Branko Milanovic* and John E. Roemer Interaction of Global and National Income Inequalities

Similar documents
TRENDS IN INCOME INEQUALITY: GLOBAL, INTER-COUNTRY, AND WITHIN COUNTRIES Zia Qureshi 1

Global income inequality

Is Global Inequality Really Falling?

Trends in inequality worldwide (Gini coefficients)

INCOME INEQUALITY WITHIN AND BETWEEN COUNTRIES

Changes in the global income distribution and their political consequences

THE COFFEES OF THE SECRETARY-GENERAL JAMES K. GALBRAITH

Global income inequality: new results and implications for 21 st century policy

vi. rising InequalIty with high growth and falling Poverty

Global Income Inequality by the Numbers: In History and Now An Overview. Branko Milanovic

Application of PPP exchange rates for the measurement and analysis of regional and global inequality and poverty

World changes in inequality:

INTERNATIONAL MULTILATERAL ASSISTANCE FOR SOCIO-ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT OF THE POOREST COUNTRIES OF SOUTH-EAST ASIA

Worlds Apart: Measuring International and Global Inequality

Where are the Middle Class in OECD Countries? Nathaniel Johnson (CUNY and LIS) David Johnson (University of Michigan)

Lecture 1 Economic Growth and Income Differences: A Look at the Data

WID.world Working Paper N 2018/4. Extreme inequality: evidence from Brazil, India, the Middle East and South Africa

Hot Topic: World Income Inequality Is the world becoming more unequal?

Economic Growth and Poverty Alleviation in Russia: Should We Take Inequality into Consideration?

Women in Agriculture: Some Results of Household Surveys Data Analysis 1

Globalization and Inequality : a brief review of facts and arguments

Emerging Market Consumers: A comparative study of Latin America and Asia-Pacific

Overview. Main Findings. The Global Weighted Average has also been steady in the last quarter, and is now recorded at 6.62 percent.

Gender in the South Caucasus: A Snapshot of Key Issues and Indicators 1

Inequality and the Global Middle Class

Poverty and Inequality

Global inequality recalculated and updated: the effect of new PPP estimates on global inequality and 2005 estimates

The Inequalities of. Wealth Distribution: its Economic and. Political Consequences. Dr David Rees

Trends in Poverty and Inequality in Decentralising Indonesia

HOW ECONOMIES GROW AND DEVELOP Macroeconomics In Context (Goodwin, et al.)

Inequality in Indonesia: Trends, drivers, policies

Companion for Chapter 2: An Unequal World

Interrelationship between Growth, Inequality, and Poverty: The Asian Experience

The labor market in Japan,

Global Inequality - Trends and Issues. Finn Tarp

Volume 36, Issue 1. Impact of remittances on poverty: an analysis of data from a set of developing countries

Inclusive global growth: a framework to think about the post-2015 agenda

Prospects for Inclusive Growth in the MENA Region: A Comparative Approach

Part 1: Focus on Income. Inequality. EMBARGOED until 5/28/14. indicator definitions and Rankings

Marek Dabrowski Examining interrelation between global and national income inequalities

Growth and Poverty Reduction: An Empirical Analysis Nanak Kakwani

THE ECONOMIC EFFECT OF CORRUPTION IN ITALY: A REGIONAL PANEL ANALYSIS (M. LISCIANDRA & E. MILLEMACI) APPENDIX A: CORRUPTION CRIMES AND GROWTH RATES

PUBLIC POLICIES FOR GREATER EQUALITY: LESSONS LEARNED IN THE ESCWA REGION

Direction of trade and wage inequality

ERD. Working Paper. No. Interrelationship between Growth, Inequality, and Poverty: The Asian Experience. Hyun H. Son ECONOMICS AND RESEARCH DEPARTMENT

Inequality in Asia: Trends, Drivers and Policy Implications

Does government decentralization reduce domestic terror? An empirical test

Understanding the dynamics of labor income inequality in Latin America (WB PRWP 7795)

INCLUSIVE GROWTH AND POLICIES: THE ASIAN EXPERIENCE. Thangavel Palanivel Chief Economist for Asia-Pacific UNDP, New York

Asian Development Bank Institute. ADBI Working Paper Series. Income Distributions, Inequality, and Poverty in Asia,

Remittance Prices Worldwide Issue n. 19, September 2016

The Gravity Model on EU Countries An Econometric Approach

Comments on Dani Rodrik s paper, The past, present and future of economic growth Branko Milanovic 1

Globalization and Inequality

The Challenge of Inclusive Growth: Making Growth Work for the Poor

CHAPTER I: SIZE AND GEOGRAPHICAL DISTRIBUTION OF THE POPULATION

IPR 40 th Anniversary Distinguished Public Policy Lecture. Rebecca Blank. "Why Does Inequality Matter and What Should We Do About It?

The Correlates of Wealth Disparity Between the Global North & the Global South. Noelle Enguidanos

Notes to Editors. Detailed Findings

Briefing Memo Prospect of Demographic Trend, Economic Hegemony and Security: From the mid-21 st to 22 nd Century

Visualizing. Rights C E SR. Making Human Rights Accountability More Graphic. Center for Economic and Social Rights. fact sheet no.

Global Income Distribution: From the Fall of the Berlin Wall to the Great Recession

Poverty in the Third World

Changes in the global income distribution and their political implication

Matthew A. Cole and Eric Neumayer. The pitfalls of convergence analysis : is the income gap really widening?

The Trends of Income Inequality and Poverty and a Profile of

The World Bank s Twin Goals

Global versus national inequality

Being a Good Samaritan or just a politician? Empirical evidence of disaster assistance. Jeroen Klomp

EDUCATION AND WORLD DEVELOPMENT IN : A GENERAL VIEW AND CHALLENGES FOR THE NEAR FUTURE GUISAN, Maria-Carmen *, AGUAYO, E. EXPOSITO, Pilar.

Rewriting the Rules of the Market Economy to Achieve Shared Prosperity. Joseph E. Stiglitz New York June 2016

THE RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN DEMOGRAPHIC CHANGE AND INCOME INEQUALITY IN AGING SOCIETY OF THAILAND

Accounting for the role of occupational change on earnings in Europe and Central Asia Maurizio Bussolo, Iván Torre and Hernan Winkler (World Bank)

POLICY OPTIONS AND CHALLENGES FOR DEVELOPING ASIA PERSPECTIVES FROM THE IMF AND ASIA APRIL 19-20, 2007 TOKYO

Europe, North Africa, Middle East: Diverging Trends, Overlapping Interests and Possible Arbitrage through Migration

Qatar. Switzerland Russian Federation Saudi Arabia Brazil. New Zealand India Pakistan Philippines Nicaragua Chad Yemen

A. Growing dissatisfaction with hyperglobalization

Economic and Social Council

Pallabi Mukherjee Assistant Professor, IBMR, IPS Academy, India

Working Papers in Economics

MACROECONOMICS. Key Concepts. The Importance of Economic Growth. The Wealth of Nations. GDP Growth. Elements of Growth. Total output Output per capita

The widening income dispersion in Hong Kong :

Trade led Growth in Times of Crisis Asia Pacific Trade Economists Conference 2 3 November 2009, Bangkok. Session 10

Earnings Inequality: Stylized Facts, Underlying Causes, and Policy

The elephant curve of global inequality and growth

Unit 1 Introduction to Comparative Politics Test Multiple Choice 2 pts each

The World Bank s Twin Goals

IEP Risk and Peace. Institute for Economics and Peace. Steve Killelea, Executive Chairman. Monday, 18th November 2013 EIB, Luxemburg

HSX: GROWTH OF GLOBAL MIDDLE CLASS

Explanatory note on the 2014 Human Development Report composite indices. Serbia. HDI values and rank changes in the 2014 Human Development Report

Household Inequality and Remittances in Rural Thailand: A Lifecycle Perspective

L8: Inequality, Poverty and Development: The Evidence

Trade, Employment and Inclusive Growth in Asia. Douglas H. Brooks Jakarta, Indonesia 10 December 2012

LIS Working Paper Series

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES GLOBAL INEQUALITY WHEN UNEQUAL COUNTRIES CREATE UNEQUAL PEOPLE. Martin Ravallion

FOREIGN FIRMS AND INDONESIAN MANUFACTURING WAGES: AN ANALYSIS WITH PANEL DATA

Luxembourg Income Study Working Paper Series

Immigration and all-cause mortality in Canada: An illustration using linked census and administrative data

MIDDLE CLASSES, MOBILITY, ECONOMIC GROWTH AND DEMOCRACY IN LATIN AMERICA

Transcription:

JGD 2016; 7(1): 109 115 Branko Milanovic* and John E. Roemer Interaction of Global and National Income Inequalities DOI 10.1515/jgd-2016-0023 Abstract: The current era is characterized by simultaneous increase in many countries income inequalities and a decline in global inequality. People s perception of inequality is shown to depend on how much they value absolute income vs. their national income position. Keywords: globalization; income inequality; relative income. 1 Introduction Global inequality, defined as income inequality among all citizens of the world, where incomes are adjusted to reflect differences in price levels between the countries, has been broadly stable between 1980s and early 2000s, and has since declined by several Gini points. Using an unbalanced panel of country-deciles for the period 1988 2008, Lakner and Milanovic (2015) find global inequality to have decreased from 69 Gini points in 1988 to 67 Gini points in 2011. 1 Using the updated 2011 data, Milanovic (2016) finds a further decrease, down to about 64 Gini points. This is indeed a remarkable decline that has occurred over a relatively short time period. It was driven by very high rates of income growth in China and India in particular, but also of other populous and relatively poor countries such as Vietnam, Thailand, Indonesia, and others. African countries also had a rather good first decade of the present century. On the other hand, the sluggish or even negative growth of the advanced economies has also contributed to the shrinking of the global income inequality. 1 We are using here, and in the rest of the paper, the results obtained with 2011 PPPs (see Lakner and Milanovic 2015, Table A3). *Corresponding author: Branko Milanovic, Graduate Center, City University of New York and Yale University, New York, NY 10013, USA, e-mail: bmilanovic@gc.cuny.edu John E. Roemer: Graduate Center, City University of New York and Yale University, New York, NY 10013, USA

110 Branko Milanovic and John E. Roemer It is remarkable that this historic decrease in global income inequality, explained mostly by the reduction in gaps between countries mean incomes, has coincided with rising income inequality in most individual countries, whether advanced, middle-income or poor. About two-thirds of countries had higher income inequality in 2011 than in 1988. 2 Among OECD countries, 18 out of 23 registered a significant increase in income inequality between the mid-1980s and around 2013 (see OECD 2015: p. 24). Citizen concern with rising inequality, ubiquitous in the media and in the political arena, has thus coincided with rising income inequality in most countries, despite the decline in global income inequality. If the latter were all, or most, what mattered to the people around the world, it is less likely that the inequality concerns, voiced practically daily, would have been as strong. This note explores what might lie behind them. 2 The Data In the calculations we use the Lakner-Milanovic World Panel Income Distribution (LM-WPID) dataset available (with a detailed description) at http://econ.worldbank.org/wbsite/external/extdec/extresearch/0,,contentmdk:236907 96 pagepk:64214825 pipk:64214943 thesitepk:469382,00.html. 3 The dataset provides an unbalanced panel of country/deciles over the period 1988 2008 with the average incomes of each country/decile expressed in real 2005 PPPs dollars (based on 2011 International Comparison Project results). Incomes for country/ deciles are calculated using national household surveys which in most cases (and increasing so for the more recent years) were accessed at the level of individual households (that is, not as grouped or published data). The global income distribution estimates for the period 1988 2008 are done for five benchmark years positioned at regular intervals (1988, 1993 and so forth). The number of countries included varies between 75 in 1988 and 120 in 2008. The coverage of the world population varies between 81 percent in 1988 and 94 percent in 2003. The coverage of world income is consistently higher than the population coverage because the countries without available household surveys are almost always poor. 2 Of 65 countries with Gini values in both 2011 and 1988, Gini was higher in 43 countries and lower in 22. Moreover, the average increase among the countries with higher inequality in 2011, was 5.3 Gini points while the average decrease among the other group was 3.6 Gini points (calculated from the Lakner and Milanovic database expanded to include 2011). 3 For more information see Lakner and Mlanovic (2015).

Interaction of Global and National Income Inequalities 111 This dataset was extended up to 2011 by Milanovic (unpublished results) using the same procedure and the same PPPs as in the case of the original dataset. The 2011 data include 113 countries and cover 88 percent of the world population. 3 A Simple Welfare Function We consider a simple welfare function W ij for individual i living in country j which has two arguments. A person is concerned with her absolute level of income (adjusted for the price level of the country where she lives) y ij, and with her relative position in her own country, expressed as the ratio between her income and mean income of the country μ j : y 1 λ ij W = ( y ) ij ij µ j λ (1) We use a Cobb-Douglas formulation with the parameter λ that takes values from 0 to 1. 4 As can be readily seen, if λ = 0, equation (1) reduces to include income only. Thus the Gini coefficient of global income is the Gini coefficient of the distribution of {W ij } when λ = 0. However, as λ increases, one s relative position within one s country s income distribution becomes increasingly important until it reaches the extreme case of λ = 1 when this alone matters. One s absolute (real) income is then immaterial; only the relative national position is taken into account. We can thus consider λ as a measure of national salience as opposed to the situation when λ = 0 and where only absolute income matters, a situation which may be associated with cosmopolitan worldview. Figure 1 shows the calculation of global Gini index over W for various values of λ, taken in increments of 0.1 (results shown in the Annex). The Figure displays the calculations for only λ = 0, 0.4, 0.6, 0.7 and 1. The top graph in Figure 1 gives the Gini coefficient of global income. It displays a sharp decrease of global inequality since 2003 and especially between 2008 and 2011. First, note that the values of the Gini coefficient uniformly decrease as λ increases, and second, note that the changes over time in Ginis for λ > 0 follow 4 For a different approach where, like here, global and national inequalities are included in a welfare function see Brandolini and Carta (2016).

112 Branko Milanovic and John E. Roemer 0.750 0.700 0 0.4 0.6 0.7 1 0.650 0.600 Gini 0.550 0.500 0.450 0.400 0.350 0.300 1988 1993 1998 2003 2008 2011 Year Figure 1: Global Gini (1988 2011) with different λ s. a different pattern than the change in the conventional global Gini calculated across personal incomes only. The level of inequality in all formulations with λ > 0 will be less than with λ = 0 because in all such formulations we introduce an income-moderating function similar to what we do when we transform income directly into welfare such as W = W(y) with W < 0. Since higher income levels do not lead to proportional increases in welfare, it is obvious that inequality of welfare, calculated across individuals who are assumed to have the same concave utility functions, will be less than inequality calculated across untransformed incomes. What is interesting in our case is that as λ increases, and especially when it reaches one, global inequality is substantially smaller than at λ = 0. The reason lies in the extremely high inequality of countries mean incomes: depending on the index used, some two-thirds or even three-fourths of the conventionally calculated global inequality is explained by the differences in countries mean incomes. Now, in the formulation where λ = 1, that part of global inequality vanishes as individuals are assumed to care only about their position relative to their country mean. (Differently put, the formulation for λ = 1 gives what global inequality would be if all countries mean incomes were normalized to be the same.) With regard to the dynamics over time, in the conventional calculation (λ = 0), global inequality decreases and, as shown in Figure 2, is almost 6 points lower at the end of the period than in 1988. But this is not the case with other formulations. As λ increases, the Gini of global inequality declines less, and for values of λ around 0.6, the decline disappears altogether. Moreover, with λ > 0.6, we obtain

Interaction of Global and National Income Inequalities 113 4.0 Global Gini change (in Gini points) 2.0 0.0 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 2.0 4.0 6.0 8.0 National relativism Figure 2: Change in global Gini between 1988 and 2011 for different values of λ. an increase in global inequality which in the case of complete national salience (λ = 1) reaches 4 Gini points. Thus, the range of global-inequality change between 1988 and 2011, measured from full cosmopolitanism to full national salience goes from 6 to +4 Gini points. 4 Discussion This note shows that with a moderate change in the welfare function to include also a concern with one s position in national income distribution, the evolution of global (welfare) inequality diverges from the evolution of inequality calculated across absolute (real) incomes. As the concern with one s relative position becomes greater, because during the past 30 years inequality in most countries has increased, it turns out that the relativistic element dominates over the more equal distribution of absolute incomes worldwide, and converts the decrease of income inequality into an increase of global (welfare) inequality. We believe the welfare function proposed here is reasonable because individuals welfare is sensitive to how their incomes compare with incomes of their peers. An obvious salient peer-group comprises one s co-citizens. One could use the same formulation but change the peer group. Clark and Senik (2010) show that for the people living in countries in the European Union, the salient peers are, increasingly, taken to be the EU citizenry, not solely one s own co-citizens.

114 Branko Milanovic and John E. Roemer Gradually, as globalization progresses, one could think of replacing the national mean incomes with regional mean incomes. We give two dramatic examples of the importance of acknowledging concerns for relative income. In Russia, after the economic crisis of 1998, life expectancy for men fell to less than 59 years, despite the fact that almost all Russian men still placed relatively highly in the global income distribution. Men et al. (2003) report that increased mortality was attributed in large part to vascular disease and violent causes. In the United States, Case and Deaton (2015) have documented a sharp rise in mortality and morbidity of non-hispanic White men and women in mid-life in the period 1999 2013, again due to suicide, alcohol and opiate use. The men and women who are afflicted place very high on the global distribution of income, but have experienced a sharp deterioration in their positions relative to those in the top decile of the income and wealth distribution in the United States. 5 Because the world is politically organized in nation-states where most of the decisions about economic and social policies are made, and as the movement of labor between the countries is limited, it seems reasonable at this stage to use county mean as a peer-yardstick. This seems to us especially apposite at present, when voters and politicians attention is much more focused on inequality developments nationally rather than on the favorable developments in inequality globally. In a yet another twist, which we do not explore here, it could be argued that it is precisely these favorable global developments that are causing the rising national inequalities. This possibility is especially intriguing because with a high λ, such a process can lead to particularly deleterious welfare effects. To put it simply, (i) if the rising incomes in Asia that underlie the reduction in global income inequality lead to increasing inequalities in advanced countries as well as in the Asian countries themselves, and (ii) if individuals still care more about their relative national positions, then a concern with rising national inequalities may significantly (in welfare terms) outweigh the advantages of rising welfare stemming from higher absolute incomes. Such a dynamic model would then have to include a feedback from lower global inequality into greater national inequalities and hence into individual welfare functions. Moreover, in such a model λ itself may be thought to be variable (possibly decreasing with greater globalization). 5 An alternative hypothesis to the importance of relative position in the income distribution of one s country is that a sharp change in the growth rate of one s income is what matters to people. We cannot calculate a measure based on the dynamics of income growth with available data sets since we do not have longitudinal data at individual level.

Interaction of Global and National Income Inequalities 115 Even without such a dynamic model, we suggest that with a relatively simple reformulation of welfare, the feeling of rising inequality may coexist with the fact that the conventionally measured inequality is decreasing globally. Annex Global inequality for diffferent values of λ from equation (1) (in Gini values). λ Year Change between 1988 and 2008 1988 1993 1998 2003 2008 2011 Fully cosmopolian 0 0.693 0.686 0.689 0.683 0.669 0.634 0.059 0.1 0.658 0.650 0.653 0.646 0.632 0.602 0.056 0.2 0.619 0.612 0.615 0.606 0.594 0.569 0.050 0.3 0.576 0.571 0.574 0.565 0.555 0.535 0.041 0.4 0.530 0.529 0.533 0.524 0.517 0.500 0.029 0.5 0.483 0.487 0.493 0.485 0.481 0.467 0.016 0.6 0.438 0.448 0.456 0.451 0.450 0.437 0.001 0.7 0.398 0.414 0.425 0.422 0.424 0.410 0.012 0.8 0.366 0.388 0.400 0.400 0.405 0.389 0.023 0.9 0.344 0.370 0.384 0.387 0.394 0.375 0.031 Only national 1 0.335 0.362 0.377 0.382 0.390 0.370 0.035 References Brandolini, Andrea and Francesca Carta (2016) Some Reflections on the Social Welfare Bases of the Measurement of Global Income Inequality, Journal of Globalization and Development, 7:1 15. Case, A. and A. Deaton (2015) Rising Morbidity and Mortality in Midlife Among White Non-Hispanic Americans in the 21st Century, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 112:15078 15083. Clark, Andrew E. and Claudia Senik (2010) Who Compares to Whom? The Anatomy of Income Comparisons in Europe, Economic Journal, 120:573 594. Lakner, Christoph and Branko Milanovic (2015) Global Income Distribution: From the Fall of the Berlin Wall to the Great Recession, World Bank Economic Review, 30:203 232. Men, T., P. Brennan, P. Boffetta and D. Zaridze (2003) Russian Mortality Trends for 1991 2001: Analysis by Cause and Region, British Medical Journal, 327:7421. Milanovic, Branko (2016) Global Inequality: A New Approach for the Age of Globalization. Boston and London: Harvard University Press. Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (2015) In It Together. Paris: OECD. Available at: http://www.oecd.org/social/in-it-together-why-less-inequality-benefits-all- 9789264235120-en.htm.