Why Do Migrant Workers from Poorer Countries Work for Less? A Purchasing Power-Based Explanation

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Why Do Migrant Workers from Poorer Countries Work for Less? A Purchasing Power-Based Explanation"

Transcription

1 Why Do Migrant Workers from Poorer Countries Work for Less? A Purchasing Power-Based Explanation Hyejin Ku Department of Economics Florida State University October 12, 2009 Abstract A well-known empirical regularity in economics is that when all countries price levels are translated to dollars at the prevailing nominal exchange rates, rich countries tend to have higher price levels than poor countries (the Balassa-Samuelson e ect). This paper incorporates this phenomenon into a model of international migration in which remittances allow cross-border optimization of consumption. It argues that to the extent that the real price level in the source country is lower than that in the host country and that the migrants spend part of their income in the source country, the observed labor market outcomes of migrants in the host country may look worse than expected based on real wage di erentials alone. Empirical evidence based on the labor market experiences of Mexican workers in the U.S. lends support to this theory. Key words: Balassa-Samuelson, international migration, remittances, purchasing power parity, cost of living, real exchange rate, CPI JEL classi cation codes: F22, F24, O11, O15, O24 I am grateful to Kaushik Basu, Nancy Chau, Steve Coate, Stefan Klonner, Tim Salmon, Emma Stephens, and Asaf Zussman for valuable discussions and comments. Please direct any comments or suggestions to hku@fsu.edu. 1

2 1 Introduction We often observe immigrant workers from poor countries working in dirty, dangerous, and di cult (3D) jobs in a rich host country. The question that this study addresses is why immigrants from low income countries earn lower wages than equally quali ed natives or immigrants from higher income countries. A common explanation for this is that even if the real wages for these jobs may be low according to the standards of the host country, they may still be an improvement over what the migrants would have made by staying in the source country, at least in expectation (Harris and Todaro, 1970). In addition, if migration is viewed from a dynamic standpoint, even a negative premium in the current real wage may be rationalized as long as the expected stream of income from the host country exceeds that of the source country (Sjaastad, 1962). Implicit in these explanations is that in order to justify migration, the worker should experience some sort of premium in her real wage or standards of living in either a static or dynamic sense. This paper complements these existing explanations based on geographic real wage differentials by providing a new explanation based on real price di erences between markets. Speci cally, it argues that to the extent that the real price level in the source country is lower than that in the host country and that the migrants spend part of their income in the source country, the observed labor market outcomes of migrants in the host country may look worse than expected based on real wage di erentials alone. My argument hinges on the following stylized facts. First, when all countries price levels are translated to dollars at the prevailing nominal exchange rates, rich countries tend to have higher price levels than poor countries (Balassa, 1964; Samuelson, 1964). Figure 1 shows the positive correlation between the real price level and per capita income in 136 countries. If the purchasing power parity (PPP) holds true, all countries in this diagram should have a price ratio of unity. 1 A similar picture emerges when we compare the costs of living across the globe. As of 2008, the same basket of goods and services, including rent, costs in London, 82.4 in Frankfurt, 55.9 in Prague, 49.1 in Mexico City, and 43.3 in Manila, when the price level of New York is normalized at Rogo (1996), Goldberg and Knetter (1997), and Taylor and Taylor (2004) provide a comprehensive review on the issue of PPP. 2

3 (Union Bank of Switzerland, 2008). This implies that a U.S. dollar, if converted to pesos at the market exchange rate and spent in Mexico City, can buy twice as much as in New York City. Second, migrants can optimize their consumption mix across borders via remittances or repatriated savings. The prevalence of temporary migration and the ease of separating between the location of earnings and the location of consumption via remittances are, arguably, some of the key characteristics of today s migration phenomenon. 2 By linking the Balassa-Samuelson e ect to the possibility of cross-border price arbitrage via remittances, this paper argues that the greater the real price gap between the host and the source countries, the lower the real wage in the host country that can trigger migration is. As Figure 1 shows, since poorer countries are where the real price level is also lower, we can infer that holding all else constant (including skill levels and foregone real wages), a given real wage in the host country is more likely to meet the reservation real wage of migrants from poorer countries than that of immigrants from other countries. This paper by no means claims that the Balassa-Samuelson e ect, or the persistent real price gap between rich and poor countries, is the predominant force behind the poor labor market outcomes of migrant workers. Rather, it suggests that existing explanations in the literature might be underestimating the pressure for migration from poor to rich countries in the sense that the real price gap can in and of itself alter the incentive for migration independently from the e ects of other factors including the real wage gap. Related to this is the implication that holding all else constant, if the real price gap between the host and source countries narrowed exogenously, the partial e ect from the purchasing power channel proposed in this paper would include lowered migration pressure and fewer migrants willing to work in low-paying jobs in the destination. This paper starts by presenting a simple model of international migration with remittances. Though I use the term, remittances, for expositional simplicity, remittances here really refer to any device including repatriated savings that allows migrants to spend their 2 The dramatic growth of migrants remittances in the past few decades demonstrates that remittances have become an integral part of the migration experience for today s migrants. In 2004 alone, recorded remittances received by developing countries amounted to 160 billion dollars, which is equivalent to about 6.7 percent of developing countries imports and 7.5 percent of domestic investment (World Bank, 2006). 3

4 foreign income in their countries of origin. The model is in line with the new economics of migration (Stark and Bloom, 1985; Stark, 1991), in that migration is viewed as the outcome of the collective decisions made by families or household members to overcome a variety of market failures, apart from the geographic disparity in the return on labor. 3 The main feature of my model is that I allow for the possibility of real price di erences between the host and source countries and explicitly model the role of remittances as a device for crosscountry optimization of consumption mix. 4 A testable implication of my model is that to the extent that the real price level in the source country is lower than that in the host country, the real wage in the host country which justi es migration becomes lower, and this is true for the migrants who expend a positive sum of their foreign income in their home country, but not for others. 5 Using the migration experiences of Mexican workers in the United States as an example, I present empirical evidence that is consistent with the theoretical argument of this paper. The data come from the Mexican Migration Project (MMP), a survey used in many studies such as Massey et al. (1994), Durand et al. (1996), Munshi (2003), Orrenius and Zavodny (2005), and McKenzie and Rapoport (2007). By treating di erent U.S. cities as separate host countries and exploiting the di erential change in the consumer price index (CPI) over time in those cities, I obtain variation in real price di erences between the host and source countries. Then, I compare the real wage received by migrants who send remittances or bring savings to Mexico with that received by migrants who engage in neither activity. The main empirical nding corroborates the theory. Speci cally, it shows that as the real price level in the host country relative to that in the source country rises, the change in the real wage of migrants who engage in both remittances and repatriated savings is 9:03 to 15:84 percentage points less than that of migrants who engage in neither activity. Several theoretical studies have previously addressed the issue of geographic real price 3 A prominent example is the risk diversi cation through migration among family members (Rosenzweig and Stark, 1989). 4 Hoddinot (1994) also considers a model in which utility maximization through remittances is embedded in the migration decision. However, the focus of that study was not on the issue of price asymmetry between regions, while the present study s issue is the cross-border price arbitrage via remittances. 5 In the case of a migrant who consumes 100 percent of her income in the host country, whether the currency of the host country has extra purchasing power when spent in the source country or not, this will be irrelevant. 4

5 di erences and the decision to migrate (Djajic, 1989) or return-migrate (Dustmann, 1995, 1997, and 2003; Stark and Fan, 2007; Stark et al., 1997). On the empirical front, Massey and Espinosa (1997) and Yang (2006) investigate the role of price di erentials between the host and the source countries in the decision to migrate or return-migrate. Other empirical studies also discuss the issue of real price gap while analyzing other aspects of migration. For instance, in studying the illegal immigration of Mexican workers using macro-level data, Hanson and Spilimbergo (1999) nd that a U.S. wage, expressed in its purchasing power in Mexico, is positively associated with the level of apprehension, a proxy for the illegal attempts at migration. My major point of departure from these studies is that I examine the e ects of real price di erences (i.e., real exchange rates) between countries on the labor market outcomes of migrants in the host country, in particular, real wages. In an earlier study, Fox and Stark (1987) established a positive correlation between the hours worked by Mexican workers in the United States and the depreciation of the peso against the dollar. However, since the authors directly employed the U.S.-Mexico exchange rate in their empirical analysis, it is di cult, based on that study, to disentangle the e ects of real price di erences from those of other macro-variables shifting simultaneously. In a separate study, Ku (2008) looks at the di erential responses to uctuations in the U.S.-Mexico real exchange rate for Mexican migrants who are high-remitting types (the treatment group) and those who are lowremitting types (the control group) and nds that the former respond more strongly to a given real exchange rate shock in terms of their labor market outcomes in the United States. While consistent with the theory of price arbitrage, the nding in Ku (2008) is still subject to the criticism above to the extent that there might be omitted covariates of real exchange rates. The approach of the present paper eliminates such problems by using the CPI of di erent U.S. cities (as separate destination countries ) to obtain variation in the real exchange rate between the host and source countries. In my analysis, all the macrolevel shocks a ecting the overall economies of the United States and Mexico are controlled for throughout by the inclusion of city-year xed e ects. In addition, the main outcome of interest in the present study is the real wage that migrants receive as opposed to the labor supply as in Fox and Stark (1987). 5

6 The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 presents a model of migration to illustrate environments in which geographic real price di erences matter. Section 3 describes the data. Section 4 presents the empirical results. Section 5 o ers some concluding remarks. 2 Conceptual Framework Consider a model in which there is a source country (henceforth South) and a host country (henceforth North). The price level and nominal wage o ered in the South are p and W respectively, while the North o ers p and W. The real wage in each country is then W=p w and W =p w. These countries have their own currencies, say, peso in the South and dollar in the North. The exchange rate between the currencies is denoted by e where one dollar exchanges with e pesos. The real exchange rate then is ep =p Q, which may or may not be equal to unity. Incorporating the empirically observed discrepancy between the market exchange rate and PPP is my key point of departure from the literature, where price parity between regions is typically assumed in most models. If PPP holds, Q = 1. If the currency of the North has extra purchasing power in the South, then Q > 1. If the costs of living are lower in the North, then Q < 1. Each household consists of a worker or potential migrant (1) and a dependent who is sedentary (2). The household is assumed to maximize the family utility function, U(C 1 ; C 2 ), in the sense of the unitary model (Becker, 1981). The unitary model of the household encompasses several di erent models of family structure in which a family in aggregate behaves as if it is maximizing a family utility function. 6 Alternatively, we may think of U(C 1 ; C 2 ) as the individual utility function of the worker or potential migrant who cares about her dependent s consumption for altruistic reasons. 7 Speci cally, U = C1 1 C2 ; where C 1 and C 2 refer to the consumption levels of the worker and the dependent, respec- 6 See Bergstrom (1997) for a survey of theories of the family, including the unitary approach. 7 Rapoport and Docquier (2006) provide an extensive review of the motivations for intra-household transfers in the context of migrants remittances. 6

7 tively. Households di er in one dimension: the weights assigned to the consumption of the worker and the dependent. Without loss of generality, let indicate each household s preference weight on C 2. I normalize the utility function by multiplying 1= (1 ) 1 to it. This makes the indirect utility of di erent households comparable while maintaining the heterogeneity in the intrahousehold allocation of resources between households. To focus on the main research question, it is assumed that the migrant always works and the spouse always makes zero earnings. For the same reasons, costs involved in migration are suppressed. 8 In the South, a household maximizes U subject to the budget constraint C 1 + C 2 w. The solution to this problem is C 1 = (1 )w and C 2 = w. Hence, the maximized value of utility in the South, which I denote by U S, equals w. If the worker migrates to the North, the household maximizes U with location-speci c price indices in the budget constraints since C 2, the consumption for the dependent, must be purchased in the South. Therefore, the appropriate constraints become: C 1 + R w ; C 2 QR; where R is the remittances sent back to the South. The migrant spends part of her wage, w, on her own consumption in the North and sends the rest to her dependent in the South. The real exchange rate, Q; determines how R is translated into the level of consumption in the South. The maximized value of utility in the event of migration is U N = Q w. 9 The condition that makes the worker s migration to the North worthwhile is then Q w w: For a migrant who is indi erent between migration and no-migration, Q w = w or ln w = ln Q + ln w: (1) 8 For discussions on moving costs, see e.g. Carrington et al.(1996) and Chau (1997). 9 The solution vector is (C 1 ; C 2 ; R) = ((1 )w ; w Q; w ). 7

8 Equation (1) above highlights the key di erence between my model and standard models of migration. In standard models in which purchasing power parity (PPP) between regions is implicitly assumed, the indi erence condition looks similar to the following: ln w = ln w; (2) with some accounting for the costs of migration, of course. Notice that (2) is a special case of (1) in which PPP happens to hold or the real exchange rate Q is set to unity. This makes it clear that the purchasing power-based argument proposed in this paper is not contradictory to the existing explanations based on real wage di erentials and rather, it points out an additional factor that may in uence w, the real wage in the host country that makes a migrant indi erent between migration and no migration. Going back to equation (1), the condition suggests a negative relationship between the real wage of the host country, w, and the real price level of the host country relative to that in the source country, Q, holding all else constant. Notice that this relationship holds true only if the individual allocates a positive sum of her foreign income in her home country (i.e. > 0). For an individual who spends 100 percent of her foreign income in the host country (i.e. = 0), the extra purchasing power that the Northern currency has in the South does not have any impact on her labor market decisions in the North. This is the key prediction of the model that I will rely on for my empirical analysis. For a migrant s reservation real wage to have an impact on her actual labor market outcome, we require some frictions in the labor market for migrant workers. Otherwise, workers would be sorted and compensated according to their traits related to their productivity only, leaving no room for the role of reservation wages. However, evidence from the U.S. seems to point to the existence of frictions in the labor market for migrant workers. For instance, Munshi (2003) and Beaman (2007) demonstrate the role of social networks in channeling migrants into high- vs. low-paying jobs in the U.S. If the labor market for migrant workers were frictionless, the size of social networks wouldn t have had any power in explaining an individual s occupational outcome once her observable characteristics are controlled for. In the presence of frictions in the labor market, it then follows from standard search models that migrants with a low reservation real wage may indeed be receiving a lower real wage on 8

9 average than what is received by those with a high reservation wage since a given real wage is more likely to meet the reservation real wage of the former than the latter. 3 Data My empirical analysis is based on the migration experiences of Mexican workers during the period The data come from the Mexican Migration Project (MMP), a survey commonly used in the literature. 10 The MMP started in 1982, and each year during the winter months (when seasonal migrants are home) around 200 randomly selected households are surveyed in each community chosen for the survey. Each community is surveyed only once but the heads of household are asked their entire life retrospective migration histories. For my analysis, I use only information that relies on a recall length of 15 years or fewer, assuming that people can recall events that occurred up to 15 years before with a reasonable degree of accuracy. For instance, if the head of a household was interviewed in 1995, his information pertaining to the periods between 1980 and 1995 would be used for the analysis, while information for the years prior to 1980 would be discarded. 11 The MMP is an on-going project and I use the MMP107 database, which contains information on 107 communities. My sample is restricted to the working age (16-64) individuals and information on their last migration trip to the U.S. because information on remittances and savings behavior as well as U.S. earnings is only provided for these migrants. Also, I restrict my analysis to those who migrated to a U.S. place (as de ned by the MMP) or city, that had at least 25 migrants to avoid undue in uences from outliers. After dropping observations that lack CPI data for the destination U.S. city or any relevant information such as age, level of educational attainment, wage, and remittances and savings, I am left with 1120 observations. Appendix A shows the 12 U.S. cities in which these migrants are located. Summary statistics for the migrant workers are provided in Table 1. According to the rst column, the typical Mexican migrant in my sample is 33 years of age, nished about 6 years of 10 The MMP is a collaborative research project based in Princeton University and the University of Guadalajara, and the dataset is publicly available ( 11 Later, I test whether the results are robust to changes in the length of the recall period. 9

10 schooling, is not uent in English, and is undocumented. Also, the average migrant is likely to be married with two children under 18. The next three columns provide information on migrants according to their remittances and savings status: migrants who send remittances, migrants who return with savings, and migrants who engage in both activities. No large di erence is discernible in the characteristics of migrants across the categories. Table 2 provides more details on the remittances and savings situation of the migrants. Panel A shows that 77 percent of them send remittances, 53 percent of them return with savings, and 42 percent of them engage in both activities. The average amount of remittances and savings seems to be quite similar, but the stated purposes for each activity di er. In the case of remittances, health expenses in combination with food and maintenance, account for over 75 percent of the responses. This is consistent with the fact that remittances, by de nition, are meant to support the dependents left behind in the home country. In contrast, the purposes of bringing savings home are more varied and they seem to be tied less to supporting dependents and more to bene ting the migrants themselves upon return. The U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics provides information on the consumer price index (CPI) of nine U.S. metropolitan statistical areas (MSAs). The CPI is comparable over time for an individual MSA but not comparable across MSAs at a given point in time. This does not undermine my analysis, however, since my empirical strategy relies on the di erential change in CPI over time in separate cities. Figure 2 shows the trends in CPI in di erent MSAs in the U.S. According to the gure, the trend in CPI is not parallel across di erent cities, which provides the source of variation in prices for my analysis. In some of the speci cations, I use additional macroeconomic controls. The variables include the state-level GDP and minimum wage data. The GDP data come from the Bureau of Economic Analysis in the U.S. Department of Commerce and the minimum wage data are obtained from the U.S. Department of Labor. Appendix A links each city in the MMP sample to the corresponding MSA and state. 10

11 4 Empirical Framework The testable implication of the theoretical model is that the greater the purchasing power of the host country currency when spent in the source country (i.e. the higher the real price level in the host country is relative to the source country), the lower the real wage that a migrant receives conditional upon being in the host country. In addition, this response should be observed among migrants who expend part of their foreign income in the source country, but not among those who spend all of their income in the host country. My empirical strategy is closely tied to these predictions and it proceeds by treating Mexico as a single source country and di erent U.S. cities as separate host countries. Consider the following regression: y ijt = c + jt + D i + D i P jt + (D i Z jt ) + X ijt + " ijt ; (3) where y ijt is the real wage (in logarithm) of a Mexican migrant i residing in U.S. city j in year t, c is constant, jt is city-speci c year e ects, and D i is a variable indicating whether the migrant sent remittances to Mexico or brought savings upon return. 12 P jt denotes the CPI (in logarithm or in level depending on the speci cation) of U.S. city j in year t. Z jt is a vector of time-varying economic variables relevant for the city, including the state-level real GDP (in logarithm) and real minimum wage. 13 The vector X ijt indicates an extensive list of the characteristics of individual migrants that may a ect their labor market outcomes either in Mexico or the U.S. Speci cally, it includes age, age squared, education, education squared, English pro ciency, legal status for U.S. migration (documented vs. undocumented), gender, marital status, number of children under 18, ownership of land, property and business, and the community of origin xed e ects. I cluster the standard errors by destination city*community of origin level to account for potential persistence in the wages of migrants from the same communities in Mexico due, for example, to the bene cial roles of social networks (Munshi, 2003). Since all migrants source country is the same, Mexico, the changes in CPI of individual 12 The real wage, y ijt, is constructed by dividing the nominal wage (in dollars) by the price level of the U.S. city in the relevant year. 13 Ideally, I would have liked to use the GDP data at the MSA level but for the time period covered in the present study, the state is the lowest level for which GDP data are available. 11

12 U.S. cities over time provide the source of variation in the real exchange rate (Q in the theoretical model) between the host and source countries. The city-year xed e ects, jt ; will absorb all the e ects of economic uctuations or policy changes in the destination city level, including CPI. Note that the e ects of year-to-year changes in the overall economies of Mexico and the U.S. are subsumed in jt. Therefore, it will be redundant to also include year xed e ects in the regression in addition to the city-year xed e ects. 14 The main coe cient of interest is and its sign is expected to be negative. That is, to the extent that the real price level in the host country is higher than that in the source country, a migrant who spends at least part of her foreign income in the source country tends to be associated with a lower real wage abroad than one who doesn t. To make sure that is not driven by covariates of CPI in the destination city, the regression also includes the interaction between D i and Z jt, a vector of other economic variables of city j in year t. Note that the identi cation of does not rely on the comparison of migrants between di erent U.S. cities: jt will account for the baseline di erences between migrants who are located in di erent cities. In addition, will account for the baseline di erences between migrants who send remittances or bring savings home, and those who engage in neither activity. As should be clear from equation (3), my empirical strategy does not rely on the actual real exchange rate between the U.S. and Mexico at the macro-level. The real exchange rate is correlated with many covariates potentially a ecting Mexico-U.S. migration and would complicate inference. Instead, individual U.S. cities serve as di erent destination countries here. The main advantage of this approach is that macro-level uctuations that a ect the overall economy of Mexico or the U.S. are controlled for in the analysis. There are, however, two caveats to this approach. First, this approach requires an assumption about a migrant s behavior: that whether to remit anything or none to the source country is connected to the migration decision and is decided prior to seeing one s foreign wage precisely. In the context of Mexico-U.S. migration, such assumption seems reasonable when the question is whether 14 Denote the real exchange rate between a U.S. city j and Mexico in year t by Q jt. Then Q jt = e t p jt =p t, where e t is the nominal exchange rate between the U.S. and Mexico, p jt is the price level in U.S. city j, and p t is the price level in Mexico. Essentially, I obtain variation in Q jt by varying p jt while holding e t and p t constant. The communities of origin may, of course, be di erent for migrants who are in the same U.S. city. However, unless the CPI of that city is tied long term to particular communities in Mexico, treating Mexico as a single source country will not unduly in uence the outcome. 12

13 to send any remittances at all or not while the amount sent (conditional on remittances) may depend on the realized wage in the U.S. Second, the estimate of will be subject to bias due to potential interaction between D i and P jt. For instance, a migrant who is determined to send remittances may choose a city-year in which P jt is relatively high. If such interaction between D i and P jt is idiosyncratic, this would not pose a threat to the current approach. In contrast, if the interaction is systematic (i.e. correlated with worker characteristics that may in uence their wages but are not included in the regression), then the estimate of will be biased due to omitted variables. I address this issue by including in the regression a rather extensive list of human capital, demographic, and wealth status of migrants that may directly in uence their wages. 4.1 Baseline Results Table 3 presents the estimates of equation (3). Column (1) shows that the coe cient of the interaction between remittances or savings status and the price level, is indeed negative and statistically signi cant. This is in contrast to the direct e ect of sending any remittances or savings,, which, if anything, is positive. Columns (2) through (4) show that the estimate of remains statistically signi cant and its magnitude becomes slightly larger as more control variables are included in the regression. Column (5) also includes the controls for the migrants communities of origin in Mexico. According to column (5), as the CPI in the destination goes up one standard deviation (32:32) above the mean (122:4), the change in the real wage for a migrant who sends remittances or bring savings back is 17 percentage points below that for those who engage in neither activities. 15 This implies that to a given change in the relative purchasing power of the currency of the host country, the real wage response of the migrants who spend at least part of their foreign income in the home country is over and above that of others. This is a nding consistent with the main theoretical prediction discussed earlier. Next, I test whether or not the results in Table 3 are robust to withstand the inclusion of some covariates of CPI. The set of control variables includes the real GDP and the real 15 ( 0:649) (32:32=122:4) = 0:17 13

14 minimum wage. 16 The results are presented in Table 4. As columns (1) through (4) show, the estimate of goes down slightly when the real GDP and the real minimum wage are included. However, column (4) shows that the estimate of is still negative and statistically signi cant at one percent level. The estimate in column (4) shows that as the CPI in the destination goes up one standard deviation (32:32) above the mean (122:4), a migrant who sends remittances or bring savings back is associated with a change in the real wage that is 13 percentage points below what is experienced by those who engage in neither activity. 17. My next question is on the channels through which the observed wage-compromise occurs: do the migrants in the non-zero remittances or savings group receive a lower real wage because they are sorted into lower paying jobs and if so, is there a wage-compromise e ect even within the same occupations? To answer this question, I repeat the regressions in columns (1) through (4) in Table 4 but this time with occupation- xed e ects. 18 The estimates are reported in columns (5) through (8) of Table 4. As the estimates in column (8) show, once the occupation is controlled, the coe cient is no longer statistically signi cant. This implies that the wage-compromise e ect that we observed earlier in column (4) occurs mostly through sorting into low vs. high paying jobs, and the real wage received by workers in the non-zero remittances or savings group is no less than others once their occupations are controlled for. Next, I conduct several robustness checks, which are similar to those discussed in Munshi (2003). The results are provided in Table 5. Column (1) is based on all migrants in the sample. In columns (2) and (3), I experiment with di erent sample periods discarding the survey year and the years just prior to that year. This is to address the concern that some migrants who were particularly successful or unsuccessful in the U.S. labor market might not have returned to Mexico at the time when the MMP survey was conducted. As we see in columns (2) and (3), the coe cient virtually remains the same with these sampling restrictions. Next, I turn to the issue of recall bias. Due to the retrospective nature of the MMP data, bias due to a measurement error is a potential cause for concern. As a 16 I would have liked to include unemployment rates as well. Unfortunately, the data on unemployment rate at the MSA-level were not available for most of the time period covered in my sample. 17 ( 0:486) (32:32=122:4) = 0:13 18 I use the classi cation of occupations as provided by the MMP. 14

15 robustness check, I experiment with a longer length of recall. The rationale for this is that we would expect any reporting errors to be more frequent the further back we go into past. Column (4) shows that in the extended twenty-year sample, the estimate of goes down in magnitude but it is still statistically signi cant at the conventional level. Column (5) shows that the main results are not driven by the small number of female workers in the sample. In column (6), I restrict the sample to undocumented migrants only. The coe cient is smaller in magnitude than in column (1) and it is no longer statistically signi cant. This suggests that it is the documented migrants, if any, who respond more strongly to the opportunities price arbitrage. This seems to have to do with the fact that undocumented migrants are sorted into the lowest paying jobs anyway, and thus there is little room for further compromisation in wages. Column (7) shows that the main results remain the same when the sample is restricted to workers less than 45 years of age. In column (8), I restrict the sample to individuals with less than ten years of education. The coe cient is no longer statistically signi cant in this subsample. As for the case of undocumented migrants, this may be attributed to the fact that less educated workers tend to be sorted into low-paying jobs regardless of the real price level. Lastly, I turn to the issue of functional forms. In column (9), I report the estimates of equation (3) in which Log(CP I) is replaced with CP I in level. The estimate is similar to that in column (1) when evaluated at the mean value of CPI Di erential Responses by Remittances and Savings Status So far I have assumed that the e ects of purchasing power di erences on the real wage are common for migrants who send remittances and those who bring savings upon return. From an analytical standpoint, remittances and savings are equivalent in that they both entail spending a fraction of a migrant s foreign income in the source country. However, it is an empirical question whether the two activities would actually have the same impact on inducing migrants to internalize the opportunities for geographic price arbitrage: as 19 Denote the coe cient on D Log(CP I) by and that on D CP I by e. Then, e = =CP I. According to column (1), = 0:486 and the mean of CPI is 122:4. Then, =CP I = ( 0:486)=122:4 = 0:00397 when evaluated at the mean. The estimate of e in column (9) is 0:00425, which is not widely di erent from 0:

16 we saw earlier in Table 2, the stated purposes of sending remittances and savings look rather di erent, from which we can infer that their usages are also likely to di er. To examine if remitters and savers would behave di erently, I classify the migrants into four groups depending on their remittances and savings status: neither send remittances nor bring savings upon return (group 0); send remittances but do not bring savings (group 1, denoted by D 1 ); bring savings but do not send remittances (group 2, D 2 ); and send remittances and bring savings (group 3, D 3 ). Then, using group 0 as a benchmark, I test if groups 1, 2, and 3 have di erent labor market outcomes than the base group. In a regression framework, this corresponds to the following y ijt = c + jt + X k k D k i + X k k D k i P jt + X k (D k i Z jt ) k + X ijt + " ijt : (4) which is identical to (3) except that D i is now replaced with Di 1, Di 2, and Di 3. The coe cients of interest are then 1, 2, and 3. The estimates of (4) are presented in Table 6. According to column (1), the baseline e ects of belonging to groups 1 through 3 are positive, if anything. In contrast, the coe cients for the interaction between Di k and P jt are negative for all three groups. However, as columns (2) through (4) show, the estimates remain statistically signi cant only for groups 1 and 3 when the interaction between group status and other macroeconomic variables is controlled for. According to column (4), as the real price level in the destination country rises one standard deviation (32:32) above the mean (122:4), migrants who send remittances but do not bring savings are associated with a change in the real wage that is 10:4 percentage points what is experienced by the baseline group. The corresponding di erence for migrants who engage in both remittances and repatriated savings is 15:8 percentage points. However, for those who engage in savings but not remittances, their real wage is no more (or less) responsive than that for the baseline to a change in the relative real prices. Next, I examine sorting into occupations as a potential channel through which these results are reached. To this end, I repeat the regressions in columns (1) through (4) while including occupation xed e ects. The estimates are reported in columns (5) through (8). In column (8), we see that none of 1, 2, and 3 are statistically signi cant this time. This suggests that the negative e ects in column (4) have mostly to do with the 16

17 sorting of migrants into low- vs. high-paying jobs depending on types of migrants. Table 7 presents the results of several robustness checks similar to Table 5. Depending on sample restrictions, the estimates of 1, 2, and 3 seem to vary. However, the estimate of 3 is quite robust across sampling restrictions. This is intuitive in that the migrants who engage in both remittances and savings activities are the ones mostly likely to assess their foreign wage in the basket of the source country. Therefore, when the opportunity for price arbitrage arises, these migrants would be most willing to work in low-paying jobs, in comparison to those in the baseline group. The estimates of 3 range from 0:34 to 0:60 in the full sample and the estimate is up to 0:67 in the sample of individuals less than 45 years of age. The results from the full sample can be interpreted as follows: as the real price level in the host country goes up one standard deviation (32:32) above the mean (122:4), a migrant who engages in both remittances and repatriated savings is associated with a change in the real wage that is 9:03 to 15:84 percentage points below the corresponding change for the migrants who engage in neither activities. 4.3 Discussion To put the estimates based on the U.S. city-level analysis in perspective, consider extrapolating the results to the case of the overall U.S. and Mexico as the host and source countries, respectively. Over the period considered in this study, , the real exchange rate between the U.S. and Mexico uctuated around the mean of 1:73 with the standard deviation of 0: When put in the context of Mexico-U.S. migration, the estimates in Table 7 can be interpreted as follows: As the purchasing power of the dollar in Mexico goes up one standard deviation above the mean, the change in the real wage of Mexican migrants who engage in both remittances and repatriated savings is 12:83 percentage points below that of migrants who engage in neither activities. 21 This is certainly an e ect that is economically signi cant and surprising in that a variable that is not at all intrinsic to the migrant s ability to perform in the job, namely real price di erences between the host and source countries, can in uence 20 The minimum was 1:26 and the maximum was 2:72. This means that the U.S.-Mexico real exchange rate was never at PPP during the period. 21 ( 0:6) (0:37=1:73) = 0:

18 her labor market outcome. 22 To the extent that the migrants who neither remit nor bring savings serve as a good benchmark, this paper suggests that the motivation for cross-border price arbitrage may in uence the labor market outcomes of migrants in a way that standard models of migration with PPP would not have predicted. 5 Conclusion Real price or cost-of-living di erences between regions, especially between rich and poor regions, are a well-known phenomenon. This paper investigates cross-border optimization of consumption mix through remittances or repatriated savings as a strategy that migrants from poor countries may adopt in order to take advantage of the persistent real price gap between regions. This is a phenomenon that is becoming increasingly relevant with the rise of temporary migration and the decline in transportation costs, including the costs of sending remittances. An important consequence of the migration strategy discussed in this paper is that the real wage that a migrant is willing to accept in the host country goes down when the real price level in the source country is lower than that in the host country. This in turn suggests that when we hold other factors constant, the observed labor market outcome in the host country may look worse for a migrant originating from a poorer country in which real price level tends to be lower. Using data on the labor market outcomes of Mexican migrant workers in the U.S., this paper showed some evidence that is in line with the main theoretical argument. Speci cally, it nds a negative association between the real price level in the host country (relative to that in the source country) and the real wage received by migrant workers. This paper contributes to the literature by incorporating a macro-level phenomenon, namely, real price di erences between rich and poor countries, into a migration model and providing an explanation for why migrant workers from poorer countries may be working for less in a rich host country. Though the empirical analysis in this paper considered the case of Mexico-U.S. migration, the analytical framework should be applicable to other pairs of countries or regions such as east-west migration within Europe 22 Note that the underlying di erences between migrants in the remittances and no-remittances groups are accounted for. In addition, di erences in the human capital and demographic characteristics of all migrants are controlled for throughout. 18

19 or rural-urban migration in China. References [1] Balassa, Bela (1964). The Purchasing Power Parity Doctrine: A Reappraisal, Journal of Political Economy, 72(6): [2] Beaman, Lori (2007). Social Networks and the Dynamics of Labor Market Outcomes: Evidence from Refugees Resettled in the U.S., working paper, Northwestern University. [3] Becker, Gary, Treatise on the Family, Cambridge: Harvard University Press. [4] Bergstrom, Theodore C. (1997). A Survey of Theories of the Family, in Handbook of Population Economics, edited by Mark R. Rosenzweig and Oded Stark, North-Holland. [5] Carrington, William J., Enrica Detragiache, and Tara Vishwanath (1996). Migration with Endogenous Moving Costs, American Economic Review, 86(4): [6] Chau, Nancy H. (1997). The Pattern of Migration with Variable Migration Cost, Journal of Regional Science, 37(1): [7] Djajić, Slobodan (1989). Migrants in a guest-worker system, Journal of Development Economics, vol. 31. [8] Durand, Jorge, William Kandel, Emilio A. Parrado, and Douglas S. Massey (1996). International Migration and Development in Mexican Communities, Demography, 33(2): [9] Dustmann, Christian (1995). Savings Behavior of Return Migrants: A Life-Cycle Analysis, Zeitschrift fur Wirtschafts- und Sozialwissenschften, 115: [10] Dustmann, Christian (1997). Return Migration, Uncertainty and Precautionary Savings, Journal of Development Economics, 52: [11] Dustmann, Christian (2003). Return Migration, Wage Di erentials, and the Optimal Migration Duration, European Economic Review, 47:

20 [12] Fox, Marc and Oded Stark (1987). Remittances, Exchange Rates, and the Labor Supply of Mexican Migrants in the U.S., Harvard University Migration and Development Program, discussion paper no. 33. [13] Goldberg, Penelopi K., and Michael M. Knetter (1997). Goods Prices and Exchange Rates: What Have We Learned? Journal of Economic Literature, 35(3): [14] Hanson, Gordon H., and Antonio Spilimbergo (1999). Illegal Immigration, Border Enforcement, and Relative Wages: Evidence from Apprehensions at the U.S.-Mexico Border, American Economic Review, 89(5), [15] Harris, John R., and Michael P. Todaro (1970). Migration, Unemployment and Development: A Two-Sector Analysis, American Economic Review, 60: [16] Hoddinot, John (1994). A Model of Migration and Remittances Applied to Western Kenya, Oxford Economic Papers, 46(3): [17] Ku, Hyejin (2008). Labor Migration as Price Arbitrage: Evidence from Mexican Workers in the U.S., working paper, Florida State University. [18] Massey, Douglas S., L. Goldring, and Jorge Durand (1994). Continuities in Transnational Migration: An Analysis of Nineteen Mexican Communities, American Journal of Sociology, 99(6): [19] Massey, Douglas S., and Kristin E. Espinosa (1997). What s Driving Mexico-U.S. Migration? A Theoretical, Empirical, and Policy Analysis, American Journal of Sociology, 102(4): [20] McKenzie, David, and Hillel Rapoport (2007). Network E ects and the Dynamics of Migration and Inequality: Theory and Evidence from Mexico, Journal of Development Economics, 84: [21] Munshi, Kaivan (2003). Networks in the Modern Economy: Mexican Migrants in the U.S. Labor Market, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118(2):

21 [22] Orrenius, Pia M., and Madeline Zavodny (2005). Self-Selection among Undocumented Immigrants from Mexico, Journal of Development Economics, 78: [23] Rapoport, Hillel, and Frederic Docquier (2006). The Economics of Migrants Remittances, in Handbook on the Economics of Reciprocity, Giving and Altruism, Volume 2: Applications, edited by Serge-Christophe Kolm and Jean Mercier Ythier, Elsevier-North Holland. [24] Rogo, Kenneth (1996). The Purchasing Power Parity Puzzle, Journal of Economic Literature, 34(2): [25] Rosenzweig, Mark R. and Oded Stark (1989). Consumption Smoothing, Migration, and Marriage: Evidence from Rural India, Journal of Political Economy, 97(4): [26] Samuelson, Paul A. (1964). Theoretical Notes on Trade Problems, Review of Economics and Statistics, 46(2): [27] Sjaastad, Larry A. (1962). The Costs and Returns of Human Migration, Journal of Political Economy, 70(5): [28] Stark, Oded (1991). The Migration of Labor, Oxford, UK; Cambridge, MA: B. Blackwell. [29] Stark, Oded, and David E. Bloom (1985). The New Economics of Labor Migration, American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, 1985: [30] Stark, Oded, and Simon C. Fan (2007). The Analytics of Seasonal Migration, Economics Letters, 94(2): [31] Stark, Oded, Christian Helmenstein, and Yury Yegorov (1997). Migrants Savings, Purchasing Power Parity, and the Optimal Duration of Migration, International Tax and Public Finance, 4: [32] Taylor, Alan and Mark Taylor (2004) The Purchasing Power Parity Debate, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 18(4):

22 [33] Union Bank of Switzerland (2008). Prices and Earnings: A Comparison of Purchasing Power around the Globe, UBS. [34] World Bank (2006). Global Economic Prospects 2006: Economic Implications of Remittances and Migration, The World Bank. [35] Yang, Dean (2006). Why Do Migrants Return to Poor Countries? Evidence from Philippine Migrants Response to Exchange Rate Shocks, Review of Economics and Statistics, 88(4):

23 Appendix A: Geographic Areas by Data Sources City MSA State State Data on migrants CPI GDP Min wage (MMP) (U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics) (U.S. Dept of Commerce) (U.S. Dept of Labor) Atlanta Atlanta GA GA Chicago Chicago-Gary-Kenosha IL IL Dallas Dallas-Fort Worth TX TX Houston Houston-Galveston-Brazoria TX TX Los Angeles-Long Beach Los Angeles-Riverside-Orange County CA CA New York New York-Northern New Jersey-Long Island NY NY Orange County Los Angeles-Riverside-Orange County CA CA Philadelphia Philadelphia-Wilmington-Atlantic City PA PA Riverside-San Bernardino Los Angeles-Riverside-Orange County CA CA San Diego San Diego CA CA San Francisco San Francisco-Oakland-San Jose CA CA San Jose San Francisco-Oakland-San Jose CA CA Note: Each city includes at least 25 migrants in the MMP sample. 23

24 Table 1: Characteristics of Mexican Migrants in the U.S Variables All Remit Return with savings Remit and save Panel A: Prices, wages, and migrant characteristics CPI (base year = ) (32.32) (32.19) (32.82) (32.86) Hourly Wage (current USD) (27.47) (6.57) (36.84) (3.52) Real wage ( USD) (0.16) (0.05) (0.21) (0.03) Hours worked per week (14.01) (13.74) (13.60) (13.20) Year of migration (6.73) (6.71) (6.87) (6.89) Age at time of migration (10.46) (10.27) (10.87) (10.60) Education (years) (4.00) (3.77) (4.08) (3.80) English pro ciency (0-4) (1.29) (1.26) (1.32) (1.28) Undocumented (0.44) (0.43) (0.45) (0.44) Female (0.17) (0.15) (0.16) (0.12) Married (0.44) (0.42) (0.45) (0.44) Minors (number of children < 18) (2.26) (2.34) (2.28) (2.34) Number of Land parcels owned (0.43) (0.45) (0.45) (0.47) Number of Property owned (0.58) (0.58) (0.58) (0.56) Number of Business owned (0.37) (0.36) (0.35) (0.34) Panel B: Occupational categories Agriculture, husbandry, forestry/ sheries Skilled Manufacturing Unskilled Manufacturing Service Other Observation Note: Standard deviations are in parentheses. 24

Brain drain and Human Capital Formation in Developing Countries. Are there Really Winners?

Brain drain and Human Capital Formation in Developing Countries. Are there Really Winners? Brain drain and Human Capital Formation in Developing Countries. Are there Really Winners? José Luis Groizard Universitat de les Illes Balears Ctra de Valldemossa km. 7,5 07122 Palma de Mallorca Spain

More information

Measuring International Skilled Migration: New Estimates Controlling for Age of Entry

Measuring International Skilled Migration: New Estimates Controlling for Age of Entry Measuring International Skilled Migration: New Estimates Controlling for Age of Entry Michel Beine a,frédéricdocquier b and Hillel Rapoport c a University of Luxemburg and Université Libre de Bruxelles

More information

International Migration and Gender Discrimination among Children Left Behind. Francisca M. Antman* University of Colorado at Boulder

International Migration and Gender Discrimination among Children Left Behind. Francisca M. Antman* University of Colorado at Boulder International Migration and Gender Discrimination among Children Left Behind Francisca M. Antman* University of Colorado at Boulder ABSTRACT: This paper considers how international migration of the head

More information

Purchasing-Power-Parity Changes and the Saving Behavior of Temporary Migrants

Purchasing-Power-Parity Changes and the Saving Behavior of Temporary Migrants Purchasing-Power-Parity Changes and the Saving Behavior of Temporary Migrants Alpaslan Akay, Slobodan Djajić, Murat G. Kirdar y, and Alexandra Vinogradova z st November 207 Abstract This study examines

More information

Development Economics: Microeconomic issues and Policy Models

Development Economics: Microeconomic issues and Policy Models MIT OpenCourseWare http://ocw.mit.edu 14.771 Development Economics: Microeconomic issues and Policy Models Fall 2008 For information about citing these materials or our Terms of Use, visit: http://ocw.mit.edu/terms.

More information

The Determinants and the Selection. of Mexico-US Migrations

The Determinants and the Selection. of Mexico-US Migrations The Determinants and the Selection of Mexico-US Migrations J. William Ambrosini (UC, Davis) Giovanni Peri, (UC, Davis and NBER) This draft March 2011 Abstract Using data from the Mexican Family Life Survey

More information

Gender Discrimination in the Allocation of Migrant Household Resources

Gender Discrimination in the Allocation of Migrant Household Resources DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 8796 Gender Discrimination in the Allocation of Migrant Household Resources Francisca M. Antman January 2015 Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit Institute for the

More information

Extended Families across Mexico and the United States. Extended Abstract PAA 2013

Extended Families across Mexico and the United States. Extended Abstract PAA 2013 Extended Families across Mexico and the United States Extended Abstract PAA 2013 Gabriela Farfán Duke University After years of research we ve come to learn quite a lot about household allocation decisions.

More information

Volume 35, Issue 1. An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach

Volume 35, Issue 1. An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach Volume 35, Issue 1 An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach Brian Hibbs Indiana University South Bend Gihoon Hong Indiana University South Bend Abstract This

More information

Immigration and Internal Mobility in Canada Appendices A and B. Appendix A: Two-step Instrumentation strategy: Procedure and detailed results

Immigration and Internal Mobility in Canada Appendices A and B. Appendix A: Two-step Instrumentation strategy: Procedure and detailed results Immigration and Internal Mobility in Canada Appendices A and B by Michel Beine and Serge Coulombe This version: February 2016 Appendix A: Two-step Instrumentation strategy: Procedure and detailed results

More information

Gender, Educational Attainment, and the Impact of Parental Migration on Children Left Behind

Gender, Educational Attainment, and the Impact of Parental Migration on Children Left Behind D I S C U S S I O N P A P E R S E R I E S IZA DP No. 6640 Gender, Educational Attainment, and the Impact of Parental Migration on Children Left Behind Francisca M. Antman June 2012 Forschungsinstitut zur

More information

Benefit levels and US immigrants welfare receipts

Benefit levels and US immigrants welfare receipts 1 Benefit levels and US immigrants welfare receipts 1970 1990 by Joakim Ruist Department of Economics University of Gothenburg Box 640 40530 Gothenburg, Sweden joakim.ruist@economics.gu.se telephone: +46

More information

Do Migrant Remittances Lead to Inequality? 1

Do Migrant Remittances Lead to Inequality? 1 Do Migrant Remittances Lead to Inequality? 1 Filiz Garip Harvard University May 2010 1 This research was supported by grants from the National Science Foundation, Clark Fund, Milton Fund and a seed grant

More information

The Transfer of the Remittance Fee from the Migrant to the Household

The Transfer of the Remittance Fee from the Migrant to the Household Journal of Economic Integration 25(3), September 2010; 613-625 The Transfer of the Remittance Fee from the Migrant to the Household Akira Shimada Nagasaki University Abstract This paper discusses the problem

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE SKILL COMPOSITION OF MIGRATION AND THE GENEROSITY OF THE WELFARE STATE. Alon Cohen Assaf Razin Efraim Sadka

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE SKILL COMPOSITION OF MIGRATION AND THE GENEROSITY OF THE WELFARE STATE. Alon Cohen Assaf Razin Efraim Sadka NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE SKILL COMPOSITION OF MIGRATION AND THE GENEROSITY OF THE WELFARE STATE Alon Cohen Assaf Razin Efraim Sadka Working Paper 14738 http://www.nber.org/papers/w14738 NATIONAL BUREAU

More information

DISCUSSION PAPERS IN ECONOMICS

DISCUSSION PAPERS IN ECONOMICS DISCUSSION PAPERS IN ECONOMICS Working Paper No. 09-03 Offshoring, Immigration, and the Native Wage Distribution William W. Olney University of Colorado revised November 2009 revised August 2009 March

More information

Poverty and the Binational Population: A Note on Poverty Measurement

Poverty and the Binational Population: A Note on Poverty Measurement Poverty and the Binational Population: A Note on Poverty Measurement Dr. Anita Alves Pena Colorado State University Hispanic Economic Issues Conference Americas Center, Atlanta, GA November 2010 Previous

More information

Inflation and relative price variability in Mexico: the role of remittances

Inflation and relative price variability in Mexico: the role of remittances Applied Economics Letters, 2008, 15, 181 185 Inflation and relative price variability in Mexico: the role of remittances J. Ulyses Balderas and Hiranya K. Nath* Department of Economics and International

More information

Exchange Rates and Wages in an Integrated World

Exchange Rates and Wages in an Integrated World WP/09/44 Exchange Rates and Wages in an Integrated World Prachi Mishra and Antonio Spilimbergo 2009 International Monetary Fund WP/09/44 IMF Working Paper Research Department Exchange Rates and Wages

More information

Remittances and the Brain Drain: Evidence from Microdata for Sub-Saharan Africa

Remittances and the Brain Drain: Evidence from Microdata for Sub-Saharan Africa Remittances and the Brain Drain: Evidence from Microdata for Sub-Saharan Africa Julia Bredtmann 1, Fernanda Martinez Flores 1,2, and Sebastian Otten 1,2,3 1 RWI, Rheinisch-Westfälisches Institut für Wirtschaftsforschung

More information

Table A.2 reports the complete set of estimates of equation (1). We distinguish between personal

Table A.2 reports the complete set of estimates of equation (1). We distinguish between personal Akay, Bargain and Zimmermann Online Appendix 40 A. Online Appendix A.1. Descriptive Statistics Figure A.1 about here Table A.1 about here A.2. Detailed SWB Estimates Table A.2 reports the complete set

More information

Differences in remittances from US and Spanish migrants in Colombia. Abstract

Differences in remittances from US and Spanish migrants in Colombia. Abstract Differences in remittances from US and Spanish migrants in Colombia François-Charles Wolff LEN, University of Nantes Liliana Ortiz Bello LEN, University of Nantes Abstract Using data collected among exchange

More information

What Do Networks Do? The Role of Networks on Migration and Coyote" Use

What Do Networks Do? The Role of Networks on Migration and Coyote Use What Do Networks Do? The Role of Networks on Migration and Coyote" Use Sarah Dolfin Mathematica Policy Research, Inc. Garance Genicot Georgetown University July 2009 ABSTRACT While a large literature has

More information

Online Appendix. Capital Account Opening and Wage Inequality. Mauricio Larrain Columbia University. October 2014

Online Appendix. Capital Account Opening and Wage Inequality. Mauricio Larrain Columbia University. October 2014 Online Appendix Capital Account Opening and Wage Inequality Mauricio Larrain Columbia University October 2014 A.1 Additional summary statistics Tables 1 and 2 in the main text report summary statistics

More information

Household Inequality and Remittances in Rural Thailand: A Lifecycle Perspective

Household Inequality and Remittances in Rural Thailand: A Lifecycle Perspective Household Inequality and Remittances in Rural Thailand: A Lifecycle Perspective Richard Disney*, Andy McKay + & C. Rashaad Shabab + *Institute of Fiscal Studies, University of Sussex and University College,

More information

Purchasing-Power-Parity and the Saving Behavior of Temporary Migrants

Purchasing-Power-Parity and the Saving Behavior of Temporary Migrants Working Paper in Economics No. 735 Purchasing-Power-Parity and the Saving Behavior of Temporary Migrants Alpaslan Akay, Alexandra Brausmann, Slobodan Djajic, and Murat G. Kirdar Department of Economics,

More information

Voting with Their Feet?

Voting with Their Feet? Policy Research Working Paper 7047 WPS7047 Voting with Their Feet? Access to Infrastructure and Migration in Nepal Forhad Shilpi Prem Sangraula Yue Li Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized

More information

11.433J / J Real Estate Economics

11.433J / J Real Estate Economics MIT OpenCourseWare http://ocw.mit.edu 11.433J / 15.021J Real Estate Economics Fall 2008 For information about citing these materials or our Terms of Use, visit: http://ocw.mit.edu/terms. Week 12: Real

More information

Volume 36, Issue 1. Impact of remittances on poverty: an analysis of data from a set of developing countries

Volume 36, Issue 1. Impact of remittances on poverty: an analysis of data from a set of developing countries Volume 6, Issue 1 Impact of remittances on poverty: an analysis of data from a set of developing countries Basanta K Pradhan Institute of Economic Growth, Delhi Malvika Mahesh Institute of Economic Growth,

More information

The Employment of Low-Skilled Immigrant Men in the United States

The Employment of Low-Skilled Immigrant Men in the United States American Economic Review: Papers & Proceedings 2012, 102(3): 549 554 http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/aer.102.3.549 The Employment of Low-Skilled Immigrant Men in the United States By Brian Duncan and Stephen

More information

ESSAYS ON MEXICAN MIGRATION. by Heriberto Gonzalez Lozano B.A., Universidad Autonóma de Nuevo León, 2005 M.A., University of Pittsburgh, 2011

ESSAYS ON MEXICAN MIGRATION. by Heriberto Gonzalez Lozano B.A., Universidad Autonóma de Nuevo León, 2005 M.A., University of Pittsburgh, 2011 ESSAYS ON MEXICAN MIGRATION by Heriberto Gonzalez Lozano B.A., Universidad Autonóma de Nuevo León, 2005 M.A., University of Pittsburgh, 2011 Submitted to the Graduate Faculty of the Dietrich School of

More information

Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US

Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US Ben Ost a and Eva Dziadula b a Department of Economics, University of Illinois at Chicago, 601 South Morgan UH718 M/C144 Chicago,

More information

The Immigration Policy Puzzle

The Immigration Policy Puzzle MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive The Immigration Policy Puzzle Paolo Giordani and Michele Ruta UISS Guido Carli University, World Trade Organization 2009 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/23584/

More information

Purchasing-Power-Parity and the Saving Behavior of Temporary Migrants

Purchasing-Power-Parity and the Saving Behavior of Temporary Migrants DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 11679 Purchasing-Power-Parity and the Saving Behavior of Temporary Migrants Alpaslan Akay Alexandra Brausmann Slobodan Djajić Murat G. Kırdar JULY 2018 DISCUSSION PAPER

More information

DRAFT, WORK IN PROGRESS. A general equilibrium analysis of effects of undocumented workers in the United States

DRAFT, WORK IN PROGRESS. A general equilibrium analysis of effects of undocumented workers in the United States DRAFT, WORK IN PROGRESS A general equilibrium analysis of effects of undocumented workers in the United States Marinos Tsigas and Hugh M. Arce U.S. International Trade Commission, Washington, DC, USA 14

More information

Where U.S. Immigrants Were Born 1960

Where U.S. Immigrants Were Born 1960 Where U.S. Immigrants Were Born 1960 2000 Latin America 9% Canada 10% Asia 5% Other 1% Other 6% Asia 26% Canada 3% Europe 15% Latino 22% Europe 75% Latin America 51% Foreign-Born Population by Region of

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES HOMEOWNERSHIP IN THE IMMIGRANT POPULATION. George J. Borjas. Working Paper

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES HOMEOWNERSHIP IN THE IMMIGRANT POPULATION. George J. Borjas. Working Paper NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES HOMEOWNERSHIP IN THE IMMIGRANT POPULATION George J. Borjas Working Paper 8945 http://www.nber.org/papers/w8945 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge,

More information

THE DEMOGRAPHY OF MEXICO/U.S. MIGRATION

THE DEMOGRAPHY OF MEXICO/U.S. MIGRATION THE DEMOGRAPHY OF MEXICO/U.S. MIGRATION October 19, 2005 B. Lindsay Lowell, Georgetown University Carla Pederzini Villarreal, Universidad Iberoamericana Jeffrey Passel, Pew Hispanic Center * Presentation

More information

SKILLED MIGRATION: WHEN SHOULD A GOVERNMENT RESTRICT MIGRATION OF SKILLED WORKERS?* Gabriel Romero

SKILLED MIGRATION: WHEN SHOULD A GOVERNMENT RESTRICT MIGRATION OF SKILLED WORKERS?* Gabriel Romero SKILLED MIGRATION: WHEN SHOULD A GOVERNMENT RESTRICT MIGRATION OF SKILLED WORKERS?* Gabriel Romero WP-AD 2007-25 Correspondence: Departamento de Fundamentos del Análisis Económico, Universidad de Alicante,

More information

Beyond Remittances: The Effects of Migration on Mexican Households

Beyond Remittances: The Effects of Migration on Mexican Households 4 Beyond Remittances: The Effects of Migration on Mexican Households David J. McKenzie Introduction The number of international migrants in the world increased by 21 million between 1990 and 2000, a 14

More information

Selection and Assimilation of Mexican Migrants to the U.S.

Selection and Assimilation of Mexican Migrants to the U.S. Preliminary and incomplete Please do not quote Selection and Assimilation of Mexican Migrants to the U.S. Andrea Velásquez University of Colorado Denver Gabriela Farfán World Bank Maria Genoni World Bank

More information

A Role for Government Policy and Sunspots in Explaining Endogenous Fluctuations in Illegal Immigration 1

A Role for Government Policy and Sunspots in Explaining Endogenous Fluctuations in Illegal Immigration 1 A Role for Government Policy and Sunspots in Explaining Endogenous Fluctuations in Illegal Immigration 1 Mark G. Guzman 2 Research Department Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas Joseph H. Haslag Department

More information

Online Appendices for Moving to Opportunity

Online Appendices for Moving to Opportunity Online Appendices for Moving to Opportunity Chapter 2 A. Labor mobility costs Table 1: Domestic labor mobility costs with standard errors: 10 sectors Lao PDR Indonesia Vietnam Philippines Agriculture,

More information

The Substitutability of Immigrant and Native Labor: Evidence at the Establishment Level

The Substitutability of Immigrant and Native Labor: Evidence at the Establishment Level The Substitutability of Immigrant and Native Labor: Evidence at the Establishment Level Raymundo M. Campos-Vazquez JOB MARKET PAPER November 2008 University of California, Berkeley Department of Economics

More information

I ll marry you if you get me a job Marital assimilation and immigrant employment rates

I ll marry you if you get me a job Marital assimilation and immigrant employment rates The current issue and full text archive of this journal is available at www.emeraldinsight.com/0143-7720.htm IJM 116 PART 3: INTERETHNIC MARRIAGES AND ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE I ll marry you if you get me

More information

Immigrant Legalization

Immigrant Legalization Technical Appendices Immigrant Legalization Assessing the Labor Market Effects Laura Hill Magnus Lofstrom Joseph Hayes Contents Appendix A. Data from the 2003 New Immigrant Survey Appendix B. Measuring

More information

Characteristics of the Ethnographic Sample of First- and Second-Generation Latin American Immigrants in the New York to Philadelphia Urban Corridor

Characteristics of the Ethnographic Sample of First- and Second-Generation Latin American Immigrants in the New York to Philadelphia Urban Corridor Table 2.1 Characteristics of the Ethnographic Sample of First- and Second-Generation Latin American Immigrants in the New York to Philadelphia Urban Corridor Characteristic Females Males Total Region of

More information

Remittances and Poverty. in Guatemala* Richard H. Adams, Jr. Development Research Group (DECRG) MSN MC World Bank.

Remittances and Poverty. in Guatemala* Richard H. Adams, Jr. Development Research Group (DECRG) MSN MC World Bank. Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Remittances and Poverty in Guatemala* Richard H. Adams, Jr. Development Research Group

More information

Determinants of the Choice of Migration Destination

Determinants of the Choice of Migration Destination Determinants of the Choice of Migration Destination Marcel Fafchamps y Forhad Shilpi z July 2011 Abstract This paper examines migrants choice of destination conditional on migration. The study uses data

More information

Remittance and Household Expenditures in Kenya

Remittance and Household Expenditures in Kenya Remittance and Household Expenditures in Kenya Christine Nanjala Simiyu KCA University, Nairobi, Kenya. Email: csimiyu@kca.ac.ke Abstract Remittances constitute an important source of income for majority

More information

On the robustness of brain gain estimates M. Beine, F. Docquier and H. Rapoport. Discussion Paper

On the robustness of brain gain estimates M. Beine, F. Docquier and H. Rapoport. Discussion Paper On the robustness of brain gain estimates M. Beine, F. Docquier and H. Rapoport Discussion Paper 2009-18 On the robustness of brain gain estimates Michel Beine a, Frédéric Docquier b and Hillel Rapoport

More information

Outsourcing Household Production: The Demand for Foreign Domestic Helpers and Native Labor Supply in Hong Kong

Outsourcing Household Production: The Demand for Foreign Domestic Helpers and Native Labor Supply in Hong Kong Outsourcing Household Production: The Demand for Foreign Domestic Helpers and Native Labor Supply in Hong Kong Patricia Cortes Jessica Y. Pan University of Chicago Booth School of Business November 2009

More information

A Role for Sunspots in Explaining Endogenous Fluctutations in Illegal Immigration 1

A Role for Sunspots in Explaining Endogenous Fluctutations in Illegal Immigration 1 A Role for Sunspots in Explaining Endogenous Fluctutations in Illegal Immigration 1 Mark G. Guzman Research Department Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas Joseph H. Haslag Department of Economics University

More information

Determinants of Migrants Savings in the Host Country: Empirical Evidence of Migrants living in South Africa

Determinants of Migrants Savings in the Host Country: Empirical Evidence of Migrants living in South Africa Journal of Economics and Behavioral Studies Vol. 6, No. 1, pp. 68-74, Jan 2014 (ISSN: 2220-6140) Determinants of Migrants Savings in the Host Country: Empirical Evidence of Migrants living in South Africa

More information

Paternal Migration and Education Attainment in Rural Mexico (Job Market Paper)

Paternal Migration and Education Attainment in Rural Mexico (Job Market Paper) Paternal Migration and Education Attainment in Rural Mexico (Job Market Paper) Ao Li Boston University November 14, 2013 Abstract Migration from poor to rich regions has increased dramatically in recent

More information

Economic assimilation of Mexican and Chinese immigrants in the United States: is there wage convergence?

Economic assimilation of Mexican and Chinese immigrants in the United States: is there wage convergence? Illinois Wesleyan University From the SelectedWorks of Michael Seeborg 2012 Economic assimilation of Mexican and Chinese immigrants in the United States: is there wage convergence? Michael C. Seeborg,

More information

Online Appendix for The Contribution of National Income Inequality to Regional Economic Divergence

Online Appendix for The Contribution of National Income Inequality to Regional Economic Divergence Online Appendix for The Contribution of National Income Inequality to Regional Economic Divergence APPENDIX 1: Trends in Regional Divergence Measured Using BEA Data on Commuting Zone Per Capita Personal

More information

Discovering Migrant Types Through Cluster Analysis: Changes in the Mexico-U.S. Streams from 1970 to 2000

Discovering Migrant Types Through Cluster Analysis: Changes in the Mexico-U.S. Streams from 1970 to 2000 Discovering Migrant Types Through Cluster Analysis: Changes in the Mexico-U.S. Streams from 1970 to 2000 Extended Abstract - Do not cite or quote without permission. Filiz Garip Department of Sociology

More information

July, Abstract. Keywords: Criminality, law enforcement, social system.

July, Abstract. Keywords: Criminality, law enforcement, social system. Nontechnical Summary For most types of crimes but especially for violent ones, the number of o enses per inhabitant is larger in the US than in Europe. In the same time, expenditures for police, courts

More information

Repeat Migration and Remittances as Mechanisms for Wealth Inequality in 119 Communities From the Mexican Migration Project Data

Repeat Migration and Remittances as Mechanisms for Wealth Inequality in 119 Communities From the Mexican Migration Project Data Demography (2012) 49:1335 1360 DOI 10.1007/s13524-012-0128-6 Repeat Migration and Remittances as Mechanisms for Wealth Inequality in 119 Communities From the Mexican Migration Project Data Filiz Garip

More information

Entrepreneurs out of necessity : a snapshot

Entrepreneurs out of necessity : a snapshot Entrepreneurs out of necessity : a snapshot Markus Poschke McGill University, Montréal QC, Canada H3A2T7 E-mail: markus.poschke@mcgill.ca August 2012 Abstract Entrepreneurs out of necessity as identified

More information

Migration and Remittances 1

Migration and Remittances 1 Migration and Remittances 1 Hiranya K Nath 2 1. Introduction The history of humankind has been the history of constant movements of people across natural as well as man-made boundaries. The adventure of

More information

Cross-Nativity Marriages, Gender, and Human Capital Levels of Children

Cross-Nativity Marriages, Gender, and Human Capital Levels of Children University of Connecticut DigitalCommons@UConn Economics Working Papers Department of Economics August 2007 Cross-Nativity Marriages, Gender, and Human Capital Levels of Children Delia Furtado University

More information

DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES. No EXCHANGE RATES AND WAGES IN AN INTEGRATED WORLD. Prachi Mishra and Antonio Spilimbergo

DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES. No EXCHANGE RATES AND WAGES IN AN INTEGRATED WORLD. Prachi Mishra and Antonio Spilimbergo DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES No. 7167 EXCHANGE RATES AND WAGES IN AN INTEGRATED WORLD Prachi Mishra and Antonio Spilimbergo INTERNATIONAL MACROECONOMICS and INTERNATIONAL TRADE AND REGIONAL ECONOMICS ABCD www.cepr.org

More information

Immigrant-native wage gaps in time series: Complementarities or composition effects?

Immigrant-native wage gaps in time series: Complementarities or composition effects? Immigrant-native wage gaps in time series: Complementarities or composition effects? Joakim Ruist Department of Economics University of Gothenburg Box 640 405 30 Gothenburg, Sweden joakim.ruist@economics.gu.se

More information

Sectoral gender wage di erentials and discrimination in the transitional Chinese economy

Sectoral gender wage di erentials and discrimination in the transitional Chinese economy J Popul Econ (2000) 13: 331±352 999 2000 Sectoral gender wage di erentials and discrimination in the transitional Chinese economy Pak-Wai Liu1, Xin Meng2, Junsen Zhang1 1 Chinese University of Hong Kong,

More information

I'll Marry You If You Get Me a Job: Marital Assimilation and Immigrant Employment Rates

I'll Marry You If You Get Me a Job: Marital Assimilation and Immigrant Employment Rates DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 3951 I'll Marry You If You Get Me a Job: Marital Assimilation and Immigrant Employment Rates Delia Furtado Nikolaos Theodoropoulos January 2009 Forschungsinstitut zur

More information

IMMIGRATION REFORM, JOB SELECTION AND WAGES IN THE U.S. FARM LABOR MARKET

IMMIGRATION REFORM, JOB SELECTION AND WAGES IN THE U.S. FARM LABOR MARKET IMMIGRATION REFORM, JOB SELECTION AND WAGES IN THE U.S. FARM LABOR MARKET Lurleen M. Walters International Agricultural Trade & Policy Center Food and Resource Economics Department P.O. Box 040, University

More information

Migration and Employment Interactions in a Crisis Context

Migration and Employment Interactions in a Crisis Context Migration and Employment Interactions in a Crisis Context the case of Tunisia Anda David Agence Francaise de Developpement High Level Conference on Global Labour Markets OCP Policy Center Paris September

More information

The Economics of Immigration

The Economics of Immigration The Economics of Immigration Professor Manuela Angelucci Fall 2008 1 Course Outline This course focuses on key topics in the economics of immigration. We will look at the US immigration policy, how it

More information

Abdurrahman Aydemir and Murat G. Kirdar

Abdurrahman Aydemir and Murat G. Kirdar Discussion Paper Series CDP No 23/11 Quasi-Experimental Impact Estimates of Immigrant Labor Supply Shocks: The Role of Treatment and Comparison Group Matching and Relative Skill Composition Abdurrahman

More information

Remittances and Savings from International Migration:

Remittances and Savings from International Migration: Remittances and Savings from International Migration: Theory and Evidence Using a Matched Sample Una Okonkwo Osili Department of Economics Indiana University-Purdue University Indianapolis Indianapolis,

More information

Diasporas. Revised version - September 2009

Diasporas. Revised version - September 2009 Diasporas Michel Beine a, Frédéric Docquier b and Ça¼glar Özden c a University of Luxembourg and CES-Ifo b FNRS and IRES, Université Catholique de Louvain. c World Bank, Development Research Group Revised

More information

WP SEPTEMBER Skill Upgrading and the Saving of Immigrants. Adolfo Cristobal Campoamor

WP SEPTEMBER Skill Upgrading and the Saving of Immigrants. Adolfo Cristobal Campoamor ISET WORKING PAPER SERIES WP 009 08 SEPTEMBER 2008 Skill Upgrading and the Saving of Immigrants Adolfo Cristobal Campoamor The International School of Economics at Tbilisi State University (ISET) is supported

More information

Do Remittances Promote Household Savings? Evidence from Ethiopia

Do Remittances Promote Household Savings? Evidence from Ethiopia Do Remittances Promote Household Savings? Evidence from Ethiopia Ademe Zeyede 1 African Development Bank Group, Ethiopia Country Office, P.O.Box: 25543 code 1000 Abstract In many circumstances there are

More information

Endogenous antitrust: cross-country evidence on the impact of competition-enhancing policies on productivity

Endogenous antitrust: cross-country evidence on the impact of competition-enhancing policies on productivity Preliminary version Do not cite without authors permission Comments welcome Endogenous antitrust: cross-country evidence on the impact of competition-enhancing policies on productivity Joan-Ramon Borrell

More information

Expected Earnings and Migration: The Role of Minimum Wages

Expected Earnings and Migration: The Role of Minimum Wages Expected Earnings and Migration: The Role of Minimum Wages Ernest Bo y-ramirez University of California Santa Barbara March 2010 Abstract Does increasing a state s minimum wage induce migration into the

More information

Emigration, Remittances, and Labor Force Participation in Mexico

Emigration, Remittances, and Labor Force Participation in Mexico Emigration, Remittances, and Labor Force Participation in Mexico May 2005 Gordon H. Hanson * University of California, San Diego and National Bureau of Economic Research Abstract. In this paper, I examine

More information

MEXICAN MIGRATION MATURITY AND ITS EFFECTS ON FLOWS INTO LOCAL AREAS: A TEST OF THE CUMULATIVE CAUSATION PERSPECTIVE

MEXICAN MIGRATION MATURITY AND ITS EFFECTS ON FLOWS INTO LOCAL AREAS: A TEST OF THE CUMULATIVE CAUSATION PERSPECTIVE MEXICAN MIGRATION MATURITY AND ITS EFFECTS ON FLOWS INTO LOCAL AREAS: A TEST OF THE CUMULATIVE CAUSATION PERSPECTIVE ABSTRACT James D. Bachmeier University of California, Irvine This paper examines whether

More information

Research Report. How Does Trade Liberalization Affect Racial and Gender Identity in Employment? Evidence from PostApartheid South Africa

Research Report. How Does Trade Liberalization Affect Racial and Gender Identity in Employment? Evidence from PostApartheid South Africa International Affairs Program Research Report How Does Trade Liberalization Affect Racial and Gender Identity in Employment? Evidence from PostApartheid South Africa Report Prepared by Bilge Erten Assistant

More information

5. Destination Consumption

5. Destination Consumption 5. Destination Consumption Enabling migrants propensity to consume Meiyan Wang and Cai Fang Introduction The 2014 Central Economic Working Conference emphasised that China s economy has a new normal, characterised

More information

Why Do Arabs Earn Less than Jews in Israel?

Why Do Arabs Earn Less than Jews in Israel? Why Do Arabs Earn Less than Jews in Israel? 1 Introduction Israel is a multicultural, multiethnic society. Its population brings together Western and Eastern Jews, foreign- and locally-born citizens, and

More information

Skill classi cation does matter: estimating the relationship between trade ows and wage inequality

Skill classi cation does matter: estimating the relationship between trade ows and wage inequality J. Int. Trade & Economic Development 10:2 175 209 Skill classi cation does matter: estimating the relationship between trade ows and wage inequality Kristin J. Forbes MIT Sloan School of Management and

More information

Interethnic Marriages and Economic Assimilation of Immigrants

Interethnic Marriages and Economic Assimilation of Immigrants Interethnic Marriages and Economic Assimilation of Immigrants Jasmin Kantarevic University of Toronto y and IZA z January 30, 2005 Abstract This paper examines the relationship between interethnic marriages

More information

Emigration and source countries; Brain drain and brain gain; Remittances.

Emigration and source countries; Brain drain and brain gain; Remittances. Emigration and source countries; Brain drain and brain gain; Remittances. Mariola Pytliková CERGE-EI and VŠB-Technical University Ostrava, CReAM, IZA, CCP and CELSI Info about lectures: https://home.cerge-ei.cz/pytlikova/laborspring16/

More information

Rural and Urban Migrants in India:

Rural and Urban Migrants in India: Rural and Urban Migrants in India: 1983-2008 Viktoria Hnatkovska and Amartya Lahiri July 2014 Abstract This paper characterizes the gross and net migration flows between rural and urban areas in India

More information

International Migration, Human Capital, and Entrepreneurship: Evidence from Philippine Migrants Exchange Rate Shocks

International Migration, Human Capital, and Entrepreneurship: Evidence from Philippine Migrants Exchange Rate Shocks RESEARCH SEMINAR IN INTERNATIONAL ECONOMICS Gerald R. Ford School of Public Policy The University of Michigan Ann Arbor, Michigan 48109-1220 Discussion Paper No. 531 International Migration, Human Capital,

More information

Commuting and Minimum wages in Decentralized Era Case Study from Java Island. Raden M Purnagunawan

Commuting and Minimum wages in Decentralized Era Case Study from Java Island. Raden M Purnagunawan Commuting and Minimum wages in Decentralized Era Case Study from Java Island Raden M Purnagunawan Outline 1. Introduction 2. Brief Literature review 3. Data Source and Construction 4. The aggregate commuting

More information

International Migration and Remittances: A Review of Economic Impacts, Issues, and Challenges from the Sending Country s Perspective

International Migration and Remittances: A Review of Economic Impacts, Issues, and Challenges from the Sending Country s Perspective International Migration and Remittances: A Review of Economic Impacts, Issues, and Challenges from the Sending Country s Perspective Tereso S. Tullao, Jr., PhD Christopher James Cabuay International Migration

More information

Just War or Just Politics? The Determinants of Foreign Military Intervention

Just War or Just Politics? The Determinants of Foreign Military Intervention Just War or Just Politics? The Determinants of Foreign Military Intervention Averyroughdraft.Thankyouforyourcomments. Shannon Carcelli UC San Diego scarcell@ucsd.edu January 22, 2014 1 Introduction Under

More information

Remittances and the Wage Impact of Immigration

Remittances and the Wage Impact of Immigration Remittances and the Wage Impact of Immigration William W. Olney 1 First Draft: November 2011 Revised: June 2012 Abstract This paper examines the impact of immigrant remittances on the wages of native workers

More information

The Criminal Justice Response to Policy Interventions: Evidence from Immigration Reform

The Criminal Justice Response to Policy Interventions: Evidence from Immigration Reform The Criminal Justice Response to Policy Interventions: Evidence from Immigration Reform By SARAH BOHN, MATTHEW FREEDMAN, AND EMILY OWENS * October 2014 Abstract Changes in the treatment of individuals

More information

The Migrant Network Effect: An empirical analysis of rural-to-urban migration in South Africa

The Migrant Network Effect: An empirical analysis of rural-to-urban migration in South Africa The Migrant Network Effect: An empirical analysis of rural-to-urban migration in South Africa Caroline Stapleton ERSA working paper 504 March 2015 Economic Research Southern Africa (ERSA) is a research

More information

The Impact of Migration on Children Left Behind in Developing Countries

The Impact of Migration on Children Left Behind in Developing Countries Migration and Development: Building Migration into Development Strategies The Impact of Migration on Children Left Behind in Developing Countries Andrea Rossi Harvard University, Kennedy School of Government

More information

262 Index. D demand shocks, 146n demographic variables, 103tn

262 Index. D demand shocks, 146n demographic variables, 103tn Index A Africa, 152, 167, 173 age Filipino characteristics, 85 household heads, 59 Mexican migrants, 39, 40 Philippines migrant households, 94t 95t nonmigrant households, 96t 97t premigration income effects,

More information

Brain Drain and Emigration: How Do They Affect Source Countries?

Brain Drain and Emigration: How Do They Affect Source Countries? The University of Akron IdeaExchange@UAkron Honors Research Projects The Dr. Gary B. and Pamela S. Williams Honors College Spring 2019 Brain Drain and Emigration: How Do They Affect Source Countries? Nicholas

More information

Toil and Tolerance: A Tale of Illegal Migration

Toil and Tolerance: A Tale of Illegal Migration Toil and Tolerance: A Tale of Illegal Migration by Oded Stark Universities of Bonn, Klagenfurt, and Vienna; Warsaw University; Warsaw School of Economics Mailing Address: Oded Stark September 008 ZE, University

More information

Openness and Poverty Reduction in the Long and Short Run. Mark R. Rosenzweig. Harvard University. October 2003

Openness and Poverty Reduction in the Long and Short Run. Mark R. Rosenzweig. Harvard University. October 2003 Openness and Poverty Reduction in the Long and Short Run Mark R. Rosenzweig Harvard University October 2003 Prepared for the Conference on The Future of Globalization Yale University. October 10-11, 2003

More information

Rewriting the Rules of the Market Economy to Achieve Shared Prosperity. Joseph E. Stiglitz New York June 2016

Rewriting the Rules of the Market Economy to Achieve Shared Prosperity. Joseph E. Stiglitz New York June 2016 Rewriting the Rules of the Market Economy to Achieve Shared Prosperity Joseph E. Stiglitz New York June 2016 Enormous growth in inequality Especially in US, and countries that have followed US model Multiple

More information

REMITTANCE TRANSFERS TO ARMENIA: PRELIMINARY SURVEY DATA ANALYSIS

REMITTANCE TRANSFERS TO ARMENIA: PRELIMINARY SURVEY DATA ANALYSIS REMITTANCE TRANSFERS TO ARMENIA: PRELIMINARY SURVEY DATA ANALYSIS microreport# 117 SEPTEMBER 2008 This publication was produced for review by the United States Agency for International Development. It

More information