Snyder and Strömberg (2010) point to the importance of media coverage, with higher coverage leading to less ideologically extreme Congress members. Other factors that have been considered as a source of the increasing political polarization have been gerrymandering (redistricting), midterm vs Presidential elections, characteristics of the primaries and different elements of campaign financing. Engstrom (2013) accounts for the importance of redistricting on a variety of political outcomes (competitiveness of elections, partisan control, etc), but McCarty et al. (2009) find little evidence of a causal relationship between gerrymandering an ideological extremism, specifically. Different types of elections have been studied as well, with Halberstam and Montagnes (2015) finding that midterm elections are in fact associated with more extreme senators, whereas there is growing evidence that primary elections are weak in explaining polarization. 12 Lastly, in terms of campaign contributions, Barber (2016) finds that higher donation limits on PACs 13 lead to moderate legislators, and a larger number of donations from individuals to more extreme. The effect ballot design on polarization has not been considered, however there has been extensive research on the way it can affect voting behavior. Different ballot characteristics that have been examined are ballot secrecy (e.g. Heckelman (1995)), the ordering of names (e.g. Chen et al. (2014)), and the office bloc vs. party column ballot form (e.g. Walker (1966)). In terms of the ML in particular, as expected, its presence reduces the number of split tickets (voting for different parties for different offices), with varying effects depending on the party and office up for election. 14 Note also that when selecting 12 See Hirano et al. (2010), McGhee et al. (2014) and Barber and McCarty (2015). 13 Political Action Committees 14 See Kimball et al. (2002), McAllister and Darcy (1992) and Rusk (1970), among others. 7

8 the ML, all partisan elections on the ballot 15 are automatically voted on, and all non-partisan elections are counted as non-votes, unless a voter specifically chooses a candidate for these offices as well. In fact, Feig (2007), Feig (2009) and Kimball et al. (2002) do find that the ML decreases voter roll-off 16 and Bonneau and Loepp (2014) show that it decreases participation in non-partisan elections. In terms of voter errors, on the one hand Herrnson et al. (2012) demonstrate that a straight ticket voting option increases the occurrences of people not voting for the candidate they intend to, and on the other hand, Kimball and Kropf (2005) find that it reduces over-votes, i.e. cases when voters mark too many candidates. For our purposes, the most important take-away from this literature is that the ML is in fact used by voters, and it matters even for offices further up the ballot. 17 This paper brings together these two strands of literature. We do not examine directly the effects of the ML on electoral behavior, but we go one step further and account for the importance of this characteristic of ballot design on the positions and parties of elected senators. We contribute to the political polarization literature, by offering one more significant determinant, one that has direct policy implications. 3 Theory 3.1 Setup Fix a state and an election period, the offices listed on the ballot are indexed by k, k K {1, 2..K}. Let µ {0, 1} indicate the availability of the master lever (ML), or straight-ticket option, in the given state period. µ = 1 implies that ML is present 15 Those were candidates have party affiliations. 16 Lack of votes for offices further down the ballot. 17 In terms of which voters actually use the ML, Feig (2007) and Feig (2009) show that blacks are more likely to use it, and in a lab experiment Lewkowicz (2007) finds that Democrats and Republicans are equally likely to select the ML, but strong, weak and non-partisans in order have decreasing probabilities of using it. 8

9 and µ = 0 implies that ML is not available on ballot. We consider a multi-dimensional policy space P = [ 1 2, 1 2] N, where N is the number of policy issues, such as economics and ideology. Three types of actors are positioned within the policy space: voters, parties, and candidates for a given seat. The candidates as well as the parties they represent (one candidate per party) are indexed by j, where j {R, D}. The party has a bliss point denoted by Y j = (Y j1, Y j2,...y jn ) P. (1) Without loss of generality, we label issue positions so that the Democratic party s bliss point is to the left of the Republican bliss point in every coordinate, Y Dn < Y Rn, n {1, 2..N}. The bliss point of candidate j {R, D} is denoted y j, y j = (y j1, y j2,...y jn ) P. (2) Let y jn = y jn y jn represent the difference in candidates positions and y n = y jn +y jn 2 the average between the two, 18 and similarly let Y jn and Y n denote the difference and the average of the parties bliss points. Note that Y j is taken as exogenous in the model, but y j is endogenous and results from the party s optimization program stated below (11). by x i, There is a unit mass of voters indexed by i. Voter i s position is given exogenously 18 j = {R, D} /j. x i = (x i1, x i2,...x in ) P. (3) 9

10 Integrating over the mass of voters we obtain the average voter position in the state period X = x i di P. (4) [0,1] Apart from their political positions, the voters are characterized by the status of partisanship. Let p i (j) denote the probability that voter i (whose position is x i ) is a partisan of party j. 19 The realisation of the random variable is denoted Ii P ; Ii P = 1 implies that the voter is partisan, and I P i = 0 implies thaht the voter is non-partisan, or swing. Assuming that a voter can be a partisan of at most one party, we introduce the total probability of being a partisan p i = p i (j) + p i ( j). (5) Party j s partisan advantage in the state period is denoted p (j) = p (j) p ( j). The mass of voters who are partisans of party j is p (j), where p (j) = p [0,1] i (j) di. By analogy, p is the average partisanship status, p = p [0,1] idi = p (j) + p ( j). The average partisan position on issue n is given by X P n = 1 p i x in di P. (6) p [0,1] A given voter s political positions and partisanship status are generally not independent, the covariance is given by (p i p) (x in X n ) di. In our analysis, we shall use its negative, namely the covariance between the voter s position on issue n and the likelihood of being a swing (non-partisan) voter: Alternatively, p i can be thought of as the mass of partisan voters within voter group i characterized by position x i. In contrast, p i cannot be interpreted as partisanship strength. Idiosyncratic variations in the strength of partisanship that we may observe in the data are absorbed by other model parameters such as the cost of going through the ballot and the error term in (10). 20 Here we use (1 p i ) (1 p) = (p i p). 10

11 σ n = (p i p) (x in X n ) di. (7) If σ n is positive then the swing voter status is associated with a more conservative (right-wing) position on issue n compared to the rest of the state. If σ n is negative, then the swing voters views on issue n tend to be more liberal (left-wing) than the state s average. Players, Actions, and Payoffs. Our model of an election with the master lever is an incomplete information game between two parties and a mass of voters. The game proceeds according to the following time-line: t = 1 Party j chooses a candidate (y jk ) to compete for seat k. The party derives utility from the share of votes it gets and incurs a loss if its candidate s positions differ from the party s bliss point (11). t = 2 Voter i decides whether to use the ML, if available. If the voter does not use the ML, she goes through the whole ballot incurring cost c i. t = 3 Voter i elects a candidate. The voter chooses the candidate to maximize her payoff (10). Conforming with the logic of backward induction, we analyze the game in reverse chronological order. t = 3 : Electing Candidates. If the voter uses ML, she solves a single maximization problem for the entire ballot: Û i = max j {R,D} k=1,..k u ik (j). (8) 11

12 Let ĵ i {R, D} denote the problem s solution: ĵ i is the party that gives maximum payoff to voter i in the election. If the voter goes through the ballot office by office, she solves a sequence of K distinct maximization problems: U i = k=1,..k max u ik (j k ). (9) j k {R,D} Clearly, the more refined solution (j i1, j i2,..j ik ) {R, D}K yields greater utility to the voter: U i Ûi. This is due to the restriction of the domain in (8) compared to (9). The voter s utility component in (8) and (9) is given by n u ik (j) = ω n (x in y jn ) 2 + β k + ε ij, if i is a partisan of j,, (10) n ω n (x in y jn ) 2 + ε ij, otherwise. The payoff from electing candidate j is depends on the discrepancy between the voter s and the candidates positions, the partisanship statuses and the candidate s unobserved characteristics. The first component of (10), n ω n (x in y jn ) 2, is the dis-utility experienced by i if the candidate j s positions differ from i s bliss point x i, where every issue n has weight ω n > 0. The second component is a partisanship bonus β k > 0, an extra payoff that the voter gets from electing his preferred party candidate. 21 Thirdly, ε ij is a preference shock, an advantage over the opponent j (ε ij = ε i, j ) that results from various factors such as presidential approval, differences in personality traits, perceived competence, candidate s visibility, campaign funding etc. 22 Regarding the shock, we assume that ε ij is uniform on [ 1 2, 1 2] and 21 The model predictions do not change if the utility function is modified so that electing a counterparty candidate yields a negative payoff to a partisan voter. 22 In a model focusing on the winning probability, as opposed to vote share, we would introduce 12

13 independent of (x i, p i ). t = 2 : Voter s Choice to Use the Master Lever. The voter decides whether to use the option by comparing the cost c i > 0 and the benefit U i Ûi of making a better choice by going through the entire ballot. Here, c i represents the cognitive effort and opportunity cost associated with solving K decision problems while she works on the ballot. 23 t = 1 : Party s Choice of Candidate. We model the party s problem as a tradeoff between attracting votes and satisfying its own policy agenda (ideological purity). The party solves the following optimization problem: 24 max y jn { V j n γ n (Y jn y jn ) 2 }, (11) where V j E i Pr (j i j) is the share of votes for candidate j, and γ n > 0. The first term of the party s maximization program reflects the natural driving force of political competition. The second term corresponds to the party s cost from being represented by a candidate with views diverging from the party. In a wider interpretation the term captures any force that deters optimal candidates from converging to the midpoint as implied by the standard Downs (1957) model. 25 Note that we have assumed that parties can freely select a candidate with the optimal position y j. In reality, the party s choice may be restricted by primary elections; we do not study this possibility here, but we do account for them in the empirical an aggregate candidate-specific shock η j. 23 If the cost of going through the ballot was negligible, we would have observed equal participation in the elections for all offices on the ballot. A recent study by Augenblick and Nicholson (2016) shows that this is not the case, therefore the cost is relevant. 24 We can think of the party s { global election problem, i.e. the problem where the party cares about all seats k K: max y k π ke i Pr (j k i j k ) k,n γ jkn (Y jn y jkn ) 2} with some weights jkn π k, γ jkn. Due to the additive separability of the said global election problem in y jkn, we can focus directly on (11). 25 See Harden and Carsey (2012) for an overview of work showing that candidates do not converge while campaigning for office, but rather tend to take divergent positions. 13

14 exercise. 26 Assumptions We let n ω n = n γ n = 1 and β < 1 to guarantee that the solutions are interior. We assume α n 2 γn ω n 1, for all n, implying that there is not too much disagreement between the parties and the voters on the issues relative importance. 27 To simplify the exposition, we also assume that the cost c i of going through the ballot satisfies the following double inequality: Ui IP ( ) ( ) Ûi c i U IP i =1 i Ûi. i =0 Then the voter uses ML if and only if she is a partisan. Qualitatively, our results do not depend on this assumption. In a separate appendix, we consider an alternative set-up where c i are not constrained to the above interval and distributed independently across the population of voters. 28 In this framework, the partisans are only more likely to use ML than the swing voters and the ML effects are the same as reported in Section Master Lever Effects The change in master lever status observed in the data provides exogenous variation in µ {0, 1}. 29 In this subsection we study the model s solutions with and without the master lever and deduce the ML effects on three outcomes: candidates platforms (Proposition 1), winning probabilities (Proposition 2), and the expected platform of the election winner (Proposition 3). 26 Hirano et al. (2010) and McGhee et al. (2014) find little evidence of primaries effect on the platforms pf the elected officials. 27 If parties and voters weight issues equivalently then α n = See Supplementary material included in this submission. 29 We solve the problem of selection into ML status (states either always had, never had or had and then removed the ML) using DDD. 14

15 3.2.1 Candidates Platform We start by characterizing the optimal platform derived as a solution of the Bayesian game of three stages. Proposition 1. The optimal position of candidate j on issue n, yjn, is a convex combination between the average voter position in the state X n and the party s bliss point Y jn with a drift proportional to the swing-position covariance σ n. The master lever increases the weight of the party s bliss point Y jn and the effect of the swingposition covariance σ n. The statement follows directly from the following expression derived in the Appendix (see Proof of Proposition 1 in appendix A.1) y jn = for all n, where α n 2γ n /ω n. 1 µp 1 µp + α n X n + α n 1 µp + α n Y jn + µσ n 1 µp + α n (12) When the ML is introduced voters are diverted from position voting. This implies, on the one hand, that the candidate s position has a smaller effect on the voters behavior and thus the party can choose a loyal candidate. On the other hand, since partisan voters use the ML, swing votes get a higher weight in position voting. Therefore, the party has to pay increased attention to swing voters preferences. We start by discussing these effects as they appear in (12). First effect: Party loyalty. To pin down the first effect, we focus on a state where the voter s partisanship status and her position on issue n do non-correlated (σ n = 0). (As an example take any 0-symmetric distribution of positions x i and let partisanship p i be an even function of the position, i.e., p i (x i ) = p i ( x i )). In this case, the optimal senator position is a convex combination of that of the average voter and the party bliss point, irrespective of the existence of the master lever. 15

16 However, in the presence of the ML the party can afford to choose a candidate whose views on the issue conform better with the party s views. This effect is stronger in more partisan states, supporting the conclusion from Kirkland (2014). However in an extreme conservative state, where Y Dn < Y Rn < X n, introducing the master lever leads the Republican party to choose instead a more moderate candidate. The same is true for the Democratic party in an extremely liberal state, where X n < Y Dn < Y Rn. Second effect: Following the swing voter. Now let us drop the assumption of zero covariance. In states with few partisan voters introducing the master lever will force the party to follow the direction of the swing voter. The reasoning is as follows. Suppose that holding more liberal (left-wing) views is associated with being a partisan and, therefore, associated with using the master lever. Since ML attracts left-wing voters, the average position of those who through the ballot and judge the candidates by their political positions shifts to the right. Hence, the optimal candidate s position must satisfy a more right-wing voter when ML is introduced. In other words, rightwing swing voters become decisive in voting by position. Thus, when σ n is positive the ML effect is also positive. If instead σ n is negative, the argument is symmetric: since swing voters tend to the left, then so does the average voter among those who pay attention to candidates platforms. Therefore, the party can increase the winning probability by choosing a more left-wing candidate. Note that since σ n can be viewed as a proxy for heterogeneity in an asymmetric state, the swing voter effect increases if the voters in a state hold more extreme views. Total effect. The direction of the total effect of the master lever depends on the relation between the effects of party loyalty and swing voter, which may reinforce or counteract each other. The direction of the total effect is determined by a single intuitive inequality: Introducing the master lever results in a right shift of y jn if and only if α n Y α n+1 jn + 1 X α n+1 n > Xn P. In particular, if both the party and the average 16

17 voter are more conservative than the partisan voter, then the ML results in a right shift. If both are more liberal than the partisan voter, then the ML results in a left shift. When neither is true, the ML effect depends on the partisan voter s position relative to a convex combination between the party and the average voter. The effects of party loyalty, swing voter and the total effects are discussed formally in appendix A.1 Lemmas 1, 2, and Effect on Vote Share While both parties choose their candidates position to maximize the share of votes they get, one of the parties will have an advantage due to partisanship support and the distribution of voters positions in the state. The master lever has a differential effect on relative importance of these determinants of vote share. Proposition 2. The Republican (Democratic) party gets more votes in the state where (i) the Republican (Democratic) party has more partisan support, (ii) the swing voter is more conservative (liberal) than the state s average voter, and (iii) the average voter s bliss point is to the right (left) of the average between the parties bliss points. The master lever increases the effect of (i) and (ii), and decreases the effect of (iii) in the number of votes recieved by the parties. The determinants of the parties success in the election, such as voters positions and partisanship, have the obvious effects. The party that is in one way or another closer to the electorate gets a larger number of votes. What is more surprising is that the master lever has a differential effect on these determinants. While it reinforces the role of partisanship and the covariance effect, it devalues the advantage of position proximity between the state s average voter and the party, ceters paribus, in particular given the same partisan support. What does it actually mean, to fix partisanship and covariance, while shifting the average position, say, to the right? This can be achieved by introducing a uniform right shift in all voters positions without changing their 17

18 partisanship status. The claim of the proposition is that the Republican party would benefit more from such a right shift if the master lever is absent. The intuition for the result is as follows. ML makes both partisanship and swing voters more decisive in the election, while the position of the average voter becomes less important, since fewer voters elect by position. Remark that our result has important implications on the parties target audiences in states with different ML status. In non-ml states the parties will try non-discriminatorily to affect the positions of voters in a states through mass media outlets that reach a wide audience. In ML states, however, the parties will target a specific group: the swing voters. In ML states the parties can thus achieve higher vote shares by using the same amount resources in a more focused way Compound Effect: Expected Position of the Elected Senator Knowing the optimal positions of candidates and vote shares we can evaluate the expected position of the election winner. y n = V j y jn + (1 V j ) y jn. (13) The expected platform of the election winner y is a convex combination of the endogenous positions of the Republican and Democratic candidates, where respective vote shares serve as weights. 30 Proposition 3. Consider two states that differ in the ML status, but are equivalent otherwise. In expectation, the winner in the ML state is more right-(left-)wing on an issue than the winner in the non-ml state if (i) the states are red (blue) (ii) the swing voter tends to be right-(left-)wing, (iii) the average voter is left-(right-)wing, and (iv) the average and the swing voter agree with the Republican (Democratic) party 30 In a model with aggregate noise, vote shares represent the winning probabilities; in this case (13) is the mathematical expectation of the election winner s position. 18

19 on other issues. This finding sheds light on the interplay between the results we obtained in propostions 1 and 2. The effect of the master lever on the ultimate position of the senator comes through both the determination of the winning party and and the shift in candidates positions. The party with larger partisan support is more likely to win in an ML state and therefore the elected candidate is more likely to represent this party and its platform. The same is true of the party that attracts voters on the whole set of issues. However, as we know from Proposition 2, ML makes the average voter less decisive in an election, therefore the winning candidate in a non-ml state will better represent the average voter s views. The swing voter effect works similarly on both candidates, and thus on the elected senator. 4 Empirics In this section, we identify the effect of the ML on an elected senator s position and party and use the theory to account for the mechanism behind our findings. We focus only on elected senators as this is what we can observe in the data, and throughout we discuss any issues arising from the lack of information on the losing candidate s platform. 4.1 Data We use data from the 87th ( ) to the 112th ( ) Congresses and their preceding elections. Our main dependent variable is taken from Poole and Rosenthal s DW-NOMINATE scores, which summarize a senator s position, using her (roll-call) voting history, into a two-dimensional vector for each congress. 31 The first dimension 31 See Poole and Rosenthal (2015). DW stands for dynamic weighted and allows for cross-congress comparisons. The scores are from around -1 to around 1 (some observations outside the interval), and we have converted them from 0 to

20 is the one that explains most of the variation in votes and the second one, perpendicular to the first, is set to explain the rest of the variation (Carroll et al. (2009)). We use only the former and it corresponds to y j in the theory. 32 Moreover, we construct the following senator variables using information on the US Senate website and the CQ Press Guide to US Elections: their party, year(s) of election, years in Senate, whether they were an incumbent, appointed into office (i.e. not elected) or did not complete a full term. For each senator we also note the position and characteristics of the senator in power (SIP), i.e. the one was not up for election in the same year. State-level data on the average voter position, X in the theory, is taken from Enns and Koch (2013). 33 They combine select questions of all available public opinion polls into a two-dimensional dynamic state policy mood on the size and scope of government. This is in contrast with our variable for senators that sums up positions on all issues. However, as voter beliefs on the role of the government have direct implications on most Senate policies, we assume that the two policy spaces are comparable. 34 As with the DW-NOMINATE scores, the policy mood has a major and a (orthogonal) minor component, which is weak in explaining voter opinion and which we do not use. Enns and Koch (2013) also create state-level party identification variables (fractions of self-declared Democrat, Republican and non-partisan voters) that we use both as controls and as a way to classify states into red (mostly Republicans), blue (mostly Democrats), swing (mostly non-partisans) and purple (almost equal and high numbers of both Democrat and Republican partisans). Appendix A.2 gives the precise empirical definition of this partisanship classification. We also create a positional 32 Poole and Rosenthal (2007) find that after 1978 the one main dimension is sufficient in explaining Congress member behavior. If we do use the second dimension, which captures deviations from a senator s main bliss point, the effect of the ML becomes insignificant. 33 It varies from 0 (left-wing) to 100 (right-wing). 34 This assumption is not essential for the identification. 20

21 classification, which separates states into extreme left-wing, moderate and extreme right-wing states, depending on the position of the average voter with respect to the parties bliss points (see appendix A.2). We define the latter as the median DW- NOMINATE score of all elected members of each party for a specific Congress. 35 Note also the Democratic party used to be internally divided. In some southern states its members were representing more right-wing views, as opposed to the North. After the passage of the Civil Rights Act of 1964 and the Voting Rights Act of 1965 the party division slowly dissipated. 36 Mapping this to the theory, it suggests potentially two sub-parties with two different bliss points. To allow for this possibility, we create a dummy variable southd that takes the value 1 when considering one of these originally deviant states. 37 Lastly, we construct our own data on the existence of the ML per state and Congress, which we compare with that of Klarner (2010) for corroboration Summary Statistics In the 26 Congresses that we examine, there are 894 senators up for election, 39 a total of 2620 observations (all senators, all Congresses) and 423 unique senators (excludes incumbents), belonging to either the Democratic or the Republican party. 40 The left graph of figure 1 depicts the decrease in the number of states with a ML over time, and the right one the evolution of the average position of elected senators per party. The distance between the two parties defines the polarization in 35 We use these classifications in section 4.5 when employing the theory to understand our empirical findings. We point out that a state can move across classes from one election to another, and also that these classes are based on self-declared voter opinions and not on actual votes. 36 See McCarty et al. (1997) for an analysis. 37 a. They are Arkansas, Georgia, Kentucky, Louisiana, Mississippi, North Carolina, Oklahoma, South Carolina, Tennessee, Texas and Virginia. b. For convenience we will call non-southd states, northern. 38 In the contradicting cases we found sample ballots or other evidence to deal with the discrepancy. Note also that Washington, DC does not elect senators. 39 Before each Congress there is normally at most one seat up for election per state. 40 We have removed the very few observations of Conservative and Independent party senators. 21

22 the Senate, which has been increasing. 41 As it can be seen here, and consistent with previous findings, the Republican party seems to be the stronger driving force of the polarization. 42 # States Year Average Position Year # States w/ ML DEM REP Notes - Left: Number of States with ML over time. Right: Evolution of average party position in the Senate, from left (0) to right-wing (100). Source: Data from Poole and Rosenthal (2015) Figure 1: ML Presence & Senate Polarization On the left panel of figure 2, we show the evolution of the average senatorial position per party, separating states by whether or not they offer a ML on their ballots. 43 It is evident that for the Republican party a straight ticket option is correlated with more right-wing senators (closer to 100), whereas for the Democratic party the relationship, if any, is not clear. The right graph displays the fraction of Democratic senators, by ML presence. Keeping in mind that there is a lot of variation across periods away from both fitted lines, we still see that in states without a ML there is not much change in the fraction of representatives by party over time, which is about equally split. For ML states, however, in early periods the Democratic party seems to be benefiting from its presence, whereas over time, as the set of states with the option decreases, there is stronger representation of the Republican party. 41 There are different definitions of polarization used in the literature, we picked one for illustration. 42 See McCarty et al. (2006). 43 Note that the sets of states with and without ML changes over time (figure 1). 22

23 Average Position % Elected Senators Year Year DEM ML DEM no ML REP ML REP no ML DEM ML DEM no ML Notes - Left: Evolution of average party position in the Senate separating states by ML presence; positions vary from left (0) to right-wing (100). Right: Fraction of elected senators that are Democrats by ML presence. Source: Data from Poole and Rosenthal (2015) Figure 2: Positions and Party of Elected Senators by ML Presence On the flip side of the market, we have the voters. Figure 3 shows the evolution of self-declared positions and partisanship of voters by ML presence, on the left and right graphs respectively. Voters do not seem to be systematically different across types of states, with an exception towards the end of the time period. 44 Moreover, as we discuss in section 4.1, we have created partisanship and positional classifications of states since the predictions of the theory may vary within each. 45 States can move across classes from one period to the next, and table 1 displays the number of states, in the whole time period, per class and ML. Note first that the latter is significantly present in all subcases. Second, the skewness observed across positional classes (more extreme left than extreme right-wing states) should be viewed with caution as the definitions of voter and senator positions, that determine this classification, do not perfectly align Note that the remaining fraction of voters missing from the right graph are self-declared swings (non-partisans). 45 Definitions in Appendix A See section 4.5 for a discussion. 23

24 Average Position Year % Partisans Year Voters ML Voters no ML % DEM ML % REP ML % DEM no ML % REP no ML Notes - Left: Evolution of self-declared average voter position by ML presence; positions vary from left (0) to rightwing (100). Right: Fractions of Republican and Democrat partisans by ML presence. Source: Data from Enns and Koch (2013) Figure 3: Positions and Party of Voters by ML Presence Lastly, figure 4 includes scatter-plots depicting the correlation between the average voter position and different fractions of partisanship types across all states. As expected, a higher fraction of Democratic voters corresponds to a more left-wing average voter position (top right graph), and vice versa for the Republican voters (top left), although in this case the relationship is not as clear. In terms of partisan and swing voters, there is no ex-ante reason to expect a specific direction, but we notice that a higher fraction of partisans is associated with leftist states (bottom left), whereas more swing voters imply a more right-wing state (bottom right). These correlations are key in explaining our empirical findings. 4.3 Identification In order to identify the effects of the ML on elected senators we will employ a triple difference estimator (DDD). The treatment is whether or not a state offers a straight ticket voting option on their ballots in a specific election. There are two kinds of 24

25 Table 1: Number of States by Classes & ML Type ML = 0 ML = 1 Total Red Blue Swing Purple Extreme Left Moderate Extreme Right Total Notes: Number of states by ML, partisanship and positional classes; definitions in appendix A.2. Source: Data from Poole and Rosenthal (2015) and Enns and Koch (2013) states in our sample, nonparticipants, i.e. states that never had a ML (21 states), and participant states. The latter are split into stayers, that always had the ML (15 states) and leavers, those that originally offered the option and then abolished it during the sample period (14 states), so that overall we have three groups of states. 47 Selection Bias. Whether or not a state offers the ML is a state-level decision, the result of local politics, and arguably of federal-level party politics as well. 48 The same forces behind this selection bias affect also the choice of senatorial candidates and thus our dependent variables. Since we do not have pre-treatment data for participants (i.e. there are no states that introduced the ML after 1960) we cannot use simple difference-in-difference (DD from now on) to control for time-invariant group effects. However, we do have data on leaver states after they removed the ML, and they can be used as a control group. We also account for the possibility of economy-wide changes that could affect stayers and leavers differently, in the absence of the ML, by comparing both of these groups to nonparticipant states. In particular, as in Ravallion et al. (2005), the DDD estimator, is the difference 47 a. We are using the terminology of Ravallion et al. (2005). b. Michigan, Oklahoma and Texas that removed the ML only for one year are treated as stayers. 48 For example, a popular media opinion is that the party that is losing the state is the one pushing for the removal of the ML. 25

26 X vs % REP X vs % DEM X X % X vs % Partisans % X vs % Swings X % X % Notes: Scatter plots of average voter positions, from left (0) to right-wing (100) vs fractions of republican (top left), democrat (top right), partisan (bottom left) and swing (bottom right) voters, in all state-congress combinations. Source: Data from Enns and Koch (2013) Figure 4: Average Voter Position and Partisanship Per State between the DD of stayers over nonparticipants and the DD of leavers over nonparticipants (left panel in figure 5). They show that this estimator isolates the treatment effect of the ML as long as the following hold. Identifying Assumptions (IA). Conditional on state and Congress characteristics, 1. there is no selection into removing the ML, and 2. there are no lasting effects of the ML after it is removed. The right panel in figure 5 shows the implications of these in the simple case where there is one date of removal for all leaver states. The assumptions guarantee that leavers are the right control group, so that the DDD estimator is not picking up 26

27 any leaver effects. Condition (1) implies that all participant states experience the same effects of the ML regardless of whether or not it is removed in the future, and (2) that post-ml removal leavers are behaving like non-participants states. To sum up, as the graph shows, we need leavers to have common trends with stayers before the removal of the ML and with non-participants after. We verify these conditions in section 4.6. DDD stayers (ML always) DD Identifying Assumptions y stayers nonparticipants (no ML) DDD leavers DD leavers (ML, then no ML) Figure 5: Identification remove ML nonparticipants t Specification & Clustering of Errors The corresponding regression framework is the following. Let j denote the party, s the state and t the Congress: y jst = β 0 + β 1 ML st + Controls jst + η s + η t + η p + η pj t + ε jst (14) where ML st is the treatment dummy, η s, η t, η p and p jt are state, Congress and party fixed effects and a party trend. 49 We cluster the errors at the senator-level, assuming thus that there are unobservables for each senator that may affect her position. For example her charisma may allow her further positional deviations from the voters 49 In the full specification (column (5) of table 2), we include interaction effects of the controls with the ML as we know that the parties are facing different tradeoffs and could be moving in opposite directions. We also take this into consideration when verifying the identifying assumptions. 27

One Tick and You re Out: The Effects of the. Master Lever on Senators Positions

One Tick and You re Out: The Effects of the. Master Lever on Senators Positions One Tick and You re Out: The Effects of the Master Lever on Senators Positions Olga Gorelkina University of Liverpool, Liverpool Ioanna Grypari Max Planck Institute, Bonn This Version: December 2016 Abstract

More information

Congressional Gridlock: The Effects of the Master Lever

Congressional Gridlock: The Effects of the Master Lever Congressional Gridlock: The Effects of the Master Lever Olga Gorelkina Max Planck Institute, Bonn Ioanna Grypari Max Planck Institute, Bonn Preliminary & Incomplete February 11, 2015 Abstract This paper

More information

Political Economics II Spring Lectures 4-5 Part II Partisan Politics and Political Agency. Torsten Persson, IIES

Political Economics II Spring Lectures 4-5 Part II Partisan Politics and Political Agency. Torsten Persson, IIES Lectures 4-5_190213.pdf Political Economics II Spring 2019 Lectures 4-5 Part II Partisan Politics and Political Agency Torsten Persson, IIES 1 Introduction: Partisan Politics Aims continue exploring policy

More information

The Case of the Disappearing Bias: A 2014 Update to the Gerrymandering or Geography Debate

The Case of the Disappearing Bias: A 2014 Update to the Gerrymandering or Geography Debate The Case of the Disappearing Bias: A 2014 Update to the Gerrymandering or Geography Debate Nicholas Goedert Lafayette College goedertn@lafayette.edu May, 2015 ABSTRACT: This note observes that the pro-republican

More information

Supplementary Materials for Strategic Abstention in Proportional Representation Systems (Evidence from Multiple Countries)

Supplementary Materials for Strategic Abstention in Proportional Representation Systems (Evidence from Multiple Countries) Supplementary Materials for Strategic Abstention in Proportional Representation Systems (Evidence from Multiple Countries) Guillem Riambau July 15, 2018 1 1 Construction of variables and descriptive statistics.

More information

1 Electoral Competition under Certainty

1 Electoral Competition under Certainty 1 Electoral Competition under Certainty We begin with models of electoral competition. This chapter explores electoral competition when voting behavior is deterministic; the following chapter considers

More information

Game theory and applications: Lecture 12

Game theory and applications: Lecture 12 Game theory and applications: Lecture 12 Adam Szeidl December 6, 2018 Outline for today 1 A political theory of populism 2 Game theory in economics 1 / 12 1. A Political Theory of Populism Acemoglu, Egorov

More information

Coalition Governments and Political Rents

Coalition Governments and Political Rents Coalition Governments and Political Rents Dr. Refik Emre Aytimur Georg-August-Universität Göttingen January 01 Abstract We analyze the impact of coalition governments on the ability of political competition

More information

The California Primary and Redistricting

The California Primary and Redistricting The California Primary and Redistricting This study analyzes what is the important impact of changes in the primary voting rules after a Congressional and Legislative Redistricting. Under a citizen s committee,

More information

Supporting Information Political Quid Pro Quo Agreements: An Experimental Study

Supporting Information Political Quid Pro Quo Agreements: An Experimental Study Supporting Information Political Quid Pro Quo Agreements: An Experimental Study Jens Großer Florida State University and IAS, Princeton Ernesto Reuben Columbia University and IZA Agnieszka Tymula New York

More information

Sampling Equilibrium, with an Application to Strategic Voting Martin J. Osborne 1 and Ariel Rubinstein 2 September 12th, 2002.

Sampling Equilibrium, with an Application to Strategic Voting Martin J. Osborne 1 and Ariel Rubinstein 2 September 12th, 2002. Sampling Equilibrium, with an Application to Strategic Voting Martin J. Osborne 1 and Ariel Rubinstein 2 September 12th, 2002 Abstract We suggest an equilibrium concept for a strategic model with a large

More information

The Interdependence of Sequential Senate Elections: Evidence from

The Interdependence of Sequential Senate Elections: Evidence from The Interdependence of Sequential Senate Elections: Evidence from 1946-2002 Daniel M. Butler Stanford University Department of Political Science September 27, 2004 Abstract Among U.S. federal elections,

More information

Components of party polarization in the US House of Representatives

Components of party polarization in the US House of Representatives Article Components of party polarization in the US House of Representatives Journal of Theoretical Politics 1 27 ÓThe Author(s) 215 Reprints and permissions: sagepub.co.uk/journalspermissions.nav DOI:

More information

Primary Elections and Partisan Polarization in the U.S. Congress

Primary Elections and Partisan Polarization in the U.S. Congress Primary Elections and Partisan Polarization in the U.S. Congress The Harvard community has made this article openly available. Please share how this access benefits you. Your story matters. Citation Published

More information

Party Labels and Information: The Implications of Contagion in Coelection Environments

Party Labels and Information: The Implications of Contagion in Coelection Environments Party Labels and Information: The Implications of Contagion in Coelection Environments Yosh Halberstam B. Pablo Montagnes March 13, 2009 Preliminary and Incomplete Abstract In related empirical work, we

More information

Political Science 10: Introduction to American Politics Week 10

Political Science 10: Introduction to American Politics Week 10 Political Science 10: Introduction to American Politics Week 10 Taylor Carlson tfeenstr@ucsd.edu March 17, 2017 Carlson POLI 10-Week 10 March 17, 2017 1 / 22 Plan for the Day Go over learning outcomes

More information

Following the Leader: The Impact of Presidential Campaign Visits on Legislative Support for the President's Policy Preferences

Following the Leader: The Impact of Presidential Campaign Visits on Legislative Support for the President's Policy Preferences University of Colorado, Boulder CU Scholar Undergraduate Honors Theses Honors Program Spring 2011 Following the Leader: The Impact of Presidential Campaign Visits on Legislative Support for the President's

More information

The League of Women Voters of Pennsylvania et al v. The Commonwealth of Pennsylvania et al. Nolan McCarty

The League of Women Voters of Pennsylvania et al v. The Commonwealth of Pennsylvania et al. Nolan McCarty The League of Women Voters of Pennsylvania et al v. The Commonwealth of Pennsylvania et al. I. Introduction Nolan McCarty Susan Dod Brown Professor of Politics and Public Affairs Chair, Department of Politics

More information

Forecasting the 2018 Midterm Election using National Polls and District Information

Forecasting the 2018 Midterm Election using National Polls and District Information Forecasting the 2018 Midterm Election using National Polls and District Information Joseph Bafumi, Dartmouth College Robert S. Erikson, Columbia University Christopher Wlezien, University of Texas at Austin

More information

Model of Voting. February 15, Abstract. This paper uses United States congressional district level data to identify how incumbency,

Model of Voting. February 15, Abstract. This paper uses United States congressional district level data to identify how incumbency, U.S. Congressional Vote Empirics: A Discrete Choice Model of Voting Kyle Kretschman The University of Texas Austin kyle.kretschman@mail.utexas.edu Nick Mastronardi United States Air Force Academy nickmastronardi@gmail.com

More information

Intra-Party Disagreement and Inter-Party Polarization

Intra-Party Disagreement and Inter-Party Polarization Intra-Party Disagreement and Inter-Party Polarization Mattias Polborn James M. Snyder January 13, 2016 Abstract We develop a theory of legislative competition in which voters care about national party

More information

Partisan Nation: The Rise of Affective Partisan Polarization in the American Electorate

Partisan Nation: The Rise of Affective Partisan Polarization in the American Electorate Partisan Nation: The Rise of Affective Partisan Polarization in the American Electorate Alan I. Abramowitz Department of Political Science Emory University Abstract Partisan conflict has reached new heights

More information

The Case of the Disappearing Bias: A 2014 Update to the Gerrymandering or Geography Debate

The Case of the Disappearing Bias: A 2014 Update to the Gerrymandering or Geography Debate The Case of the Disappearing Bias: A 2014 Update to the Gerrymandering or Geography Debate Nicholas Goedert Lafayette College goedertn@lafayette.edu November, 2015 ABSTRACT: This note observes that the

More information

Women as Policy Makers: Evidence from a Randomized Policy Experiment in India

Women as Policy Makers: Evidence from a Randomized Policy Experiment in India Women as Policy Makers: Evidence from a Randomized Policy Experiment in India Chattopadhayay and Duflo (Econometrica 2004) Presented by Nicolas Guida Johnson and Ngoc Nguyen Nov 8, 2018 Introduction Research

More information

UC Davis UC Davis Previously Published Works

UC Davis UC Davis Previously Published Works UC Davis UC Davis Previously Published Works Title Constitutional design and 2014 senate election outcomes Permalink https://escholarship.org/uc/item/8kx5k8zk Journal Forum (Germany), 12(4) Authors Highton,

More information

The Effect of Electoral Geography on Competitive Elections and Partisan Gerrymandering

The Effect of Electoral Geography on Competitive Elections and Partisan Gerrymandering The Effect of Electoral Geography on Competitive Elections and Partisan Gerrymandering Jowei Chen University of Michigan jowei@umich.edu http://www.umich.edu/~jowei November 12, 2012 Abstract: How does

More information

Third Party Voting: Vote One s Heart or One s Mind?

Third Party Voting: Vote One s Heart or One s Mind? Third Party Voting: Vote One s Heart or One s Mind? Emekcan Yucel Job Market Paper This Version: October 30, 2016 Latest Version: Click Here Abstract In this paper, I propose non-instrumental benefits

More information

Socially Optimal Districting: An Empirical Investigation

Socially Optimal Districting: An Empirical Investigation Preliminary Draft September 2005 Socially Optimal Districting: An Empirical Investigation Abstract This paper provides an empirical exploration of the potential gains from socially optimal districting.

More information

Capture and Governance at Local and National Levels

Capture and Governance at Local and National Levels Capture and Governance at Local and National Levels By PRANAB BARDHAN AND DILIP MOOKHERJEE* The literature on public choice and political economy is characterized by numerous theoretical analyses of capture

More information

3 Electoral Competition

3 Electoral Competition 3 Electoral Competition We now turn to a discussion of two-party electoral competition in representative democracy. The underlying policy question addressed in this chapter, as well as the remaining chapters

More information

USING MULTI-MEMBER-DISTRICT ELECTIONS TO ESTIMATE THE SOURCES OF THE INCUMBENCY ADVANTAGE 1

USING MULTI-MEMBER-DISTRICT ELECTIONS TO ESTIMATE THE SOURCES OF THE INCUMBENCY ADVANTAGE 1 USING MULTI-MEMBER-DISTRICT ELECTIONS TO ESTIMATE THE SOURCES OF THE INCUMBENCY ADVANTAGE 1 Shigeo Hirano Department of Political Science Columbia University James M. Snyder, Jr. Departments of Political

More information

The Provision of Public Goods Under Alternative. Electoral Incentives

The Provision of Public Goods Under Alternative. Electoral Incentives The Provision of Public Goods Under Alternative Electoral Incentives Alessandro Lizzeri and Nicola Persico March 10, 2000 American Economic Review, forthcoming ABSTRACT Politicians who care about the spoils

More information

Preferential votes and minority representation in open list proportional representation systems

Preferential votes and minority representation in open list proportional representation systems Soc Choice Welf (018) 50:81 303 https://doi.org/10.1007/s00355-017-1084- ORIGINAL PAPER Preferential votes and minority representation in open list proportional representation systems Margherita Negri

More information

Strategic Partisanship: Party Priorities, Agenda Control and the Decline of Bipartisan Cooperation in the House

Strategic Partisanship: Party Priorities, Agenda Control and the Decline of Bipartisan Cooperation in the House Strategic Partisanship: Party Priorities, Agenda Control and the Decline of Bipartisan Cooperation in the House Laurel Harbridge Assistant Professor, Department of Political Science Faculty Fellow, Institute

More information

Do two parties represent the US? Clustering analysis of US public ideology survey

Do two parties represent the US? Clustering analysis of US public ideology survey Do two parties represent the US? Clustering analysis of US public ideology survey Louisa Lee 1 and Siyu Zhang 2, 3 Advised by: Vicky Chuqiao Yang 1 1 Department of Engineering Sciences and Applied Mathematics,

More information

Classical papers: Osborbe and Slivinski (1996) and Besley and Coate (1997)

Classical papers: Osborbe and Slivinski (1996) and Besley and Coate (1997) The identity of politicians is endogenized Typical approach: any citizen may enter electoral competition at a cost. There is no pre-commitment on the platforms, and winner implements his or her ideal policy.

More information

How Political Parties Shape Electoral Competition

How Political Parties Shape Electoral Competition How Political Parties Shape Electoral Competition Nicolas Motz Department of Economics, University College London (UCL) This version: 20 Sep 2014 Latest draft: www.nmotz.com/nmpartyf.pdf Abstract Across

More information

THREATS TO SUE AND COST DIVISIBILITY UNDER ASYMMETRIC INFORMATION. Alon Klement. Discussion Paper No /2000

THREATS TO SUE AND COST DIVISIBILITY UNDER ASYMMETRIC INFORMATION. Alon Klement. Discussion Paper No /2000 ISSN 1045-6333 THREATS TO SUE AND COST DIVISIBILITY UNDER ASYMMETRIC INFORMATION Alon Klement Discussion Paper No. 273 1/2000 Harvard Law School Cambridge, MA 02138 The Center for Law, Economics, and Business

More information

What is The Probability Your Vote will Make a Difference?

What is The Probability Your Vote will Make a Difference? Berkeley Law From the SelectedWorks of Aaron Edlin 2009 What is The Probability Your Vote will Make a Difference? Andrew Gelman, Columbia University Nate Silver Aaron S. Edlin, University of California,

More information

SPECIALIZED LEARNING AND POLITICAL POLARIZATION

SPECIALIZED LEARNING AND POLITICAL POLARIZATION SPECIALIZED LEARNING AND POLITICAL POLARIZATION Sevgi Yuksel New York University December 24, 2014 For latest version click on https://files.nyu.edu/sy683/public/jmp.pdf ABSTRACT This paper presents a

More information

Corruption and Political Competition

Corruption and Political Competition Corruption and Political Competition Richard Damania Adelaide University Erkan Yalçin Yeditepe University October 24, 2005 Abstract There is a growing evidence that political corruption is often closely

More information

The disadvantages of winning an election.

The disadvantages of winning an election. The disadvantages of winning an election. Enriqueta Aragones Institut d Anàlisi Econòmica, CSIC Santiago Sánchez-Pagés University of Edinburgh January 2010 Abstract After an election, the winner has to

More information

Do Individual Heterogeneity and Spatial Correlation Matter?

Do Individual Heterogeneity and Spatial Correlation Matter? Do Individual Heterogeneity and Spatial Correlation Matter? An Innovative Approach to the Characterisation of the European Political Space. Giovanna Iannantuoni, Elena Manzoni and Francesca Rossi EXTENDED

More information

A positive correlation between turnout and plurality does not refute the rational voter model

A positive correlation between turnout and plurality does not refute the rational voter model Quality & Quantity 26: 85-93, 1992. 85 O 1992 Kluwer Academic Publishers. Printed in the Netherlands. Note A positive correlation between turnout and plurality does not refute the rational voter model

More information

Pork Barrel as a Signaling Tool: The Case of US Environmental Policy

Pork Barrel as a Signaling Tool: The Case of US Environmental Policy Pork Barrel as a Signaling Tool: The Case of US Environmental Policy Grantham Research Institute and LSE Cities, London School of Economics IAERE February 2016 Research question Is signaling a driving

More information

Why Are The Members Of Each Party So Polarized Today

Why Are The Members Of Each Party So Polarized Today Why Are The Members Of Each Party So Polarized Today The study also suggests that in America today, it is virtually impossible to live in an Are more likely to follow issue-based groups, rather than political

More information

Judicial Elections and Their Implications in North Carolina. By Samantha Hovaniec

Judicial Elections and Their Implications in North Carolina. By Samantha Hovaniec Judicial Elections and Their Implications in North Carolina By Samantha Hovaniec A Thesis submitted to the faculty of the University of North Carolina in partial fulfillment of the requirements of a degree

More information

The Impact of Unions on Municipal Elections and Fiscal Policies in U.S. Cities

The Impact of Unions on Municipal Elections and Fiscal Policies in U.S. Cities The Impact of Unions on Municipal Elections and Fiscal Policies in U.S. Cities Holger Sieg University of Pennsylvania and NBER Yu Wang University of Pennsylvania Prepared for the Carnegie-NYU-Rochester

More information

Applying Ranked Choice Voting to Congressional Elections. The Case for RCV with the Top Four Primary and Multi-Member Districts. Rob Richie, FairVote

Applying Ranked Choice Voting to Congressional Elections. The Case for RCV with the Top Four Primary and Multi-Member Districts. Rob Richie, FairVote Applying Ranked Choice Voting to Congressional Elections The Case for RCV with the Top Four Primary and Multi-Member Districts Rob Richie, FairVote American Exceptionalism: Inescapable Realities for Reformers

More information

AMERICAN JOURNAL OF UNDERGRADUATE RESEARCH VOL. 3 NO. 4 (2005)

AMERICAN JOURNAL OF UNDERGRADUATE RESEARCH VOL. 3 NO. 4 (2005) , Partisanship and the Post Bounce: A MemoryBased Model of Post Presidential Candidate Evaluations Part II Empirical Results Justin Grimmer Department of Mathematics and Computer Science Wabash College

More information

Partisan Advantage and Competitiveness in Illinois Redistricting

Partisan Advantage and Competitiveness in Illinois Redistricting Partisan Advantage and Competitiveness in Illinois Redistricting An Updated and Expanded Look By: Cynthia Canary & Kent Redfield June 2015 Using data from the 2014 legislative elections and digging deeper

More information

Research Statement. Jeffrey J. Harden. 2 Dissertation Research: The Dimensions of Representation

Research Statement. Jeffrey J. Harden. 2 Dissertation Research: The Dimensions of Representation Research Statement Jeffrey J. Harden 1 Introduction My research agenda includes work in both quantitative methodology and American politics. In methodology I am broadly interested in developing and evaluating

More information

Campaign Contributions as Valence

Campaign Contributions as Valence Campaign Contributions as Valence Tim Lambie-Hanson Suffolk University June 11, 2011 Tim Lambie-Hanson (Suffolk University) Campaign Contributions as Valence June 11, 2011 1 / 16 Motivation Under what

More information

Voluntary Voting: Costs and Benefits

Voluntary Voting: Costs and Benefits Voluntary Voting: Costs and Benefits Vijay Krishna and John Morgan May 21, 2012 Abstract We compare voluntary and compulsory voting in a Condorcet-type model in which voters have identical preferences

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES HOW ELECTIONS MATTER: THEORY AND EVIDENCE FROM ENVIRONMENTAL POLICY. John A. List Daniel M. Sturm

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES HOW ELECTIONS MATTER: THEORY AND EVIDENCE FROM ENVIRONMENTAL POLICY. John A. List Daniel M. Sturm NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES HOW ELECTIONS MATTER: THEORY AND EVIDENCE FROM ENVIRONMENTAL POLICY John A. List Daniel M. Sturm Working Paper 10609 http://www.nber.org/papers/w10609 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC

More information

Appendices for Elections and the Regression-Discontinuity Design: Lessons from Close U.S. House Races,

Appendices for Elections and the Regression-Discontinuity Design: Lessons from Close U.S. House Races, Appendices for Elections and the Regression-Discontinuity Design: Lessons from Close U.S. House Races, 1942 2008 Devin M. Caughey Jasjeet S. Sekhon 7/20/2011 (10:34) Ph.D. candidate, Travers Department

More information

Cross-District Variation in Split-Ticket Voting

Cross-District Variation in Split-Ticket Voting Cross-District Variation in Split-Ticket Voting Daniel J. Lee Robert Lupton Department of Political Science Michigan State University January 10, 2014 Abstract We test hypotheses on split-ticket voting

More information

Median voter theorem - continuous choice

Median voter theorem - continuous choice Median voter theorem - continuous choice In most economic applications voters are asked to make a non-discrete choice - e.g. choosing taxes. In these applications the condition of single-peakedness is

More information

1. The Relationship Between Party Control, Latino CVAP and the Passage of Bills Benefitting Immigrants

1. The Relationship Between Party Control, Latino CVAP and the Passage of Bills Benefitting Immigrants The Ideological and Electoral Determinants of Laws Targeting Undocumented Migrants in the U.S. States Online Appendix In this additional methodological appendix I present some alternative model specifications

More information

'Wave riding' or 'Owning the issue': How do candidates determine campaign agendas?

'Wave riding' or 'Owning the issue': How do candidates determine campaign agendas? 'Wave riding' or 'Owning the issue': How do candidates determine campaign agendas? Mariya Burdina University of Colorado, Boulder Department of Economics October 5th, 008 Abstract In this paper I adress

More information

ONLINE APPENDIX: Why Do Voters Dismantle Checks and Balances? Extensions and Robustness

ONLINE APPENDIX: Why Do Voters Dismantle Checks and Balances? Extensions and Robustness CeNTRe for APPlieD MACRo - AND PeTRoleuM economics (CAMP) CAMP Working Paper Series No 2/2013 ONLINE APPENDIX: Why Do Voters Dismantle Checks and Balances? Extensions and Robustness Daron Acemoglu, James

More information

SIERRA LEONE 2012 ELECTIONS PROJECT PRE-ANALYSIS PLAN: INDIVIDUAL LEVEL INTERVENTIONS

SIERRA LEONE 2012 ELECTIONS PROJECT PRE-ANALYSIS PLAN: INDIVIDUAL LEVEL INTERVENTIONS SIERRA LEONE 2012 ELECTIONS PROJECT PRE-ANALYSIS PLAN: INDIVIDUAL LEVEL INTERVENTIONS PIs: Kelly Bidwell (IPA), Katherine Casey (Stanford GSB) and Rachel Glennerster (JPAL MIT) THIS DRAFT: 15 August 2013

More information

Turnover and Accountability of Appointed and Elected Judges

Turnover and Accountability of Appointed and Elected Judges Turnover and Accountability of Appointed and Elected Judges Supplementary Material Claire S.H. Lim Stanford University April 2, 11 This paper contains additional details of the data and the estimation

More information

DO VOTERS AFFECT OR ELECT POLICIES? EVIDENCE FROM THE U. S. HOUSE*

DO VOTERS AFFECT OR ELECT POLICIES? EVIDENCE FROM THE U. S. HOUSE* EVIDENCE FROM THE U. S. HOUSE* DAVID S. LEE ENRICO MORETTI MATTHEW J. BUTLER There are two fundamentally different views of the role of elections in policy formation. In one view, voters can affect candidates

More information

The relative importance of cultural and economic issues for the polarization of the U.S. electorate,

The relative importance of cultural and economic issues for the polarization of the U.S. electorate, The relative importance of cultural and economic issues for the polarization of the U.S. electorate, 1972 2008 Stefan Krasa Mattias Polborn May 10, 2011 Abstract We develop a simple model in which voters

More information

Ideological extremism and primaries.

Ideological extremism and primaries. Ideological extremism and primaries. Agustin Casas February 1, 2016 Abstract Party affiliation decisions and endogenous valence are necessary to understand the effects of nomination rules on the political

More information

Publicizing malfeasance:

Publicizing malfeasance: Publicizing malfeasance: When media facilitates electoral accountability in Mexico Horacio Larreguy, John Marshall and James Snyder Harvard University May 1, 2015 Introduction Elections are key for political

More information

POLI 300 Fall 2010 PROBLEM SET #5B: ANSWERS AND DISCUSSION

POLI 300 Fall 2010 PROBLEM SET #5B: ANSWERS AND DISCUSSION POLI 300 Fall 2010 General Comments PROBLEM SET #5B: ANSWERS AND DISCUSSION Evidently most students were able to produce SPSS frequency tables (and sometimes bar charts as well) without particular difficulty.

More information

The Robustness of Herrera, Levine and Martinelli s Policy platforms, campaign spending and voter participation

The Robustness of Herrera, Levine and Martinelli s Policy platforms, campaign spending and voter participation The Robustness of Herrera, Levine and Martinelli s Policy platforms, campaign spending and voter participation Alexander Chun June 8, 009 Abstract In this paper, I look at potential weaknesses in the electoral

More information

ON IGNORANT VOTERS AND BUSY POLITICIANS

ON IGNORANT VOTERS AND BUSY POLITICIANS Number 252 July 2015 ON IGNORANT VOTERS AND BUSY POLITICIANS R. Emre Aytimur Christian Bruns ISSN: 1439-2305 On Ignorant Voters and Busy Politicians R. Emre Aytimur University of Goettingen Christian Bruns

More information

How The Public Funding Of Elections Increases Candidate Polarization

How The Public Funding Of Elections Increases Candidate Polarization How The Public Funding Of Elections Increases Candidate Polarization Andrew B. Hall Department of Government Harvard University January 13, 2014 Abstract I show that the public funding of elections produces

More information

Immigration and Internal Mobility in Canada Appendices A and B. Appendix A: Two-step Instrumentation strategy: Procedure and detailed results

Immigration and Internal Mobility in Canada Appendices A and B. Appendix A: Two-step Instrumentation strategy: Procedure and detailed results Immigration and Internal Mobility in Canada Appendices A and B by Michel Beine and Serge Coulombe This version: February 2016 Appendix A: Two-step Instrumentation strategy: Procedure and detailed results

More information

Political Economy. Pierre Boyer. Master in Economics Fall 2018 Schedule: Every Wednesday 08:30 to 11:45. École Polytechnique - CREST

Political Economy. Pierre Boyer. Master in Economics Fall 2018 Schedule: Every Wednesday 08:30 to 11:45. École Polytechnique - CREST Political Economy Pierre Boyer École Polytechnique - CREST Master in Economics Fall 2018 Schedule: Every Wednesday 08:30 to 11:45 Boyer (École Polytechnique) Political Economy Fall 2018 1 / 18 Outline

More information

Learning and Visualizing Political Issues from Voting Records Erik Goldman, Evan Cox, Mikhail Kerzhner. Abstract

Learning and Visualizing Political Issues from Voting Records Erik Goldman, Evan Cox, Mikhail Kerzhner. Abstract Learning and Visualizing Political Issues from Voting Records Erik Goldman, Evan Cox, Mikhail Kerzhner Abstract For our project, we analyze data from US Congress voting records, a dataset that consists

More information

Purposes of Elections

Purposes of Elections Purposes of Elections o Regular free elections n guarantee mass political action n enable citizens to influence the actions of their government o Popular election confers on a government the legitimacy

More information

Enriqueta Aragones Harvard University and Universitat Pompeu Fabra Andrew Postlewaite University of Pennsylvania. March 9, 2000

Enriqueta Aragones Harvard University and Universitat Pompeu Fabra Andrew Postlewaite University of Pennsylvania. March 9, 2000 Campaign Rhetoric: a model of reputation Enriqueta Aragones Harvard University and Universitat Pompeu Fabra Andrew Postlewaite University of Pennsylvania March 9, 2000 Abstract We develop a model of infinitely

More information

Should the Democrats move to the left on economic policy?

Should the Democrats move to the left on economic policy? Should the Democrats move to the left on economic policy? Andrew Gelman Cexun Jeffrey Cai November 9, 2007 Abstract Could John Kerry have gained votes in the recent Presidential election by more clearly

More information

Determinants and Effects of Negative Advertising in Politics

Determinants and Effects of Negative Advertising in Politics Department of Economics- FEA/USP Determinants and Effects of Negative Advertising in Politics DANILO P. SOUZA MARCOS Y. NAKAGUMA WORKING PAPER SERIES Nº 2017-25 DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS, FEA-USP WORKING

More information

Chapter Four: Chamber Competitiveness, Political Polarization, and Political Parties

Chapter Four: Chamber Competitiveness, Political Polarization, and Political Parties Chapter Four: Chamber Competitiveness, Political Polarization, and Political Parties Building off of the previous chapter in this dissertation, this chapter investigates the involvement of political parties

More information

DOES GERRYMANDERING VIOLATE THE FOURTEENTH AMENDMENT?: INSIGHT FROM THE MEDIAN VOTER THEOREM

DOES GERRYMANDERING VIOLATE THE FOURTEENTH AMENDMENT?: INSIGHT FROM THE MEDIAN VOTER THEOREM DOES GERRYMANDERING VIOLATE THE FOURTEENTH AMENDMENT?: INSIGHT FROM THE MEDIAN VOTER THEOREM Craig B. McLaren University of California, Riverside Abstract This paper argues that gerrymandering understood

More information

Reviewing Procedure vs. Judging Substance: The Effect of Judicial Review on Agency Policymaking*

Reviewing Procedure vs. Judging Substance: The Effect of Judicial Review on Agency Policymaking* Reviewing Procedure vs. Judging Substance: The Effect of Judicial Review on Agency Policymaking* Ian R. Turner March 30, 2014 Abstract Bureaucratic policymaking is a central feature of the modern American

More information

The Macro Polity Updated

The Macro Polity Updated The Macro Polity Updated Robert S Erikson Columbia University rse14@columbiaedu Michael B MacKuen University of North Carolina, Chapel Hill Mackuen@emailuncedu James A Stimson University of North Carolina,

More information

Party Ideology and Policies

Party Ideology and Policies Party Ideology and Policies Matteo Cervellati University of Bologna Giorgio Gulino University of Bergamo March 31, 2017 Paolo Roberti University of Bologna Abstract We plan to study the relationship between

More information

Elite Polarization and Mass Political Engagement: Information, Alienation, and Mobilization

Elite Polarization and Mass Political Engagement: Information, Alienation, and Mobilization JOURNAL OF INTERNATIONAL AND AREA STUDIES Volume 20, Number 1, 2013, pp.89-109 89 Elite Polarization and Mass Political Engagement: Information, Alienation, and Mobilization Jae Mook Lee Using the cumulative

More information

Reputation and Rhetoric in Elections

Reputation and Rhetoric in Elections Reputation and Rhetoric in Elections Enriqueta Aragonès Institut d Anàlisi Econòmica, CSIC Andrew Postlewaite University of Pennsylvania April 11, 2005 Thomas R. Palfrey Princeton University Earlier versions

More information

What is fairness? - Justice Anthony Kennedy, Vieth v Jubelirer (2004)

What is fairness? - Justice Anthony Kennedy, Vieth v Jubelirer (2004) What is fairness? The parties have not shown us, and I have not been able to discover.... statements of principled, well-accepted rules of fairness that should govern districting. - Justice Anthony Kennedy,

More information

Pavel Yakovlev Duquesne University. Abstract

Pavel Yakovlev Duquesne University. Abstract Ideology, Shirking, and the Incumbency Advantage in the U.S. House of Representatives Pavel Yakovlev Duquesne University Abstract This paper examines how the incumbency advantage is related to ideological

More information

POLITICAL EQUILIBRIUM SOCIAL SECURITY WITH MIGRATION

POLITICAL EQUILIBRIUM SOCIAL SECURITY WITH MIGRATION POLITICAL EQUILIBRIUM SOCIAL SECURITY WITH MIGRATION Laura Marsiliani University of Durham laura.marsiliani@durham.ac.uk Thomas I. Renström University of Durham and CEPR t.i.renstrom@durham.ac.uk We analyze

More information

How Political Parties Shape Electoral Competition

How Political Parties Shape Electoral Competition How Political Parties Shape Electoral Competition Nicolas Motz Department of Economics, University College London (UCL) December 2014 Abstract This paper provides a model of party formation that can explain

More information

The Role of the Trade Policy Committee in EU Trade Policy: A Political-Economic Analysis

The Role of the Trade Policy Committee in EU Trade Policy: A Political-Economic Analysis The Role of the Trade Policy Committee in EU Trade Policy: A Political-Economic Analysis Wim Van Gestel, Christophe Crombez January 18, 2011 Abstract This paper presents a political-economic analysis of

More information

Incumbency Advantages in the Canadian Parliament

Incumbency Advantages in the Canadian Parliament Incumbency Advantages in the Canadian Parliament Chad Kendall Department of Economics University of British Columbia Marie Rekkas* Department of Economics Simon Fraser University mrekkas@sfu.ca 778-782-6793

More information

The Outlook for the 2010 Midterm Elections: How Large a Wave?

The Outlook for the 2010 Midterm Elections: How Large a Wave? The Outlook for the 2010 Midterm Elections: How Large a Wave? What is at stake? All 435 House seats 256 Democratic seats 179 Republican seats Republicans needs to gain 39 seats for majority 37 Senate seats

More information

EXTENDING THE SPHERE OF REPRESENTATION:

EXTENDING THE SPHERE OF REPRESENTATION: EXTENDING THE SPHERE OF REPRESENTATION: THE IMPACT OF FAIR REPRESENTATION VOTING ON THE IDEOLOGICAL SPECTRUM OF CONGRESS November 2013 Extend the sphere, and you take in a greater variety of parties and

More information

Online Appendix: Robustness Tests and Migration. Means

Online Appendix: Robustness Tests and Migration. Means VOL. VOL NO. ISSUE EMPLOYMENT, WAGES AND VOTER TURNOUT Online Appendix: Robustness Tests and Migration Means Online Appendix Table 1 presents the summary statistics of turnout for the five types of elections

More information

Disasters and Incumbent Electoral Fortunes: No Implications for Democratic Competence

Disasters and Incumbent Electoral Fortunes: No Implications for Democratic Competence Disasters and Incumbent Electoral Fortunes: No Implications for Democratic Competence Scott Ashworth Ethan Bueno de Mesquita February 1, 2013 Abstract A recent empirical literature shows that incumbent

More information

Illegal Migration and Policy Enforcement

Illegal Migration and Policy Enforcement Illegal Migration and Policy Enforcement Sephorah Mangin 1 and Yves Zenou 2 September 15, 2016 Abstract: Workers from a source country consider whether or not to illegally migrate to a host country. This

More information

Non-Voted Ballots and Discrimination in Florida

Non-Voted Ballots and Discrimination in Florida Non-Voted Ballots and Discrimination in Florida John R. Lott, Jr. School of Law Yale University 127 Wall Street New Haven, CT 06511 (203) 432-2366 john.lott@yale.edu revised July 15, 2001 * This paper

More information

Amy Tenhouse. Incumbency Surge: Examining the 1996 Margin of Victory for U.S. House Incumbents

Amy Tenhouse. Incumbency Surge: Examining the 1996 Margin of Victory for U.S. House Incumbents Amy Tenhouse Incumbency Surge: Examining the 1996 Margin of Victory for U.S. House Incumbents In 1996, the American public reelected 357 members to the United States House of Representatives; of those

More information

HOTELLING-DOWNS MODEL OF ELECTORAL COMPETITION AND THE OPTION TO QUIT

HOTELLING-DOWNS MODEL OF ELECTORAL COMPETITION AND THE OPTION TO QUIT HOTELLING-DOWNS MODEL OF ELECTORAL COMPETITION AND THE OPTION TO QUIT ABHIJIT SENGUPTA AND KUNAL SENGUPTA SCHOOL OF ECONOMICS AND POLITICAL SCIENCE UNIVERSITY OF SYDNEY SYDNEY, NSW 2006 AUSTRALIA Abstract.

More information

The Seventeenth Amendment, Senate Ideology, and the Growth of Government

The Seventeenth Amendment, Senate Ideology, and the Growth of Government The Seventeenth Amendment, Senate Ideology, and the Growth of Government Danko Tarabar College of Business and Economics 1601 University Ave, PO BOX 6025 West Virginia University Phone: 681-212-9983 datarabar@mix.wvu.edu

More information