To first recap AY s argument as to why the observed trends of variances are compatible with trade barriers:

Similar documents
The widening income dispersion in Hong Kong :

China s (Uneven) Progress Against Poverty. Martin Ravallion and Shaohua Chen Development Research Group, World Bank

The Impact of Interprovincial Migration on Aggregate Output and Labour Productivity in Canada,

Urban income inequality in China revisited,

The Effects of Interprovincial Migration on Human Capital Formation in China 1

capita terms and for rural income and consumption, disparities appear large. Furthermore, both

5A. Wage Structures in the Electronics Industry. Benjamin A. Campbell and Vincent M. Valvano

Birth Control Policy and Housing Markets: The Case of China. By Chenxi Zhang (UO )

The Trend of Regional Income Disparity in the People s Republic of China

Overview The Dualistic System Urbanization Rural-Urban Migration Consequences of Urban-Rural Divide Conclusions

Asian Development Bank Institute. ADBI Working Paper Series URBANIZATION AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT IN THE PEOPLE S REPUBLIC OF CHINA

Analysis of Urban Poverty in China ( )

Overview: Income Inequality and Poverty in China,

GLOBALIZATION AND URBAN-RURAL INEQUALITY: EVIDENCE FROM CHINA

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr

The impact of Chinese import competition on the local structure of employment and wages in France

Economic Growth and Regional Income Disparities in Canada and the Northern United States

The impacts of minimum wage policy in china

Migration Networks, Hukou, and Destination Choices in China

The Role of Labor Market in Explaining Growth and Inequality: The Philippines Case. Hyun H. Son

LABOUR AND EMPLOYMENT

11. Demographic Transition in Rural China:

CHAPTER 2 LITERATURE REVIEWS

Recent Trends in China s Distribution of Income and Consumption: A Review of the Evidence

Levels and Trends in Multidimensional Poverty in some Southern and Eastern African countries, using counting based approaches

Urban!Biased!Social!Policies!and!the!Urban3Rural!Divide!in!China! by! Kaijie!Chen! Department!of!Political!Science! Duke!University!

The Wage Labor Market and Inequality in Vietnam in the 1990s

There is a seemingly widespread view that inequality should not be a concern

65. Broad access to productive jobs is essential for achieving the objective of inclusive PROMOTING EMPLOYMENT AND MANAGING MIGRATION

EUROPEAN COMMISSION DIRECTORATE-GENERAL FOR AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT

Reconciling Educational Adequacy and Equity Arguments Through a Rawlsian Lens

Matthew A. Cole and Eric Neumayer. The pitfalls of convergence analysis : is the income gap really widening?

Ohio State University

Regional Inequality of Higher Education in China and the Role of Unequal Economic Development

Family Ties, Labor Mobility and Interregional Wage Differentials*

The Consequences of Marketization for Health in China, 1991 to 2004: An Examination of Changes in Urban-Rural Differences

Informal Employment and its Effect on the Income Distribution in Urban China

Can immigration constitute a sensible solution to sub national and regional labour shortages?

How Does Globalisation Affect Regional Inequality within A Developing Country? Evidence from China

Changing income distribution in China

Urban-Rural Disparity in Post-reform China

Migration at the Provincial Level in China: Effects of the Economic Motivation and Migration Cost

The wage gap between the public and the private sector among. Canadian-born and immigrant workers

Preliminary Demographic Analysis of First Nations and Métis People

UNIVERSITY OF WAIKATO. Hamilton New Zealand. Rising Regional Income Inequality in China: Fact or Artefact? Chao Li and John Gibson

New Evidence on the Urbanization of Global Poverty

Ecological Analyses of Permanent and Temporary Migration Streams. in China in the 1990s. Dudley L. Poston, Jr. Li Zhang. Texas A&M University ABSTRACT

Inclusive Growth and Poverty Eradication Policies in China

Global Employment Trends for Women

A poverty-inequality trade off?

ECON 141 Ch. 2 Dr. Mohammed Alwosabi

New Brunswick Population Snapshot

Real Wage Trends, 1979 to 2017

A Profile of the Gauteng Province: Demographics, Poverty, Income, Inequality and Unemployment from 2000 till 2007

Labour Market Reform, Rural Migration and Income Inequality in China -- A Dynamic General Equilibrium Analysis

WHO MIGRATES? SELECTIVITY IN MIGRATION

Poverty and Inequality

GLOBALIZACIÓN, CRECIMIENTO Y COMPETITIVIDAD. Patricio Pérez Universidad de Cantabria

Education and Fertility in Two Chinese Provinces : to

Inequality of Wage Rates, Earnings, and Family Income in the United States, PSC Research Report. Report No

Chapter 1 Introduction and Goals

Labor Market Dropouts and Trends in the Wages of Black and White Men

Income Inequality in Urban China: A Comparative Analysis between Urban Residents and Rural-Urban Migrants

Research Report. How Does Trade Liberalization Affect Racial and Gender Identity in Employment? Evidence from PostApartheid South Africa

Inequality is Bad for the Poor. Martin Ravallion * Development Research Group, World Bank 1818 H Street NW, Washington DC

A Comparative Perspective on Poverty Reduction in Brazil, China, and India

Goal 3: Promote Gender Equality and Empower Women

Influence of Identity on Development of Urbanization. WEI Ming-gao, YU Gao-feng. University of Shanghai for Science and Technology, Shanghai, China

Econ 340. Lecture 4 Modern Theories and Additional Effects of Trade

Reaping the Dividends of Reforms on Hukou System. Du Yang

IV. Labour Market Institutions and Wage Inequality

Has China Lost Its Edge? Todd C. Lee Managing Director, Greater China Country Intelligence Global Insight

Rural Labor Force Emigration on the Impact. and Effect of Macro-Economy in China

Part 1: Focus on Income. Inequality. EMBARGOED until 5/28/14. indicator definitions and Rankings

Citation IDE Discussion Paper. No

Population Composition

Regional Income Trends and Convergence

Urbanization, Educational Expansion, and Expenditures Inequality in Indonesia in 1996, 1999, and 2002

Persistent Inequality

Rural-urban Migration and Urbanization in Gansu Province, China: Evidence from Time-series Analysis

Globalization: It Doesn t Just Happen

Government Briefing Note for Oireachtas Members on UK-EU Referendum

Employment outcomes of postsecondary educated immigrants, 2006 Census

Comparison on the Developmental Trends Between Chinese Students Studying Abroad and Foreign Students Studying in China

Volume 35, Issue 1. An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach

Working women have won enormous progress in breaking through long-standing educational and

Immigration, Wage Inequality and unobservable skills in the U.S. and the UK. First Draft: October 2008 This Draft March 2009

LONG RUN GROWTH, CONVERGENCE AND FACTOR PRICES

INCREASE IN LABOR FORCE PARTICIPATION RATE AND URBANIZATION IN TAIWAN

Provincial and Territorial Culture Indicators, 2010 to 2014

Youth labour market overview

SIMPLE LINEAR REGRESSION OF CPS DATA

Cleavages in Public Preferences about Globalization

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE EFFECT OF IMMIGRATION ON PRODUCTIVITY: EVIDENCE FROM US STATES. Giovanni Peri

The Jus Semper Global Alliance Living Wages North and South

REGIONAL DISPARITIES IN EMPLOYMENT STRUCTURES AND PRODUCTIVITY IN ROMANIA 1. Anca Dachin*, Raluca Popa

GLOBALISATION AND WAGE INEQUALITIES,

Inflation and relative price variability in Mexico: the role of remittances

Earnings Inequality: Stylized Facts, Underlying Causes, and Policy

The imbalance of economic development. between urban and rural areas in China. Author: Jieying LI

Transcription:

Appendix: Variance Decomposition Conceptual issues in detail To first recap AY s argument as to why the observed trends of variances are compatible with trade barriers: The [reform period] Chinese data are compatible with a rise in trade barriers. [1] A growing diversity of nominal labor productivities could easily arise from growing interregional price disparities, which would increase both the variation of relative prices and, due to a decline in factor price equalization, the variation of real labor productivities. [2] A rise in the variance of labor allocations could come from increasingly perverse labor allocations, as provinces poured resources into areas of comparative disadvantage, a view that would also not be incompatible with the growing negative correlation between productivities and factor allocations. (p. 1118) Trying to sort through the various causalities, AY appears to make the following argument: (1) A rise in trade barriers causes an increase in inter-provincial price disparities. These cause (a) an increase in the variation of relative prices, and (b) a decline in factor price equalization and therefore an increase in the variation of real labor productivities. Increasing price dispersion and increasing variation in real labor productivity imply the observed increasing variation in relative nominal labor productivities. (The variance of the ln of the latter rises from 0.12 to 0.15 between 1978 and 1997.) (2) A rise in trade barriers causes provinces to pour resources into areas of comparative disadvantage, which causes perverse labor allocations, which in turn leads to the observed growing diversity of relative labor allocations. (The variance of the ln of the latter rises from 0.56 to 0.73.) Increasing labor allocation in a sector of comparative disadvantage goes hand in hand with a lowering of this sector s relative labor productivity. (The covariance falls from 0.01 to negative 0.17.) But the causalities are problematic. (1) As argued earlier, trade barriers need not cause interprovincial price disparities. AY has not even shown that price disparity increased between 1978 and 1997; at best, he has shown that price dispersion increased and decreased in individual years after 1986, that price dispersion in his series fluctuated within a very narrow range between 1990 and 1999 (without being able to document corresponding highs and lows in trade wars), and that price dispersion was particularly low in 1997 (when it is now supposed to be significantly higher than in 1978). Furthermore, the time pattern of inter-regional price disparities observed in China is well explained by institutional factors without the need to conjure up trade barriers. But suppose price dispersion had indeed increased between 1978 and 1997, something for which we have no evidence. (a) If a province were to newly establish trade barriers and were to use these trade barriers to increase prices, then prices in all product categories agricultural procurement, consumer goods, and industrial materials would rise. The ratio of primary to Carsten A. Holz, 3 January 2008 1

secondary prices remains unchanged, i.e., trade barriers (in contrast to AY s claim) imply a constant variation of relative prices. (b) But perhaps all provinces erect trade barriers only in favor of industry (as AY s economic rationale would suggest). Assume that each province increases industrial prices in such a manner that, across provinces, price dispersion of industrial materials changes in such a way as to cause an increase in the variation of relative prices (with the differential behavior of provinces asking for an explanation). At higher prices of industrial goods, presumably less is sold (in the limited provincial market with high trade barriers), i.e., real output falls. If, for a particular province, the percentage decline in secondary sector real output matches the percentage increase in secondary sector prices, relative labor productivity remains unchanged. Trade wars then imply constant variation in relative labor productivity over time, something AY found for the U.S, but not for China ( China s provinces became increasingly dissimilar in terms of sectoral productivities, AY, p. 1117). (2) Trade barriers need not cause provinces to pour resources into areas of comparative disadvantage. Provinces may pour resources into areas of comparative advantage where profits could be highest; each province may protect only those of its industries where it has a potential comparative advantage. If provinces were indeed found to pour resources into areas of comparative disadvantage (the evidence is lacking), this could be the result of central investment and development plans. A general economic development argument would suggest that different provinces, developing at different speeds, might move laborers out of agriculture each at their own pace (potentially increasing the variance of relative labor allocations). On the other hand, if AY makes the assumption that all provinces favor the secondary sector, needed for the first part of his argument to go through and an assumption that matches his economic rationale, the only conclusion that can be drawn is that relative labor allocations (as measured by primary divided by secondary sector employment) fall. What the variance of relative labor allocations does, cannot be determined without additional assumptions (which he does not specify). Alternative explanation One alternative explanation of AY s supposed findings, beyond those already offered immediately above, is the following. The reform period began with price increases for agricultural products mandated by the central government. Industrial relative to agricultural prices fell near-continuously from 100 in 1978 to 56.1 in 1997. Alternatively, the implicit deflator of the primary sector in the national income accounts stood at 549 in 1997 (up from 100 in 1978), that of industry at 234 and that of the secondary sector in total (covering industry and construction) at 254. 1 I.e., the planning period anti-agriculture price scissors (also noted by AY, p. 1096) decreased or disappeared. Due to this relative price rise in agriculture, with the primary sector in the nominator, relative nominal labor productivity rises. This rise is further helped by 1 For the industry-agriculture comparison see Statistical Yearbook 1998, p. 302. The index is the general price parity index of industrial and agricultural products gongnongye shangpin zonghe bijia zhishu. (Industry and construction constitute the secondary sector; in 1978, construction accounted for 7.92% of secondary sector value added, and in 1997 for 12.92% (Statistical Yearbook 2005, p. 51).) For the national income accounts data see Statistical Yearbook 2005, pp. 51, 54. Carsten A. Holz, 3 January 2008 2

the transfer of labor from primary to secondary sector, but retarded by increasing relative real output in the secondary relative to the primary sector. Figure 1a shows the rise in average relative nominal labor productivity as well as in its dispersion between 1978 and 1997. An increase in dispersion can simply come about through a nationwide uniform upward percentage change in relative nominal labor productivities across provinces. Or it could come about through differential price changes, possibly imposed by the center. Economic development with increasing industrialization and tertiary sector development implies a transfer of labor out of the primary sector and into the other two sectors. Figure 1b illustrates the fall in average primary vs. secondary sector labor allocation between 1978 and 1997 and also suggests a decrease in dispersion, especially after excluding the outlier Tibet. (The lesser outlier of Jilin in Figure 1a makes no significant difference to the conclusion on the variance of relative nominal labor productivities.) In the paper I consequently make the point that the variance of relative labor allocations decreases, as seen in the figure here, in contrast to the variance of the ln of the relative labor allocations. If there were any need to provide an argument for an increase in the variance of relative labor allocations: the variance could increase if provinces development speed differed significantly. Or it could fall, as it actually does, in contrast to AY s reading of the data, if, for example, the starting point is a nationally distorted production structure that gives rise to catching up effects. Time series values for China Figure 2 reports the time series values of the variances and covariances of the natural logarithm (as in AY s presentation) for the primary vs. secondary sector ratios. The natural logarithm findings are not only sensitive to the time period chosen but also to the choice of sectors. 2 Figure 3 reports the time series values of the variances and covariances of the natural logarithm (as in AY s presentation). In the period 1987-99, the variance of the nominal output ratio decreases from 0.18 to 0.09, the variance of relative labor productivities is almost unchanged at 0.04 and 0.06, relative labor allocations decrease from 0.16 to 0.11, and the covariance at negative 0.01 and negative 0.04 is near-zero in the two years. Following AY s logic, this is a pattern of decreasing trade barriers. The absolute values in Figure 2 (mirroring the data presented by AY) differ from those of AY in his selected years for reasons that I do not know. AY s Lotus files are available on his website, but my Lotus program is unable to open them (the files appear created in a more recent version); similarly, Excel (recent version on Windows XP, or approx. 1998 version on Windows 98) cannot open them; StatTransfer 7 cannot read them; our department computer technician also had no success. 2 AY only mentions in passing relative output of primary to secondary industry, two predominantly tradable sectors (pp. 1116f.). I do not understand in how far tradability for both sectors is needed. At any rate, only about 20-40% of all grain produced in China is actually traded and much of this trade could occur very locally (see Carsten Holz, 2006, Appendix 13); i.e., AY s predominantly tradable primary sector possibly involves very little trade. In as far as much of the labor flow between secondary and tertiary sector is likely to happen in urban areas, the household registration system is less likely to obstruct such flows. Carsten A. Holz, 3 January 2008 3

Carsten A. Holz, 3 January 2008 4

1997 0.40 0.35 0.30 0.25 0.20 0.15 0.10 0.05 (a) Relative labor productivity Jilin 0.00 0.00 0.05 0.10 0.15 0.20 0.25 0.30 0.35 0.40 1978 1997 16 15 14 13 12 11 10 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1 0 (b) Relative labor allocation Tibet 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 1978 For data sources see the first table in the paper, with the second source for the 1997 labor data. The values are not in logarithmic form. Figure 1. Ratios of Primary to. Secondary Sector 0.8 0.7 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 Var. output ratio Var. labor prod. ratio Var. labor ratio Cov. labor prod. r., labor r. 0.1 0.0-0.1-0.2-0.3 1978 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 For data sources see Table 1 in the paper. Tianjin is always excluded, and 1979-83 values are without Tibet. For the two variations of each series in 1995-98 see notes to Table 1 in the paper on the two labor series, and the appendix on labor data. Figure 2. Variance/Covariance of the Natural Logarithm of Primary Vs. Secondary Sector Ratios Carsten A. Holz, 3 January 2008 5

0.2 0.1 0.1 0.0-0.1 Var. output ratio Var. labor prod. ratio Var. labor ratio Cov. labor prod. r., labor r. -0.1 1978 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 For data sources see Table 1 in the paper. Tianjin is always excluded, and 1979-83 values are without Tibet. For the two variations of each series in 1995-98 see notes to Table 1 in the paper on the two labor series, and the appendix on labor data. Figure 3. Variance/Covariance of the Natural Logarithm of Secondary Vs. Tertiary Sector Ratios Carsten A. Holz, 3 January 2008 6