The Effectiveness of Peacekeeping Missions in Civil Wars: Disaggregating Interventions,

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "The Effectiveness of Peacekeeping Missions in Civil Wars: Disaggregating Interventions,"

Transcription

1 The Effectiveness of Peacekeeping Missions in Civil Wars: Disaggregating Interventions, Tobias Böhmelt, Nils W. Metternich, Ulrich H. Pilster, and Andrea Ruggeri* University of Essex, United Kingdom First Draft (10,199 words) December 8, 2009 * The authors are listed in alphabetical order.

2 2 Abstract The recent literature on the effectiveness of peacekeeping missions is largely driven by two streams. While some scholars provide evidence for a significant positive contribution, others claim that the United Nations and other peacekeeping organizations tend to negatively influence peace processes or have no impact at all. Two shortcomings are characteristic for both rationales: peacekeeping interventions are either operationalized as a simple binary variable or categorized along the distinct purposes of the missions in question. This, however, ignores the composition of peacekeeping troops, since peacekeeping interventions are treated as a black box, thereby leaving out valuable information. We intend to fill this gap by disaggregating state coalitions in peacekeeping operations. More specifically, this paper analyzes in detail the size and leverage of an intervening group, peacekeepers regime types, and their supply-side incentives. We elaborate a theory and, utilizing newly compiled data on peacekeeping operations in civil wars from 1948 to 2000, test our hypotheses with a selection-duration estimator. Keywords: peacekeeping; effectiveness; group size; regime type; supply-side incentives; selection-duration analysis

3 3 Introduction The recent research on the effectiveness of peacekeeping missions by the United Nations (UN), other international organizations, ad-hoc coalitions, or a single state is driven by a heated debate. While scholars such as Doyle and Sambanis (2000; 2006), Fortna (2003; 2004), and Gilligan and Sergenti (2006) provide evidence for a significant positive contribution, authors such as Dubey (2003) claim instead that peacekeeping missions tend to have no impact at all. Furthermore, Greig and Diehl (2005) even find evidence that peacekeeping is likely to have a negative impact on the long-term effectiveness of a peace process. Two shortcomings pertaining to the examination of peacekeeping per se are characteristic for these streams in the literature. First, peacekeeping missions are either treated as a simple binary variable or, second, scholars merely distinguish along the categories of involvement, e.g., enforcement, monitoring, or state building. In other words, when studying the effectiveness of these interventions, the previous work has largely ignored the characteristics of the nation states that form a peacekeeping coalition, and how these countries coordinate their mission. This, consequently, disregards the composition of peacekeeping troops, and leaves out valuable information that may be able to contribute significantly toward our understanding of the effectiveness or failure of peacekeeping missions. We intend to fill this gap by disaggregating state coalitions in peacekeeping operations, thereby opening the black box of such interventions. The rationale behind our research is grounded in the fact that states contributing to such operations are driven by their own incentives and are tied to each other through various kinds of relationships. They share information and resources, and pursue other means of synchronizing and/or integrating activities. Militaries operating within a peacekeeping coalition vary in terms of their doctrines, technology and their operational readiness, training, intelligence and communication, mobility and force protection, or

4 4 logistics. Ultimately, this may make interventions more synergetic or create conflicts among the peacekeepers that actually hamper successful operations. In addressing these issues in detail, this paper contributes to the existing literature by focusing on a set of crucial aspects of the interveners that form peacekeeping missions. First, we examine the size of an intervening group, arguing that size and peacekeeping effectiveness are characterized by an inverted U-shaped relationship. More interveners are generally able to draw upon a vast amount of leverage and resources, and create synergy due to combined efforts, making them more effective. On the other hand, a very large number of interveners also implies higher organizational costs and greater heterogeneity of interests, leading to less effective outcomes (Buchanan and Tullock 1962; Snidal 1994; see also Olson 1965). Second, we examine the regime type of peacekeepers and how this affects their ability to coordinate their efforts. A coalition of states that is largely democratic should be more effective due to inclusivity, a shared culture of peaceful conflict resolution, and increased communication flows (see Dixon 1994; Raymond 1994; Bercovitch and Houston 2000; Mitchell 2002). Finally, we focus on the supplyside incentives of peacekeepers. Countries generally choose to participate in peacekeeping missions due to rational calculations and, hence, this does not occur at random. As a result, only if countries have a thorough interest in peace in a conflict country, then we would expect them to invest more in order to prevent further fighting, ultimately making those peacekeeping operations more effective. In the remainder of this paper, we first review the relevant literature on the effectiveness of UN and non-un peacekeeping missions, emphasizing their weaknesses in light of the possibility of disaggregating interventions. Building upon existing studies that examine peacekeeping missions from a commitment-problem perspective, we then develop a theory that combines group size, regime type, as well as supply-side incentives with peacekeeping effectiveness. Afterwards,

5 5 we detail the research design and, utilizing newly compiled data on peacekeeping operations in civil wars from 1948 to 2000, test our hypotheses with a selection-duration estimator (Boehmke, Morey, and Shannon 2006). The final section concludes. Literature Review Do peacekeepers promote peace? In particular against the background that the post Cold War era has seen an impressive increase in peacekeeping interventions, this is a crucial question and answering it is not only of academic interest, but should also significantly influence the rationales of policymakers (Fortna and Howard 2008). However, the previous literature has not yet been able to agree if peacekeepers help sustaining peace after conflicts or if they are actually counterproductive due to the failure of their interventions. Nevertheless, multiple studies tried to answer whether peacekeepers can make a positive contribution to peace, but as stated above obtained mixed findings. First, Doyle and Sambanis (2000; see also 2005; 2006) examine the interventions of UN peacekeepers and -builders in civil wars after the end of World War II. The authors argue that peacekeeping missions have to address the roots of hostility, local capacities for change toward a peaceful settlement, and a sufficiently large international commitment to the peace process for reaching effective outcomes. In order to test their claims, Doyle and Sambanis (2000: 783f) employ a binary item on the success/failure of a peacekeeping effort and, in consistence with their empirical findings, conclude that the UN has a significantly positive impact toward resolving civil wars and keeping peace. Second, Fortna (2003; 2004) pursues to contribute to the same research question, albeit with a different research design. Instead of relying on the rather subjective binary variable from Doyle and Sambanis (2000; see also 2006), she uses the duration of peace after the warring parties

6 6 agreed on a ceasefire for operationalizing peacekeeping effectiveness. Among other results, Fortna (2004: 283f) finds support that peacekeeping interventions of both the UN and non-un organizations lengthen the peace and increase post-conflict stability. The author also naïvely disaggregates peacekeeping missions along 1) observer, 2) traditional, 3) multidimensional, and 4) enforcement interventions, and apart from the latter category obtains a significant as well as positive contribution toward peace for all of these mission types. However, King and Zeng (2007a; 2007b) challenge Fortna s findings from a methodological perspective. More precisely, conflicts with peacekeeping interventions are unlikely to be a randomly selected set and ignoring this can either under- or overestimate the effectiveness of third-party interventions. Because of this self-selective character of peacekeeping missions, a research design that does not consider selection effects can give rise to misleading and biased findings (Heckman 1979). As a suggestion to circumvent this issue, Gilligan and Sergenti (2006) employ matching methods. Matching corrects for the non-random assignment and controls for the existence of confounding factors by identifying cases in a control group that match as closely as possible treated observations, i.e., cases where we actually observe peacekeeping. The differences between the treated and the untreated cases are then reduced to a minimum, and based upon the comparison of these most similar cases, Gilligan and Sergenti (2006) can make inferences about the causal effect of UN peacekeeping, where any difference between the two sets is then solely attributed to the treatment. Given a sophisticated research design, the authors are able to rule out influences of several covariates and find that UN peacekeeping is indeed likely to make a positive contribution to peace. A shortcoming of matching as such is again, however, that it requires treating peacekeeping as a simple dichotomous item. Next to the studies of these previous authors, another stream in the literature takes a different perspective. Dubuy (2003) does not find that UN peacekeeping either shortens or lengthens the

7 7 duration of peace after a civil war has ended. Further, although Greig and Diehl (2005) are able to unveil some evidence that UN peacekeeping helps decreasing the chances of renewed warfare, this is rather a short-term effect. In the long run, peacekeeping interventions make it actually less likely that belligerents will engage in negotiations to completely resolve the conflict, and, hence, this increases the chances that a new dispute will break out due to the same issues that caused that conflict in the first place. Finally, Diehl, Reifschneider, and Hensel (1996; see also Beardsley and Schmidt 2008) examine the impact of UN interventions on the likelihood and severity of repeated conflict between belligerents. These authors categorize UN interventions along their underlying purposes, i.e., passive interventions, active missions, operational deployment, and a residual category, but Diehl et al. (1996: 693ff) do not find any significant effect of either mission type on the chances of repeated dispute or conflict severity. In sum, despite the fact that all these studies addressed the same research question, the findings are mixed. One stream finds a positive contribution of peacekeeping interventions, while the other is highly skeptical of that. We argue that two key theoretical shortcomings, which have major empirical implications, are likely to be the main reason for that. In all of these examinations, peacekeeping missions are either treated as a simple binary variable, i.e., did peacekeeping occur or not, or just characterized along the mission type or purpose of an intervention in question. This leaves out a significant amount of valuable information, however, since these previous models do not look beyond the dichotomous distinction between peacekeeping missions and cases that did not see those interventions. One notable exception is Mariani (2008), who argues in consistence with our project that the existing research has failed to produce a sound theory of peacekeeping because it treated peacekeeping operations as a black box. The author attempts to disaggregate UN interventions along the functional specifications of a mission in question. Put differently, Mariani (2008) uses the peacekeeping functions framework

8 8 as developed by Diehl, Druckman, and Wall (1998) in order to categorize peacekeeping missions as 1) traditional peacekeeping, 2) observation missions, 3) collective enforcement, 4) election supervision, 5) humanitarian assistance, 6) state building, 7) pacification, 8) preventive deployment, 9) arms controls, 10) protective services, 11) interventions in support of democracy, and 12) sanctions enforcement. Employing these categories, the author then examines their impact on the duration of peace after a ceasefire agreement. However, Mariani s (2008) findings are largely inconclusive, lacking substantial or statistical significance at conventional levels. Although we appreciate this first step toward moving beyond the simple dichotomy, we believe that Mariani s (2008) findings emphasize that other mechanisms are at work when disaggregating peacekeeping missions. More specifically, in the following we focus on the actors that form a peacekeeping mission, i.e., the nation states. These countries differ in terms of their interests, preferences, regime types, or capabilities, which in turn is likely to influence whether a peacekeeping intervention will be effective or not. Theory: Disaggregating Peacekeeping Missions - Size, Democracy, and Supply- Side Incentives General Approach. Commitment problems are the focus of numerous studies that seek to explain the onset (e.g., Powell 2006), duration (e.g., Fearon 2004), or recurrence (e.g., Werner and Yuen 2005) of interstate disputes and civil wars (see also Fearon 1995; Walter 1997; 2009). 1 Commitment problems arise if belligerents perceive a high risk that opponents will renege on agreements in the future (Powell 2006). Reneging on settlements is usually caused by future power shifts, which can occur due to the following reasons. First, warring parties typically have to demobilize after the end of a conflict. However, demobilization increases the vulnerability of 1 Due to the focus of our study, we elaborate our arguments solely in a civil-war context.

9 9 ex-belligerents. Especially in the context of civil wars, the government is generally the only party left with forces, weapons, and sufficient military power to fight possible internal threats after demobilization. This, however, implies that once the rebel organization(s) have decreased their military capacity, the government has an opportunity to renege on former agreements (Walter 2009). Second, even if demobilization is not implemented, former opponents are likely to have different recovery rates, which may highly determine their prospective fighting capabilities or bargaining leverage afterwards. Finally, the incumbent government might exploit post-war institutional weaknesses to politically marginalize former opponents. For example, leaders in democratic systems can take advantage of different mechanisms to manipulate political power. One of the most prominent ones is systematic electoral fraud (Collier 2009). Government leaders might also form new coalitions, thereby marginalizing groups after the conflict, although they were promised government posts in peace negotiations. Additionally, leaders might manipulate the political balance by redrawing election districts or distributing private goods to regions that are decisive for staying in power. In autocratic systems these kinds of commitment problems might be even worse. Ministers can be expelled, opposition leaders may be killed, and constitutions rewritten, ultimately paving the way for the absolute control of the government leader. Against this background, the question arises how peacekeeping interventions can help to solve these commitment problems. We argue that third parties seeking to intervene and to mitigate commitment problems have to focus on two different, albeit related issues. A peacekeeping force either has to reduce the probability of a prospective power shift or, second, to increase the costs of exploiting it. However, third parties are only able to credibly address these issues, if the benefits of mitigating possible commitment problems outweigh the costs of doing

10 10 so. More formally, peacekeeping has to fulfill the following basic condition in order to yield credibility (see also Lake and Rothchild 1996): EU (~ Enforce) < EU ( Enforce) (1) Put differently, the expected utility of renewed conflict, EU(~Enforce), has to be smaller than the expected utility of peace, given the peacekeeping effort of some third parties to punish the government or to effectively control rebel organizations. Furthermore, we treat EU(Enforce), i.e., the expected utility of enforcing the terms of a settlement, as being determined by a probability (p) of keeping peace (Ω) minus any direct or indirect costs (c) that are associated with an intervention: EU ( Enforce) = pω c (2) In a third step, we further assume that p is a contest success function (see Skarperdas 1996), which is determined by the forces (F P ) invested by peacekeepers as well as the resistance of peace spoilers (F S ): e FP p = (3) F + F Here, e is the effectiveness parameter of the peacekeepers. When combining (3) with (2) and (1), we see that, ceteris paribus, higher levels of the peacekeeping effectiveness e induce that EU(Enforce) increases as well. Hence, it is then also more likely that peacekeepers come across as more credible, since EU(Enforce) is larger than EU(~Enforce). However, not all peacekeeping forces are created equal, but it is likely that these vary in terms of their credibility and, hence, effectiveness. Put differently, we need to answer what determines e, i.e., the effectiveness of a peacekeeping mission? In what follows, we suggest that it is necessary to focus on the underlying factors that drive a peacekeeping force and that e e P S

11 11 depends on the number of actors involved in a peacekeeping intervention, their regime types, and supply-side incentives. Size. The literature generally argues that a large coalition of states is more likely than smaller peacekeeping forces to secure a peace agreement and to increase effectiveness (see Walter 2002; Wright and Greig 2008). First, Touval and Zartman (1985: 40), for example, emphasize that third parties only gain the warring parties consent to intervene if they are likely help the antagonists out of a predicament, and for this they usually need leverage. Ward (2006: 153) also argues that states must have the ability to threaten or to bribe other countries, i.e., using leverage, in order to ensure cooperation. The combined leverage of a large peacekeeping force can then create obligations and expectations that help enforce compliance with a peaceful agreement. A small peacekeeping force does often not have such an amount of leverage that may be necessary for effectively securing peace after conflicts. Second, since non-cooperating actors, i.e., antagonists that are reluctant to comply with a ceasefire and the states of the intervening coalition, can be excluded from other forms of reciprocity, larger peacekeeping forces increase the likelihood that both interveners and the warring parties will pursue shared goals through complementary means. Third, states as part of a peacekeeping coalition are likely to have connected issues and interests. This establishes trust, which is a crucial element for overcoming collective action problems and being ultimately more effective in keeping peace. Forth, third parties can signal their commitment through mission size (Walter 1997; 2002). Larger missions serve as a signal of credibility due to of sunken costs: only parties that are credibly committed to a peace process would be willing to pay high costs. Finally, larger peacekeeping forces usually have a higher rate of communication, which facilitates coordination and decreases uncertainty (see Frazier and Dixon 2006: 391ff; Dorussen and Ward 2008).

12 12 Figure 1. The Impact of Leverage on Peacekeeping Effectiveness. Peacekeeping Effectiveness Leverage However, it is likely that there are decreasing returns with respect to higher levels of peacekeeping effectiveness arising from more leverage and, hence, larger forces. In other words, we argue that a very large coalition of peacekeepers is only to a certain extent more effective than smaller groups. 2 Intervening states vary in terms of their interests, intelligence, capabilities, communication flows, etc. The larger a coalition of peacekeepers, the higher the likelihood of unanticipated problems of coordination, which ultimately may cause that a sufficiently large coalition does not contribute significantly more than a smaller set of interveners to effective outcomes. Figure 1 depicts this relationship. Related to, albeit different from the last claim is the mechanism arguing that larger groups providing a public good in this case peace are more difficult and more costly to organize (see Buchanan and Tullock 1962; Olson 1965: 46ff; Chamberlain 1974). Organizational costs increase with group size in two different ways. First, the larger a group of states forming a peacekeeping force, the more likely it is that the intervening coalition is characterized by greater heterogeneity of interests (Snidal 1994). This in turn makes it more difficult for the peacekeepers to reach any agreement at all or something beyond a minimal consensus with regards to the strategy of their 2 Note that this argument may well explain why Walter (2002) does not find empirical support for her claim on the linear relationship between capabilities and peacekeeping effectiveness.

13 13 operation. Second, states can participate in peacekeeping efforts without contributing much or anything at all, but obtaining heightened international prestige after an intervention ended successfully (see Walter 1997; 2000). Beardsley (2010) argues in a similar way when suggesting a collective action problem in which the presence of multiple third parties with the potential to offer mediation reduces the likelihood that any mediation will take place at all. Under these circumstances, enforcement through monitoring and/or sanctioning is essential in order to prevent states from free-riding on other states peacekeeping efforts (Fearon 1998: 270). Monitoring procedures ensure that contributions become perceptible for the entire peacekeeping coalition. In addition, only the prospect to detect non-contributions to an effort of peacekeeping allows states to sanction defectors accordingly (see Axelrod and Keohane 1985: 235; North 1990: 57; Olson 1965: 45f). However, with an increasing number of peacekeepers, the more costly it is to organize monitoring devices that provide perceptibility of individual contributions and enforcing actors compliance also becomes less likely to succeed (see Axelrod and Keohane 1985: 234ff; Frohlich and Oppenheimer 1974; North 1990: 57; Olson 1965: 36). Figure 2. The Impact of Organizational Costs on Peacekeeping Effectiveness. Peacekeeping Effectiveness Organizational Costs Figure 2 illustrates this mechanism. Organizational costs hardly matter when a peacekeeping force comprises a few states only. At some point, however, the impact of organizational costs is

14 14 likely to decrease the chances of cooperative success or the level of peacekeeping effectiveness as in our study rapidly. When combing this curve with Figure 1 above, we obtain an inverted U- shaped relationship between the size of an intervening group and peacekeeping effectiveness as a result. We therefore postulate: Hypothesis 1. The size of an intervening group and peacekeeping effectiveness are characterized by an inverted U-shaped relationship. Both small and very large peacekeeping forces are less likely to intervene effectively. Peacekeepers Regime Types. Drawing upon the democratic peace literature (e.g., Oneal and Russett 1999), democracies have a common structural background and institutional procedures. This gives these kinds of regimes more inclusivity, a higher level of transparency, as well as promotes a common understanding that induces shared norms and perceptions. One of the most important norms of democracies is the peaceful resolution of conflicts (e.g., Dixon 1994; Raymond 1994; Bercovitch and Houston 2000; Mitchell 2002). This should make democratic belligerents not only more likely to settle their disputes peacefully, but also have an impact on the efforts of peacekeepers that are (largely) democratic. Democratic interveners all share, practice, and understand concepts such as limited governments, respect for judicial practices, as well as constitutional constraints (Simmons 1999). Due to their previous, long-lasting practice and experience with these issues they will be more likely to be effective in intervening disputes than (largely) autocratic coalitions, which are not familiar with them. Two related and similar arguments are worth noting here. First, Dixon (1994) claims that democracies will be more effective when intervening, since they operate under a norm of bounded competition that favors the use of compromise. When participating in peacekeeping

15 15 operations, democracies seek to follow this principle. Second, a peacekeeping coalition of states that is (largely) democratic will be more effective, as it credibly commits not only to these principles of intervention, but also to actively enforcing peace after an agreement and is therefore more effective in convincingly signaling belligerents to settle their conflict even in the absence of strong incentives for doing so (Gilady and Russett 2002: 404; see Werner and Yuen 2005). Finally, the inclusivity and transparency of democratic systems allows enhanced information flows between these sorts of regimes, making them more effective in keeping and securing peace due to two reasons. First, increased information about each other ultimately leads to less uncertainty, more trust, and higher reliability (Mitchell, Kadera and Crescenzi 2005: 8). This is crucial against the background that conflict management, and hence peacekeeping, depends on the credible and truthful transmission of information (Dorussen and Ward 2008: 193). On the opposite, promises of autocracies are less likely to be credible, since there is an insecure hold of power and the absence of an heir (Olson 1993: 571). Second, increased flows of information allow democracies to coordinate their efforts and resources more effectively (Choi 2003: 145). Unlike autocracies, democracies tend to have transparent, open systems, which increases the likelihood that democracies know about each others internal evaluations, their intentions, the intensity of their preferences, and their willingness to adhere to an agreement even in adverse future circumstances (Keohane 1983: 162f). To recap, democratic peacekeeping coalitions are characterized by high levels of communication, shared norms, and inclusivity, which should facilitate coordinative efforts between these kinds of states. This in turn is likely to increase the rate of success of peacekeeping interventions. Our second hypothesis therefore claims:

16 16 Hypothesis 2. The more democratic a peacekeeping force, the more effective the intervention attempt. Supply-Side Incentives. Countries that comprise a peacekeeping force must have sufficient and credible interests at stake when intervening in order to successfully keep peace (Touval and Zartman 1985: 258f; Lake and Rothchild 1996; Walter 1997: 340; 2000). States have interests, if they share perceptions and norms, or have a common understanding with the belligerents. The colonial ties between Belgium and the Democratic Republic of the Congo, for instance, can explain to a significant extent the involvement of the former in most of the peacekeeping missions there. Most importantly, however, countries seeking to intervene are driven by strategic and security-related interests. Gleditsch, Salehyan, and Schultz (2008) theoretically argue and empirically demonstrate that civil wars increase the likelihood of interstate wars in/with the neighborhood of a conflict state. Among other causal mechanisms presented in their research, Gleditsch et al. (2008: 486f) show that civil wars induce negative externalities that affect the decision-making calculus of geographically close states. More specifically, civil war countries may initiate military action against neighboring states in order to undertake cross-border counterinsurgency actions (see also Salehyan 2007a) or to engage in retaliatory attacks against interventionist neighbors in the hope of coercing those into withdrawing support (Schultz 2007). This in turn increases the likelihood of conflict between the civil war country and one or more neighboring states significantly. As a result, the latter do have strong incentives for preventing not only the spread of conflict, since this is always an inefficient activity (Fearon 1995), but also to address the source of this potential negative externality, i.e., the civil war as such. In other words, civil wars increase the likelihood that surrounding states have a valid security interest in

17 17 the conflict, which ultimately should increase their incentives to effectively contain civil war and to promote peace. In a similar, albeit different manner, Gleditsch et al. (2008) highlight spillover effects (see also Sandler 2004). Civil wars can create new tensions because of spillovers from the fighting, such as mass refugee migration, or damage of cross-border infrastructure (Gleditsch et al. 2008: 487). Especially the former consequence of civil wars poses severe challenges to neighboring states, since refugee flows are likely to be an economic burden and/or cause political instability (Sandler 2004: 201; Salehyan and Gleditsch 2006). Likewise, Murdoch and Sandler (2002a; 2002b; 2004) show that both the income per capita and economic growth severely drop in countries that are in proximity to those states experiencing a civil war. Eventually, those spillovers can become militarized when states close their borders or take other measures to prevent conflict spillover transmissions. In sum, peacekeepers must have incentives to effectively keep peace in a conflict state (Walter 1997; 2000). If these incentives are not present, then we would expect that the chances of a peacekeeping force to ensure a stable and sustaining peace drop crucially. However, supply-side incentives are most likely to be given if states have a relevant security interest in a conflict most prominently due to negative externalities and spillover effects, since these would directly harm a country neighboring a civil war state (Salehyan 2007b). In turn, supply-side incentives should make parties more willing to bear the costs and risks and remain committed to peacekeeping. Hence, we test the following claim in our last hypothesis: Hypothesis 3. The stronger a peacekeeping force s supply-side incentives, the more effective the intervention attempt.

18 18 Research Design Data. We employ a modified version of Fortna s (2004) data on peace spells in or after civil wars in order to empirically test our hypotheses. These data are based upon the collection efforts of Doyle and Sambanis (2000) and cover civil wars in the post World War II era until the year A civil war is defined as as an armed conflict that caused more than 1,000 total battle deaths; that represented a challenge to the sovereignty of an internationally recognized state; and occurred within the recognized boundary of that state; that involved the state as one of the principal combatants; and in which the rebels were able to mount an organized military opposition to the state and to inflict significant casualties on the state (Fortna 2004: 276; see also Doyle and Sambanis 2000). Furthermore, we follow the consensus in the literature and define peacekeeping as the deployment of international personnel under the coordination of the UN or any other organization/coalition/actor to help maintain peace and security (see Fortna and Howard 2008: 285). Fortna s (2004) data suffer from a few shortcomings, such as omitting some short-lived ceasefires, but note that this should not affect our results negatively. On the contrary, the exclusion of these ceasefires is likely to underestimate the impact of our covariates, since more comprehensive data would find the stabilizing effects of peacekeeping to be even greater (Fortna 2004: 276). Using Fortna (2004) as our basic framework, we then modified the data by collecting additional information on our core variables of interest, which are described in detail below. The unit of analysis, i.e., a ceasefire or the peace spell of a civil war, does not alter, and we believe that relying on these data provides two crucial advantages over other kinds of civil war data. First, our data sample has been drawn from the population of civil wars since 1948 and not from the population of peacekeeping efforts. This gives us leverage for comparing peacekeeping

19 19 interventions and those cases that did not see such a conflict management attempt. This also mitigates the impact of selection bias (Regan and Stam 2000: 240). Second, Fortna s (2004) data include all kinds of peacekeeping interventions in civil wars, i.e., enforcement, monitoring, traditional peacekeeping, and state building. This ensures that we cover the comprehensive spectrum of peacekeeping operations, increasing the generalizability of our findings. Dependent Variable. In order to measure the effectiveness of peacekeeping interventions, we follow Fortna (2004) and employ the duration of peace, i.e., the time elapsed between the termination of fighting and the start of another war, if any, between the same parties. In total, we obtain 389 observations that cover 130 civil wars in Out of these 389 observations, 47 experienced a failure. Our dependent variable ranges between 1 and 19,131 days, while its mean is at 4,668 days. As our dependent variable measures the length of peace, a regular duration-type estimator seems the appropriate choice for testing our hypotheses. However, recall that assessing the effectiveness of peacekeeping efforts that we observe must also consider the prior selection stage of intervention, or the question of what influences the willingness of third parties to intervene in civil wars. Both stages are intertwined and the civil wars that actually see peacekeeping are unlikely to be a random sample (Gilligan and Sergenti 2006). On one hand, we may surmise that peacekeepers are more likely to intervene in civil wars that are easier. However, it may also be the case that peacekeepers primarily intervene in the more difficult wars, as these cases pose higher risks of instability to the international order. If the first scenario applies, we may exaggerate the effectiveness of peacekeeping, while the latter may lead us to underestimate it.

20 20 More generally, previous research ignoring the role of selection may have yielded misleading results on the effectiveness of peacekeeping (King and Zeng 2007a; 2007b). To control for this non-random assignment, we employ a duration estimator with sample selection (Boehmke et al. 2006). The correction of this estimator mirrors those for other selection models (see Heckman 1979) by developing a maximum likelihood estimator that simultaneously explains the selection and duration processes. Furthermore, this model estimates the correlation between the error terms in the two equations, allowing us to test for the presence of non-random sample selection. 3 We use a Weibull distribution for the duration stage, while the first stage follows a probit setup and employs the onset of peacekeeping in civil wars as the treatment item. Explanatory Variables. The core variables of interest follow the lines of our theoretical argumentation. 4 First, we run models where we include a count item measuring the number of states that formed a peacekeeping intervention. We collected the information on the size of peacekeeping operations using the Military Balance statistics from the International Institute for Strategic Studies ( ), and information from the United Nations Peacekeeping Department as well as the Secretary-General s reports to the Security Council. 5 This variable ranges in the interval [1; 43]. We include its squared term in the models to test our hypothesis on the inverted U-shaped relationship between coalition size and peacekeeping effectiveness. 3 Boehmke et al. (2006) use a bivariate exponential distribution to implement their Weibull estimator. One limitation of that is that the ρ coefficient estimating the error correlation is restricted to ρ smaller or equal to However Boehmke et al. (2006) argue that even if ρ is outside this range, their estimator may provide a better approximation to the unbiased relationships than completely ignoring selection problems. We also run their estimator with a lognormal instead of a Weibull distribution, as ρ is not restricted for this former case. Generally, our results stay robust, but ρ becomes fairly large (0.8) indeed. 4 Note that we also replicate two models from Fortna (2004) in the next section. These models essentially incorporate the same set of variables as described here with one exception. Fortna (2004: 285) employs a naïve approach in order to disaggregate peacekeeping interventions. More precisely, she dichotomously categorizes missions as 1) observer, 2) traditional peacekeeping, 3) multidimensional peacekeeping, and 4) enforcement efforts, using no peacekeeping as a baseline category. In some of the following models, hence, we use the same set of disaggregation variables in order to demonstrate that this categorization does not seem to be sufficient. 5 Related documents can be found at and repsc.htm

21 21 Second, the overall level of democracy of an intervening coalition is measured by the average value of all intervening countries polity2 value from the Polity IV data (Marshall and Jaggers 2002), which ranges from (almost full autocracy) to +10 (full democracy) in our sample. The average polity score is calculated by weighting each peacekeeping country s individual polity2 value using their number of troops contributed to a mission. If only one state forms a peacekeeping force, the polity2 score is employed without any further modifications. We expect this item to be positively related to the duration of peace. Third, for capturing the supply-side incentives of peacekeepers, we rely on the notion that in particular externalities and spillover effects may drive security concerns (Gleditsch et al. 2008). Based upon that, we generated variables that measure the capital-capital distance between an intervener and the civil war country (see Pearson 1974), and then calculated an average score in order to obtain the final variable for each peacekeeping operation. This item is again weighted using a country s specific troop contribution and we originally obtained the data via EUGene (Bennett and Stam 2000). Thus, we claim that the smaller the geographical distance between peacekeepers and belligerents as measured by this variable, the higher the propensity for longer peace spells. Control Covariates. Although we are primarily interested in disaggregating peacekeeping interventions and what impact this may have on the duration of peace, we also have to control for other factors that influence the dependent variable and our core independent variables in order to avoid potential omitted variable bias. Also, including determinants of peacekeeping effectiveness that other studies have identified may further help to control for selection effects. Finally, we need the control items for identifying the influences of peacekeeping onset, i.e., the dependent variable in the first stage of our empirical models. We closely follow Doyle and Sambanis s

22 22 (2000) and Fortna s (2004: 277) rationale as well as research design in order to decide on the controls. More specifically, we consider for the selection stage, first, a dummy variable coding the outcome of a war. Victory captures whether the fighting ended with a decisive victory by one side. Second, we include an item measuring whether a peace treaty was signed (Treaty). Third, another dichotomous variable (Wartype) distinguishes ethnic, religious, and identity conflicts from ideological, revolutionary, or other wars. Forth, we also include a variable pertaining to the costs of a war. Intensity is measured by the natural log of the number of battle as well as civilian deaths in the context of a civil war. Fifth, including a duration item corrects in addition to our other strategies for possible temporal dependencies and selection effects (see Regan and Stam 2000). Duration measures the length of a war in months. Sixth, a larger number of parties involved in a civil war increases uncertainty and, hence, we incorporate a binary variable (Factions) that marks whether the war involved more than two factions. Seventh, the level of development of a civil war state is coded with a proxy based on per capita electricity consumption (Development), and a country s natural resource dependence is measured via Exports, i.e., the primary commodity exports as a percent of GDP. Eighth, as elaborated above, democracies have a common structural background and institutional procedures, which increases the chances that these states are more favorable towards a stable peace. We therefore consider the prior history of democracy in a civil war country as measured by the average polity2 score over the five years before the war (Prior Democracy). Finally, we include a variable on the size of the government s army in a civil war (Army). Since Fortna (2004) uses the same set of variables not only when explaining which civil wars eventually see peacekeeping efforts, but also for examining the influences of peace duration, we

23 23 additionally run models in which we include these control variables in the outcome equation of the following empirical models. Empirical Findings We start with replicating some of Fortna s (2004) models that we employ as baseline estimations. Taking the existing selection effects into account, we then expand her analysis by trying to replicate her findings via the selection-duration model (Boehmke et al. 2006). This allows us to compare Fortna s (2004) and our disaggregation approach more precisely. Finally, we substitute Fortna s (2004) mission categories for our variables on the disaggregated peacekeepers characteristics, showing that our theoretical arguments about the effect of size, regime type, and supply-side incentives are largely supported by the empirical findings. In more detail, Fortna (2004: 279) estimates one model for the post World War II period for determining where peacekeepers intervene. The logit estimation uses a dummy variable for peacekeeping onset as the dependent variable and the controls we outlined above as explanatory items. In order to unveil the impact of peacekeeping, Fortna (2004: 285) continues with a Cox model, where the duration of peace after a ceasefire has been established signifies the dependent variable. The same set of controls is used again, but peacekeeping per se is disaggregated via a naïve approach, i.e., along the categories of observer, traditional, multinational, and enforcement missions. The replication estimates are listed in Table 1.

24 24 Table 1. Replication Models of Fortna (2004). PK Onset Peace Duration (Logit Model 1) (Cox Model 2) Observer 0.20 (0.13)** Traditional Peacekeeping 0.46 (0.29)* Multidimensional Peacekeeping 0.72 (0.46)* Enforcement Mission 1.88 (1.26) Victory (1.01)*** (0.07)*** Treaty (1.06) (0.25) Wartype (0.42) (0.53) Intensity (0.16) (0.12)** Duration (0.003) (0.002) Factions (0.55) (0.25) Exports (3.77) (36.63)* Development (0.0003)* (0.0004)** Prior Democracy (0.06) (0.03) Government Army Size ** (0.001) (0.0004)* Constant 0.73 (1.95) N Log Pseudo Likelihood Wald χ *** *** Pseudo R Note: table entries are coefficients (logit model) or odds ratios (Cox model); clustered robust standard errors in parentheses; * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1% (two-tailed). The logit model suggests that peacekeepers are more likely to intervene in more developed countries with an internal conflict and in civil war states where the government is weak. However, the most robust impact stems from Victory: peacekeepers tend to stay out of countries where conflict has ended in a decisive victory for either side. 6 As Table 1 further shows, 6 Recall that we use the logit s exact model specifications for the selection equation in the selection-duration estimator. Hence, a precise identification of that stage is a relatively strong requirement for doing so. This is given

25 25 we were also able to replicate Fortna s (2004: 285) duration model, where she distinguishes between different categories of peacekeeping and finds that peacekeeping along mission types does prolong peace. Note, however, that this model emphasizes at the same time that it is difficult to differentiate between the impact of each specific mission type: regardless if a peacekeeping force acts as an observer, executes traditional peacekeeping, is engaged in peacebuilding, or seeks to enforce peace, the effect on the duration of peace seems to be the same, as the size of the hazard ratios only marginally differs from each other. For the remainder of the analysis, we would like to stress two points accordingly. First and as outlined above, we appreciate Fortna s (2004) insights on the importance of distinguishing between different types of peacekeeping missions, although the replicated models demonstrate that her approach seems not entirely sufficient. Second, and following our theory, we need to go further by a) taking selection effects more directly into account and b) approaching the disaggregation of peacekeeping missions from a different perspective. As a first step toward addressing these issues, we continue with Table 2 that replicates the previous models using the selection-duration estimator (Boehmke et al. 2006). As indicated before, the selection stage corresponds to Fortna s (2004) logit estimations, while the duration stage firstly considers the different peacekeeping mission types only (Model 3) and then proceeds with incorporating the other determinants of peace duration (Model 4). Both model estimations leave out observer missions, using it as the reference category. here, however. The replicated logit model has a satisfactory fit and correctly classifies ca. 83% of the cases (69% in the null model).

26 26 Table 2. Replication Models of Fortna (2004) using a Selection-Duration Estimator. Model 3 Model 4 Outcome Eq. Selection Eq. Outcome Eq. Selection Eq. Observer - baseline - - baseline - Traditional Peacekeeping (0.43) (0.43) Multidimensional Peacekeeping (0.37) (0.38) Enforcement Mission (0.31) (0.53) Victory (0.65)*** (0.37)** (0.67)*** Treaty (0.67)* (0.35)** (0.69)* Wartype (0.27) (0.29) (0.28) Intensity (0.07) (0.08) (0.07) Duration (0.001) (0.002) (0.002) Factions (0.31)** (0.33) (0.31)** Exports (1.43) (2.08)* (1.45) Development (0.0002) (0.0001) (0.0002) Prior Democracy (0.03) (0.02)*** (0.04) Government Army Size (0.001) (0.0008) (0.001) Constant (0.28)*** (0.94) (0.90)*** (0.94) N (Censored) 360 (85) 360 (85) Log Pseudo Likelihood Wald χ *** 56.50*** ρ 0.25*** 0.25*** Note: table entries are probit coefficients (selection equation) or coefficients (outcome equation) pertaining to the accelerated failure time, i.e., larger coefficients correspond to smaller hazards and longer durations; clustered robust standard errors in parentheses; * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1% (two-tailed). Table 2 clearly demonstrates that civil wars with peacekeeping interventions cannot be considered a random sample. The significant estimate of ρ indicates that the selection model fits the data better than independent estimates of logit/probit and duration equations, respectively.

27 27 The ρ estimates the correlation of the error terms in the two stages. This parameter can be highly sensitive to model specifications, however, and should be expected to be negative if unobserved features that increase the likelihood of selection (i.e., peacekeeping onset) actually decrease the duration of peace after ceasefires. The fact that ρ is positive in all models (including Table 3 below) implies that unobserved features that make peacekeeping missions more likely also induce longer spells of peace. This may perhaps be likened to a positive impact of unobserved forms of resolve among the interveners, as the literature suggests multiple other forms of unobserved influences that could have these effects arising from the characteristics of the disputants and the conflict itself (see Gartzke 1999). Note that our results here are mostly consistent with Table 1, but emphasize again that Fortna s (2004) disaggregation approach does not tell us much when trying to determine which peacekeeping/peacekeepers characteristics are crucial for effectiveness. More specifically and like Fortna (2004), we cannot distinguish between each specific type of peacekeeping. In addition, however, once we directly take into account selection effects, we do not find any significant impact of those peacekeeping categories on the duration of peace after a ceasefire. Model 4 demonstrates that adding controls does not alter this result. Although this is not the focus of this paper, note that with regards to the other determinants of peacekeeping onset and peacekeeping effectiveness we also see crucial differences as compared to the replicated models above, which do not simultaneously consider the two-stage process. The selection equation, for example, shows that Treaty and Factions become significant at conventional levels. The level of development of a civil war country and the size of a government s army play a far minor role now, though. Furthermore, the outcome equation unveils some major differences as well. Among others, although Victory stays robust, Treaty has now a significantly negative impact on the duration of peace. More importantly, Intensity changes its sign and is no longer significant, while

The Influence of International Organizations on Militarized Dispute Initiation and Duration. Megan Shannon University of Mississippi

The Influence of International Organizations on Militarized Dispute Initiation and Duration. Megan Shannon University of Mississippi The Influence of International Organizations on Militarized Dispute Initiation and Duration Megan Shannon University of Mississippi Daniel Morey University of Kentucky Frederick J. Boehmke University of

More information

Online Supplement to Female Participation and Civil War Relapse

Online Supplement to Female Participation and Civil War Relapse Online Supplement to Female Participation and Civil War Relapse [Author Information Omitted for Review Purposes] June 6, 2014 1 Table 1: Two-way Correlations Among Right-Side Variables (Pearson s ρ) Lit.

More information

The Influence of International Organizations on Militarized Dispute Initiation and Duration 1

The Influence of International Organizations on Militarized Dispute Initiation and Duration 1 International Studies Quarterly (2010) 54, 1123 1141 The Influence of International Organizations on Militarized Dispute Initiation and Duration 1 Megan Shannon University of Mississippi Daniel Morey University

More information

Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation

Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation S. Roy*, Department of Economics, High Point University, High Point, NC - 27262, USA. Email: sroy@highpoint.edu Abstract We implement OLS,

More information

Supplementary Material for Preventing Civil War: How the potential for international intervention can deter conflict onset.

Supplementary Material for Preventing Civil War: How the potential for international intervention can deter conflict onset. Supplementary Material for Preventing Civil War: How the potential for international intervention can deter conflict onset. World Politics, vol. 68, no. 2, April 2016.* David E. Cunningham University of

More information

Short- and Long-Term Effects of United Nations Peace Operations

Short- and Long-Term Effects of United Nations Peace Operations Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Short- and Long-Term Effects of United Nations Peace Operations Nicholas Sambanis In

More information

Partial Peace. Rebel Groups Inside and Outside of Civil War Settlements. Abstract

Partial Peace. Rebel Groups Inside and Outside of Civil War Settlements. Abstract Partial Peace Rebel Groups Inside and Outside of Civil War Settlements Abstract Previous research proposes that for peace to become durable it is essential to include all rebel groups in any settlement

More information

Contiguous States, Stable Borders and the Peace between Democracies

Contiguous States, Stable Borders and the Peace between Democracies Contiguous States, Stable Borders and the Peace between Democracies Douglas M. Gibler June 2013 Abstract Park and Colaresi argue that they could not replicate the results of my 2007 ISQ article, Bordering

More information

How to Intervene in Civil Wars: Strategic Interests, Humanitarianism, and Third-Party Intervention. Sang Ki Kim University of Iowa

How to Intervene in Civil Wars: Strategic Interests, Humanitarianism, and Third-Party Intervention. Sang Ki Kim University of Iowa How to Intervene in Civil Wars: Strategic Interests, Humanitarianism, and Third-Party Intervention Sang Ki Kim University of Iowa Abstract This paper examines how major powers intervene in civil wars in

More information

1. The Relationship Between Party Control, Latino CVAP and the Passage of Bills Benefitting Immigrants

1. The Relationship Between Party Control, Latino CVAP and the Passage of Bills Benefitting Immigrants The Ideological and Electoral Determinants of Laws Targeting Undocumented Migrants in the U.S. States Online Appendix In this additional methodological appendix I present some alternative model specifications

More information

Just War or Just Politics? The Determinants of Foreign Military Intervention

Just War or Just Politics? The Determinants of Foreign Military Intervention Just War or Just Politics? The Determinants of Foreign Military Intervention Averyroughdraft.Thankyouforyourcomments. Shannon Carcelli UC San Diego scarcell@ucsd.edu January 22, 2014 1 Introduction Under

More information

Evaluating the conflict-reducing effect of UN peacekeeping operations

Evaluating the conflict-reducing effect of UN peacekeeping operations Evaluating the conflict-reducing effect of UN peacekeeping operations Håvard Hegre 1,2, Lisa Hultman 1, and Håvard Mokleiv Nygård 2 1 Department of Peace and Conflict Research, Uppsala University 2 Peace

More information

Peacekeepers as Signals

Peacekeepers as Signals Peacekeepers as Signals Page Fortna and Lisa Martin January 25, 2005 Peacekeeping the deployment of international troops and monitors to war-torn areas is an institution intended to help recent belligerents

More information

All s Well That Ends Well: A Reply to Oneal, Barbieri & Peters*

All s Well That Ends Well: A Reply to Oneal, Barbieri & Peters* 2003 Journal of Peace Research, vol. 40, no. 6, 2003, pp. 727 732 Sage Publications (London, Thousand Oaks, CA and New Delhi) www.sagepublications.com [0022-3433(200311)40:6; 727 732; 038292] All s Well

More information

Towards a Continuous Specification of the Democracy-Autocracy Connection. D. Scott Bennett The Pennsylvania State University

Towards a Continuous Specification of the Democracy-Autocracy Connection. D. Scott Bennett The Pennsylvania State University Towards a Continuous Specification of the Democracy-Autocracy Connection D. Scott Bennett The Pennsylvania State University Forthcoming, 2006 International Studies Quarterly (v 50 pp. 513-537) Mail: Department

More information

Openness and Internal Conflict. Christopher S. P. Magee Department of Economics Bucknell University Lewisburg, PA

Openness and Internal Conflict. Christopher S. P. Magee Department of Economics Bucknell University Lewisburg, PA Openness and Internal Conflict Christopher S. P. Magee Department of Economics Bucknell University Lewisburg, PA 17837 cmagee@bucknell.edu Tansa George Massoud Department of Political Science Bucknell

More information

The System Made Me Stop Doing It. The Indirect Origins of Commercial Peace

The System Made Me Stop Doing It. The Indirect Origins of Commercial Peace Erik Gartzke UCSD egartzke@ucsd.edu The System Made Me Stop Doing It The Indire The System Made Me Stop Doing It The Indirect Origins of Commercial Peace Erik Gartzke UCSD egartzke@ucsd.edu May 7, 2016

More information

Evaluating the conflict-reducing effect of UN peacekeeping operations Preprint: Article forthcoming in Journal of Politics.

Evaluating the conflict-reducing effect of UN peacekeeping operations Preprint: Article forthcoming in Journal of Politics. Evaluating the conflict-reducing effect of UN peacekeeping operations Preprint: Article forthcoming in Journal of Politics Håvard Hegre 1,2, Lisa Hultman 1, and Håvard Mokleiv Nygård 2 1 Department of

More information

EXPECTATIONS, RIVALRIES, AND CIVIL WAR DURATION

EXPECTATIONS, RIVALRIES, AND CIVIL WAR DURATION International Interactions, 31: 349 374, 2005 Copyright Taylor & Francis LLC ISSN: 0305-0629 DOI: 10.1080/03050620500303449 GINI 0305-0629 0000-0000 International Interactions, Vol. 31, No. 04, October

More information

Even Generals Need Friends: How Domestic and International Reactions to Coups Influence Regime Survival

Even Generals Need Friends: How Domestic and International Reactions to Coups Influence Regime Survival Even Generals Need Friends: How Domestic and International Reactions to Coups Influence Regime Survival Clayton L. Thyne Jonathan M. Powell Sarah Hayden Emily VanMeter Journal of Conflict Resolution Online

More information

Democracy and the Settlement of International Borders,

Democracy and the Settlement of International Borders, Democracy and the Settlement of International Borders, 1919-2001 Douglas M Gibler Andrew Owsiak December 7, 2016 Abstract There is increasing evidence that territorial conflict is associated with centralized

More information

Mixed Motives? Explaining the Decision to Integrate Militaries at Civil War's End

Mixed Motives? Explaining the Decision to Integrate Militaries at Civil War's End Political Science Faculty Publications Political Science 4-2014 Mixed Motives? Explaining the Decision to Integrate Militaries at Civil War's End Caroline A. Hartzell Gettysburg College Follow this and

More information

Publicizing malfeasance:

Publicizing malfeasance: Publicizing malfeasance: When media facilitates electoral accountability in Mexico Horacio Larreguy, John Marshall and James Snyder Harvard University May 1, 2015 Introduction Elections are key for political

More information

Powersharing, Protection, and Peace. Scott Gates, Benjamin A. T. Graham, Yonatan Lupu Håvard Strand, Kaare W. Strøm. September 17, 2015

Powersharing, Protection, and Peace. Scott Gates, Benjamin A. T. Graham, Yonatan Lupu Håvard Strand, Kaare W. Strøm. September 17, 2015 Powersharing, Protection, and Peace Scott Gates, Benjamin A. T. Graham, Yonatan Lupu Håvard Strand, Kaare W. Strøm September 17, 2015 Corresponding Author: Yonatan Lupu, Department of Political Science,

More information

the united nations peacekeeping and rule of law reform in post-conflict societies

the united nations peacekeeping and rule of law reform in post-conflict societies the united nations peacekeeping and rule of law reform in post-conflict societies sweta maturu, emory university (2013) ABSTRACT The United Nations frequently engages in peacekeeping activities in post-conflict

More information

Corruption, Political Instability and Firm-Level Export Decisions. Kul Kapri 1 Rowan University. August 2018

Corruption, Political Instability and Firm-Level Export Decisions. Kul Kapri 1 Rowan University. August 2018 Corruption, Political Instability and Firm-Level Export Decisions Kul Kapri 1 Rowan University August 2018 Abstract In this paper I use South Asian firm-level data to examine whether the impact of corruption

More information

University of Georgia, Athens, Georgia, USA

University of Georgia, Athens, Georgia, USA This article was downloaded by:[university of Georgia] On: 21 August 2007 Access Details: [subscription number 731594552] Publisher: Taylor & Francis Informa Ltd Registered in England and Wales Registered

More information

Winning with the bomb. Kyle Beardsley and Victor Asal

Winning with the bomb. Kyle Beardsley and Victor Asal Winning with the bomb Kyle Beardsley and Victor Asal Introduction Authors argue that states can improve their allotment of a good or convince an opponent to back down and have shorter crises if their opponents

More information

The Impact of State Relationships on If, When, and How Conflict Management Occurs 1

The Impact of State Relationships on If, When, and How Conflict Management Occurs 1 International Studies Quarterly (2011) 55, 691 715 The Impact of State Relationships on If, When, and How Conflict Management Occurs 1 Molly M. Melin Loyola University Chicago This paper examines if, when,

More information

The Relevance of Politically Relevant Dyads in the Study of Interdependence and Dyadic Disputes

The Relevance of Politically Relevant Dyads in the Study of Interdependence and Dyadic Disputes Conflict Management and Peace Science, 22:113 133, 2005 Copyright C Peace Science Society (International) ISSN: 0738-8942 print / 1549-9219 online DOI: 10.1080/07388940590948556 The Relevance of Politically

More information

Allying to Win. Regime Type, Alliance Size, and Victory

Allying to Win. Regime Type, Alliance Size, and Victory Allying to Win Regime Type, Alliance Size, and Victory Christopher J. Fariss Erik Gartzke Benjamin A. T. Graham Abstract Studies of regime type and war reveal that democracies tend to win the wars they

More information

How and When Armed Conflicts End: Web appendix

How and When Armed Conflicts End: Web appendix How and When Armed Conflicts End: Web appendix This is an appendix for Joakim Kreutz, 2010. How and When Armed Conflicts End: Introduction the UCDP Conflict Termination Dataset, Journal of Peace Research

More information

Human Rights Violations and Competitive Elections in Dictatorships

Human Rights Violations and Competitive Elections in Dictatorships Human Rights Violations and Competitive Elections in Dictatorships Jessica Maves The Pennsylvania State University Department of Political Science jessica.maves@psu.edu Seiki Tanaka Syracuse University

More information

Appendix: Regime Type, Coalition Size, and Victory

Appendix: Regime Type, Coalition Size, and Victory Appendix: Regime Type, Coalition Size, and Victory Benjamin A. T. Graham Erik Gartzke Christopher J. Fariss Contents 10 Introduction to the Appendix 2 10.1 Testing Hypotheses 1-3 with Logged Partners....................

More information

International Migration and Military Intervention in Civil War

International Migration and Military Intervention in Civil War Online Appendix 1 International Migration and Military Intervention in Civil War Online Appendix In this appendix, we report a variety of additional model specifications in order to increase the confidence

More information

Transborder Identities, Bias, and Third-Party Conflict Management

Transborder Identities, Bias, and Third-Party Conflict Management Transborder Identities, Bias, and Third-Party Conflict Management August 16, 2018 Emir Yazici Ph.D. Candidate Department of Political Science University of Missouri 113 Professional Building Columbia MO

More information

The Role of External Support in Violent and Nonviolent Civil. Conflict Outcomes

The Role of External Support in Violent and Nonviolent Civil. Conflict Outcomes The Role of External Support in Violent and Nonviolent Civil Conflict Outcomes Prepared for the Western Political Science Association Annual Conference 2015 Jaime Jackson April 4, 2015 1 In 2000, Serbian

More information

The Past is Ever-Present: Civil War as a Dynamic Process 1. Benjamin T. Jones

The Past is Ever-Present: Civil War as a Dynamic Process 1. Benjamin T. Jones The Past is Ever-Present: Civil War as a Dynamic Process 1 Benjamin T. Jones jones.2781@osu.edu Abstract The literature on civil wars is extensive and growing. Past studies have focused on a series of

More information

Evaluating the conflict-reducing effect of UN peacekeeping operations

Evaluating the conflict-reducing effect of UN peacekeeping operations Evaluating the conflict-reducing effect of UN peacekeeping operations Håvard Hegre 1,2, Lisa Hultman 1, and Håvard Mokleiv Nygård 2,3 1 Department of Peace and Conflict Research, Uppsala University 2 Peace

More information

Oxford Research Encyclopedia of Politics

Oxford Research Encyclopedia of Politics Oxford Research Encyclopedia of Politics Effectiveness of Peacekeeping Operations Jessica Di Salvatore and Andrea Ruggeri Subject: Contentious Politics and Political Violence, World Politics Online Publication

More information

Guns and Butter in U.S. Presidential Elections

Guns and Butter in U.S. Presidential Elections Guns and Butter in U.S. Presidential Elections by Stephen E. Haynes and Joe A. Stone September 20, 2004 Working Paper No. 91 Department of Economics, University of Oregon Abstract: Previous models of the

More information

THE IMPACT OF EXTERNAL SUPPORT ON INTRASTATE CONFLICT

THE IMPACT OF EXTERNAL SUPPORT ON INTRASTATE CONFLICT Parente, Impact of External Support on Intrastate Conflict THE IMPACT OF EXTERNAL SUPPORT ON INTRASTATE CONFLICT Adam Parente Abstract Supporting participants in intrastate conflict often appears as a

More information

A COMPARISON BETWEEN TWO DATASETS

A COMPARISON BETWEEN TWO DATASETS A COMPARISON BETWEEN TWO DATASETS Bachelor Thesis by S.F. Simmelink s1143611 sophiesimmelink@live.nl Internationale Betrekkingen en Organisaties Universiteit Leiden 9 June 2016 Prof. dr. G.A. Irwin Word

More information

Understanding Taiwan Independence and Its Policy Implications

Understanding Taiwan Independence and Its Policy Implications Understanding Taiwan Independence and Its Policy Implications January 30, 2004 Emerson M. S. Niou Department of Political Science Duke University niou@duke.edu 1. Introduction Ever since the establishment

More information

Incumbency as a Source of Spillover Effects in Mixed Electoral Systems: Evidence from a Regression-Discontinuity Design.

Incumbency as a Source of Spillover Effects in Mixed Electoral Systems: Evidence from a Regression-Discontinuity Design. Incumbency as a Source of Spillover Effects in Mixed Electoral Systems: Evidence from a Regression-Discontinuity Design Forthcoming, Electoral Studies Web Supplement Jens Hainmueller Holger Lutz Kern September

More information

Horizontal Educational Inequalities and Civil Conflict: The Nexus of Ethnicity, Inequality, and Violent Conflict

Horizontal Educational Inequalities and Civil Conflict: The Nexus of Ethnicity, Inequality, and Violent Conflict Undergraduate Economic Review Volume 8 Issue 1 Article 10 2012 Horizontal Educational Inequalities and Civil Conflict: The Nexus of Ethnicity, Inequality, and Violent Conflict Katharine M. Lindquist Carleton

More information

Following the Leader: The Impact of Presidential Campaign Visits on Legislative Support for the President's Policy Preferences

Following the Leader: The Impact of Presidential Campaign Visits on Legislative Support for the President's Policy Preferences University of Colorado, Boulder CU Scholar Undergraduate Honors Theses Honors Program Spring 2011 Following the Leader: The Impact of Presidential Campaign Visits on Legislative Support for the President's

More information

Transnational Dimensions of Civil War

Transnational Dimensions of Civil War Transnational Dimensions of Civil War Kristian Skrede Gleditsch University of California, San Diego & Centre for the Study of Civil War, International Peace Research Institute, Oslo See http://weber.ucsd.edu/

More information

Evaluating the conflict-reducing effect of UN peace-keeping operations

Evaluating the conflict-reducing effect of UN peace-keeping operations Evaluating the conflict-reducing effect of UN peace-keeping operations Håvard Hegre 1,3, Lisa Hultman 2, and Håvard Mokleiv Nygård 1,3 1 University of Oslo 2 Swedish National Defence College 3 Centre for

More information

Uncertainty and international return migration: some evidence from linked register data

Uncertainty and international return migration: some evidence from linked register data Applied Economics Letters, 2012, 19, 1893 1897 Uncertainty and international return migration: some evidence from linked register data Jan Saarela a, * and Dan-Olof Rooth b a A bo Akademi University, PO

More information

Rethinking Civil War Onset and Escalation

Rethinking Civil War Onset and Escalation January 16, 2018 Abstract Why do some civil conflicts simmer at low-intensity, while others escalate to war? This paper challenges traditional approaches to the start of intrastate conflict by arguing

More information

Violent Conflict and Inequality

Violent Conflict and Inequality Violent Conflict and Inequality work in progress Cagatay Bircan University of Michigan Tilman Brück DIW Berlin, Humboldt University Berlin, IZA and Households in Conflict Network Marc Vothknecht DIW Berlin

More information

corruption since they might reect judicial eciency rather than corruption. Simply put,

corruption since they might reect judicial eciency rather than corruption. Simply put, Appendix Robustness Check As discussed in the paper, many question the reliability of judicial records as a proxy for corruption since they might reect judicial eciency rather than corruption. Simply put,

More information

The Determinants of Low-Intensity Intergroup Violence: The Case of Northern Ireland. Online Appendix

The Determinants of Low-Intensity Intergroup Violence: The Case of Northern Ireland. Online Appendix The Determinants of Low-Intensity Intergroup Violence: The Case of Northern Ireland Online Appendix Laia Balcells (Duke University), Lesley-Ann Daniels (Institut Barcelona d Estudis Internacionals & Universitat

More information

Educated Preferences: Explaining Attitudes Toward Immigration In Europe. Jens Hainmueller and Michael J. Hiscox. Last revised: December 2005

Educated Preferences: Explaining Attitudes Toward Immigration In Europe. Jens Hainmueller and Michael J. Hiscox. Last revised: December 2005 Educated Preferences: Explaining Attitudes Toward Immigration In Jens Hainmueller and Michael J. Hiscox Last revised: December 2005 Supplement III: Detailed Results for Different Cutoff points of the Dependent

More information

Figure 2: Proportion of countries with an active civil war or civil conflict,

Figure 2: Proportion of countries with an active civil war or civil conflict, Figure 2: Proportion of countries with an active civil war or civil conflict, 1960-2006 Sources: Data based on UCDP/PRIO armed conflict database (N. P. Gleditsch et al., 2002; Harbom & Wallensteen, 2007).

More information

Table A.2 reports the complete set of estimates of equation (1). We distinguish between personal

Table A.2 reports the complete set of estimates of equation (1). We distinguish between personal Akay, Bargain and Zimmermann Online Appendix 40 A. Online Appendix A.1. Descriptive Statistics Figure A.1 about here Table A.1 about here A.2. Detailed SWB Estimates Table A.2 reports the complete set

More information

EXPORT, MIGRATION, AND COSTS OF MARKET ENTRY EVIDENCE FROM CENTRAL EUROPEAN FIRMS

EXPORT, MIGRATION, AND COSTS OF MARKET ENTRY EVIDENCE FROM CENTRAL EUROPEAN FIRMS Export, Migration, and Costs of Market Entry: Evidence from Central European Firms 1 The Regional Economics Applications Laboratory (REAL) is a unit in the University of Illinois focusing on the development

More information

GENDER EQUALITY IN THE LABOUR MARKET AND FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT

GENDER EQUALITY IN THE LABOUR MARKET AND FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT THE STUDENT ECONOMIC REVIEWVOL. XXIX GENDER EQUALITY IN THE LABOUR MARKET AND FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT CIÁN MC LEOD Senior Sophister With Southeast Asia attracting more foreign direct investment than

More information

Ohio State University

Ohio State University Fake News Did Have a Significant Impact on the Vote in the 2016 Election: Original Full-Length Version with Methodological Appendix By Richard Gunther, Paul A. Beck, and Erik C. Nisbet Ohio State University

More information

Regions of Hierarchy and Security: US Troop Deployments, Spatial Relations, and Defense Burdens

Regions of Hierarchy and Security: US Troop Deployments, Spatial Relations, and Defense Burdens International Interactions Empirical and Theoretical Research in International Relations ISSN: 0305-0629 (Print) 1547-7444 (Online) Journal homepage: http://www.tandfonline.com/loi/gini20 Regions of Hierarchy

More information

Research Statement. Jeffrey J. Harden. 2 Dissertation Research: The Dimensions of Representation

Research Statement. Jeffrey J. Harden. 2 Dissertation Research: The Dimensions of Representation Research Statement Jeffrey J. Harden 1 Introduction My research agenda includes work in both quantitative methodology and American politics. In methodology I am broadly interested in developing and evaluating

More information

A REPLICATION OF THE POLITICAL DETERMINANTS OF FEDERAL EXPENDITURE AT THE STATE LEVEL (PUBLIC CHOICE, 2005) Stratford Douglas* and W.

A REPLICATION OF THE POLITICAL DETERMINANTS OF FEDERAL EXPENDITURE AT THE STATE LEVEL (PUBLIC CHOICE, 2005) Stratford Douglas* and W. A REPLICATION OF THE POLITICAL DETERMINANTS OF FEDERAL EXPENDITURE AT THE STATE LEVEL (PUBLIC CHOICE, 2005) by Stratford Douglas* and W. Robert Reed Revised, 26 December 2013 * Stratford Douglas, Department

More information

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr Abstract. The Asian experience of poverty reduction has varied widely. Over recent decades the economies of East and Southeast Asia

More information

Beyond Keeping Peace: United Nations Effectiveness in the Midst of Fighting

Beyond Keeping Peace: United Nations Effectiveness in the Midst of Fighting Beyond Keeping Peace: United Nations Effectiveness in the Midst of Fighting Lisa Hultman Associate Professor of Peace and Conflict Research Uppsala University Jacob Kathman Associate Professor of Political

More information

September 13, 2006 Democracy Out of Anarchy: How Do Features of A Civil War Influence the Likelihood of Post-Civil War Democracy?

September 13, 2006 Democracy Out of Anarchy: How Do Features of A Civil War Influence the Likelihood of Post-Civil War Democracy? September 13, 2006 Democracy Out of Anarchy: How Do Features of A Civil War Influence the Likelihood of Post-Civil War Democracy? Mehmet Gurses Department of Political Science University of North Texas

More information

LABOUR-MARKET INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS IN OECD-COUNTRIES: WHAT EXPLANATIONS FIT THE DATA?

LABOUR-MARKET INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS IN OECD-COUNTRIES: WHAT EXPLANATIONS FIT THE DATA? LABOUR-MARKET INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS IN OECD-COUNTRIES: WHAT EXPLANATIONS FIT THE DATA? By Andreas Bergh (PhD) Associate Professor in Economics at Lund University and the Research Institute of Industrial

More information

Should We Stay or Should We Go? Investigating the Impacts of Intervention on Post-War Development

Should We Stay or Should We Go? Investigating the Impacts of Intervention on Post-War Development Skidmore College Creative Matter Economics Student Theses and Capstone Projects Economics 2018 Should We Stay or Should We Go? Investigating the Impacts of Intervention on Post-War Development Benjamin

More information

The Effect of Sexual Violence on Negotiated Outcomes in Civil Conflict: Online Appendix

The Effect of Sexual Violence on Negotiated Outcomes in Civil Conflict: Online Appendix The Effect of Sexual Violence on Negotiated Outcomes in Civil Conflict: Online Appendix Summary statistics The following table presents information about the variables used in Table 1 of the manuscript.

More information

Partial Peace Rebel Groups Inside and Outside Civil War Settlements

Partial Peace Rebel Groups Inside and Outside Civil War Settlements Public Disclosure Authorized Pol i c y Re s e a rc h Wo r k i n g Pa p e r 4572 WPS4572 Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Pos t -Co n f l i c t Tr a n s i t i o n s Wo r k i n g

More information

The Laws of War and Public Opinion: An Experimental Study

The Laws of War and Public Opinion: An Experimental Study University of Chicago Law School Chicago Unbound Coase-Sandor Working Paper Series in Law and Economics Coase-Sandor Institute for Law and Economics 2014 The Laws of War and Public Opinion: An Experimental

More information

WEB APPENDIX. to accompany. Veto Players and Terror. Journal of Peace Research 47(1): Joseph K. Young 1. Southern Illinois University.

WEB APPENDIX. to accompany. Veto Players and Terror. Journal of Peace Research 47(1): Joseph K. Young 1. Southern Illinois University. WEB APPENDIX to accompany Veto Players and Terror Journal of Peace Research 47(1): 1-13 Joseph K. Young 1 Departments of Political Science and Criminology/Criminal Justice Southern Illinois University

More information

Theory, Data, and Deterrence: A Response to Kenwick, Vasquez, and Powers*

Theory, Data, and Deterrence: A Response to Kenwick, Vasquez, and Powers* Theory, Data, and Deterrence: A Response to Kenwick, Vasquez, and Powers* Brett Ashley Leeds Department of Political Science Rice University leeds@rice.edu Jesse C. Johnson Department of Political Science

More information

NATIONAL DEFENCE AND SECURITY

NATIONAL DEFENCE AND SECURITY NATIONAL DEFENCE AND SECURITY Natasha Grozdanoska European University, Faculty of Detectives and Criminology, Republic of Macedonia Abstract Safety is a condition in which states consider that there is

More information

Reanalysis: Are coups good for democracy?

Reanalysis: Are coups good for democracy? 681908RAP0010.1177/2053168016681908Research & PoliticsMiller research-article2016 Research Note Reanalysis: Are coups good for democracy? Research and Politics October-December 2016: 1 5 The Author(s)

More information

General Deterrence and International Conflict: Testing Perfect Deterrence Theory

General Deterrence and International Conflict: Testing Perfect Deterrence Theory International Interactions, 36:60 85, 2010 Copyright Taylor & Francis Group, LLC ISSN: 0305-0629 print/1547-7444 online DOI: 10.1080/03050620903554069 General Deterrence and International Conflict: Testing

More information

The Impact of the Interaction between Economic Growth and Democracy on Human Development: Cross-National Analysis

The Impact of the Interaction between Economic Growth and Democracy on Human Development: Cross-National Analysis Edith Cowan University Research Online ECU Publications 2012 2012 The Impact of the Interaction between Economic Growth and Democracy on Human Development: Cross-National Analysis Shrabani Saha Edith Cowan

More information

Democratization Conceptualisation and measurement

Democratization Conceptualisation and measurement Democratization and measurement University College Dublin 25 January 2011 Concepts Concept: abstract notion (in social science). E.g. culture,, money. : defining the concept. Operationalization: deciding

More information

Remittances and the Brain Drain: Evidence from Microdata for Sub-Saharan Africa

Remittances and the Brain Drain: Evidence from Microdata for Sub-Saharan Africa Remittances and the Brain Drain: Evidence from Microdata for Sub-Saharan Africa Julia Bredtmann 1, Fernanda Martinez Flores 1,2, and Sebastian Otten 1,2,3 1 RWI, Rheinisch-Westfälisches Institut für Wirtschaftsforschung

More information

Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US

Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US Ben Ost a and Eva Dziadula b a Department of Economics, University of Illinois at Chicago, 601 South Morgan UH718 M/C144 Chicago,

More information

GOVERNANCE RETURNS TO EDUCATION: DO EXPECTED YEARS OF SCHOOLING PREDICT QUALITY OF GOVERNANCE?

GOVERNANCE RETURNS TO EDUCATION: DO EXPECTED YEARS OF SCHOOLING PREDICT QUALITY OF GOVERNANCE? GOVERNANCE RETURNS TO EDUCATION: DO EXPECTED YEARS OF SCHOOLING PREDICT QUALITY OF GOVERNANCE? A Thesis submitted to the Faculty of the Graduate School of Arts and Sciences of Georgetown University in

More information

Summary Report. United Nations Mediation: Experiences and Reflections from the Field

Summary Report. United Nations Mediation: Experiences and Reflections from the Field Summary Report United Nations Mediation: Experiences and Reflections from the Field An Informal Meeting Organized by the President of the General Assembly 9 November 2011, 3.00-6.00 pm, Conference Room

More information

United Nations Peacekeeping and Violence against Civilians in Civil War

United Nations Peacekeeping and Violence against Civilians in Civil War United Nations Peacekeeping and Violence against Civilians in Civil War Jacob Kathman State University of New York at Buffalo Lisa Hultman Uppsala University Megan Shannon Florida State University Abstract

More information

Evaluating the conflict-reducing effect of UN peace-keeping operations

Evaluating the conflict-reducing effect of UN peace-keeping operations Evaluating the conflict-reducing effect of UN peace-keeping operations Håvard Hegre 1,3, Lisa Hultman 2, and Håvard Mokleiv Nygård 1,3 1 University of Oslo 2 Swedish National Defence College 3 Centre for

More information

The Principle of Convergence in Wartime Negotiations. Branislav L. Slantchev Department of Political Science University of California, San Diego

The Principle of Convergence in Wartime Negotiations. Branislav L. Slantchev Department of Political Science University of California, San Diego The Principle of Convergence in Wartime Negotiations Branislav L. Slantchev Department of Political Science University of California, San Diego March 25, 2003 1 War s very objective is victory not prolonged

More information

ADDITIONAL RESULTS FOR REBELS WITHOUT A TERRITORY. AN ANALYSIS OF NON- TERRITORIAL CONFLICTS IN THE WORLD,

ADDITIONAL RESULTS FOR REBELS WITHOUT A TERRITORY. AN ANALYSIS OF NON- TERRITORIAL CONFLICTS IN THE WORLD, ADDITIONAL RESULTS FOR REBELS WITHOUT A TERRITORY. AN ANALYSIS OF NON- TERRITORIAL CONFLICTS IN THE WORLD, 1970-1997. January 20, 2012 1. Introduction Rebels Without a Territory. An Analysis of Non-territorial

More information

Authoritarian Reversals and Democratic Consolidation

Authoritarian Reversals and Democratic Consolidation Authoritarian Reversals and Democratic Consolidation Milan Svolik Abstract I present a new empirical approach to the study of democratic consolidation. This approach leads to new insights into the determinants

More information

Errata Summary. Comparison of the Original Results with the New Results

Errata Summary. Comparison of the Original Results with the New Results Errata for Karim and Beardsley (2016), Explaining Sexual Exploitation and Abuse in Peacekeeping Missions: The Role of Female Peacekeepers and Gender Equality in Contributing Countries, Journal of Peace

More information

When Civil Wars Recur: Conditions for Durable Peace after Civil Wars

When Civil Wars Recur: Conditions for Durable Peace after Civil Wars International Studies Perspectives (2011) 12, 171 189. When Civil Wars Recur: Conditions for Durable Peace after Civil Wars T. David Mason University of North Texas Mehmet Gurses Florida Atlantic University

More information

SHOULD THE UNITED STATES WORRY ABOUT LARGE, FAST-GROWING ECONOMIES?

SHOULD THE UNITED STATES WORRY ABOUT LARGE, FAST-GROWING ECONOMIES? Chapter Six SHOULD THE UNITED STATES WORRY ABOUT LARGE, FAST-GROWING ECONOMIES? This report represents an initial investigation into the relationship between economic growth and military expenditures for

More information

Welfare State and Local Government: the Impact of Decentralization on Well-Being

Welfare State and Local Government: the Impact of Decentralization on Well-Being Welfare State and Local Government: the Impact of Decentralization on Well-Being Paolo Addis, Alessandra Coli, and Barbara Pacini (University of Pisa) Discussant Anindita Sengupta Associate Professor of

More information

Mediation in Interstate Disputes

Mediation in Interstate Disputes brill.com/iner Mediation in Interstate Disputes Sara McLaughlin Mitchell 1 Department of Political Science, University of Iowa, Iowa City, IA 52242, USA (E-mail: sara-mitchell@uiowa.edu) Received 15 May

More information

Taking matters into their own hands: An analysis of the determinants of state-conducted peacekeeping in civil wars

Taking matters into their own hands: An analysis of the determinants of state-conducted peacekeeping in civil wars journal of peace R ESEARCH Taking matters into their own hands: An analysis of the determinants of state-conducted peacekeeping in civil wars Journal of Peace Research 48(2) 171 184 ª The Author(s) 2011

More information

Harsh R. Pandya, B.S.

Harsh R. Pandya, B.S. INSURGENCY OUTCOME AND DURATION INFORMING A GRAND STRATEGY FOR COIN WARFARE A Thesis submitted to the Faculty of the Graduate School of Arts and Sciences of Georgetown University in partial fulfillment

More information

Benefit levels and US immigrants welfare receipts

Benefit levels and US immigrants welfare receipts 1 Benefit levels and US immigrants welfare receipts 1970 1990 by Joakim Ruist Department of Economics University of Gothenburg Box 640 40530 Gothenburg, Sweden joakim.ruist@economics.gu.se telephone: +46

More information

Volume 35, Issue 1. An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach

Volume 35, Issue 1. An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach Volume 35, Issue 1 An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach Brian Hibbs Indiana University South Bend Gihoon Hong Indiana University South Bend Abstract This

More information

the notion that poverty causes terrorism. Certainly, economic theory suggests that it would be

the notion that poverty causes terrorism. Certainly, economic theory suggests that it would be he Nonlinear Relationship Between errorism and Poverty Byline: Poverty and errorism Walter Enders and Gary A. Hoover 1 he fact that most terrorist attacks are staged in low income countries seems to support

More information

IMMIGRATION REFORM, JOB SELECTION AND WAGES IN THE U.S. FARM LABOR MARKET

IMMIGRATION REFORM, JOB SELECTION AND WAGES IN THE U.S. FARM LABOR MARKET IMMIGRATION REFORM, JOB SELECTION AND WAGES IN THE U.S. FARM LABOR MARKET Lurleen M. Walters International Agricultural Trade & Policy Center Food and Resource Economics Department P.O. Box 040, University

More information

Analysis of public opinion on Macedonia s accession to Author: Ivan Damjanovski

Analysis of public opinion on Macedonia s accession to Author: Ivan Damjanovski Analysis of public opinion on Macedonia s accession to the European Union 2014-2016 Author: Ivan Damjanovski CONCLUSIONS 3 The trends regarding support for Macedonia s EU membership are stable and follow

More information

Gender wage gap in the workplace: Does the age of the firm matter?

Gender wage gap in the workplace: Does the age of the firm matter? Gender wage gap in the workplace: Does the age of the firm matter? Iga Magda 1 Ewa Cukrowska-Torzewska 2 1 corresponding author, Institute for Structural Research (IBS) & Warsaw School of Economics; iga.magda@sgh.waw.pl

More information