Immigrant-Native Differences in Welfare Participation: The Role of Entry and Exit Rates

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Immigrant-Native Differences in Welfare Participation: The Role of Entry and Exit Rates"

Transcription

1 DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No Immigrant-Native Differences in Welfare Participation: The Role of Entry and Exit Rates Jörgen Hansen Magnus Lofstrom August 2006 Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit Institute for the Study of Labor

2 Immigrant-Native Differences in Welfare Participation: The Role of Entry and Exit Rates Jörgen Hansen Concordia University, CEPR, CIRANO, CIREQ and IZA Bonn Magnus Lofstrom University of Texas at Dallas and IZA Bonn Discussion Paper No August 2006 IZA P.O. Box Bonn Germany Phone: Fax: Any opinions expressed here are those of the author(s) and not those of the institute. Research disseminated by IZA may include views on policy, but the institute itself takes no institutional policy positions. The Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA) in Bonn is a local and virtual international research center and a place of communication between science, politics and business. IZA is an independent nonprofit company supported by Deutsche Post World Net. The center is associated with the University of Bonn and offers a stimulating research environment through its research networks, research support, and visitors and doctoral programs. IZA engages in (i) original and internationally competitive research in all fields of labor economics, (ii) development of policy concepts, and (iii) dissemination of research results and concepts to the interested public. IZA Discussion Papers often represent preliminary work and are circulated to encourage discussion. Citation of such a paper should account for its provisional character. A revised version may be available directly from the author.

3 IZA Discussion Paper No August 2006 ABSTRACT Immigrant-Native Differences in Welfare Participation: The Role of Entry and Exit Rates * This paper analyzes differences in welfare transitions between natives and immigrants in Sweden using a large representative panel data set, LINDA, for the years 1991 to The data contains administrative information on welfare use, country of birth, and time of arrival in Sweden among other things, and provides an excellent opportunity to examine immigrantnative differences in welfare use. The empirical results suggest that the main reason for the large immigrant-native welfare gap observed in the data is differences in welfare entry rates. Thus, policies aimed to reduce these transitions may be particularly successful in reducing welfare use in general and the immigrant-native welfare gap in particular. JEL Classification: I30, I38, J15, J18, J61 Keywords: welfare, immigration, labor market behavior, transition, state dependence Corresponding author: Magnus Lofstrom University of Texas at Dallas School of Social Sciences P.O. Box GR 31 Richardson, TX USA lofstrom@utdallas.edu * We would like to thank Ken Chay for providing programming code for estimation of the fixed effects logit specification utilized.

4 1. Introduction The increase in immigration experienced by many Western countries in the last decade has led to raised concerns regarding immigrant over-utilization in welfare programs. In fact, this concern has incited some countries to restrict access to some government transfer programs for immigrants. In the U.S. for example, The Personal Responsibility and Work Opportunity Reconciliation Act (PRWORA) of 1996, restricts non-citizens who arrived after 1996 the right to receive most types of public assistance. In Germany, immigrants without permanent residency may lose the right to stay in the country or may be denied residency extensions if they depend on social assistance. Although the country studied in this paper, Sweden, does not treat immigrants differently from natives with respect to social assistance, immigration is central to the welfare debate. By the mid-1990 s immigrants in Sweden accounted for nearly half of the country s expenditure on social assistance. 1 This is quite remarkable since immigrants represent approximately an 11 percent minority of the population (roughly the same foreign born population proportion as in the US, the UK, Austria, Belgium, France and the Netherlands). In addition, given that real expenditures on the social assistance program in Sweden increased by 170 percent between 1983 and 1996 and that the share of immigrants in the population during the same period increased from 7.6 percent to 10.8 percent, it is clear that understanding immigrants welfare utilization is essential in explaining the expenditure trend. Several studies have examined differences in welfare participation between immigrants and natives (see for instance Baker and Benjamin, 1995; Borjas and Hilton, 1996; Hansen and Lofstrom, 2003 and Riphahn, 1998 for Canada, the U.S., Sweden and Germany respectively). However, to our knowledge, no study has analyzed immigrant welfare entry and exits, mainly due to a lack of representative panel data with sufficiently large number of foreign born individuals. Understanding the dynamic processes underlying the observed utilization of government transfer programs is essential, as pointed out by Plant (1984). Of interest is also whether there are differences in the 1 The increase in welfare expenditures can at least partially be explained by the increase in refugee immigrants from former Yugoslavia who arrived during this period. 1

5 transitions between foreign and native born. This is of particular importance since immigrants are commonly found to be more likely to participate in welfare programs than natives in, for example, Sweden, Germany and the U.S. (Hansen and Lofstrom, 2003; Riphahn, 1998 and Borjas and Hilton, 1996). An important question is whether the higher participation rates are due to higher entry rates among immigrants or lower exit rates, or a combination of the two. If, for example, immigrant and native welfare entry rates are similar, but immigrants display lower welfare exit rates, this would suggest that welfare is more of a temporary income support for native households than among immigrant households, who once they have started to receive assistance, may have difficulties leaving welfare. In this paper we confine the analysis to transitions into and out of welfare and/or unemployment. Given that welfare may act as a form of unemployment insurance, particularly for new immigrants who are not yet eligible for the existing unemployment compensation programs, we consider alternative definitions of welfare participation to address this issue. Our goal is to answer the following questions: Are the greater welfare participation rates among immigrants due to differences in entry and/or exit rates and what are the specific roles of differences in welfare dynamics on the immigrant-native welfare gap? We also address the question of what factors affect welfare transition probabilities. To answer these questions we estimate dynamic logit models, controlling for both endogenous initial condition and unobserved heterogeneity, taking advantage of a large nationally representative longitudinal data set, Longitudinal Individual Data (LINDA). The data utilized contains information on more than 300,000 individuals annually for the period 1991 to The data is collected from administrative records which imply essentially no attrition and equally important, accurately reported welfare status. The data show that immigrants are more likely to stay on welfare, or to receive unemployment insurance, given participation in the previous year and are less likely to exit welfare/unemployment in consecutive years than natives. Our empirical results suggest that the main reason for the immigrant-native welfare gap is differences in welfare entry rates. When using natives estimated entry rates in predicting welfare participation for immigrants, we found that the welfare gap diminished substantially. 2

6 While using natives estimated exit rates also reduced the gap, the reduction was substantially smaller. Our results also indicate that immigrant-native differences in observable characteristics are not the main contributors to the immigrant-native welfare gap. Although some aspects of the immigrant welfare experiences are likely to be unique to Sweden, the many similarities in the immigrant and asylum seeker inflow, including how refugee immigrants are introduced to the new countries public assistance systems and the difficulties faced in the labor market, suggests that our results are informative to the immigration debate in other countries. The paper is organized in the following way. In section 2 we give background information about immigration, the social assistance program and unemployment insurance in Sweden. Section 3 describes the data and variables while Section 4 depicts trends and differences, between immigrants and natives, in government transfer program participation and transitions. In Section 5 we present the model and empirical specification. We discuss the results in Section 6 and conclude in Section Immigration and Welfare Programs in Sweden One important reason for the increase in welfare participation during the first half of the 1990 s, and the consequent growth in expenditures, was the widespread downturn in the economy and the subsequent rise in unemployment during this period. Figure 1 shows separately the unemployment rate for Swedish and foreign citizens between 1991 and The official unemployment rate, among Swedish citizens, grew from 1.7 percent in 1990 to around 8 percent in 1996 and For foreign citizens, the labor market deteriorated even more. In 1990, approximately 4 percent were unemployed. This had increased to 25 percent by Even though the unemployment rates for foreign citizens decreased more than those for Swedish citizens in the subsequent period, a large gap remains in Additionally, the increase in welfare expenditures in Sweden in the 2 We lack information on separate unemployment rates for natives and immigrants for this period. It should be noted that the group of Swedish citizens include naturalized foreign-born individuals. 3

7 1990 s can partly be explained by the large inflows of immigrants who arrived during this period, who were not yet eligible for unemployment insurance, and therefore had to rely on social assistance for their subsistence. Immigration into Sweden The inflow of immigrants to Sweden has undergone a number of changes during the last six decades. Figure 2 shows annual immigration to Sweden from 1940 to 2001, both in terms of the level of the immigrant inflow and inflow expressed as the proportion of the total population in the corresponding year. Overall, annual immigration has amounted to about 0.4 percent of the population, but notably higher during the 1990 s. Naturally, the large inflow of immigrants has also changed the composition of the population in Sweden. The reasons people immigrate to Sweden have changed substantially since World- War II. In principle, we can distinguish between three categories of immigrants, based on the reasons for immigration: economic migrants (e.g. due to the recruitment of labor), tied movers (i.e. family ties) and refugees. In the late 1940 s, a large fraction of the immigrants arrived in Sweden as refugees, mainly from the Nordic countries. However, in the period from 1950 to 1970, most of the immigrants were recruited by the Swedish industry or migrated because of family ties. The recruitment of foreign workers during the 1950 s and 1960 s was also prevalent in other European countries, such as Austria, Germany and the Netherlands (Bauer et al, 2000). From 1970 and onwards, the proportion of immigrants arriving as refugees has increased significantly, from less than 10 percent of the immigrant inflow in 1970 to about 70 percent in the early 1990 s. In 1994, this proportion dropped from 70 percent to about 50 percent, mostly due to the improved conditions in the Balkan countries. Since the 1980 s, roughly 1/3 of refugee immigrants migrated from former Yugoslavia and approximately 1/4 from Iran and Iraq. Overall, about one half of immigrants in Sweden today come from Europe, of these, 40 percent are Nordic citizens. Social Assistance in Sweden 4

8 The Swedish welfare system is well known internationally for the high degree of income security that it provides for its citizens. Recently, this generous system has been the target of a number of reforms, mainly due to the recession that hit Sweden, and many other countries, in the early 1990 s. As an ultimate safety net, people in Sweden are covered by social assistance (SA). As with unemployment insurance, the eligibility rules and benefit levels are the same for immigrants and natives. In order to be eligible for SA, all other welfare programs, such as unemployment compensation, housing allowance (bostadsbidrag), child allowance (barnbidrag), maintenance allowance (underhållsbidrag) and various pensions, must be exhausted first. The benefit levels vary both across family types and regions, but are intended to cover expenses essential for a decent standard of living. To be eligible for SA benefits, a family must have income and assets below certain specified benefits levels, known as norms. The norms were, until 1998, determined in each of the 288 municipalities in Sweden. However, as of the 1 st of January 1998, the regional variations in the norms were replaced by a national norm in order to reduce the inequality aspect of having differentiated benefit levels across municipalities. 3 The norms serve as guidelines for the social worker who decides the actual size of the benefits. SA benefits are paid according to a schedule that sets a guarantee amount for a family of a given size. These benefits are reduced at a 100 percent reduction rate as the family s income rises. Unemployment Insurance in Sweden The Swedish unemployment insurance system consists of two parts: unemployment benefits (Arbetslöshetskassa, UB) and unemployment assistance (Kontant arbetsmarknadsstöd, UA). In 1990, the coverage was slightly less than 80 percent of the labor force, with roughly 70 percent covered by UB and 10 percent by UA. To be entitled to compensation from UB, an unemployed worker must have paid membership fees to the 3 According to the national norm in 1998, a single person would receive 2,884 SEK per month in SA while a couple with two children would receive about 7,500 SEK per month (depending on the age of the children). These amounts are intended to cover expenses for so called necessary consumption, such as food, basic clothing, leisure, health, newspapers, telephone and fees for TV, and partially for housing. The SA system also grants the right to so called reasonable housing, which is not included in the norm amount. The additional assistance for housing is known as "bostadsbidrag". In 1998, the exchange rate was roughly 8 SEK per U.S. Dollar, about the same as the current, 2006, exchange rate. 5

9 UB fund for the last 12 months and must have been working for at least 75 days preceding the current unemployment spell. These conditions imply that many of the new entrants in the labor market, such as young workers and immigrants, are not entitled to compensation from UB. There is a time limit on UB and entitled workers can receive benefits for a maximum of 300 working days. Compared to non-scandinavian countries, the benefit levels are quite generous with replacement rates varying between 75 and 90 percent during the 1990 s. 4 Workers who are not eligible for receiving UB may be entitled to compensation from UA. There exists a similar work requirement for receiving UA as for receiving UB, but there is no membership requirement. However, UA is substantially less generous than UB, both in terms of benefit duration and compensation levels. 5 Immigration and Welfare in Other Developed Countries in the 1990s Sweden s immigrant experience in the 1990s is not unique, particularly regarding refugees and welfare. The inflow of new refugee immigrants in Europe has put an increased pressure on immigrant public assistance expenditure and hence increasing efforts have been taken to integrate immigrants effectively into the respective labor markets (SOPEMI, 2000). Like Sweden, Austria, France, Germany, the Netherlands and the United Kingdom, among others, received large numbers of asylum seekers during the 1990 s. The policy of introducing refugees to public assistance upon arrival in the new host country is not surprising given the limited available opportunities for self-support and is also utilized in, for example, Germany (Riphanh, 1998) and the Netherlands (van Ours and Veenman, 1999). U.S. policy also recognizes the difficult situation faced by newly arrived refugee immigrants and consequently, non-naturalized refugees in the U.S. are exempt from the restrictions placed on immigrant access to welfare introduced by PRWORA. Lastly, the relationship between immigrant and native unemployment is not unique to Sweden. Like Sweden, immigrants in Austria, Belgium, France and the 4 Until 1993, the UB replacement rate was 90 percent of earnings up to a maximum level determined by the government. In July 1993, the replacement rate was reduced to 80 percent and in January 1996, it was further reduced to 75 percent. The replacement rate was raised back to 80 percent in September of It should be noted that the actual unemployment compensation received through UB is frequently less than the replacement rate due to a relatively low maximum benefit amount. 6

10 Netherlands, also experience unemployment rates that are at least twice as high as the ones experienced by the native born population (SOPEMI, 2003). 3. Data Description of the Data and Sampling Procedures The data used in this paper is obtained from a recently created Swedish longitudinal data set, Longitudinal Individual Data (LINDA). LINDA is a register-based data set and it consists of a large panel of individuals, and their household members, which are representative for the population from 1960 to LINDA is a joint endeavor between the Department of Economics at Uppsala University, The National Social Insurance Board (RFV), Statistics Sweden, and the Ministries of Finance and Labor. The main administrator of the data set is Statistics Sweden. LINDA contains a 3 percent representative random sample of the Swedish population, corresponding to approximately 300,000 individuals for the period studied here. The sampled population consists of all individuals, including children and elderly persons, who live in Sweden in the given year. The sampling procedure used in constructing the panel data set ensures that each cross-section is representative for the population in each year. For a more detailed description of the data used here, including the sampling structure, see Edin and Fredriksson (2000). The sample used in this study consists of information from LINDA for the years and consists of men and women between the ages of 18 and 65. We exclude students and retired individuals. Furthermore, we restrict our sample to a balanced panel over the entire period, yielding a sample size of 92,223 individuals. As a sensitivity check, we estimate our models using an unbalanced panel. 6 We define a person to be an immigrant if he/she was born abroad, and a refugee immigrant if he/she was born in a refugee country, as defined by the Swedish Immigration Board, or in a sub-saharan 5 Under the UA program, an unemployed worker receives approximately 200 SEK/day, corresponding to roughly 30 percent of average earnings, and the maximum benefit period is 150 working days. 6 This is may be of particular importance since the balanced panel does not include immigrants who arrived after

11 country. 7 If the person is an immigrant or a refugee, we have information about the year of arrival in Sweden. 8 Table 1 shows summary statistics for the three groups, natives, immigrants from non-refugee and immigrants from refugee countries separately for men and women. In the subsequent analysis, we include immigrants who have been in Sweden for at least two years in a given time period. The reason for this sample selection is that the great majority of refugee immigrants receive welfare upon arrival to Sweden automatically. The immigration board then assists the refugee immigrants in various activities, including language training, in order to ease them into the labor market. A typical "integration" period lasts for 1-2 years. During this time, the immigrant is particularly limited in their choice of labor market states. Including these immigrants may therefore overstate the state dependence in welfare use among immigrants. To ensure that our results are not driven by this exclusion restriction, we estimated the models reported below including the most recent immigrants. The welfare dependence among refugee immigrants increases somewhat, as expected, but the conclusions regarding welfare dynamics remain largely unchanged. 9 Variable Definitions To answer the questions regarding welfare persistence in Sweden, we estimate dynamic logit models controlling for both unobserved individual heterogeneity and initial conditions. We want to capture dependence on two important government transfer programs that may serve different roles for immigrants and natives; receipt of social 7 The countries defined by the Swedish Immigration Board as refugee countries: Ethiopia, Afghanistan, Bulgaria, Bangladesh, Bosnia, Chile, Sri Lanka, Cuba, Iraq, Iran, India, Yugoslavia, China, Croatia, Lebanon, Moldavia, Peru, Pakistan, Poland, Russia, Soviet Union, Romania Somalia, Syria, Togo, Turkey, Ukraine, Uganda and Vietnam. However our refugee/non-refugee country definition is time variant with respect to arrival year. For example, immigrants from Yugoslavia who arrived prior to 1975 are defined as non-refugee immigrants and immigrants from the former Eastern Bloc countries, including the Soviet Union, who arrived after 1995 are also defined as non-refugee immigrants. 8 All immigrants included in LINDA, whether defined as refugees or not, have obtained residence permits. This means, for instance, that asylum seekers who have not yet obtained a residence permit are not included in LINDA. Furthermore, the data does not allow us to identify the exact year of arrival for immigrants who arrived in 1968 or earlier. 9 The possibility of non-random return migration is another reason to define the immigrant sample in this way. Edin et al (2000) find that that return migration among refugees is low, less than 10 percent within 5 years since arrival, and if an immigrant is to leave Sweden, it is most likely to take place within the first few years after arrival. By excluding the most recent immigrants we may decrease the potential effects of return migration on our estimates. We also find it comforting that the results do not change very much between the samples with and without the years since migration restriction. 8

12 assistance and unemployment compensation. Since many immigrants, particularly recently arrived immigrants, may not be eligible to receive unemployment benefits, we utilize two alternative state definitions. One is simply for receiving social assistance and the alternative measure is for collecting social assistance and/or unemployment compensation. Since LINDA lacks information about individuals time allocation, we need to rely on the income sources to classify individuals into the welfare states. We define individuals as welfare recipients if they received social assistance for at least one month during the year. We classify a person as a welfare/ui recipient if he or she received welfare for at least a month and/or received more than one-half of the so-called "basic amount", SEK 18,100, in unemployment benefits during the year. 10 Previous research has found greater sensitivity in public assistance participation to local labor market conditions among immigrants than natives in the U.S. (Lofstrom and Bean, 2002). To address this issue, local labor market variables are assigned to each individual in each year based on the individual s municipality of residence. The information is obtained from Statistics Sweden s labor force surveys. 4. Welfare Entry, Exit and Participation Sweden experienced an increase in immigration in the 1990 s. During this period the economy was also entrenched in a severe recession, with a trough around which only moderately leveled off by Throughout the period studied here, immigrants participated to a greater extent in social assistance, as well as our measures for receipt of either unemployment compensation and/or social assistance programs, than natives did, shown in Appendix Table A1. Furthermore, non-refugee immigrants utilized these programs less than refugees. The table also suggests that there is a greater difference between immigrant and native welfare utilization than in the immigrant-native difference in participation in the unemployment insurance programs. For example, the average welfare participation rate for male refugee immigrants during the

13 period was roughly six times higher than the average utilization rates for native born males. The average combined Welfare/UI participation rate was only around three times as high for refugees, relative to natives. The discrepancy in the relative utilization rates in the programs between immigrants and natives is at least partially due to UI ineligibility for, in particular recent, refugee immigrants. The table also shows that the immigrant-native participation gap is smaller for women than men. There are substantial differences in the dynamic welfare behavior between immigrants and natives. Table 2 shows transition probability matrices separately for the three groups, as well as by gender. This table reveals several interesting relationships and patterns. We first examine the issue of state dependence, i.e. the probability of staying on welfare in two consecutive years, in the raw data. The data shows that immigrants are more likely to receive welfare in a given year, conditional on having received welfare in the previous year. The probability that native born men will stay on welfare in two consecutive years is 0.62, while for both non-refugee and refugee immigrants it is higher, 0.66 and 0.72 respectively. This relative relationship holds for our alternative welfare measure which includes participation in either social assistance and/or UI, but the differences are somewhat smaller. Clearly, these results also mean that immigrants are less likely to move out-of welfare than natives. As with the unconditional participation probabilities, the differences across groups are smaller for women. In fact, there appear to be no difference in the probability to stay on welfare in two consecutive years for native born and non-refugee women. Conditional on not receiving welfare or unemployment compensation in a given year, it also appears that immigrants are more likely to collect either welfare or UI than natives are in the next year. Table 2 shows that about 1 percent of native males move from non-welfare dependence to welfare participation in consecutive years. The equivalent entry transition probability for refugee immigrants is slightly greater than 0.05, while it is close to 0.03 for non-refugee immigrants. If UI is included, the probability of shifting into welfare increases to 0.04 for native males, 0.05 for nonrefugee immigrants and to almost 0.1 for immigrants from refugee countries. As with the 10 The seemingly arbitrary value of annual unemployment compensation chosen to indicate unemployment, 18,100 SEK, refers to one-half of the so called "basic amount" or basbelopp in Swedish. The results presented below do not appear to be sensitive to alternative levels of annual unemployment compensation. 10

14 above reported probabilities, the differences across nativity groups are smaller for women. 11 One of the objectives of this paper is to study the determinants of the transitions, or movements, in and out-of public assistance, and if there are any differences in these determinants between immigrants and natives. However, before we analyze the observed disparity in the behavior of immigrants and natives, we want to briefly examine differences in the observable characteristics between individuals who stay in a particular state and the ones who change states. Appendix Tables A3 and A4 show mean characteristics by previous year s state separately for men and women by nativity group. In general, it appears that any movements out of welfare are associated with higher educational attainment, being married and having more children. Also a general relationship for state dependency appears to be age, namely, older individuals seem to be less likely to move out of previous year s state. Immigrants who have been in Sweden a longer time appear to be more likely to move out-of welfare and less likely to move into welfare. The descriptive statistics indicates that immigrants are more likely to utilize both welfare and unemployment compensation than natives. Immigrants from refugee countries participate in these transfer programs to a greater extent than non-refugee immigrants. This is caused by both lower welfare exit probabilities and higher welfare entry rates. The immigrant-native gap is particularly large for immigrants from refugee countries. Some of the above discussed differences between immigrants and natives may be due to differences in schooling levels, age, marital status, family composition, geographic location and local labor market conditions, but also to individual characteristics that are unobservable to the econometrician. 11 Given the differences in transition probabilities between immigrants and natives, we would also expect the distribution of the number of welfare and labor market spells to differ across groups. Table A2 shows the distribution of these spells for the balanced panel. Approximately 90 percent of native men did not utilize social assistance at all during the period , while only slightly more than half of refugee immigrants experienced no welfare participation spell. Close to 3 percent of refugee immigrants collected welfare for each of the eleven years. The respective figure for natives is substantially lower, 0.3 percent. Non-refugee immigrant men are utilizing social assistance less frequently than immigrants from refugee countries. These patterns hold up for the measure also including UI, as well as for women, although the differences are again smaller than what they are for men. 11

15 5. Model and Empirical Specification To analyze transitions into and out of welfare, we estimate a dynamic logit model designed to control for unobserved heterogeneity and endogenous initial conditions. We further assume that the dynamic structure of welfare use can be approximated by a firstorder Markov model. The model can be described as follows. Assume that individuals (indexed by i, i=1,2,,n) who belong to one of three nativity groups (indexed by m, natives (m=1), non-refugee immigrants (m=2), and refugee immigrants (m=3)) choose between receiving welfare and not receiving welfare benefits in any time period t (t=2,3,,t). Let the latent variable y * imt, which represents the value for an individual i, who belongs to nativity group m, from receiving welfare benefits at time t, be specified as: y = α + X β + y γ + ε y * imt m imt m imt 1 m imt imt = > * 1( yimt 0) where X imt is a vector of observable characteristics, including time dummies, age, educational attainment, family composition, local unemployment rate, years since migration, arrival cohort dummies, and source country dummies. 12 1( ) is an indicator function equal to one if the enclosed statement is true and zero otherwise, and y imt-1 is a dummy variable indicating if the individual received welfare in the previous time period or not. The error term, ε imt, is assumed to have the following error-components structure: εimt = ηim + νimt where η im represents an unobserved time-invariant individual specific effect and ν imt represents an error term and is assumed to be i.i.d. logistically distributed. 13 We also 12 We define the following immigrant arrival cohorts; arrival before 1968, between 1968 and 1975, between 1976 and 1980, between 1981 and 1985, between 1986 and 1990 and arrival after Note however that the permanent factor, η, allows for a particular form of serial correlation in ε. 12

16 assume that X imt is strictly exogenous, conditional on η im, and that η im is independent of ν imkt. 14 Given these assumptions, the probability that an individual i, from nativity group m, receives welfare at time t is: Py ( = 1 X, η, y,..., y ) = exp(-[ α + X β + y γ + η ]) imt im im im1 imt 1 m imt m imt 1 m im -1 where y im1 is an indicator of welfare recipiency in the initial sample period, and X ( X,..., X ). im im1 imt We follow Wooldridge (2005) and model the distribution of the unobserved effects conditional on the initial value of the dependent variable and any exogenous explanatory variables. 15 The main advantage with this approach is that it relaxes the need to explicitly specify a distribution for the initial condition, and we can write the latent variable * y imt, in this context as: y = α + X β + y γ + ε y * imt m imt m imt 1 m imt imt = > * 1( yimt 0) where εimt = ηim + νimt and η = X λ + y ρ + κ * im im m im1 m im 14 The strict exogeneity assumption implies, among other things, that feedback from the dependent variable on future values of the explanatory variables are ruled out. Arellano and Carrasco (2003) present and estimates models where this assumption is relaxed and the explanatory variables are instead predetermined. 15 See also Arellano and Carrasco (2003) for a discussion of alternative model specifications in binary choice panel data models. We have also estimated specifications under alternative assumptions regarding the unobserved heterogeneity and initial conditions (a random-effects model with a probability distribution on the initial conditions and a fixed-effects model which makes no assumptions on unobserved heterogeneity and initial conditions). We found that the results on welfare persistence were similar across alternative model specifications. The results are presented in Tables A5-A10. 13

17 where X * im is a row vector of all non-redundant explanatory variables in all time periods, so Xi ( Xi0,..., X it) defined above nests X * im. In this setup, the unobserved heterogeneity component, η im, is allowed to be correlated with X * im. Note however that the coefficients on time-invariant variables in X imt are not identified. The likelihood contribution for individual i given observed characteristics and unobserved heterogeneity, can be written as: T * im() θ = ( t = 2 imt imt 1, im1, Ximt, Ximt, κm ) g( κm )d κm L P y y y We assume that the probability distribution of κ im can be approximated by a discrete distribution with a finite number, J, of support points, in the spirit of Heckman and Singer (1984). Associated with each support point is a probability, π, where J = j 1 π = 1 and π 0 j j. Finally, we normalized the mean to zero, E( κ im ) = 0, and the variance to one, Var( κ im ) = 1. We experimented with different values for J, and found that a model with J=2 fitted the data quite well. 16 This low dimensionality has been found in many studies of mixture models (e.g. Cameron and Heckman (2001), Ham and Lalonde (1996), and Eberwein, Ham and Lalonde (1997)). j 6. Empirical Results In this section, we present the results from estimating the two specifications of the dynamic welfare probability model: a standard logit with no unobserved effects and the dynamic random effects logit specification presented above, which we will refer to as the correlated random effects (CRE) specification. We focus our attention on the welfare dynamics, i.e. entry and exit probabilities. We first discuss the effects of modeling individual time invariant heterogeneity on the estimated transition probabilities. We also 16 In a recent paper, Chay and Hyslop, 2000, estimate dynamic models of welfare use and labor force participation and find that the results regarding state dependence are not very sensitive to different distributional assumptions with respect to the unobserved heterogeneity. 14

18 discuss the effects of entry and exit probabilities on welfare participation rates, particularly on the immigrant-native welfare utilization gap. The section ends with a discussion of the sensitivity of our results towards a number of assumptions, as well as a discussion of whether our findings can reasonably be generalized to other time periods. 6.1 Estimated Entry and Exit Rates To obtain estimated entry and exit rates from welfare, we again follow Wooldridge (2005) and average out the distribution of the unobserved heterogeneity and compute estimated participation probabilities as; N m * -1 * * * * * * -1 imt = Ximt Ximt imt 1 im1 m α + Ximt βm + imt 1γm + Ximtλ m + im1ρm i=1 ( ) m Pr y 1,, y, y =N exp(-[ y y ]) where the parameter estimates in the estimated probabilities are divided by the estimated standard deviation of the total error variance. 17 To illustrate the importance of controlling for endogenous initial conditions and unobserved heterogeneity, we present estimated transition rates for a standard logit specification in addition to those obtained from the CRE specification described in Section 5 above. For the standard logit specification, and * ρ m are set to 0. To obtain estimates of the entry rate, we evaluate the equation above, setting yimt 1 to 0; * λ m N m * -1 * * * * * -1 imt = Ximt Ximt imt 1 = im1 m α + Ximt βm + Ximtλ m + im1ρm i=1 ( ) m Pr y 1,, y 0, y =N exp(-[ y ]) The estimates of the exit rate are obtained as; * ( yimt Ximt X imt yimt 1 yim1) 1 Pr = 1,, = 1, 17 Full set of estimated parameters are available in Tables A5-A10 in Appendix. 15

19 The estimated transition rates are presented in Table For the standard logit model, which ignores the roles of unobserved heterogeneity and endogenous initial conditions, the estimated entry rate is 0.01 for native males, for non-refugee males, for refugee males, for native females, for non-refugee females, and for refugee females. The estimated entry rates, which are similar to those presented in Table 2, suggest that the higher welfare participation rates among refugee immigrants, relative to natives, are partially due to higher incidences of entering welfare in any given time period, relative to natives. When controls for endogenous initial conditions and time invariant unobserved heterogeneity are incorporated into the model, our CRE specification, we find significant increases in the estimated entry rates for all groups. The probability that a native male (female) initiates welfare receipt in any given time period increase from (0.009) in the simple logit specification to (0.013) in the CRE specification. For male (female) immigrants from refugee countries, the estimated entry rate increases from (0.024) to (0.038). Thus, while the entry rates increased for all groups in the CRE specification, the difference in welfare entry rates between refugee immigrants and natives is higher than in the simple logit specification. The reason the entry rates increase in the CRE specification, relative to those found in the simple logit specification, is that the lagged dependent variable, yimt 1, is positively correlated with the unobserved heterogeneity term, η im. While the simple logit specification erroneously assumes that Corr ( yimt 1, ηim ) = 0, the CRE specification allows yimt 1 and η im to be correlated. The estimated exit rates, also presented in Table 3, show that both male and female natives have higher probabilities of leaving welfare in any given time period than similarly endowed immigrants. Further, immigrants from non-refugee countries are more likely to leave welfare than refugee immigrants. This pattern holds regardless of estimation method. However, the simple logit model substantially underestimates the exit rates (and consequently overestimates persistence in welfare) for all groups. The difference in exit rates between the simple logit model and the CRE specification 18 We obtained 5,000 draws from the asymptotic distribution of the maximum likelihood parameters and computed the transition rates for each draw. We subsequently calculated the standard errors as the standard deviation of the distribution of simulated values of the transition rates. 16

20 highlights the fact that a substantial proportion of persistence in welfare is due to unobserved heterogeneity (e.g. labor market preferences, skills, disability, and/or any other time-invariant variables omitted from the set of observables). 19 Overall, the estimated transition probabilities presented in Table 3 suggest that the immigrant-native gap in welfare use in Sweden is due to a combination of both higher entry rates and lower exit rates among immigrants. The results also point to the importance of controlling for endogenous initial conditions and time invariant unobserved heterogeneity, such as in the CRE specification. In specifications that ignore these issues, welfare entry and exit rates, as well as differences in immigrant-native welfare dynamics, are substantially underestimated. 6.2 The Role of Observables and Transition Probabilities for the Immigrant- Native Welfare Participation Gap In this section we discuss the effects of entry and exit probabilities on welfare participation rates, particularly on the immigrant-native welfare utilization gap. In order to relate the transition probabilities, we assume that welfare participation is in steadystate and hence the welfare participation rate can be expressed as; Entry Rate Welfare Participation Rate =. Entry Rate + Exit Rate Utilizing the observed entry and exit rates, as shown in Table 3, under the assumption of welfare being in steady state, the implied welfare participation rates are approximately 3, 7 and 16 percent respectively for native, non-refugee and refugee males respectively. For all three groups, the implied welfare participation rates are somewhat below the observed average participation rates, which also hold for women. A plausible reason for the differences between the average observed and the implied participation rates is that the observed welfare participation rates changes, mostly declined, over the 19 The economics literature (e.g. Heckman (1981), Chay and Hyslop (2000), Hansen and Lofstrom (2001)) generally distinguish between true (or structural) persistence, in which past participation has a causal effect on current participation, and spurious persistence, in which there is no causal effect of past participation. 17

21 sample period. The unadjusted welfare participation gaps for men are 4.4 percent and 12.9 percent for immigrants from non-refugee and refugee countries respectively. The unadjusted gaps among women are substantially smaller, about ½ of the respective immigrant-native male gaps. The implied welfare participation rates and immigrant-native participation gaps, based on transition rates under different scenarios, are shown in Table 4. All simulations are based on the CRE estimates. Compared to the unadjusted differences in welfare participation, the predicted gaps among males drop by about one percentage points when we use the predictions based on parameters from the CRE specifications. For women, the immigrant-native gap is reduced by about one half of a percentage point for non-refugees and by approximately 1.5 percentage points for female immigrants from refugee countries. We also analyze the gaps under the assumption of immigrants experiencing the native entry and exit rates separately. The predicted welfare participation gaps are very small, less than one percentage points for all groups, under the hypothetical scenario in which immigrant entry rates are those predicted of natives, maintaining immigrants predicted exit rates. Table 4 shows that the participation gaps are substantially greater under the alternative hypothetical, in which immigrants experience natives predicted exit rates. Now, the gap for male non-refugees is close to 3 percent, while it is slightly more than 7 percent for male refugees. These simulations strongly suggest that the welfare participation gap is predominantly caused by differences in entry rates, as opposed to exit rates, although both transition rates contribute to immigrant-native welfare participation gap. The role of differences between immigrants and natives in observable characteristics is also addressed in Table 4. We predict immigrant entry and exit rates utilizing the estimated immigrant CRE parameter vector while using native sample means. The simulations suggest that differences in observables is not the main contributing factor in explaining welfare utilization differences between immigrants and natives. In fact, it appears that differences in our observable controls between male natives and refugees explain only about 3 percent of the welfare participation gap. Differences in observables between male natives and male non-refugee immigrants 18

22 appears to contribute meaningfully to the welfare participation gap, approximately 20 percent is explained by these differences. Similarly, slightly less that 20 percent of the female refugee immigrant-native welfare participation gap is due to differences in observables. Roughly 2/3 of the small, 1.5 percentage points, female non-refugee-native welfare gap appears to be due to differences in the observables. The results in Table 4 also suggest that it is immigrant-native difference in the observables of welfare entrants and non-entrants that contribute relatively more to explaining differences in welfare utilization between immigrants and natives. 6.3 Results from Alternative Model Specifications The empirical analysis presented above is based on data where the dependent variable equals one if a person received social assistance for at least one month during the year, and equals zero otherwise. However, it may be the case that social assistance serves as a form of unemployment insurance (UI) for certain groups who have not yet established themselves on the labor market, such as recent immigrants, as well as young natives, and therefore are not covered by the traditional UI system in Sweden. To explore if our estimated results of differences in transition rates between natives and immigrants, as well as the role of these rates on the immigrant-native welfare participation gap, are sensitive towards the definition of the dependent variable, we reestimated the CRE models using a different definition of welfare participation. In this alternative definition, individuals are defined to be participants if they received social assistance and/or unemployment insurance during the year. The results from the application of this alternative definition are presented in Table 5. As expected, the entry rates increase for all groups. For instance, for native males, the probability of initiating welfare and/or UI is 0.05, about 3.6 times higher than the entry rate for welfare only. For male refugees, the entry rate increase from to The exit rates are also significantly affected by the definition of welfare participation. For all groups, the exit rates decrease substantially. For native males, the exit rate decrease from to 0.59 and for refugee males, the exit rate drop from 0.61 to

23 Overall, these results suggest that transition rates in welfare participation are dependent on how we define welfare use. Using the broader definition, not surprisingly, we find a higher incidence of initiating welfare and a lower probability of leaving welfare for all groups. However, although the transition rates are significantly affected, our results concerning the role of entry and exit rates on the immigrant-native welfare participation gaps remain largely the same. In Table 6, we present predicted participation rates as well as differences in participation between natives and immigrants from nonrefugee and refugee countries, respectively. The participation rates are predicted in the same way as in Section 6.2 above (i.e. assuming steady-state). Both the simulated participation rates and the implied immigrant-native participation gaps increase using our broader welfare definition. The predicted participation rates in welfare and/or UI is highest for refugee males, 32 percent, and lowest for native females, slightly below 8 percent. Assuming native entry rates in generating participation rates for immigrants yield substantially lower predicted participation rates and immigrant-native participation gaps. For example, if non-refugee immigrants faced the same entry probabilities as natives, maintaining differences in exit rates, the estimated difference in welfare participation between this group and natives would essentially disappear, the simulated gap is for males and for females. These results closely resemble our findings in Section 6.2. We obtain similar results for refugee immigrants, with a substantial reduction in the welfare gap. However, a non-negligible gap remains even after assuming native entry rates. If we instead use natives exit rate in generating participation rates for immigrants, the immigrant-native participation gaps remains quite large, especially for refugee immigrants. This result is also consistent with our findings above, and indicates that a major reason for differences in welfare use between immigrants and natives are the relatively large differences in probabilities of entering welfare. To further examine the robustness of our results, we estimated specifications of the logit model under alternative assumptions regarding the unobserved heterogeneity and initial conditions. We considered a random-effects model with a probability distribution on the initial conditions, following Heckman (1981) and a fixed-effects logit model, which makes no assumptions on unobserved heterogeneity and initial conditions, 20

Immigrant Assimilation and Welfare Participation Do Immigrants Assimilate Into or Out of Welfare?

Immigrant Assimilation and Welfare Participation Do Immigrants Assimilate Into or Out of Welfare? Immigrant Assimilation and Welfare Participation Do Immigrants Assimilate Into or Out of Welfare? Jorgen Hansen Magnus Lofstrom abstract This paper analyzes differences in welfare utilization between immigrants

More information

Immigrant Assimilation and Welfare Participation: Do Immigrants Assimilate Into or Out-of Welfare

Immigrant Assimilation and Welfare Participation: Do Immigrants Assimilate Into or Out-of Welfare DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 100 Immigrant Assimilation and Welfare Participation: Do Immigrants Assimilate Into or Out-of Welfare Jörgen Hansen Magnus Lofstrom December 1999 Forschungsinstitut zur

More information

English Deficiency and the Native-Immigrant Wage Gap

English Deficiency and the Native-Immigrant Wage Gap DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 7019 English Deficiency and the Native-Immigrant Wage Gap Alfonso Miranda Yu Zhu November 2012 Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit Institute for the Study of Labor

More information

Table A.2 reports the complete set of estimates of equation (1). We distinguish between personal

Table A.2 reports the complete set of estimates of equation (1). We distinguish between personal Akay, Bargain and Zimmermann Online Appendix 40 A. Online Appendix A.1. Descriptive Statistics Figure A.1 about here Table A.1 about here A.2. Detailed SWB Estimates Table A.2 reports the complete set

More information

Occupational Selection in Multilingual Labor Markets

Occupational Selection in Multilingual Labor Markets DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 3446 Occupational Selection in Multilingual Labor Markets Núria Quella Sílvio Rendon April 2008 Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit Institute for the Study of Labor

More information

WORKING PAPER. State dependence in Swedish social assistance in the 1990s: What happened to those who were single before the recession?

WORKING PAPER. State dependence in Swedish social assistance in the 1990s: What happened to those who were single before the recession? WORKING PAPER 10/2013 State dependence in Swedish social assistance in the 1990s: What happened to those who were single before the recession? Daniela Andrén and Thomas Andrén Economics ISSN 1403-0586

More information

Human capital transmission and the earnings of second-generation immigrants in Sweden

Human capital transmission and the earnings of second-generation immigrants in Sweden Hammarstedt and Palme IZA Journal of Migration 2012, 1:4 RESEARCH Open Access Human capital transmission and the earnings of second-generation in Sweden Mats Hammarstedt 1* and Mårten Palme 2 * Correspondence:

More information

Unemployment of Non-western Immigrants in the Great Recession

Unemployment of Non-western Immigrants in the Great Recession DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 7598 Unemployment of Non-western Immigrants in the Great Recession Jakub Cerveny Jan C. van Ours August 2013 Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit Institute for the

More information

I'll Marry You If You Get Me a Job: Marital Assimilation and Immigrant Employment Rates

I'll Marry You If You Get Me a Job: Marital Assimilation and Immigrant Employment Rates DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 3951 I'll Marry You If You Get Me a Job: Marital Assimilation and Immigrant Employment Rates Delia Furtado Nikolaos Theodoropoulos January 2009 Forschungsinstitut zur

More information

Intergenerational Mobility, Human Capital Transmission and the Earnings of Second-Generation Immigrants in Sweden

Intergenerational Mobility, Human Capital Transmission and the Earnings of Second-Generation Immigrants in Sweden DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 1943 Intergenerational Mobility, Human Capital Transmission and the Earnings of Second-Generation Immigrants in Sweden Mats Hammarstedt Mårten Palme January 2006 Forschungsinstitut

More information

Hispanic Self-Employment: A Dynamic Analysis of Business Ownership

Hispanic Self-Employment: A Dynamic Analysis of Business Ownership DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 2101 Hispanic Self-Employment: A Dynamic Analysis of Business Ownership Magnus Lofstrom Chunbei Wang April 2006 Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit Institute for

More information

How Long Does it Take to Integrate? Employment Convergence of Immigrants And Natives in Sweden*

How Long Does it Take to Integrate? Employment Convergence of Immigrants And Natives in Sweden* ISSN 1651-0852 FIEF Working Paper Series 2002 No. 185 How Long Does it Take to Integrate? Employment Convergence of Immigrants And Natives in Sweden* by Lena Nekby Abstract This study examines employment

More information

Welfare Dependency among Danish Immigrants

Welfare Dependency among Danish Immigrants WORKING PAPER 06-6 Kræn Blume and Mette Verner Welfare Dependency among Danish Immigrants Department of Economics ISBN 87-7882-161-4 (print) ISBN 87-7882-162-2 (online) Welfare Dependency among Danish

More information

IMMIGRANT EARNINGS, ASSIMILATION AND HETEROGENEITY

IMMIGRANT EARNINGS, ASSIMILATION AND HETEROGENEITY IMMIGRANT EARNINGS, ASSIMILATION AND HETEROGENEITY by Saman Rashid * Abstract In this study, I examine firstly the determinants of the wage earnings for immigrants from different countries, and secondly

More information

NERO INTEGRATION OF REFUGEES (NORDIC COUNTRIES) Emily Farchy, ELS/IMD

NERO INTEGRATION OF REFUGEES (NORDIC COUNTRIES) Emily Farchy, ELS/IMD NERO INTEGRATION OF REFUGEES (NORDIC COUNTRIES) Emily Farchy, ELS/IMD Sweden Netherlands Denmark United Kingdom Belgium France Austria Ireland Canada Norway Germany Spain Switzerland Portugal Luxembourg

More information

Source country culture and labor market assimilation of immigrant women in Sweden: evidence from longitudinal data

Source country culture and labor market assimilation of immigrant women in Sweden: evidence from longitudinal data J16 J22 Gender Immigrant Rev Econ Household (2018) 16:585 627 DOI 10.1007/s11150-018-9420-6 Source country culture and labor market assimilation of immigrant women in Sweden: evidence from longitudinal

More information

Ethnic Intergenerational Transmission of Human Capital in Sweden

Ethnic Intergenerational Transmission of Human Capital in Sweden School of Economics and Management Lund University Department of Economics M. Sc. Thesis 10p Ethnic Intergenerational Transmission of Human Capital in Sweden Author: Håkan Lenhoff Tutors: Inga Persson,

More information

Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US

Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US Ben Ost a and Eva Dziadula b a Department of Economics, University of Illinois at Chicago, 601 South Morgan UH718 M/C144 Chicago,

More information

Immigrant Employment and Earnings Growth in Canada and the U.S.: Evidence from Longitudinal data

Immigrant Employment and Earnings Growth in Canada and the U.S.: Evidence from Longitudinal data Immigrant Employment and Earnings Growth in Canada and the U.S.: Evidence from Longitudinal data Neeraj Kaushal, Columbia University Yao Lu, Columbia University Nicole Denier, McGill University Julia Wang,

More information

Social Conditions in Sweden

Social Conditions in Sweden Conditions in Sweden Villa Vigoni Conference on Reporting in Europe Measuring and Monitoring Progress in European Societies Is Life Still Getting Better? March 9-11, 2010 Danuta Biterman The National Board

More information

The Savings Behavior of Temporary and Permanent Migrants in Germany

The Savings Behavior of Temporary and Permanent Migrants in Germany DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 1632 The Savings Behavior of Temporary and Permanent Migrants in Germany Thomas K. Bauer Mathias Sinning June 2005 Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit Institute

More information

Low-Skilled Immigrant Entrepreneurship

Low-Skilled Immigrant Entrepreneurship DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 4560 Low-Skilled Immigrant Entrepreneurship Magnus Lofstrom November 2009 Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit Institute for the Study of Labor Low-Skilled Immigrant

More information

Dynamics of employment assimilation

Dynamics of employment assimilation Akay IZA Journal of Migration (2016) 5:13 DOI 10.1186/s40176-016-0061-3 ORIGINAL ARTICLE Dynamics of employment assimilation Alpaslan Akay 1,2,3 Open Access Correspondence: alpaslan.akay@economics.gu.se

More information

Why Are People More Pro-Trade than Pro-Migration?

Why Are People More Pro-Trade than Pro-Migration? DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 2855 Why Are People More Pro-Trade than Pro-Migration? Anna Maria Mayda June 2007 Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit Institute for the Study of Labor Why Are People

More information

Inter- and Intra-Marriage Premiums Revisited: It s Probably Who You Are, Not Who You Marry!

Inter- and Intra-Marriage Premiums Revisited: It s Probably Who You Are, Not Who You Marry! DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 5317 Inter- and Intra-Marriage Premiums Revisited: It s Probably Who You Are, Not Who You Marry! Lena Nekby November 2010 Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit Institute

More information

The impact of parents years since migration on children s academic achievement

The impact of parents years since migration on children s academic achievement Nielsen and Rangvid IZA Journal of Migration 2012, 1:6 ORIGINAL ARTICLE Open Access The impact of parents years since migration on children s academic achievement Helena Skyt Nielsen 1* and Beatrice Schindler

More information

Immigration Policy, Assimilation of Immigrants and Natives' Sentiments towards Immigrants: Evidence from 12 OECD-Countries

Immigration Policy, Assimilation of Immigrants and Natives' Sentiments towards Immigrants: Evidence from 12 OECD-Countries DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 187 Immigration Policy, Assimilation of Immigrants and Natives' Sentiments towards Immigrants: Evidence from 12 OECD-Countries Thomas K. Bauer Magnus Lofstrom Klaus F.

More information

Immigrant Legalization

Immigrant Legalization Technical Appendices Immigrant Legalization Assessing the Labor Market Effects Laura Hill Magnus Lofstrom Joseph Hayes Contents Appendix A. Data from the 2003 New Immigrant Survey Appendix B. Measuring

More information

Immigrants and Welfare Programmes: Exploring the Interactions between Immigrant Characteristics, Immigrant Welfare Dependence and Welfare Policy

Immigrants and Welfare Programmes: Exploring the Interactions between Immigrant Characteristics, Immigrant Welfare Dependence and Welfare Policy DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 3494 Immigrants and Welfare Programmes: Exploring the Interactions between Immigrant Characteristics, Immigrant Welfare Dependence and Welfare Policy Alan Barrett Yvonne

More information

A Longitudinal Analysis of Post-Migration Education

A Longitudinal Analysis of Post-Migration Education Preliminary Draft May 21, 2001 A Longitudinal Analysis of Post-Migration Education Jorgen Hansen Concordia University Magnus Lofstrom University of California at Irvine Kirk Scott Lund University Abstract

More information

Explaining the Deteriorating Entry Earnings of Canada s Immigrant Cohorts:

Explaining the Deteriorating Entry Earnings of Canada s Immigrant Cohorts: Explaining the Deteriorating Entry Earnings of Canada s Immigrant Cohorts: 1966-2000 Abdurrahman Aydemir Family and Labour Studies Division Statistics Canada aydeabd@statcan.ca 613-951-3821 and Mikal Skuterud

More information

Levels and trends in international migration

Levels and trends in international migration Levels and trends in international migration The number of international migrants worldwide has continued to grow rapidly over the past fifteen years reaching million in 1, up from million in 1, 191 million

More information

Canadian Labour Market and Skills Researcher Network

Canadian Labour Market and Skills Researcher Network Canadian Labour Market and Skills Researcher Network Working Paper No. 69 Immigrant Earnings Growth: Selection Bias or Real Progress? Garnett Picot Statistics Canada Patrizio Piraino Statistics Canada

More information

Divorce risks of immigrants in Sweden

Divorce risks of immigrants in Sweden Divorce risks of immigrants in Sweden Gunnar Andersson, Kirk Scott Abstract Migration is a stressful life event that may be related to subsequent marital instability. However, while the demographic dynamics

More information

Self-employed immigrants and their employees: Evidence from Swedish employer-employee data

Self-employed immigrants and their employees: Evidence from Swedish employer-employee data Self-employed immigrants and their employees: Evidence from Swedish employer-employee data Mats Hammarstedt Linnaeus University Centre for Discrimination and Integration Studies Linnaeus University SE-351

More information

Migration With Endogenous Social Networks in China

Migration With Endogenous Social Networks in China Migration With Endogenous Social Networks in China Jin Zhou (University of Western Ontario) May 2015 Abstract Numerous empirical studies have documented a strong association between social networks and

More information

The Structure of the Permanent Job Wage Premium: Evidence from Europe

The Structure of the Permanent Job Wage Premium: Evidence from Europe DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 7623 The Structure of the Permanent Job Wage Premium: Evidence from Europe Lawrence M. Kahn September 2013 Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit Institute for the

More information

Public Policy and the Labor Market Adjustment of New Immigrants to Australia

Public Policy and the Labor Market Adjustment of New Immigrants to Australia DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 620 Public Policy and the Labor Market Adjustment of New Immigrants to Australia Deborah A. Cobb-Clark October 2002 Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit Institute

More information

Benefit levels and US immigrants welfare receipts

Benefit levels and US immigrants welfare receipts 1 Benefit levels and US immigrants welfare receipts 1970 1990 by Joakim Ruist Department of Economics University of Gothenburg Box 640 40530 Gothenburg, Sweden joakim.ruist@economics.gu.se telephone: +46

More information

ISBN International Migration Outlook Sopemi 2007 Edition OECD Introduction

ISBN International Migration Outlook Sopemi 2007 Edition OECD Introduction ISBN 978-92-64-03285-9 International Migration Outlook Sopemi 2007 Edition OECD 2007 Introduction 21 2007 Edition of International Migration Outlook shows an increase in migration flows to the OECD International

More information

Precautionary Savings by Natives and Immigrants in Germany

Precautionary Savings by Natives and Immigrants in Germany DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 2942 Precautionary Savings by Natives and Immigrants in Germany Matloob Piracha Yu Zhu July 2007 Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit Institute for the Study of

More information

The Transmission of Women s Fertility, Human Capital and Work Orientation across Immigrant Generations

The Transmission of Women s Fertility, Human Capital and Work Orientation across Immigrant Generations DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 3732 The Transmission of Women s Fertility, Human Capital and Work Orientation across Immigrant Generations Francine D. Blau Lawrence M. Kahn Albert Yung-Hsu Liu Kerry

More information

EMMA NEUMAN 2016:11. Performance and job creation among self-employed immigrants and natives in Sweden

EMMA NEUMAN 2016:11. Performance and job creation among self-employed immigrants and natives in Sweden EMMA NEUMAN 2016:11 Performance and job creation among self-employed immigrants and natives in Sweden Performance and job creation among self-employed immigrants and natives in Sweden Emma Neuman a Abstract

More information

Local labor markets and earnings of refugee immigrants

Local labor markets and earnings of refugee immigrants Empir Econ (2017) 52:31 58 DOI 10.1007/s00181-016-1067-7 Local labor markets and earnings of refugee immigrants Anna Godøy 1 Received: 17 February 2015 / Accepted: 21 December 2015 / Published online:

More information

Migration and Tourism Flows to New Zealand

Migration and Tourism Flows to New Zealand Migration and Tourism Flows to New Zealand Murat Genç University of Otago, Dunedin, New Zealand Email address for correspondence: murat.genc@otago.ac.nz 30 April 2010 PRELIMINARY WORK IN PROGRESS NOT FOR

More information

EXPORT, MIGRATION, AND COSTS OF MARKET ENTRY EVIDENCE FROM CENTRAL EUROPEAN FIRMS

EXPORT, MIGRATION, AND COSTS OF MARKET ENTRY EVIDENCE FROM CENTRAL EUROPEAN FIRMS Export, Migration, and Costs of Market Entry: Evidence from Central European Firms 1 The Regional Economics Applications Laboratory (REAL) is a unit in the University of Illinois focusing on the development

More information

Living in the Shadows or Government Dependents: Immigrants and Welfare in the United States

Living in the Shadows or Government Dependents: Immigrants and Welfare in the United States Living in the Shadows or Government Dependents: Immigrants and Welfare in the United States Charles Weber Harvard University May 2015 Abstract Are immigrants in the United States more likely to be enrolled

More information

The emigration of immigrants, return vs onward migration: evidence from Sweden

The emigration of immigrants, return vs onward migration: evidence from Sweden J Popul Econ 19:19 22 (200) DOI 10.100/s00148-00-0080-0 ORIGINAL PAPER Lena Nekby The emigration of immigrants, return vs onward migration: evidence from Sweden Received: 15 June 2004 / Accepted: 1 March

More information

Growth, Volatility and Political Instability: Non-Linear Time-Series Evidence for Argentina,

Growth, Volatility and Political Instability: Non-Linear Time-Series Evidence for Argentina, DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 3087 Growth, Volatility and Political Instability: Non-Linear Time-Series Evidence for Argentina, 1896-2000 Nauro F. Campos Menelaos G. Karanasos October 2007 Forschungsinstitut

More information

Remittances and the Brain Drain: Evidence from Microdata for Sub-Saharan Africa

Remittances and the Brain Drain: Evidence from Microdata for Sub-Saharan Africa DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 10367 Remittances and the Brain Drain: Evidence from Microdata for Sub-Saharan Africa Julia Bredtmann Fernanda Martínez Flores Sebastian Otten November 2016 Forschungsinstitut

More information

Supplementary information for the article:

Supplementary information for the article: Supplementary information for the article: Happy moves? Assessing the link between life satisfaction and emigration intentions Artjoms Ivlevs Contents 1. Summary statistics of variables p. 2 2. Country

More information

In the Picture Resettled Refugees in Sweden

In the Picture Resettled Refugees in Sweden Chapter 3 In the Picture Resettled Refugees in Sweden Pieter Bevelander Introduction In 2007, over 1.2 million Swedish people (13.4% of the population) were born abroad. Almost one hundred thousand immigrants

More information

Selection Policy and the Labour Market Outcomes of New Immigrants

Selection Policy and the Labour Market Outcomes of New Immigrants DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 1380 Selection Policy and the Labour Market Outcomes of New Immigrants Deborah A. Cobb-Clark November 2004 Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit Institute for the

More information

Immigrant-native wage gaps in time series: Complementarities or composition effects?

Immigrant-native wage gaps in time series: Complementarities or composition effects? Immigrant-native wage gaps in time series: Complementarities or composition effects? Joakim Ruist Department of Economics University of Gothenburg Box 640 405 30 Gothenburg, Sweden joakim.ruist@economics.gu.se

More information

Employment Assimilation of Immigrants: Evidence from Finland

Employment Assimilation of Immigrants: Evidence from Finland Employment Assimilation of Immigrants: Evidence from Finland Matti Sarvimäki 1, Kari Hämäläinen, Aki Kangasharju, Sari Pekkala Government Institute for Economic Research (VATT) Arkadiankatu 7, P.O Box

More information

F E M M Faculty of Economics and Management Magdeburg

F E M M Faculty of Economics and Management Magdeburg OTTO-VON-GUERICKE-UNIVERSITY MAGDEBURG FACULTY OF ECONOMICS AND MANAGEMENT The Immigrant Wage Gap in Germany Alisher Aldashev, ZEW Mannheim Johannes Gernandt, ZEW Mannheim Stephan L. Thomsen FEMM Working

More information

Ethnic Persistence, Assimilation and Risk Proclivity

Ethnic Persistence, Assimilation and Risk Proclivity DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 2537 Ethnic Persistence, Assimilation and Risk Proclivity Holger Bonin Amelie Constant Konstantinos Tatsiramos Klaus F. Zimmermann December 2006 Forschungsinstitut zur

More information

Assessing the Employment Effects of Labor Market Training Programs in Sweden

Assessing the Employment Effects of Labor Market Training Programs in Sweden Assessing the Employment Effects of Labor Market Training Programs in Sweden Daniela Andrén and Thomas Andrén α Working Papers in Economics no 7 May 22 Abstract Several studies have examined the effects

More information

I. LEVELS AND TRENDS IN INTERNATIONAL MIGRANT STOCK

I. LEVELS AND TRENDS IN INTERNATIONAL MIGRANT STOCK I. LEVELS AND TRENDS IN INTERNATIONAL MIGRANT STOCK A. INTERNATIONAL MIGRANT STOCK BY DEVELOPMENT GROUP The Population Division estimates that, worldwide, there were 214.2 million international migrants

More information

Migrant Youth: A statistical profile of recently arrived young migrants. immigration.govt.nz

Migrant Youth: A statistical profile of recently arrived young migrants. immigration.govt.nz Migrant Youth: A statistical profile of recently arrived young migrants. immigration.govt.nz ABOUT THIS REPORT Published September 2017 By Ministry of Business, Innovation and Employment 15 Stout Street

More information

Labor Market Dropouts and Trends in the Wages of Black and White Men

Labor Market Dropouts and Trends in the Wages of Black and White Men Industrial & Labor Relations Review Volume 56 Number 4 Article 5 2003 Labor Market Dropouts and Trends in the Wages of Black and White Men Chinhui Juhn University of Houston Recommended Citation Juhn,

More information

Differences in Unemployment Dynamics between Migrants and Natives in Germany

Differences in Unemployment Dynamics between Migrants and Natives in Germany Differences in Unemployment Dynamics between Migrants and Natives in Germany Arne Uhlendorff (DIW Berlin, IZA Bonn) Klaus F. Zimmermann (IZA Bonn, University Bonn, DIW Berlin) Preliminary Version January

More information

IS THE MEASURED BLACK-WHITE WAGE GAP AMONG WOMEN TOO SMALL? Derek Neal University of Wisconsin Presented Nov 6, 2000 PRELIMINARY

IS THE MEASURED BLACK-WHITE WAGE GAP AMONG WOMEN TOO SMALL? Derek Neal University of Wisconsin Presented Nov 6, 2000 PRELIMINARY IS THE MEASURED BLACK-WHITE WAGE GAP AMONG WOMEN TOO SMALL? Derek Neal University of Wisconsin Presented Nov 6, 2000 PRELIMINARY Over twenty years ago, Butler and Heckman (1977) raised the possibility

More information

3Z 3 STATISTICS IN FOCUS eurostat Population and social conditions 1995 D 3

3Z 3 STATISTICS IN FOCUS eurostat Population and social conditions 1995 D 3 3Z 3 STATISTICS IN FOCUS Population and social conditions 1995 D 3 INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION IN THE EU MEMBER STATES - 1992 It would seem almost to go without saying that international migration concerns

More information

Do when and where matter? Initial labor market conditions and immigrant earnings

Do when and where matter? Initial labor market conditions and immigrant earnings Do when and where matter? Initial labor market conditions and immigrant earnings Olof Åslund Dan-Olof Rooth WORKING PAPER 2003:7 The Institute for Labour Market Policy Evaluation (IFAU) is a research institute

More information

Cohort Effects in the Educational Attainment of Second Generation Immigrants in Germany: An Analysis of Census Data

Cohort Effects in the Educational Attainment of Second Generation Immigrants in Germany: An Analysis of Census Data Cohort Effects in the Educational Attainment of Second Generation Immigrants in Germany: An Analysis of Census Data Regina T. Riphahn University of Basel CEPR - London IZA - Bonn February 2002 Even though

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES WELFARE REFORM, LABOR SUPPLY, AND HEALTH INSURANCE IN THE IMMIGRANT POPULATION. George J. Borjas

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES WELFARE REFORM, LABOR SUPPLY, AND HEALTH INSURANCE IN THE IMMIGRANT POPULATION. George J. Borjas NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES WELFARE REFORM, LABOR SUPPLY, AND HEALTH INSURANCE IN THE IMMIGRANT POPULATION George J. Borjas Working Paper 9781 http://www.nber.org/papers/w9781 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC

More information

Ethnicity, Job Search and Labor Market Reintegration of the Unemployed

Ethnicity, Job Search and Labor Market Reintegration of the Unemployed DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 4660 Ethnicity, Job Search and Labor Market Reintegration of the Unemployed Amelie F. Constant Martin Kahanec Ulf Rinne Klaus F. Zimmermann December 2009 Forschungsinstitut

More information

Savings, Asset Holdings, and Temporary Migration

Savings, Asset Holdings, and Temporary Migration This paper analyzes savings and asset holdings of immigrants in relation to their return plans. We argue that savings and asset accumulation may be affected by return plans of immigrants. Further, the

More information

Immigrants Employment Outcomes over the Business Cycle

Immigrants Employment Outcomes over the Business Cycle DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 5354 Immigrants Employment Outcomes over the Business Cycle Pia Orrenius Madeline Zavodny December 2010 Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit Institute for the Study

More information

Economic Activity in London

Economic Activity in London CIS2013-10 Economic Activity in London September 2013 copyright Greater London Authority September 2013 Published by Greater London Authority City Hall The Queens Walk London SE1 2AA www.london.gov.uk

More information

Chronic Low Income and Low-income Dynamics Among Recent Immigrants

Chronic Low Income and Low-income Dynamics Among Recent Immigrants Catalogue no. 11F0019MIE No. 294 ISSN: 1205-9153 ISBN: 978-0-662-44993-5 Research Paper Analytical Studies Branch Research Paper Series Chronic Low Income and Low-income Dynamics Among Recent Immigrants

More information

The Impact of Having a Job at Migration on Settlement Decisions: Ethnic Enclaves as Job Search Networks

The Impact of Having a Job at Migration on Settlement Decisions: Ethnic Enclaves as Job Search Networks The Impact of Having a Job at Migration on Settlement Decisions: Ethnic Enclaves as Job Search Networks Lee Tucker Boston University This version: October 15, 2014 Abstract Observational evidence has shown

More information

Case Evidence: Blacks, Hispanics, and Immigrants

Case Evidence: Blacks, Hispanics, and Immigrants Case Evidence: Blacks, Hispanics, and Immigrants Spring 2010 Rosburg (ISU) Case Evidence: Blacks, Hispanics, and Immigrants Spring 2010 1 / 48 Blacks CASE EVIDENCE: BLACKS Rosburg (ISU) Case Evidence:

More information

IMMIGRANTS IN THE ISRAELI HI- TECH INDUSTRY: COMPARISON TO NATIVES AND THE EFFECT OF TRAINING

IMMIGRANTS IN THE ISRAELI HI- TECH INDUSTRY: COMPARISON TO NATIVES AND THE EFFECT OF TRAINING B2v8:0f XML:ver::0: RLEC V024 : 2400 /0/0 :4 Prod:Type:com pp:2ðcol:fig::nilþ ED:SeemaA:P PAGN: SCAN: 2 IMMIGRANTS IN THE ISRAELI HI- TECH INDUSTRY: COMPARISON TO NATIVES AND THE EFFECT OF TRAINING Sarit

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES HOMEOWNERSHIP IN THE IMMIGRANT POPULATION. George J. Borjas. Working Paper

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES HOMEOWNERSHIP IN THE IMMIGRANT POPULATION. George J. Borjas. Working Paper NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES HOMEOWNERSHIP IN THE IMMIGRANT POPULATION George J. Borjas Working Paper 8945 http://www.nber.org/papers/w8945 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge,

More information

Volume 35, Issue 1. An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach

Volume 35, Issue 1. An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach Volume 35, Issue 1 An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach Brian Hibbs Indiana University South Bend Gihoon Hong Indiana University South Bend Abstract This

More information

Within-Groups Wage Inequality and Schooling: Further Evidence for Portugal

Within-Groups Wage Inequality and Schooling: Further Evidence for Portugal DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 2828 Within-Groups Wage Inequality and Schooling: Further Evidence for Portugal Corrado Andini June 2007 Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit Institute for the Study

More information

Online Appendix for. Home Away From Home? Foreign Demand and London House Prices

Online Appendix for. Home Away From Home? Foreign Demand and London House Prices Online Appendix for Home Away From Home? Foreign Demand and London House Prices List of Tables A.1 Summary statistics across wards..................... 14 A.2 Robustness of the results.........................

More information

MATS HAMMARSTEDT & CHIZHENG MIAO 2018:4. Self-employed immigrants and their employees Evidence from Swedish employer-employee data

MATS HAMMARSTEDT & CHIZHENG MIAO 2018:4. Self-employed immigrants and their employees Evidence from Swedish employer-employee data MATS HAMMARSTEDT & CHIZHENG MIAO 2018:4 Self-employed immigrants and their employees Evidence from Swedish employer-employee data Self-employed immigrants and their employees: Evidence from Swedish employer-employee

More information

Uppsala Center for Fiscal Studies

Uppsala Center for Fiscal Studies Uppsala Center for Fiscal Studies Department of Economics Working Paper 2013:2 Ethnic Diversity and Preferences for Redistribution: Reply Matz Dahlberg, Karin Edmark and Heléne Lundqvist Uppsala Center

More information

Industrial & Labor Relations Review

Industrial & Labor Relations Review Industrial & Labor Relations Review Volume 60, Issue 3 2007 Article 5 Labor Market Institutions and Wage Inequality Winfried Koeniger Marco Leonardi Luca Nunziata IZA, University of Bonn, University of

More information

The Savings Behavior of Temporary and Permanent Migrants in Germany

The Savings Behavior of Temporary and Permanent Migrants in Germany The Savings Behavior of Temporary and Permanent Migrants in Germany Thomas K. Bauer and Mathias Sinning - DRAFT - Abstract This paper examines the relative savings position of migrant households in West

More information

The Changing Relationship between Fertility and Economic Development: Evidence from 256 Sub-National European Regions Between 1996 to 2010

The Changing Relationship between Fertility and Economic Development: Evidence from 256 Sub-National European Regions Between 1996 to 2010 The Changing Relationship between Fertility and Economic Development: Evidence from 256 Sub-National European Regions Between 996 to 2 Authors: Jonathan Fox, Freie Universitaet; Sebastian Klüsener MPIDR;

More information

Can immigrants insure against shocks as well as the native-born?

Can immigrants insure against shocks as well as the native-born? APPLIED ECONOMICS https://doi.org/10.1080/00036846.2018.1486987 Can immigrants insure against shocks as well as the native-born? Asadul Islam a, Steven Stillman b and Christopher Worswick c a Department

More information

BRIEFING. International Migration: The UK Compared with other OECD Countries.

BRIEFING. International Migration: The UK Compared with other OECD Countries. BRIEFING International Migration: The UK Compared with other OECD Countries AUTHOR: DR CARLOS VARGAS-SILVA PUBLISHED: 11/3/214 2nd Revision www.migrationobservatory.ox.ac.uk This briefing uses data from

More information

What Happens to the Careers of European Workers When Immigrants Take Their Jobs?

What Happens to the Careers of European Workers When Immigrants Take Their Jobs? DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 7282 What Happens to the Careers of European Workers When Immigrants Take Their Jobs? Cristina Cattaneo Carlo V. Fiorio Giovanni Peri March 2013 Forschungsinstitut zur

More information

Payments from government to people

Payments from government to people 3 PAYMENTS Most people make payments such as for utility bills or domestic remittances. And most receive payments such as wages, other payments for work, or government transfers. The 2017 Global Findex

More information

Working Papers in Economics

Working Papers in Economics University of Innsbruck Working Papers in Economics Foreign Direct Investment and European Integration in the 90 s Peter Egger and Michael Pfaffermayr 2002/2 Institute of Economic Theory, Economic Policy

More information

GEORG-AUGUST-UNIVERSITÄT GÖTTINGEN

GEORG-AUGUST-UNIVERSITÄT GÖTTINGEN GEORG-AUGUST-UNIVERSITÄT GÖTTINGEN FACULTY OF ECONOMIC SCIENCES CHAIR OF MACROECONOMICS AND DEVELOPMENT Bachelor Seminar Economics of the very long run: Economics of Islam Summer semester 2017 Does Secular

More information

The Labor Market Costs of Conflict: Closures, Foreign Workers, and Palestinian Employment and Earnings

The Labor Market Costs of Conflict: Closures, Foreign Workers, and Palestinian Employment and Earnings DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 2282 The Labor Market Costs of Conflict: Closures, Foreign Workers, and Palestinian Employment and Earnings Sami H. Miaari Robert M. Sauer September 2006 Forschungsinstitut

More information

PRELIMINARY DRAFT PLEASE DO NOT CITE

PRELIMINARY DRAFT PLEASE DO NOT CITE Health Insurance and Labor Supply among Recent Immigrants following the 1996 Welfare Reform: Examining the Effect of the Five-Year Residency Requirement Amy M. Gass Kandilov PhD Candidate Department of

More information

Immigration and Internal Mobility in Canada Appendices A and B. Appendix A: Two-step Instrumentation strategy: Procedure and detailed results

Immigration and Internal Mobility in Canada Appendices A and B. Appendix A: Two-step Instrumentation strategy: Procedure and detailed results Immigration and Internal Mobility in Canada Appendices A and B by Michel Beine and Serge Coulombe This version: February 2016 Appendix A: Two-step Instrumentation strategy: Procedure and detailed results

More information

Household Inequality and Remittances in Rural Thailand: A Lifecycle Perspective

Household Inequality and Remittances in Rural Thailand: A Lifecycle Perspective Household Inequality and Remittances in Rural Thailand: A Lifecycle Perspective Richard Disney*, Andy McKay + & C. Rashaad Shabab + *Institute of Fiscal Studies, University of Sussex and University College,

More information

SocialSecurityEligibilityandtheLaborSuplyofOlderImigrants. George J. Borjas Harvard University

SocialSecurityEligibilityandtheLaborSuplyofOlderImigrants. George J. Borjas Harvard University SocialSecurityEligibilityandtheLaborSuplyofOlderImigrants George J. Borjas Harvard University February 2010 1 SocialSecurityEligibilityandtheLaborSuplyofOlderImigrants George J. Borjas ABSTRACT The employment

More information

Temporary Employment Agencies: A Route for Immigrants to Enter the Labour Market?

Temporary Employment Agencies: A Route for Immigrants to Enter the Labour Market? DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 1090 Temporary Employment Agencies: A Route for Immigrants to Enter the Labour Market? Pernilla Andersson Eskil Wadensjö March 2004 Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der

More information

Migrant Wages, Human Capital Accumulation and Return Migration

Migrant Wages, Human Capital Accumulation and Return Migration Migrant Wages, Human Capital Accumulation and Return Migration Jérôme Adda Christian Dustmann Joseph-Simon Görlach February 14, 2014 PRELIMINARY and VERY INCOMPLETE Abstract This paper analyses the wage

More information

Family Ties, Labor Mobility and Interregional Wage Differentials*

Family Ties, Labor Mobility and Interregional Wage Differentials* Family Ties, Labor Mobility and Interregional Wage Differentials* TODD L. CHERRY, Ph.D.** Department of Economics and Finance University of Wyoming Laramie WY 82071-3985 PETE T. TSOURNOS, Ph.D. Pacific

More information

Selection in migration and return migration: Evidence from micro data

Selection in migration and return migration: Evidence from micro data Economics Letters 94 (2007) 90 95 www.elsevier.com/locate/econbase Selection in migration and return migration: Evidence from micro data Dan-Olof Rooth a,, Jan Saarela b a Kalmar University, SE-39182 Kalmar,

More information

Substitution Between Individual and Cultural Capital: Pre-Migration Labor Supply, Culture and US Labor Market Outcomes Among Immigrant Woman

Substitution Between Individual and Cultural Capital: Pre-Migration Labor Supply, Culture and US Labor Market Outcomes Among Immigrant Woman D I S C U S S I O N P A P E R S E R I E S IZA DP No. 5890 Substitution Between Individual and Cultural Capital: Pre-Migration Labor Supply, Culture and US Labor Market Outcomes Among Immigrant Woman Francine

More information