University of Virginia Law School

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "University of Virginia Law School"

Transcription

1 University of Virginia Law School The John M. Olin Program in Law and Economics Working Paper Series Year 2008 Paper 46 The Fault that Lies within Our Contract Law George M. Cohen University of Virginia School of Law, This working paper is hosted by The Berkeley Electronic Press (bepress) and may not be commercially reproduced without the permission of the copyright holder. Copyright c 2008 by the author.

2 The Fault that Lies within Our Contract Law George M. Cohen Abstract Scholars and courts typically describe and defend American contract law as a system of strict liability, or liability without fault. Strict liability generally means that the reason for nonperformance does not matter in determining whether a contracting party breached. Strict liability also permeates the doctrines of contract damages, under which the reason for the breach does not matter in determining the measure of damages, and the doctrines of contract formation, under which the reason for failing to contract does not matter. In this essay, prepared for a symposium on Fault and Contract Law sponsored by the University of Michigan School of Law and to be published in the University of Michigan Law Review, I take issue with the strict liability paradigm, as I have in my prior work on contract law. In my view, the theoretical justifications for strict liability as a general paradigm for contract law oversimplify contractual intent, the relationship between intent and fault, and the nature of contractual fault. Moreover, the strict liability label is descriptively misleading, once one dips even slightly below the surface of contract doctrine. Fault shows up throughout contract law. Efforts to make contract law conform more to the strict liability paradigm and exorcise fault are wrongheaded. In any case, such efforts are doomed to fail. Fault may not be the dominant feature of contract law, but it plays an inherent, invaluable, and ineluctable supporting part. The strict liability impulse occurs when contract intent, contract terms, and contract doctrine coincide with a persuasive story of promisor fault, and when the consequences of strict liability are blunted because the promisor can easily mitigate them. But strict liability, like other contract rules, is merely a fault-based presumption. Determining the limits of that presumption means considering why parties make contract and why they do not perform them, in other words, fault. Courts and scholars should would do better to acknowledge the role of fault and think about how to use fault more effectively within the framework of contract doctrine.

3 DRAFT 5/28/08 The Fault that Lies within Our Contract Law George M. Cohen * Scholars and courts typically describe and defend American contract law as a system of strict liability, or liability without fault. 1 I disagree with that position. 2 In my view, the theoretical justifications for strict liability as a general paradigm for contract law oversimplify contractual intent, the relationship between intent and fault, and the nature of contractual fault. Moreover, the strict liability label is descriptively misleading, once one dips even slightly below the surface of contract doctrine. Efforts to make contract law conform more to the strict liability paradigm and exorcize fault are wrongheaded. In any case, such efforts are doomed to fail. Fault may not be the dominant feature of contract law, but it plays an inherent, invaluable, and ineluctable supporting part. Courts and scholars would do better to acknowledge this role and think about how to use fault more effectively within the framework of contract doctrine. The Meaning of Strict Liability in Contract Law Usually when courts or scholars label contract law a strict liability system, they are referring to a specific doctrinal area: performance and breach. Under the strict liability view, a court imposes liability on a contracting party when that party fails to honor his agreement, regardless of whether the court can attribute that failure to any Afault@ by the breaching party. 3 In the paradigmatic case, if a contracting party promises to provide a good or service and fails to deliver, or delivers a defective good or service, that party breaches the contract even if there were no reasonable precautions that party could have taken to prevent the nondelivery or defect. Strict liability means that the contract provides a Awarranty@ of results; it protects against all risk Hosted by The Berkeley Electronic Press

4 of nonperformance or imperfect performance. In short, the reason for nonperformance does not matter. Although the strict liability paradigm appears most prominently in performance and breach doctrine, the paradigm permeates most other doctrinal areas of contract law as well. Broadly speaking, the main doctrinal areas other than performance are formation and remedy. In the contract law of damages, Holmes long ago articulated the strict liability view, which holds that just as the reason for nonperformance does not matter in determining breach, the reason for the breach does not matter in determining contract damages. 4 An aggrieved party who can prove breach is entitled to a remedy that compensates him for his loss, generally defined doctrinally as protecting the expectation interest. Fault seems irrelevant to determining compensation. The strict liability label does not usually appear in connection with the law of contract formation, but formation doctrine also seems to comport with the strict liability view. In this case, however, it is the reason for failing to contract, rather than for failing to perform, that does not matter. Technically, the doctrine is one of strict nonliability rather than strict liability. The idea is the same, though the story is different. Contracts are voluntary agreements; no one is obliged to agree. So contract law generally imposes no liability unless and until the parties agree. However a court might determine whether and when parties agree, Afault@ again seems irrelevant. Justifications for Strict Liability Pronouncing contract law to be a strict liability system is, it turns out, easier than justifying such a system. Two broad types of justifications are a traditionalist or philosophical

5 approach, which focuses on faithfulness to contractual intent, and an economic or functionalist approach, which focuses on the facilitation of better contracting behavior. From a traditionalist perspective, strict liability seems to follow naturally from two simple premises. First, contract law grounds liability in the mutual intentions of the contracting parties. Second, fault is a social judgment distinct from the intentions of the parties. The tort law of accidents between strangers naturally bases liability on fault because strangers have no mutual intentions. Courts in tort cases must therefore resort to some social judgment such as fault. In contract law, by contrast, the parties themselves define the basis and scope of liability, so in theory no social judgment is necessary (other than the social judgment to enforce agreements according to the intentions of the parties). The parties themselves define the standard of conduct applicable to them by the terms of their agreement. 5 The only relevant fault is breach of any agreement the parties intended to make. Fault thus merges with mutual intent and cannot serve as an independent criterion of liability. This justification is incomplete, however. If the parties intend that courts should determine contract liability based on why nonperformance occurred, few people would call that a strict liability system. Strict liability connotes not merely court deference to rules of conduct established by contracting parties, but also a standard of conduct that is not itself fault-based. A traditionalist justification of strict liability, then, must defend the proposition that the parties intend that the reason for nonperformance does not matter. 6 That proposition is, however, often contestable. Law and economics scholars have tried to explain and justify strict liability in contract law on consequentialist grounds. Like traditional scholars and courts, economic scholars start Hosted by The Berkeley Electronic Press

6 from the premise that courts should enforce agreements according to the parties= mutual intention, but proceed differently from that premise. As the well-known theory goes, contracting parties generally have the incentive to form and write efficient contracts, but not necessarily to perform them, so courts facilitate efficient contracting by enforcing the bargain according to the intentions of the parties. If courts try instead to the parties= behavior, for example, by injecting courts= Aown of that conflict with the parties= preferences, parties will contract around those restrictions if they can and lose out on mutually beneficial trades if they cannot. That still leaves the question of whether the parties intend strict liability. Most contracting parties, economists argue, prefer a strict liability contract regime even if they do not expressly say so. The reasons supporting that conclusion usually fall into one of three categories: superior risk bearing, comparative institutional competence, and litigation costs. First, the promisor is usually in a better position than the promisee to bear a risk that would make performance of that promise more costly or less valuable. Institutionally, contracting parties are better equipped than the courts to make whatever fault determinations are desirable. Finally, fault-based liability imposes higher litigation costs on the parties than strict liability, because fault is more costly for courts to assess, and these costs generally outweigh whatever the benefits of a fault-based system. Although these rationales for strict liability have some plausibility and doctrinal support, ultimately they are not persuasive. The Uncertainty of Mutual Intent Both the traditional and economic justifications for strict liability rely on a strong

7 dichotomy between mutual intent and fault. In the traditional view, contract law is about mutual intent and fault is about social judgment. In the economic view, parties fully express their preferences in their contract, so court attempts to impose external fault standards on them will lead to inefficiency. The asserted dichotomy between intent and fault is false, or at least misleading. The relationship between the two is more complex. In the first place, both justifications depend crucially on there being such a thing as the actual mutual intention of contracting parties, which resolves all potential disputes, and which courts can determine with reasonable accuracy at relatively low cost. Otherwise, courts inevitably wind up making illegitimate social judgments or thwarting the preferences of the contracting parties, leading to inefficient contracting around or failures to contract. Determining mutual intent is an inherently uncertain enterprise, however. The very concept of mutual intent is essentially an ideal, like a Platonic form. The parties do their best to express their mutual intent, most commonly in a written contract, but these expressions are imperfect. Contracts are largely a set of rules, and all rules require interpretation, stories that explain their purpose or meaning in a particular situation. 7 As new and unanticipated situations arise, disputes requiring interpretation inevitably occur. Parties generally resolve these disputes on their own, sometimes by modifying their contract, but in some situations they cannot and so bring their disputes to the courts. In these disputes, the parties typically present contesting versions of what mutual intent requires. Contract law helps courts chose between these competing versions of mutual intent. It is designed, therefore, for the marginal case, not the average contract. Contract law is, however, just another set of rules. These rules provide proxies, presumptions, and guidance for how courts should determine mutual intent, but they are also imperfect. Like contract terms, contract doctrines require interpretation. Contracting Hosted by The Berkeley Electronic Press

8 parties engage in such interpretation when they draft, perform, and dispute new contracts, which lead to new court interpretations of contracts and contract law, and the process goes on. The nature of this ongoing process of interpretation belies a fixed and easily determined mutual intent in contested cases. Of course, contracting parties often try to influence court interpretation by expressing in their contract preferences about how courts should ascertain mutual intent. The typical example is merger clauses. We might call this intent procedural or secondary, compared to the substantive or primary intent of how parties should and should not behave under the contract. Defenders of strict liability assert that even if primary intent is uncertain, so long as courts follow the parties= secondary intent, they will generally get primary intent right. 8 That approach, however, merely shifts the problem of uncertain intent to a different place. It does not pre-empt the need for interpretation. In fact, it adds an additional interpretive question: when primary and secondary intent conflict, which should the court follow? 9 The difference between primary and secondary intent is just one example of a more general phenomenon: multiple intents. Contracting parties may have more than one goal. They may make multiple promises and incur multiple obligations. Multifaceted intent compounds the problem of uncertainty and further muddies the distinction between intent and social policy. The more expressions of intent there are, the more likely it will be that disputes will arise over how to reconcile or prioritize the different intentions when they conflict. I do not mean to suggest that the uncertainty of intent and the need for interpretation mean that all interpretations of intent are equally valid. Quite the opposite. Some interpretations are better than others. Rather, my point is that the justifications for strict liability assume that

9 expressing and determining intent is relatively easy and writing down more or better contract terms or contract doctrine can obviate or minimize the need for interpretation. Otherwise, how would one know when courts are lapsing into illegitimate Asocial policy or creating A inefficient@ rules. We should be wary of overly confident assertions of mutual intent without sufficient justification or acknowledgment of plausible alternative interpretations. Otherwise, a theory that supposedly fosters judicial humility winds up instead fostering judicial hubris. In my view, true humility lies in acknowledging the uncertainty of intent. Doing so opens the door to fault. The Relationship Between Fault and Intent The strong dichotomy between intent and fault, on which the justifications for strict liability depend, founders not only on the uncertainty of intent, but also the variety of ways that fault can help inform intent. First, contracting parties can expressly use fault concepts in their contracts. Examples of contract terms incorporating a fault standard include best efforts, 10 good faith, and reasonableness clauses. When disputing parties call on courts to interpret these terms in determining mutual intent, fault gets incorporated into contract law. Second, parties may intend to be governed by fault standards even if they do not expressly say so. Courts that perceive such intent will imply fault standards as part of the contract. The most common example is a contract for professional services, for which courts presume that the professional does not intend to guarantee results, and the client agrees to accept the professional standard of care. Although less frequently mentioned, courts often apply similar standards to other service contracts. 11 Moreover, in agency and other fiduciary contracts, courts imply duties of care and loyalty because they presume principals and agents intend that agents Hosted by The Berkeley Electronic Press

10 should not misbehave by shirking or pursuing conflicting interests or the like. Third, contracting parties often draft terms designed to discourage certain kinds of conduct. Even though these terms do not explicitly mention fault, fault may help explain the purpose behind these terms and therefore facilitate their interpretation. For example, progress payments reduce the ability of the paying party to hold up a performing party who goes first. Contingency payments encourage effort that might not otherwise be forthcoming. These terms often present questions of interpretation, not only of these terms themselves but of how they relate to the contract as a whole. On the one hand, the terms reveal the parties= concern with fault, which a court may interpret as extending beyond the domain of the specific term. On the other hand, courts may interpret these terms as expressing the parties= intent that the terms are the exclusive means of addressing fault. That is, the terms represent an attempt to pre-empt court determinations of fault. If the former interpretation is at least in some cases better, as I believe it is, fault will be relevant in determining mutual intent. Fourth, fault can help resolve a conflict between plausible competing interpretations of intent by focusing on narrower grounds. Courts may be more confident about whether the parties intended to prohibit specific conduct in a particular circumstance than about what the parties affirmatively intended, or intended more generally in their contract. 12 Finally, fault may be inconsistent with contractual intent. Contract terms may expressly or impliedly attempt to limit the application of fault. For example, courts interpret insurance contracts as expressing the intent that the insurance company=s fault in assessing risk is irrelevant; if a risk that the policy covers occurs, the insurance company must pay. Similarly, courts interpret the intent of option contracts 13 and at will employment contracts as generally

11 giving absolute discretion to one or both parties, thereby making fault irrelevant. The previous discussion, however, suggests several caveats against too quickly assuming inconsistency between intent and fault, as critics of fault doctrines like good faith sometimes do. Sometimes what appears to be a conflict between fault and intent may in reality reflect different interpretations of uncertain intent. 14 Moreover, terms limiting fault require interpretation about how for these limits extend. Fault may reappear if the reason for excluding fault does not apply. Lastly, I know of no evidence or theory to support the proposition that contracting parties ever intend the exclusion of all considerations of fault in all aspects of their dealings. We do not see contracts, for example, in which parties agree to flip a coin to resolve any possible dispute that might arise. The Meaning of Fault in Contract Law Having discussed the strict liability theory=s unsatisfactory dichotomy between intent and fault, I turn now to the economic theory of superior risk bearing and the question of whether it supports strict liability. Ironically, the superior risk bearer idea, which is itself fault-based, has led to an unduly cramped view of the role of fault in contract law. One reason for this is an excessive focus on precaution-taking. From the perspective of precaution-taking, strict liability (or strict nonliability) makes sense in four cases: (1) cost-effective precautions are generally possible, and the defendant is so often the better precaution-taker that the benefits of making individualized fault assessments are not worth the costs; (2) fault is likely to be equally balanced on both sides, so making relative fault assessments is not worth the cost; (3) the activity itself should be discouraged rather than done safely; and (4) neither party can take cost-effective precautions against some risk. Hosted by The Berkeley Electronic Press

12 Contract law contains examples of each of these cases, though each has its limits. For example, case (1) seems to describe the paradigm strict liability case of a failure by the seller of goods or services to take reasonable precautions, such as proper quality control, as a result of which the goods or services are defective. We have already seen, however, that courts abandon strict liability in the case of services when the assumptions underlying strict liability do not hold. Case (2) seems to describe the situation in which both parties are equally able to take precautions by adding contract terms that protect their interests or clarify their intent, so in cases of ambiguity either one could be deemed at fault and liability should not turn on the failure to take such precautions. A notable exception to this rule is, of course, the rule of interpreting ambiguities against the drafter when one party drafts the contract. 15 Case (3) includes the consideration doctrine=s refusal to enforce gratuitous promises, because enforcing such promises might discourage parties from making them. There are exceptions to this doctrine, however, in cases in which the concerns with activity level effects are reduced. 16 Case (4) includes changes in market conditions that neither party could take precautions to prevent. Even here, contract law can encourage a different kind of precaution taking, such as precautions to reduce the harm that does occur. The foreseeability doctrine in contract damages serves this purpose. In fact, however, the nature of contractual liability provides space for a much more robust notion of fault. 17 Although precaution-taking is important in contract law, two other forms of fault B mitigation and opportunism B are even more important. Precaution-taking matters in two situations where contract law most resembles the tort law of accidents: accidental contracts and accidental contingencies. 18 Accidental contracts are contracts that should not have been made, that is they were jointly unprofitable at the time of formation, but one or both parties did not

13 know that. Accidental contingencies are circumstances arising after contract formation that make the contract jointly unprofitable. In both cases, it makes sense to ask whether the contracting parties could have taken reasonable precautions to prevent the contract or the contingency, for example by investing more in information. On the other hand, if the contract is jointly profitable when made and continues to be jointly profitable, but a Aregret contingency@ occurs that makes the contract less profitable for one side, then mitigation and opportunism become more important. 19 Although contract doctrine focuses on promisee mitigation, promisors can mitigate as well; in fact, the often superior ability of promisors to mitigate is a crucial, though often underappreciated, rationale for strict liability in contract performance and contract damages, and to some extent strict nonliability in contract formation. A key feature of mitigation is the ability to provide substitute performance, and promisors are often in a better position than promisees to repair and replace their defective performance or purchase market substitutes. By the same token, promisees are often better able to Amitigate@ by finding substitute contracting partners at the formation stage. Contracting parties cannot mitigate or take reasonable precautions to prevent all contractual losses, however. That is where opportunism comes in. One party in a contractual relationship often takes some action, or fails to take some action, that creates the possibility of non-mitigatable loss; that is, one party becomes vulnerable to wrongful expropriation by the other, with Awrongful@ defined with reference either to the parties= agreement, contractual norms, or conventional morality. In the paradigmatic case of opportunistic behavior, one party makes a relationship-specific investment (or Areliance expenditure@ in legal terms) in the contract, which leaves that party vulnerable to threats by the other to deprive the first party of his investment. Specific investments can occur before or after the formation of the contract. A party may form Hosted by The Berkeley Electronic Press

14 an intention to act opportunistically not only at the outset of a contractual relationship (classic A fraud@) but as the relationship proceeds. More important, opportunistic behavior can occur even in the absence of specific investments. All that opportunism requires is some change in position growing out of the contractual relationship that exposes one party to potential and non-mitigatable risk or loss that intentional conduct by the other party can impose. This vulnerability can arise in a number of ways. For example, one party may perform before the other one does, providing a benefit to the other party who may then try to keep that benefit without performing his reciprocal obligations. Or one party may forego other contracting opportunities, which then become unavailable, such as when market prices or other market conditions change. Or one party may make information available to the other party, who may then use the information to the first party=s disadvantage. Or one party may act negligently and the other party, aware of the first party=s negligence, tries to exploit rather than correct it. 20 Many contract terms and contract law doctrines aim to deter opportunistic behavior. Identifying opportunistic behavior is not always easy, however. One problem is that all contract rules and contract law doctrines themselves create the potential for exploitation by a party seeking to act opportunistically. Contrary to the views of some scholars, 21 the potential for making opportunistic use of contract terms and contract law doctrines is not limited to the kinds of legal precepts often referred to as Astandards@; as I argued above, all legal precepts require interpretation, no matter how they are formulated. Not only may a party seeking to act opportunistically attempt to justify its behavior under some contract term or contract law doctrine, such a party may also try to justify its behavior by pointing to its own (real or asserted)

15 non-mitigatable loss. Contract disputes, then, present questions not only about precaution-taking, but whether the problem causing nonperformance was accidental, whether and by whom any losses at any stage could be mitigated, and whether either party is acting opportunistically. In short, there are good reasons for thinking that the reason for nonperformance often matters in litigated cases. Despite the claims of strict liability theorists to the contrary, contract doctrine often allows parties to make such arguments. The Appearance of Fault in Contract Doctrine The concept of fault appears throughout contract doctrine, but in ways that seem to defy any coherent pattern. Fault is like an odd relative that contract doctrine for the most part tries to hide in a closet, but somehow refuses to be cabined and keeps peskily poking its head out. A theory that seeks to explain contract law must attempt to understand how and why fault appears in contract doctrine. Just as contracts may expressly include fault concepts, so contract doctrine contains a number of direct expressions of fault. The bewildering variety of these expressions scattered throughout the doctrinal landscape of contract law obscures the ubiquity of fault concepts. Fault expressions in contract doctrine include: fault, good faith, best efforts, unconscionability, wilful breach, injustice, forfeiture, know or has reason to know, all the circumstances, and reasonable diligence. Even when contract doctrine does not use fault language, the doctrine=s purpose may be to discourage certain types of faulty behavior. For example, the statute of frauds, parol evidence rule, the objective theory of contracts, and to some extent the consideration doctrine aim to deter Hosted by The Berkeley Electronic Press

16 assertions of false promises. Moreover, contract doctrines often contain fault-based presumptions. One may find such presumptions even in doctrines not obviously directed at fault. For example, one can understand the market damage rule as reflecting a fault-based presumption that breaches to take advantage of a change in market price are opportunistic. The concept of fault-based presumptions is important because fault becomes relevant if the assumptions underlying the presumptions do not hold. Fault can also serve as a check on contract doctrines when courts fear that these doctrines may otherwise lead them to stray too far from intent. Fault in this case is the metric by which courts assess the gap between formalist concepts and normative reality. Similarly, courts sometimes turn to fault when they must make choices between which doctrinal category to use when several are available in a particular case, navigate between doctrines and their exceptions, and help resolve conflicts between doctrines. With these roles for fault in contract doctrine in mind, I offer some representative examples of where fault concepts appear in contract doctrine. Because I have previously written about fault in contract damage doctrine, I will focus on other areas. The term Afault@ appears infrequently in the Restatement and UCC Article 2. Most occurrences of the term are connected to the excuse doctrines of mistake and impracticability. That is surprising. The usual justifications for the excuse doctrines emphasize the mutual innocence of the parties, not fault. 22 Yet the excuse doctrines include provisions that limit their application if the party asserting the defense is Aat fault.@ 23 The excuse doctrines are based on inadequate information available to the parties at the time they contracted. In mistake, the information relates to facts; in impracticability, it relates to

17 risks. If the parties, had they known the relevant facts, would not have contracted or, had they known the relevant risk, would not have required the party disadvantaged by the risk under the contract to bear it, the parties most likely would not have wanted the contract enforced. A party seeking enforcement in this situation is likely acting opportunistically. Contract law responds by shifting the presumption from strict liability to strict nonliability. Determining the parties= mutual intent about what relevant facts or risks they assumed when contracting is, however, uncertain. As a result, rules allowing excuse for mistake or impracticability give promisors a vehicle for claiming these excuses opportunistically, that is, by falsely alleging a Amistake@ or A impracticability.@ Excuse doctrine tries to reduce the risk of promisor opportunism that it introduces. First, the doctrine requires the promisor to present some kind of Aobjective@ evidence, meaning not easily subject to promisor manipulation. In the case of mutual mistake, the objective evidence is that the other party is also mistaken; in impracticability, the change is usually either a market change, or a change specific to the promisor that is hard to fake, such as death or destruction of a particular thing. In either case, the doctrine also allows evidence relevant to determining which party is the superior mitigator. Finally, the doctrine allows the promisee to challenge the application of the doctrine by proving Afault@ by the promisor. My concern is not to defend particular details or interpretations of excuse doctrine. Rather, my point is that the existence and structure of excuse doctrine are neither accidental nor aberrational. It establishes a pattern repeated throughout contract doctrine. The doctrine itself aims to deter opportunistic behavior by one party, but in doing so creates the possibility of opportunistic behavior by the other party, and so contains an exception or limitation to deal with this possibility. Regardless of the limited use of the term Afault,@ the doctrine as a whole Hosted by The Berkeley Electronic Press

18 contains both fault-based presumptions, and in addition some doctrinal vehicle by which the parties can introduce and contest fault assessments. These fault assessments are bounded. The doctrine tries to rely on objective evidence, such as the knowledge or conduct of both parties, the knowledge or conduct of third parties (the or the and whether one party can more easily get substitutes. Consider another pair of doctrinal examples that, like mistake and impracticability, straddle the domains of formation and performance. The doctrines of misunderstanding in R2d ' 20 and interpretation in R2d ' 201 are essentially identical, and both incorporate a fault standard, though without using the term Afault.@ 24 Instead, both sections use the concepts of Aknow@ and A reason to know,@ fault concepts that appear in the law of fraud. Like mistake and impracticability, the misunderstanding and interpretation rules seem to start from the premise that fault does not matter. If the parties agree on a meaning, that meaning prevails. If they A attach different meanings@ to Amanifestations of assent,@ a Apromise,@ an Aagreement,@ or Aterms,@ there is no contract so long as neither party is at fault or both are equally at fault. If, however, the relative fault of one party exceeds that of the other, there is a contract and meaning of the party whose fault is greater loses. 25 A party who knows or has reason to know the other party=s meaning is likely acting opportunistically in asserting a contrary meaning. The Aknow or has reason to know@ standard opens the door to fault assessments. One might well ask how sections 20 and 201 square with the objective theory of contract. The objective theory is based on manifestations that have Aobjective@ meanings. The Aattached meanings@ of sections 20 and 201 seem subjective rather than objective. In fact, however, sections 20 and 201 are perfectly consistent with the objective theory of contract if that theory is

19 understood in fault terms. The objective theory presumes that when one party manifests intent, and later asserts a different intent, either he negligently misled the other party or is acting opportunistically now. That is, the party manifesting intent Aknows or has reason to know that the other party may infer from his conduct that he assents.@ 26 Sections 20 and 201 say precisely the same thing. If, on the other hand, the fault-based presumptions of the objective theory do not apply, the grounds for applying the objective theory disappear as well. 27 The Aknow or has reason to know@ standard calls attention to the opportunistic use of information, 28 a subject that has received insufficient attention from the defenders of strict liability. For example, knowledge plays a prominent role in the law of agency, which significantly overlaps with contract law. Agents make most business contracts. Agency law contains a doctrine that imputes to the principal knowledge of facts that the agent knows or has reason to know. 29 But how this doctrine relates to contract law is not always clear. 30 In particular, many contract disputes arise when the company=s agents who negotiated the contract are not the same as the agents seeking to enforce or escape it later. 31 When, for example, management changes, is the new management bound by the understandings of the old management under the imputation of knowledge doctrine? The imputed knowledge doctrine is itself based on fault considerations, namely the need to balance the danger of the agent withholding bad information from the principal to the disadvantage of the third party against the danger of the agent colluding with the third party against the interests of the principal. Thus, deciding how it ought to apply in contract law inevitably invites fault assessments. The Aknow or has reason to know@ standard also appears in a number of formation rules governing offer and acceptance. Offer and acceptance doctrine may seem largely removed from Hosted by The Berkeley Electronic Press

20 fault. As mentioned already, freedom not to contract seems to limit the role of fault in contract formation. Further support for fault-free formation doctrine comes from the fact that the duty of good faith does not apply to contract formation. In fact, this is an artifact of focusing on only one aspect of information. Contract law excludes the duty of good faith from formation to allow parties to misrepresent certain information about themselves for the purpose of protecting their private information and their investment in that information, and thereby obtaining a larger share of the contractual surplus. Once again, however, a rule that seems designed to preclude fault considerations instead merely defines the boundaries of such considerations. There are other ways that parties can opportunistically abuse information in the contract formation process. For example, one party cannot mislead the other about the likelihood of a deal to obtain more time to evaluate the deal. A party who wants more time must either take a chance that the other will walk away or buy an option. By the same token, a contracting party cannot opportunistically forestall the other party=s ability to acquire further information necessary to evaluate the deal by insisting on the deal=s closure when the first party has reason to know the other party is still investigating. 32 Nor can a party use negotiations to extract and then expropriate beneficial information from the other party without paying for it. A final example is the use of the word Ajustice@ in connection with formation doctrines based on reliance. 33 These doctrines developed to thwart what courts perceived to be opportunistic attempts by promisors to escape liability through various strict nonliability rules of formation: consideration, offer and acceptance, and the statute of frauds. As we have seen, reliance can provide a platform for opportunistic behavior by those seeking to rely on strict

21 interpretations of rules. But as is well understood, reliance is not by itself proof of opportunistic behavior. And reliance-based liability itself can lead to opportunistic investments in or assertions of reliance. So once again, contract doctrine provides an outlet for making fault assessments, by limiting the application of reliance doctrines to situations in which requires enforcement. The Inevitability of Fault Even if one disagrees with my conclusions that fault often comports with mutual intent and believes that contract doctrine should be revised to reduce further or eliminate entirely the role of fault in contract law, I believe there is an additional problem with rigorous and systematic strict liability regime: it cannot work. Law is an inherently normative enterprise and judges are part of that enterprise. They are not automatons; they exercise judgment, which includes making normative assessments like fault. Coase taught us that contracting parties can often contract around unwanted legal rules. But we sometimes forget the legal realist lesson (perhaps we should call it the Court Theorem) that courts can often find ways to exercise fault judgments if they are inclined to do so, through interpretation of contract terms, contract doctrine, or other legal doctrines outside of contract. Game theorists fail to capture this phenomenon because they model courts as setting the rules the parties play by and then largely disappearing from the scene. In reality, courts are players in an ongoing and constantly changing game. There will of course be differences in inclinations toward strict liability or fault approaches, not only across judges but for individual judges across cases. The point is, however, that fault will out. Conclusion: A Role for Strict Liability, and Fault Although I have argued that the strict liability view of contract law needs to be Hosted by The Berkeley Electronic Press

22 significantly qualified, it is important to recognize the source of the strict liability impulse. Strict liability matters when contractual intent, contract term, and contract doctrine coincide with a persuasive story of promisor fault. Moreover, strict liability makes the most sense when its consequences are blunted, most notably because the promisor can easily mitigate by getting substitutes. The conditions for strict liability are most likely to exist in contracts for the sale of goods. We are comfortable interpreting these contracts as allocating the risk of changes in market price, or requiring perfect tender, in large part because of the assumption of easy substitutability. These situations are certainly not trivial in contract law. Nevertheless, they are far from describing the full spectrum of contract disputes. Even in goods cases, the conditions for strict liability are often not satisfied. In those situations, we should expect to see, and do see, courts incorporating fault standards into their considerations of contract liability, as we do in many services contracts. In short, strict liability encompasses situations in which courts feel comfortable presuming promisor opportunism. Calling contract law a strict liability system serves the useful purpose of emphasizing contract law=s commitment to deterring promisor opportunism. But strict liability, like other contract rules, is merely a fault-based presumption. Determining the limits of that presumption means considering why parties make contracts why they do not perform them, in other words, fault. Scholars should embrace and help shape the fault that lies within our contract law, rather * Brokaw Professor of Corporate Law, University of Virginia School of Law. 1 See, e.g., R2d Chapter 11, Introductory Note (AContract liability is strict liability.... The obligor is therefore liable in damages for breach of contract even if he is without fault....@); Bruce W. Frier & James J. White, The Modern Law of Contracts 23 (2005).

23 2 This essay thus continues a theme that has run throughout my writing on contract law. George M. Cohen, The Negligence-Opportunism Tradeoff in Contract Law, 20 Hofstra L. Rev. 941 (1992); George M. Cohen, The Fault Lines in Contract Damages, 80 Va. L. Rev (1994); George M. Cohen, Implied Terms and Interpretation in Contract Law, in 3 Encyclopedia of Law and Economics 78 (Boudewijn Bouckert & Gerrit de Geest, eds., 2000); George M. Cohen, Finding Fault with Wonnell=s ATwo Contractual Wrongs,@ 38 San Diego L. Rev. 137 (2001). 3 R2d ' 235 cmt. b (AWhen performance is due,... anything short of full performance is a breach, even if the party who does not fully perform was not at fault....@). 4 Globe Refining Co. v. Landa Cotton Oil Co., 190 U.S. 540, 544 (1903) (AIf a contract is broken the measure of damages generally is the same, whatever the cause of the breach.@). For a critique of the Holmesian strict liability view of contract damages, see Cohen, Fault Lines, supra note 2 5 The traditionalist justification is one possible interpretation of Holmes= famous statement: AThe duty to keep a contract at common law means a prediction that you must pay damages if you do not keep it, B and nothing else.@ Holmes, The Path of the Law, 10 Harv. L. Rev. 457 (1897). 6 Professor Smith defends a much more sophisticated philosophical approach to strict liability. He accepts that contracting parties intend to compensate each other regardless of the reason for nonperformance. He then divides the contractual obligation into an obligation to perform and then a separate obligation to pay compensation in the event of innocent nonperformance. He then argues that courts apply a Afault@ system of liability to each obligation, which ends up looking like a system of strict liability because any Afault@ assessment by a court winds up being irrelevant. Stephen A. Smith, Contract Theory (2004). 7 See generally Robert Cover, The Supreme Court, 1982 Term B Forward: Nomos and Narrative, 97 Harv. L. Rev. 4 (1983). (2003). 8 Alan Schwartz & Robert E. Scott, Contract Theory and the Limits of Contract Law, 113 Yale L.J I have a similar reaction to recent theories that argue for less judicial intervention in contracts on the ground that parties intend to rely on Afairness norms@ rather than court enforcement. See, e.g., Robert E. Scott, A Theory of Hosted by The Berkeley Electronic Press

24 Self-Enforcing Indefinite Agreements, 103 Colum. L. Rev (2003). Suppose that parties do have that intention (which is far from clear in many cases). If one party behaves unreasonably, and so violates a fairness norm, the other party may, in violation of another fairness norm, take the dispute to court. The theorists argue that the procedural norm should take priority over the substantive norm. Why? Violating either norm will make some people more reluctant to rely on fairness norms. 10 See generally, E. Allan Farnsworth, On Trying to Keep One=s Promises: The Duty of Best Efforts in Contract Law, 46 U. Pitt. L. Rev. 1 (1984). 11 For example, in Milau Assocs. v. North Ave. Development Corp., 368 N.E.2d 1247 (NY 1977), the court rejected the application of UCC ' (implied warranty of fitness for a particular purpose) to a contract for the installation of a sprinkler system in a building, finding instead that Aunless the parties have contractually bound themselves to a higher standard of performance, reasonable care and competence owed generally by practitioners in the particular trade or profession defines the limits of an injured party=s justifiable demands.@ Id. at The court added: AGiven the predominantly service-oriented character of the transaction, neither the code nor the common law of this State can be read to imply an undertaking to guard against economic loss stemming from the nonnegligent performance by a construction firm which has not contractually bound itself to provide perfect results....@ Id. at See also R2d Agency ' 377 cmt. b (reasonable efforts standard applies to agency contracts); UCC ' 2-306(2) (implying Abest efforts@ obligation in exclusive dealing contracts involving goods unless the parties otherwise agree). 12 Cf. Robert S. Summers, AGood Faith@ in General Contract Law and the Sales Provisions of the Uniform Commercial Code, 54 Va. L. Rev. 195 (1968). 13 Economic scholars have become enamored of analogizing many contract terms and doctrines to options. See generally Avery Katz, The Option Element in Contracting, 90 Va. L. Rev (2004). While the analogies can be enlightening, one danger of them is that they too casually smuggle the strict liability connotation of options to other areas where plausible arguments can be made for fault-based approaches. That is, option analogies put the strict liability rabbit in the hat. 14 The classic statement remains Cardozo=s: AFrom the conclusion that promises may not be treated as

25 dependent to the extent of their uttermost minutiae without a sacrifice of justice, the progress is a short one to the conclusion that they may not be so treated without a perversion of intention.@ Jacob & Youngs, Inc. v. Kent, 129 N.E. 889, (NY 1921). 15 R2d ' Charles J. Goetz & Robert E. Scott, Enforcing Promises: An Examination of the Basis of Contract, 89 Yale L.J (1980). 17 See, generally Cohen, Negligence-Opportunism Tradeoff, supra note 2; see also e.g., UCC '' 1-201(16) (defining Afault@ broadly as Awrongful act, omission or breach@); 2-613, cmt. 1 (fault includes both negligence and wilful wrong). 18 See Cohen, Fault Lines, supra note 2, at. 19 Charles J. Goetz & Robert E. Scott, The Mitigation Principle: Toward a General Theory of Contractual Obligation, 69 Va. L. Rev. 967 (1983). 20 See, e.g., R2d ' 49 (offeree cannot accept beyond deadline if offeror negligently delayed in communicating the offer but offeree knows or has reason to know of the delay), ' 153 (allowing relief for unilateral mistake if the other party had reason to know of the mistake or his fault caused it) 21 Schwartz & Scott, supra note 8, at. 22 The fact that the excuse doctrines involve an absence of fault does not mean that their very existence disproves a strict liability theory of contract. The absence of fault is necessary but not sufficient for these doctrines to apply. See Smith, supra note 6, at See UCC (allowing excuse if Agoods suffer casualty without fault of either party@); R2d '' 261 (allowing excuse if Aa party=s performance is made impracticable without his fault@), 265 (allowing excuse if Aa party=s principal purpose is substantially frustrated without his fault@), 157 (mistaken party=s fault bars excuse if Ahis fault amounts to a failure to act in good faith and in accordance with reasonable standards of fair dealing,@ but not if fault is simply Ain failing to know or discover the facts before making the contract@). 24 The Restatement writers do use the term Afault@ in comment d to ' 20 (describing the Abasic principle@ of Hosted by The Berkeley Electronic Press

26 the section as being that Ano contract is formed if neither party is at fault or if both parties are equally at but there is a contract if Aboth parties are not equally at fault@). 25 See, e.g., In re Hub Recycling, Inc., 106 B.R. 372 (D.N.J. 1989) (applying ' 201 to interpret insurance company=s Pollution Exclusion Clause, which defined pollutant to include Awaste, including materials to be recycled,@ as applying to recycled material only if it was an irritant or contaminant, on ground that insurance company knew that insured company was in the recycling business). The Restatement rules on trade and other usages, which are essentially particular applications of ' 201, also incorporate a Aknow or has reason to know@ standard. R2d '' 220, 221, 222; see also UCC ' 1-205(3) (trade usage of which the parties Aare or should be aware@ can be used to interpret the agreement). R2d ' 211(3) applies a similar standard to standardized agreements. If the party who drafts the standardized agreement Ahas reason to believe@ that the other party would not have agreed to a particular term if he knew it was there, the term is excluded from the agreement. 26 R2d ' 19(2). In addition to the Aknow or reason to know@ standard, the objective theory uses the term A justify@ to open the door to fault considerations. See '' 2 (promise defined as a manifestation of intent Aso made as to justify a promisee in understanding that a commitment has been made@); 24 (similar definition of offer). 27 For a recent critique of the objective theory sounding some similar themes, see Lawrence M. Solan, Contract as Agreement, 83 Notre Dame L. Rev. 353 (2007). 28 In some situations the Aknow or has reason to know@ standard serves a somewhat different function, albeit still fault-based. When a party knows or has reason to know of special needs of the other party, the party with knowledge may have an obligation to take special precautions to protect the other party from harm. See UCC '' (reason to know creates implied warranty of fitness), 2-715(2)(a) (seller=s reason to know of buyer=s general or particular requirements and needs makes seller potentially liable for consequential damages); cf. R2d ' 351(1) (A reason to foresee@ standard). 29 R3d Agency ' 5.03 & cmt. (d)(1) (A[F]acts known to a contracting party may be relevant to interpreting terms in the contract, may establish defenses to duties of performance, and may provide grounds on which the contract may be rescinded. If an agent enters into a contract on behalf of a principal, notice is imputed to the principal of material facts that the agent knows or has reason to know.@).

The Fault That Lies Within Our Contract Law

The Fault That Lies Within Our Contract Law Michigan Law Review Volume 107 Issue 8 2009 The Fault That Lies Within Our Contract Law George M. Cohen University of Virginia Law School Follow this and additional works at: http://repository.law.umich.edu/mlr

More information

UNIDROIT PRINCIPLES OF INTERNATIONAL COMMERCIAL CONTRACTS 2004 (I)

UNIDROIT PRINCIPLES OF INTERNATIONAL COMMERCIAL CONTRACTS 2004 (I) UNIDROIT PRINCIPLES OF INTERNATIONAL COMMERCIAL CONTRACTS 2004 (I) PREAMBLE (Purpose of the Principles) These Principles set forth general rules for international commercial contracts. They shall be applied

More information

Article 6. Binding force of contract A contract validly entered into is binding upon the parties.

Article 6. Binding force of contract A contract validly entered into is binding upon the parties. Principles of Latin American Contract Law Chapter 1. Preamble Section 1. General provisions Article 1. Scope of Application (1) These principles set forth general rules applicable to domestic and international

More information

QUESTION What contract rights and remedies, if any, does Olivia have against Juan? Discuss.

QUESTION What contract rights and remedies, if any, does Olivia have against Juan? Discuss. QUESTION 1 Olivia is a florist who specializes in roses. She has a five-year written contract with Juan to sell him as many roses as he needs for his wedding chapel. Over the past three years, Olivia sold

More information

Principles of European Contract Law

Principles of European Contract Law Article 1:101: Application of the Principles Principles of European Contract Law CHAPTER 1: GENERAL PROVISIONS Section 1: Scope of the Principles (1) These Principles are intended to be applied as general

More information

Financial Markets Lawyers Group N.Y. Laws, Ch. 311, which is codified at Sections et seq. of the General

Financial Markets Lawyers Group N.Y. Laws, Ch. 311, which is codified at Sections et seq. of the General SULLIVAN & CROMWELL June 10, 1998 MEMORANDUM TO: RE: Financial Markets Lawyers Group Interpretation of New York s Recently Enacted Continuity of Contract Statute Introduction On July 29, 1997, New York

More information

PART 2 FORMATION, TERMS, AND READJUSTMENT OF CONTRACT. (a) A contract or modification thereof is enforceable,

PART 2 FORMATION, TERMS, AND READJUSTMENT OF CONTRACT. (a) A contract or modification thereof is enforceable, 1 PART 2 FORMATION, TERMS, AND READJUSTMENT OF CONTRACT SECTION 2-201. NO FORMAL REQUIREMENTS. (a) A contract or modification thereof is enforceable, whether or not there is a record signed by a party

More information

Question 2. Delta has not yet paid for any of the three Model 100 presses despite repeated demands by Press.

Question 2. Delta has not yet paid for any of the three Model 100 presses despite repeated demands by Press. Question 2 Delta Print Co. ( Delta ) ordered three identical Model 100 printing presses from Press Manufacturer Co. ( Press ). Delta s written order form described the items ordered by model number. Delta

More information

Contracts Professor Keith A. Rowley William S. Boyd School of Law University of Nevada Las Vegas Spring Contract Terms (Expanded)

Contracts Professor Keith A. Rowley William S. Boyd School of Law University of Nevada Las Vegas Spring Contract Terms (Expanded) Contracts Professor Keith A. Rowley William S. Boyd School of Law University of Nevada Las Vegas Contract Terms (Expanded) I. Construing and Interpreting Contracts A. Purpose: A court s primary concern

More information

CONTRACT LAW. Elements of a Contract

CONTRACT LAW. Elements of a Contract CONTRACT LAW Contracts: Types and Sources in Australia CONTRACT: An agreement concerning promises made between two or more parties with the intention of creating certain legal rights and obligations upon

More information

Contracts Professor Keith A. Rowley William S. Boyd School of Law University of Nevada Las Vegas Spring Contract Terms

Contracts Professor Keith A. Rowley William S. Boyd School of Law University of Nevada Las Vegas Spring Contract Terms Contracts Professor Keith A. Rowley William S. Boyd School of Law University of Nevada Las Vegas Contract Terms I. Construing and Interpreting Contracts A. Purpose: A court s primary concern is to ascertain

More information

Chinese Contract Law: A Brief Introduction. ZHANG Xuezhong. Assistant Professor of Law.

Chinese Contract Law: A Brief Introduction. ZHANG Xuezhong. Assistant Professor of Law. Chinese Contract Law: A Brief Introduction ZHANG Xuezhong Assistant Professor of Law zhangxuezhong@ecupl.edu.cn East China University of Politics and Law Overview 1. In General 2. Principles of Chinese

More information

Question If CapCo files a lawsuit against the Bears seeking damages for breach of contract, who is likely to prevail? Discuss.

Question If CapCo files a lawsuit against the Bears seeking damages for breach of contract, who is likely to prevail? Discuss. Question 2 CapCo sells baseball caps to youth leagues and recently approached two new teams, the Bears and the Lions. Uncertain how many caps the team would require, the Bears team manager signed a written

More information

The Article 1 Revision Process

The Article 1 Revision Process SMU Law Review Volume 54 Issue 2 Article 8 2001 The Article 1 Revision Process Kathleen Patchel Boris Auerbach Follow this and additional works at: https://scholar.smu.edu/smulr Recommended Citation Kathleen

More information

Question 1: I read that a mentally impaired adult s contracts may be void or voidable. Which is it?

Question 1: I read that a mentally impaired adult s contracts may be void or voidable. Which is it? Question 1: I read that a mentally impaired adult s contracts may be void or voidable. Which is it? Answer 1: It depends. If a court of proper jurisdiction has found an adult to be non compos mentis, or

More information

MANUFACTURER LIABLE FOR BREACH OF EXPRESS WARRANTY: PRIVITY NOT REQUIRED

MANUFACTURER LIABLE FOR BREACH OF EXPRESS WARRANTY: PRIVITY NOT REQUIRED RECENT DEVELOPMENTS MANUFACTURER LIABLE FOR BREACH OF EXPRESS WARRANTY: PRIVITY NOT REQUIRED Rogers v. Toni Home Permanent Co., 167 Ohio St. 244, 147 N.E.2d 612 (1958) In her petition plaintiff alleged

More information

BAREXAMDOCTOR.COM UNLIMITED ESSAYS AND PTS ONLINE! ESSAY APPROACH. Bar Exam Doctor. CONTRACTS ESSAY

BAREXAMDOCTOR.COM UNLIMITED ESSAYS AND PTS ONLINE! ESSAY APPROACH. Bar Exam Doctor.   CONTRACTS ESSAY ESSAY APPROACH www.barexamdoctor.com CONTRACTS ESSAY I. DOES THE UCC APPLY? a. The UCC governs all Ks for the sale of goods b. The UCC also has special rule governing transactions between merchants c.

More information

Responsible Victims and (Partly) Justified Offenders

Responsible Victims and (Partly) Justified Offenders Responsible Victims and (Partly) Justified Offenders R. A. Duff VERA BERGELSON, VICTIMS RIGHTS AND VICTIMS WRONGS: COMPARATIVE LIABILITY IN CRIMINAL LAW (Stanford University Press 2009) If you negligently

More information

Strict Liability Versus Negligence: An Economic Analysis of the Law of Libel

Strict Liability Versus Negligence: An Economic Analysis of the Law of Libel BYU Law Review Volume 1981 Issue 2 Article 6 5-1-1981 Strict Liability Versus Negligence: An Economic Analysis of the Law of Libel Gary L. Lee Follow this and additional works at: https://digitalcommons.law.byu.edu/lawreview

More information

The Expectation Remedy Revisited

The Expectation Remedy Revisited Yale Law School Yale Law School Legal Scholarship Repository Faculty Scholarship Series Yale Law School Faculty Scholarship 2012 The Expectation Remedy Revisited Alan Schwartz Yale Law School Follow this

More information

Case Western Reserve University. From the SelectedWorks of Juliet P Kostritsky. Juliet P Kostritsky. March 24, 2009

Case Western Reserve University. From the SelectedWorks of Juliet P Kostritsky. Juliet P Kostritsky. March 24, 2009 Case Western Reserve University From the SelectedWorks of Juliet P Kostritsky March 24, 2009 THE MEANS/ENDS DILEMMA IN CONTRACT INTERPRETATION: A RESPONSE TO PROFESSORS KRAUS AND SCOTT: HOW THE INTRACTABILITY

More information

Creation of the K a. Statute of Frauds land part performance one year debt 500 b. Offer master of the offer revoke mailbox rule absence of terms

Creation of the K a. Statute of Frauds land part performance one year debt 500 b. Offer master of the offer revoke mailbox rule absence of terms Contracts outline I. Creation of the K a. Statute of Frauds requires that a sufficient writing, signed by the party to be charged be in existence for the following subject-matter (doesn t apply to restitution

More information

Contracts Professor Keith A. Rowley William S. Boyd School of Law University of Nevada Las Vegas Spring Contract Formation

Contracts Professor Keith A. Rowley William S. Boyd School of Law University of Nevada Las Vegas Spring Contract Formation Contracts Professor Keith A. Rowley William S. Boyd School of Law University of Nevada Las Vegas Contract Formation I. Foundations A. Mutual Assent: Each party to a contract manifests its assent to the

More information

COPYRIGHTED MATERIAL THE LEGAL CONTEXT OF CONSTRUCTION 1.1 INTRODUCTION

COPYRIGHTED MATERIAL THE LEGAL CONTEXT OF CONSTRUCTION 1.1 INTRODUCTION 1 1.1 INTRODUCTION THE LEGAL CONTEXT OF CONSTRUCTION Construction projects are complex and multifaceted. Likewise, the law governing construction is complex and multifaceted. Aside from questions of what

More information

Chapter 9: Contract Formation. Copyright 2009 South-Western Legal Studies in Business, a part of South-Western Cengage Learning.

Chapter 9: Contract Formation. Copyright 2009 South-Western Legal Studies in Business, a part of South-Western Cengage Learning. Chapter 9: Contract Formation a Copyright part of South-Western 2009 South-Western Cengage Legal Learning. Studies Business, Introduction is a declaration that something will or will not happen in the

More information

THE CONSUMER PROTECTION ACT 2014

THE CONSUMER PROTECTION ACT 2014 THE CONSUMER PROTECTION ACT 2014 Introduction The consumers now stand in need of greater protection. The consumers fifty years ago needed only a reasonable modicum of skill and knowledge to recognize the

More information

TABLE OF CONTENTS. Preface... iii Preface to the First Edition... v Table of Cases... TC-1 Table of Statutes... TS-1

TABLE OF CONTENTS. Preface... iii Preface to the First Edition... v Table of Cases... TC-1 Table of Statutes... TS-1 TABLE OF CONTENTS PAGE Preface... iii Preface to the First Edition... v Table of Cases... TC-1 Table of Statutes... TS-1 PART I. INTRODUCTION... 1-17 CHAPTER 1. INTRODUCTION... 1 PART II. ENFORCEABILITY...

More information

MISTAKE. (1) the other party to the contract knew or should have known of the mistake; or

MISTAKE. (1) the other party to the contract knew or should have known of the mistake; or MISTAKE Mistake of Fact: The parties entered into a contract with different understandings of one or more material facts relating to the contract s performance. Mutual Mistake: A mistake by both contracting

More information

Although the costs of materials and labor are roughly equal, the primary purpose of the

Although the costs of materials and labor are roughly equal, the primary purpose of the Claim 1: Acme Flooring Applicable Law: Although the costs of materials and labor are roughly equal, the primary purpose of the contract was for rendering services because the service component of installation

More information

OVERVIEW OF CONTRACT LAW

OVERVIEW OF CONTRACT LAW OVERVIEW OF CONTRACT LAW Liability is generally the key issue in regards to contractual disputes. Purpose of K law is to provide the rules which determine when one party is liable to another under or in

More information

Anticipatory Breach of Contract in the United Nations Convention on Contracts for the International Sale of Goods

Anticipatory Breach of Contract in the United Nations Convention on Contracts for the International Sale of Goods JOURNAL OF SIMULATION, VOL. 6, NO. 3, June 2018 45 Anticipatory Breach of Contract in the United Nations Convention on Contracts for the International Sale of Goods Xiangxiu Wang *, Yongpeng Zhao, Yawen

More information

Proceduralism and Epistemic Value of Democracy

Proceduralism and Epistemic Value of Democracy 1 Paper to be presented at the symposium on Democracy and Authority by David Estlund in Oslo, December 7-9 2009 (Draft) Proceduralism and Epistemic Value of Democracy Some reflections and questions on

More information

UNITED NATIONS CONVENTION ON CONTRACTS FOR THE INTERNATIONAL SALE OF GOODS (1980) [CISG]

UNITED NATIONS CONVENTION ON CONTRACTS FOR THE INTERNATIONAL SALE OF GOODS (1980) [CISG] Go to CISG Table of Contents Go to Database Directory UNITED NATIONS CONVENTION ON CONTRACTS FOR THE INTERNATIONAL SALE OF GOODS (1980) [CISG] For U.S. citation purposes, the UN-certified English text

More information

A COMMENT ON RESTATEMENT THIRD OF TORTS PROPOSED TREATMENT OF THE LIABILITY OF POSSESSORS OF LAND. George C. Christie

A COMMENT ON RESTATEMENT THIRD OF TORTS PROPOSED TREATMENT OF THE LIABILITY OF POSSESSORS OF LAND. George C. Christie A COMMENT ON RESTATEMENT THIRD OF TORTS PROPOSED TREATMENT OF THE LIABILITY OF POSSESSORS OF LAND George C. Christie In Tentative Draft Number 6 of Restatement (Third) of Torts: Liability for Physical

More information

Class Unification of Law - Uniform Law (Rechtsvereinheitlichung) Summer term 2015

Class Unification of Law - Uniform Law (Rechtsvereinheitlichung) Summer term 2015 Class Unification of Law - Uniform Law (Rechtsvereinheitlichung) Summer term 2015 Time schedule of the class 09.04.2015 Basics of unification of law: notion, purposes, history 16.04.2015 Methods of unification

More information

Contracts Professor Keith A. Rowley William S. Boyd School of Law University of Nevada Las Vegas Spring Course Introduction

Contracts Professor Keith A. Rowley William S. Boyd School of Law University of Nevada Las Vegas Spring Course Introduction Contracts Professor Keith A. Rowley William S. Boyd School of Law University of Nevada Las Vegas Course Introduction I. What is a Contract? A. Epstein, Markell & Ponoroff (p. 1): [A] promise or set of

More information

MBE WORKSHOP: CONTRACTS PROFESSOR LISA MCELROY DREXEL UNIVERSITY SCHOOL OF LAW

MBE WORKSHOP: CONTRACTS PROFESSOR LISA MCELROY DREXEL UNIVERSITY SCHOOL OF LAW MBE WORKSHOP: CONTRACTS PROFESSOR LISA MCELROY DREXEL UNIVERSITY SCHOOL OF LAW CHAPTER 1: CONTRACTS Editor's Note 1: The below outline is taken from the National Conference of Bar Examiners' website. NOTE:

More information

NEGATIVE TEN COURSE POINTS

NEGATIVE TEN COURSE POINTS Page 1 of 9 as your signature PRINT your name comprehensive EXAM #3 Business Law Fundamentals LAWS 3930 sections -001, -002-003 Chapters 1-4, 24, 6, 7, 9, 10 through 23, 43, 44, 46, 50, & 51 INSTRUCTIONS:

More information

Question 1. Under what theory or theories might Paul recover, and what is his likelihood of success, against: a. Charlie? b. KiddieRides-R-Us?

Question 1. Under what theory or theories might Paul recover, and what is his likelihood of success, against: a. Charlie? b. KiddieRides-R-Us? Question 1 Twelve-year-old Charlie was riding on his small, motorized 3-wheeled all terrain vehicle ( ATV ) in his family s large front yard. Suddenly, finding the steering wheel stuck in place, Charlie

More information

DRAFTING AND ANALYZING CONTRACTS

DRAFTING AND ANALYZING CONTRACTS 0001 VERSACOMP (4.2 ) COMPOSE2 (4.43) NEW LAW SCH. Front Matter SAMPLE for PERFECTBOUND Pubs J:\VRS\DAT\03037\FM.GML --- r3037_fm.sty --- POST DRAFTING AND ANALYZING CONTRACTS A Guide to the Practical

More information

IN THE COURT OF COMMON PLEAS OF LYCOMING COUNTY, PA. RICHARD PAULHAMAUS, : Plaintiff : : v. : No ,962 : WEIS MARKETS, INC.

IN THE COURT OF COMMON PLEAS OF LYCOMING COUNTY, PA. RICHARD PAULHAMAUS, : Plaintiff : : v. : No ,962 : WEIS MARKETS, INC. IN THE COURT OF COMMON PLEAS OF LYCOMING COUNTY, PA RICHARD PAULHAMAUS, : Plaintiff : : v. : No. 97-01,962 : WEIS MARKETS, INC., : Defendant : OPINION AND ORDER Defendant Weis Markets has requested this

More information

Recent Case: Sales - Limitation of Remedies - Failure of Essential Purpose [Adams v. J.I. Case Co., 125 Ill. App. 2d 368, 261 N.E.

Recent Case: Sales - Limitation of Remedies - Failure of Essential Purpose [Adams v. J.I. Case Co., 125 Ill. App. 2d 368, 261 N.E. Case Western Reserve Law Review Volume 22 Issue 2 1971 Recent Case: Sales - Limitation of Remedies - Failure of Essential Purpose [Adams v. J.I. Case Co., 125 Ill. App. 2d 368, 261 N.E.2d 1 (1970)] Case

More information

Prosecuting the Press for Publishing Classified Information

Prosecuting the Press for Publishing Classified Information University of Chicago Law School Chicago Unbound Journal Articles Faculty Scholarship 2006 Prosecuting the Press for Publishing Classified Information Geoffrey R. Stone Follow this and additional works

More information

CHAPTER 2 CONTRACT LAWS INDIAN CONTRACT ACT, A contract is an agreement made between two or more parties which the law will enforce.

CHAPTER 2 CONTRACT LAWS INDIAN CONTRACT ACT, A contract is an agreement made between two or more parties which the law will enforce. CHAPTER 2 CONTRACT LAWS INDIAN CONTRACT ACT, 1872 Definition of Contract A contract is an agreement made between two or more parties which the law will enforce. Sec 2(h) defines contract as an agreement

More information

Concord University School of Law Practice Essay

Concord University School of Law Practice Essay Concord University School of Law Practice Essay Instructions: This is a timed practice, and you should take no more than one hour to complete this exercise. Set a timer and allow no interruptions. Before

More information

Chapter XIX EQUITY CONDENSED OUTLINE

Chapter XIX EQUITY CONDENSED OUTLINE Chapter XIX EQUITY CONDENSED OUTLINE I. NATURE AND SCOPE OF EQUITY B. Equitable Maxims and Other General Doctrines. C. Marshaling Assets. II. SPECIFIC PERFORMANCE OF CONTRACTS B. When Specific Performance

More information

LAW OFFICE OF MARK ROYSNER Mulholland Highway, Suite 382 Calabasas, CA

LAW OFFICE OF MARK ROYSNER Mulholland Highway, Suite 382 Calabasas, CA WHAT DOES THAT MEAN? Definitions of Legal Terms Typically Found in Meetings and Exhibition Industry Contracts. By Mark Roysner, Esq. This is a glossary of legal terms and phrases commonly found in hotel,

More information

Strict Liability and Product Liability PRODUCT LIABILITY WARRANTY LAW

Strict Liability and Product Liability PRODUCT LIABILITY WARRANTY LAW Strict Liability and Product Liability PRODUCT LIABILITY The legal liability of manufacturers, sellers, and lessors of goods to consumers, users and bystanders for physical harm or injuries or property

More information

CONTRACTS. A contract is a legally enforceable agreement between two or more parties whereby they make the future more predictable.

CONTRACTS. A contract is a legally enforceable agreement between two or more parties whereby they make the future more predictable. CONTRACTS LESE Spring 2002 O'Hara 1 A contract is a legally enforceable agreement between two or more parties whereby they make the future more predictable. Contracts are in addition to the preexisting,

More information

CHAPTER EIGHT. Conclusion. 8.0 The Research Question and its Impact on the Existing Literature. Contracts for the International Sale of Goods 1980.

CHAPTER EIGHT. Conclusion. 8.0 The Research Question and its Impact on the Existing Literature. Contracts for the International Sale of Goods 1980. CHAPTER EIGHT Conclusion 8.0 The Research Question and its Impact on the Existing Literature The purpose of this thesis has been to examine the interpretation and application of the buyer s remedy of avoidance

More information

CONTRACTS Mid-Term Examination Santa Barbara College of Law Fall 2000 Instructor: Craig Smith. Time Allotted - Two Hours

CONTRACTS Mid-Term Examination Santa Barbara College of Law Fall 2000 Instructor: Craig Smith. Time Allotted - Two Hours CONTRACTS Mid-Term Examination Santa Barbara College of Law Fall 2000 Instructor: Craig Smith Time Allotted - Two Hours An answer should demonstrate your ability to analyze the facts presented by the question,

More information

Contract Law for Paralegals: Chapter 8 Chapter 8

Contract Law for Paralegals: Chapter 8 Chapter 8 Contract Law for Paralegals: Chapter 8 Chapter 8 Tab Text CHAPTER 8 Contract Enforceability: Protecting a Party Against Overreaching Chapter 8 deals with the second group of contract enforcement problems-ad

More information

California Bar Examination

California Bar Examination California Bar Examination Essay Question: Torts And Selected Answers The Orahte Group is NOT affiliated with The State Bar of California PRACTICE PACKET p.1 Question Autos, Inc. manufactures a two-seater

More information

Contracts II Professor Keith A. Rowley William S. Boyd School of Law University of Nevada Las Vegas Spring 2004

Contracts II Professor Keith A. Rowley William S. Boyd School of Law University of Nevada Las Vegas Spring 2004 Contracts II Professor Keith A. Rowley William S. Boyd School of Law University of Nevada Las Vegas Sample Exam Question #5 - Model Answer In the words of renowned contracts scholar Pete Townshend, A promise

More information

Restatement Third of Torts: Coordination and Continuation *

Restatement Third of Torts: Coordination and Continuation * Restatement Third of Torts: Coordination and Continuation * With the near completion of the project on Physical-Emotional Harm, the Third Restatement of Torts now covers a wide swath of tort territory,

More information

TITLE 7 CONTRACTS TABLE OF CONTENTS

TITLE 7 CONTRACTS TABLE OF CONTENTS TITLE 7 CONTRACTS TABLE OF CONTENTS CHAPTER 7.01 General Provisions 7.0101 Definition 1 7.0102 Essential elements of a contract 1 7.0103 Law of place applied to contracts 1 7.0104 Time of performance 1

More information

TYPES OF MONETARY DAMAGES

TYPES OF MONETARY DAMAGES TYPES OF MONETARY DAMAGES A breach of contract entitles the non-breaching party to sue for money damages, including: Compensatory Damages: Damages that compensate the non-breaching party for the injuries

More information

CONTRACTS Ponoroff 2016

CONTRACTS Ponoroff 2016 A. Contract Law (Overview) a. Contract The promise or set of promises that the law recognizes by way of enforcement. i. Promise The liability involved in contract law is undertaken intentionally by the

More information

Dilution's (Still) Uncertain Future

Dilution's (Still) Uncertain Future Chicago-Kent College of Law From the SelectedWorks of Graeme B. Dinwoodie 2006 Dilution's (Still) Uncertain Future Graeme B. Dinwoodie, Chicago-Kent College of Law Available at: https://works.bepress.com/graeme_dinwoodie/47/

More information

PRIVATIZATION AND INSTITUTIONAL CHOICE

PRIVATIZATION AND INSTITUTIONAL CHOICE PRIVATIZATION AND INSTITUTIONAL CHOICE Neil K. K omesar* Professor Ronald Cass has presented us with a paper which has many levels and aspects. He has provided us with a taxonomy of privatization; a descripton

More information

Illegality. Illegality. Meaning of Illegality. Irwin/McGraw-Hill 2001 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All Rights Reserved.

Illegality. Illegality. Meaning of Illegality. Irwin/McGraw-Hill 2001 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All Rights Reserved. Illegality Chapter 15 (8) Slide 1 Illegality When an agreement involves an act or a promise that violates some legislative or court-made rule, agreement will not be enforceable on ground of illegality

More information

A Comparative Study of the Uniform Commercial Code and the Foreign Economic Contract Law of the People's Republic of China

A Comparative Study of the Uniform Commercial Code and the Foreign Economic Contract Law of the People's Republic of China Berkeley Journal of International Law Volume 6 Issue 1 Winter Article 2 1988 A Comparative Study of the Uniform Commercial Code and the Foreign Economic Contract Law of the People's Republic of China Yan

More information

CONTRACT LAW (2) Il est précisé que le thème «CONTRACT LAW» est abordé à travers 2 fiches, cette fiche étant la seconde. I. VALIDITY OF THE CONTRACT

CONTRACT LAW (2) Il est précisé que le thème «CONTRACT LAW» est abordé à travers 2 fiches, cette fiche étant la seconde. I. VALIDITY OF THE CONTRACT CONTRACT LAW (2) Il est précisé que le thème «CONTRACT LAW» est abordé à travers 2 fiches, cette fiche étant la seconde. Plan : I. VALIDITY OF THE CONTRACT II. LEGALITY OF THE SUBJECT MATTER III. REALITY

More information

Expectation Damages Now A Real Possibility In Delaware

Expectation Damages Now A Real Possibility In Delaware Portfolio Media. Inc. 860 Broadway, 6th Floor New York, NY 10003 www.law360.com Phone: +1 646 783 7100 Fax: +1 646 783 7161 customerservice@law360.com Expectation Damages Now A Real Possibility In Delaware

More information

CONTRACTS MID-TERM EXAMINATION December 2006 Santa Barbara/Ventura Colleges of Law Instructor: Craig Smith QUESTION 1

CONTRACTS MID-TERM EXAMINATION December 2006 Santa Barbara/Ventura Colleges of Law Instructor: Craig Smith QUESTION 1 CONTRACTS MID-TERM EXAMINATION December 2006 Santa Barbara/Ventura Colleges of Law Instructor: Craig Smith QUESTION 1 Moe was a collector of exotic cars. One day he saw an ad in the classified section

More information

UNITED STATES BANKRUPTCY COURT FOR THE WESTERN DISTRICT OF MICHIGAN

UNITED STATES BANKRUPTCY COURT FOR THE WESTERN DISTRICT OF MICHIGAN UNITED STATES BANKRUPTCY COURT FOR THE WESTERN DISTRICT OF MICHIGAN In re: MODERN PLASTICS CORPORATION, Debtor. / NEW PRODUCTS CORPORATION and UNITED STATES OF AMERICA, Case No. 09-00651 Hon. Scott W.

More information

California Bar Examination

California Bar Examination California Bar Examination Essay Question: Contracts And Selected Answers The Orahte Group is NOT affiliated with The State Bar of California PRACTICE PACKET p.1 Question Berelli Co., the largest single

More information

INTERNATIONAL SALE OF GOODS ACT

INTERNATIONAL SALE OF GOODS ACT c t INTERNATIONAL SALE OF GOODS ACT PLEASE NOTE This document, prepared by the Legislative Counsel Office, is an office consolidation of this Act, current to December 2, 2015. It is intended for information

More information

Contracts II Professor Keith A. Rowley William S. Boyd School of Law University of Nevada Las Vegas Spring Optional Homework #1 - Model Answers

Contracts II Professor Keith A. Rowley William S. Boyd School of Law University of Nevada Las Vegas Spring Optional Homework #1 - Model Answers Contracts II Professor Keith A. Rowley William S. Boyd School of Law University of Nevada Las Vegas Optional Homework #1 - Model Answers 1. Read King v. Trustees of Boston University, 647 N.E.2d 1196 (Mass.

More information

POLITICAL AUTHORITY AND PERFECTIONISM: A RESPONSE TO QUONG

POLITICAL AUTHORITY AND PERFECTIONISM: A RESPONSE TO QUONG SYMPOSIUM POLITICAL LIBERALISM VS. LIBERAL PERFECTIONISM POLITICAL AUTHORITY AND PERFECTIONISM: A RESPONSE TO QUONG JOSEPH CHAN 2012 Philosophy and Public Issues (New Series), Vol. 2, No. 1 (2012): pp.

More information

RESTATEMENT (THIRD) OF TORTS: COORDINATION AND CONTINUATION

RESTATEMENT (THIRD) OF TORTS: COORDINATION AND CONTINUATION RESTATEMENT (THIRD) OF TORTS: COORDINATION AND CONTINUATION Ellen Pryor* With the near completion of the project on Physical and Emotional Harm, the Restatement (Third) of Torts now covers a wide swath

More information

CONDENSED OUTLINE FOR TORTS I

CONDENSED OUTLINE FOR TORTS I Condensed Outline of Torts I (DeWolf), November 25, 2003 1 CONDENSED OUTLINE FOR TORTS I [Use this only as a supplement and corrective for your own more detailed outlines!] The classic definition of a

More information

Testing Political Economy Models of Reform in the Laboratory

Testing Political Economy Models of Reform in the Laboratory Testing Political Economy Models of Reform in the Laboratory By TIMOTHY N. CASON AND VAI-LAM MUI* * Department of Economics, Krannert School of Management, Purdue University, West Lafayette, IN 47907-1310,

More information

Afterword: Rational Choice Approach to Legal Rules

Afterword: Rational Choice Approach to Legal Rules Chicago-Kent Law Review Volume 65 Issue 1 Symposium on Post-Chicago Law and Economics Article 10 April 1989 Afterword: Rational Choice Approach to Legal Rules Jules L. Coleman Follow this and additional

More information

Contract Law Final Exam Version C

Contract Law Final Exam Version C Contract Law Final Exam Version C True/False Indicate whether the statement is true or false. 1. Compliance and excuse are valid defenses to a breach of contract action. 2. To have a constructive or implied

More information

EFFICIENCY OF COMPARATIVE NEGLIGENCE : A GAME THEORETIC ANALYSIS

EFFICIENCY OF COMPARATIVE NEGLIGENCE : A GAME THEORETIC ANALYSIS EFFICIENCY OF COMPARATIVE NEGLIGENCE : A GAME THEORETIC ANALYSIS TAI-YEONG CHUNG * The widespread shift from contributory negligence to comparative negligence in the twentieth century has spurred scholars

More information

BARRY ALLAN CONTACT PART II. Introduction 1. OBJECTIVE THEORY OF CONTRACT 2. A MODEL OF CONTRACT

BARRY ALLAN CONTACT PART II. Introduction 1. OBJECTIVE THEORY OF CONTRACT 2. A MODEL OF CONTRACT BARRY ALLAN CONTACT PART II Introduction 1. OBJECTIVE THEORY OF CONTRACT We use the objective principle to decide whether there has been an agreement, consideration and intention to be bound between the

More information

CHANGES TO OHIO S GENERAL CORPORATION LAW, NONPROFIT CORPORATION LAW, AND LLC CODE: A MIXED BAG. by James B. Rosenthal Cohen Rosenthal & Kramer LLP

CHANGES TO OHIO S GENERAL CORPORATION LAW, NONPROFIT CORPORATION LAW, AND LLC CODE: A MIXED BAG. by James B. Rosenthal Cohen Rosenthal & Kramer LLP CHANGES TO OHIO S GENERAL CORPORATION LAW, NONPROFIT CORPORATION LAW, AND LLC CODE: A MIXED BAG by James B. Rosenthal Cohen Rosenthal & Kramer LLP 2012 James B. Rosenthal The Ohio legislature has passed

More information

UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE FOURTH CIRCUIT. v. No

UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE FOURTH CIRCUIT. v. No PUBLISHED UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE FOURTH CIRCUIT 4444444444444444444444444444444444444444444444447 HESS ENERGY, INCORPORATED, Plaintiff-Appellee, v. No. 02-2129 LIGHTNING OIL COMPANY, LIMITED,

More information

STATE OF MICHIGAN COURT OF APPEALS

STATE OF MICHIGAN COURT OF APPEALS STATE OF MICHIGAN COURT OF APPEALS DAVID J. CONRAD, D.D.S., and ROBERTA A. CONRAD, UNPUBLISHED December 12, 2013 Plaintiffs-Appellants, v No. 308705 Saginaw Circuit Court CERTAINTEED CORPORATION, LC No.

More information

Genuineness of Assent

Genuineness of Assent Genuineness of Assent A party who demonstrates that she did not genuinely assent to the terms of a contract may avoid an otherwise valid contract. Genuine assent may be lacking due to mistake, fraudulent

More information

The Justification of Justice as Fairness: A Two Stage Process

The Justification of Justice as Fairness: A Two Stage Process The Justification of Justice as Fairness: A Two Stage Process TED VAGGALIS University of Kansas The tragic truth about philosophy is that misunderstanding occurs more frequently than understanding. Nowhere

More information

Econ 522 Review 3: Tort Law, Criminal Law, and the Legal Process

Econ 522 Review 3: Tort Law, Criminal Law, and the Legal Process Econ 522 Review 3: Tort Law, Criminal Law, and the Legal Process Spring 2014 This document is by no means comprehensive, but instead serves as a rough guide to the material we have discussed on tort law,

More information

Comment on Baker's Autonomy and Free Speech

Comment on Baker's Autonomy and Free Speech University of Minnesota Law School Scholarship Repository Constitutional Commentary 2011 Comment on Baker's Autonomy and Free Speech T.M. Scanlon Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarship.law.umn.edu/concomm

More information

Prufrex USA, Inc. TERMS AND CONDITIONS OF PURCHASE

Prufrex USA, Inc. TERMS AND CONDITIONS OF PURCHASE Prufrex USA, Inc. TERMS AND CONDITIONS OF PURCHASE 1 Contract Formation: These Terms and Conditions of Purchase (the "Terms and Conditions") apply to any purchases by Prufrex USA, Inc., its subsidiaries,

More information

Question 3. Sam hereby agrees that he will not perform interior design services in Town for a period of two years.

Question 3. Sam hereby agrees that he will not perform interior design services in Town for a period of two years. Question 3 Sam decided to sell his interior design business in Town to Betty. While reviewing a purchase agreement drafted by Sam, Betty insisted on a covenant by Sam not to compete with her in the interior

More information

NEGLIGENCE. All four of the following must be demonstrated for a legal claim of negligence to be successful:

NEGLIGENCE. All four of the following must be demonstrated for a legal claim of negligence to be successful: NEGLIGENCE WHAT IS NEGLIGENCE? Negligence is unintentional harm to others as a result of an unsatisfactory degree of care. It occurs when a person NEGLECTS to do something that a reasonably prudent person

More information

FAIRNESS VERSUS WELFARE. Louis Kaplow & Steven Shavell. Thesis: Policy Analysis Should Be Based Exclusively on Welfare Economics

FAIRNESS VERSUS WELFARE. Louis Kaplow & Steven Shavell. Thesis: Policy Analysis Should Be Based Exclusively on Welfare Economics FAIRNESS VERSUS WELFARE Louis Kaplow & Steven Shavell Thesis: Policy Analysis Should Be Based Exclusively on Welfare Economics Plan of Book! Define/contrast welfare economics & fairness! Support thesis

More information

The Culture of Modern Tort Law

The Culture of Modern Tort Law Valparaiso University Law Review Volume 34 Number 3 pp.573-579 Summer 2000 The Culture of Modern Tort Law George L. Priest Recommended Citation George L. Priest, The Culture of Modern Tort Law, 34 Val.

More information

CHAPTER 8: GENUINE AGREEMENT

CHAPTER 8: GENUINE AGREEMENT CHAPTER 8: GENUINE AGREEMENT GENUINE AGREEMENT AND RESCISSION A valid offer and valid acceptance generally results in an enforceable contract. If one of the parties used physical threats to acquire the

More information

Comments and observations received from Governments

Comments and observations received from Governments Extract from the Yearbook of the International Law Commission:- 1997,vol. II(1) Document:- A/CN.4/481 and Add.1 Comments and observations received from Governments Topic: International liability for injurious

More information

Title. The Uniform Trust Decanting Act s conflicting official commentary. Summary. The Text

Title. The Uniform Trust Decanting Act s conflicting official commentary. Summary. The Text Title The Uniform Trust Decanting Act s conflicting official commentary Summary The texts of the myriad trust-related uniform statutes could be better coordinated and synchronized. So also could the official

More information

SALE OF GOODS (VIENNA CONVENTION) ACT 1986 No. 119

SALE OF GOODS (VIENNA CONVENTION) ACT 1986 No. 119 SALE OF GOODS (VIENNA CONVENTION) ACT 1986 No. 119 NEW SOUTH WALES TABLE OF PROVISIONS 1. Short title 2. Commencement 3. Interpretation 4. Act binds Crown 5. Convention to have the force of law 6. Convention

More information

Reality of Consent. Reality of Consent. Reality of Consent. Chapter 13

Reality of Consent. Reality of Consent. Reality of Consent. Chapter 13 Reality of Consent Chapter 13 Reality of Consent It is crucial to the economy and commerce that the law be counted on to enforce contracts. However, in some cases there are compelling reasons to permit

More information

UC Berkeley Latin American and Caribbean Law and Economics Association (ALACDE) Annual Papers

UC Berkeley Latin American and Caribbean Law and Economics Association (ALACDE) Annual Papers UC Berkeley Latin American and Caribbean Law and Economics Association (ALACDE) Annual Papers Title Fault in Contract Law Permalink https://escholarship.org/uc/item/8j99f7hh Author Posner, Eric A. Publication

More information

ARE UNREASONED ARBITRATION AWARDS IRRATIONAL? Robert M. Hall

ARE UNREASONED ARBITRATION AWARDS IRRATIONAL? Robert M. Hall ARE UNREASONED ARBITRATION AWARDS IRRATIONAL? By Robert M. Hall [Mr. Hall is a former law firm partner, a former insurance and reinsurance company executive and acts as a reinsurance and insurance consultant

More information

Contracts - Credit Card Liability Resulting from Unauthorized Use - Texaco v. Goldstein, 229 N.Y.S.2d 51 (Munic. Ct. 1962)

Contracts - Credit Card Liability Resulting from Unauthorized Use - Texaco v. Goldstein, 229 N.Y.S.2d 51 (Munic. Ct. 1962) DePaul Law Review Volume 12 Issue 1 Fall-Winter 1962 Article 14 Contracts - Credit Card Liability Resulting from Unauthorized Use - Texaco v. Goldstein, 229 N.Y.S.2d 51 (Munic. Ct. 1962) DePaul College

More information

ARCHITECTS REGISTRATION COUNCIL SEMINARS

ARCHITECTS REGISTRATION COUNCIL SEMINARS ARCHITECTS REGISTRATION COUNCIL SEMINARS CONTRACT FORMATION FRED PHIRI ARCH.Bw May 27, 2017 1 Contents Legal Systems Legal Systems Examples Legal System Applications Civil Law Relationships Law of Obligations

More information

A) Preliminaries B) Formation

A) Preliminaries B) Formation Contracts Page 1 of 12 A) Preliminaries 1) Governing law The Uniform Commercial Code (UCC) governs transactions that are predominantly for goods (movable property, identifiable to the contract at formation),

More information

TRIBUTE GEOFFREY C. HAZARD, JR., AND THE LESSONS OF HISTORY

TRIBUTE GEOFFREY C. HAZARD, JR., AND THE LESSONS OF HISTORY TRIBUTE GEOFFREY C. HAZARD, JR., AND THE LESSONS OF HISTORY TOBIAS BARRINGTON WOLFF In the field of civil procedure, it is sometimes a struggle to get practitioners, judges, and scholars to give history

More information