Residential segregation and socioeconomic outcomes When did ghettos go bad?

Similar documents
Ghettos and the Transmission of Ethnic Capital. David M. Cutler Edward L. Glaeser. Harvard University and NBER. Jacob L. Vigdor* Duke University

Housing Segregation and Earnings: Identifying Regional Differences over Time

When Are Ghettos Bad? Lessons from Immigrant Segregation In the United States

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES RACE AND HOME OWNERSHIP FROM THE CIVIL WAR TO THE PRESENT. William J. Collins Robert A. Margo

I ll marry you if you get me a job Marital assimilation and immigrant employment rates

The Effect of Ethnic Residential Segregation on Wages of Migrant Workers in Australia

Volume 35, Issue 1. An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach

ARE GHETTOS GOOD OR BAD?*

John Parman Introduction. Trevon Logan. William & Mary. Ohio State University. Measuring Historical Residential Segregation. Trevon Logan.

I'll Marry You If You Get Me a Job: Marital Assimilation and Immigrant Employment Rates

Neighborhood Segregation and Black Entrepreneurship

The Effect of Ethnic Residential Segregation on Wages of Migrant Workers in Australia

The Rise and Decline of the American Ghetto

The Employment of Low-Skilled Immigrant Men in the United States

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES HOMEOWNERSHIP IN THE IMMIGRANT POPULATION. George J. Borjas. Working Paper

SEVERE DISTRESS AND CONCENTRATED POVERTY: TRENDS FOR NEIGHBORHOODS IN CASEY CITIES AND THE NATION

Research Report. How Does Trade Liberalization Affect Racial and Gender Identity in Employment? Evidence from PostApartheid South Africa

Revisiting Residential Segregation by Income: A Monte Carlo Test

The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 112, No. 3. (Aug., 1997), pp

Benefit levels and US immigrants welfare receipts

Are Suburban Firms More Likely to Discriminate Against African Americans?

INEQUALITY AND THE MEASUREMENT OF RESIDENTIAL SEGREGATION BY INCOME IN AMERICAN NEIGHBORHOODS. by Tara Watson*

The Brookings Institution Metropolitan Policy Program Bruce Katz, Director

Race, Gender, and Residence: The Influence of Family Structure and Children on Residential Segregation. September 21, 2012.

Part 1: Focus on Income. Inequality. EMBARGOED until 5/28/14. indicator definitions and Rankings

Migration, Poverty & Place in the Context of the Return Migration to the US South

Labor Market Dropouts and Trends in the Wages of Black and White Men

HOUSEHOLD TYPE, ECONOMIC DISADVANTAGE, AND RESIDENTIAL SEGREGATION: EMPIRICAL PATTERNS AND FINDINGS FROM SIMULATION ANALYSIS.

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES WHITE SUBURBANIZATION AND AFRICAN-AMERICAN HOME OWNERSHIP, Leah Platt Boustan Robert A. Margo

The Effects of Housing Prices, Wages, and Commuting Time on Joint Residential and Job Location Choices

Cities, Skills, and Inequality

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES MEXICAN ENTREPRENEURSHIP: A COMPARISON OF SELF-EMPLOYMENT IN MEXICO AND THE UNITED STATES

Analyzing the effects of residential segregation on socioeconomic. outcomes among minorities.

APPENDIX H. Success of Businesses in the Dane County Construction Industry

High Technology Agglomeration and Gender Inequalities

Stuart A. Gabriel and Gary D. Painter* Abstract. In a paper published in The Review of Economics and Statistics some 20 years ago, we sought to

The Rise of the Black Middle Class and Declines in Black-White Segregation, *

The Rise and Decline of the American Ghetto. David M. Cutler and Edward L. Glaeser

Labor Market Performance of Immigrants in Early Twentieth-Century America

Segregation in Motion: Dynamic and Static Views of Segregation among Recent Movers. Victoria Pevarnik. John Hipp

Black Immigrant Residential Segregation: An Investigation of the Primacy of Race in Locational Attainment Rebbeca Tesfai Temple University

Relationships between the Growth of Ethnic Groups and Socioeconomic Conditions in US Metropolitan Areas

The Immigrant Double Disadvantage among Blacks in the United States. Katharine M. Donato Anna Jacobs Brittany Hearne

furmancenter.org WORKING PAPER Desvinculado y Desigual: Is Segregation Harmful to Latinos?

Segregation and Employment in Swedish Regions

The Effect of Integration: A Study on the Impact of Diversity on Economic Indicators

Immigrant-native wage gaps in time series: Complementarities or composition effects?

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES RACE, SEGREGATION, AND POSTAL EMPLOYMENT: NEW EVIDENCE ON SPATIAL MISMATCH. Leah Platt Boustan Robert A.

Self-employed immigrants and their employees: Evidence from Swedish employer-employee data

by William J. Collins and Robert A. Margo

Economic assimilation of Mexican and Chinese immigrants in the United States: is there wage convergence?

Inequality in Labor Market Outcomes: Contrasting the 1980s and Earlier Decades

Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US

The Causes of Wage Differentials between Immigrant and Native Physicians

Latin American Immigration in the United States: Is There Wage Assimilation Across the Wage Distribution?

English Deficiency and the Native-Immigrant Wage Gap

Customer Discrimination and Employment Outcomes for Minority Workers. Harry J. Holzer Michigan State University address:

Chapter 5. Residential Mobility in the United States and the Great Recession: A Shift to Local Moves

George J. Borjas Harvard University. September 2008

Does Residence in an Ethnic Community Help Immigrants in a Recession? Cathy Yang Liu Georgia State University

Determinants of Return Migration to Mexico Among Mexicans in the United States

Measuring Residential Segregation

RESIDENTIAL LOCATION, WORKPLACE LOCATION, AND BLACK EARNINGS

The Impact of Licensing Decentralization on Firm Location Choice: the Case of Indonesia

Was the Late 19th Century a Golden Age of Racial Integration?

The Misunderstood Consequences of Shelley v. Kraemer Extended Abstract

Pulling Open the Sticky Door

South Americans Chinese

ARTICLE IN PRESS. JID:YJUEC AID:2667 /FLA [m5g; v 1.53; Prn:2/09/2008; 9:03] P.1 (1-10) Journal of Urban Economics ( )

PROJECTING THE LABOUR SUPPLY TO 2024

Individual and Community Effects on Immigrant Naturalization. John R. Logan Sookhee Oh Jennifer Darrah. Brown University

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES WHITE SUBURBANIZATION AND AFRICAN-AMERICAN HOME OWNERSHIP, Leah Platt Boustan Robert A. Margo

Take the Money and Run: Economic Segregation in U.S. Metropolitan Areas. Paul A. Jargowsky School of Social Sciences University of Texas at Dallas

Ethnic Enclave Residence and Employment Accessibility of Latino Workers in Chicago, Los Angeles and Washington, D.C.

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES MAKING IT IN AMERICA: SOCIAL MOBILITY IN THE IMMIGRANT POPULATION. George J. Borjas

Unequal Recovery, Labor Market Polarization, Race, and 2016 U.S. Presidential Election. Maoyong Fan and Anita Alves Pena 1

Michael Haan, University of New Brunswick Zhou Yu, University of Utah

Racial Differences in Adult Labor Force Transition Trends

Firm racial segregation and affirmative action in the highway construction industry

Rural and Urban Migrants in India:

Union Members and Gainful Workers in Los Angeles, 1930 to 1950

Are Suburban Firms More Likely to Discriminate Against African-Americans?

Metropolitan Growth and Neighborhood Segregation by Income. Tara Watson Williams College November 2005

The Brookings Institution Metropolitan Policy Program Bruce Katz, Director

FOREIGN FIRMS AND INDONESIAN MANUFACTURING WAGES: AN ANALYSIS WITH PANEL DATA

Explaining differences in access to home computers and the Internet: A comparison of Latino groups to other ethnic and racial groups

Does segregation matter for Latinos?

Characteristics of Poverty in Minnesota

Labor Force patterns of Mexican women in Mexico and United States. What changes and what remains?

Racial Wage Disparity in US Cities

NST TUTE FOR RESEARCHON

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES. THE WAGE GAINS OF AFRICAN-AMERICAN WOMEN IN THE 1940s. Martha J. Bailey William J. Collins

Does Owner-Occupied Housing Affect Neighbourhood Crime?

Rural and Urban Migrants in India:

The Decline in Earnings of Childhood Immigrants in the U.S.

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES EMPLOYMENT IN BLACK URBAN LABOR MARKETS: PROBLEMS AND SOLUTIONS. Judith K. Hellerstein David Neumark

Business Cycles, Migration and Health

Black-White Segregation, Discrimination, and Home Ownership

Language Proficiency and Earnings of Non-Official Language. Mother Tongue Immigrants: The Case of Toronto, Montreal and Quebec City

Cracks in the Melting Pot: Immigration, School Choice, and Segregation *

Transcription:

Economics Letters 69 (2000) 239 243 www.elsevier.com/ locate/ econbase Residential segregation and socioeconomic outcomes When did ghettos go bad? * William J. Collins, Robert A. Margo Vanderbilt University and National Bureau of Economic Research, Box 35-B, Nashville, TN 37235, USA Received 20 December 1999; accepted 25 April 2000 Abstract Cutler and Glaeser (1997) show that urban residential segregation has a strong adverse effect on labor market and social outcomes of young African-Americans relative to whites. We show that this effect is a fairly recent historical phenomenon. There is little evidence of such an effect from 1940 to 1970; rather, it emerged between 1970 and 1980, and it grew stronger during the 1980s. 2000 Elsevier Science S.A. All rights reserved. Keywords: Race; Segregation; Ghetto JEL classification: R00; J15; I30 1. Introduction Racially or ethnically segregated communities of minorities may either promote or hamper the 1 economic well-being of their residents (Cutler and Glaeser, 1997). By maintaining neighborhoods that are integrated across income groups, ghettos could benefit lower-income minorities who would otherwise be residentially isolated (Handlin, 1959; Glazer and Moynihan, 1963; Wilson, 1987). On the other hand, such physical separation could impede a group s economic progress through adverse cultural, peer, or neighborhood effects, spatial mismatch between jobs and residential locations, and inadequate provision of local public goods (Kain, 1968; Case and Katz, 1991; Borjas, 1995; Glaeser et al., 1996). In the end, whether ghettos are good or bad is an empirical question. Using census data for 1990, Cutler and Glaeser (1997) find substantial adverse effects of segregation on a variety of socioeconomic outcomes for African-Americans. In this paper we apply Cutler and Glaeser s *Corresponding author. Tel.: 1 1-615-322-3428; fax: 1 1-615-343-8495. E-mail address: william.collins@vanderbilt.edu (W.J. Collins). 1 Following Cutler and Glaeser, we use the term ghetto to refer to racially or ethnically segregated minority communities. 0165-1765/ 00/ $ see front matter 2000 Elsevier Science S.A. All rights reserved. PII: S0165-1765(00)00300-1

240 W.J. Collins, R.A. Margo / Economics Letters 69 (2000) 239 243 methodology to census data from 1940 to 1980. In contrast to their results, we generally find little or no evidence that segregation was associated with idleness or single motherhood prior to 1970; rather, 2 the bad effects of ghettos appear to have emerged in the 1970s, and then intensified in the 1980s. 2. Data and Results Following Cutler and Glaeser, we focus our attention on socioeconomic outcomes of people between 20 and 30 years of age who reside in metropolitan areas. For 1940, 1950, 1970, 1980, and 1990 we extracted people of those ages from the IPUMS (Integrate Public Use Microdata Series) 3 samples of census data. The outcomes of interest are idleness, annual income, and children born to 4 never-married women. For comparability, our specification mimics that of Cutler and Glaeser (1997). We regress an outcome variable on a variety of metropolitan area characteristics (proportion of labor force in manufacturing, proportion of population that is black, median household income, size of population, and level of segregation), interactions of each of the metro area variables with race 5 (black 5 1), and age dummies. The key coefficient is the interaction of the segregation measure and race, the sign of which indicates whether segregation has a significantly different effect (positive or negative) on blacks relative to whites. Although it is plausible on a priori grounds that the segregation measure is endogenous, Cutler and Glaeser (1997) demonstrate that ordinary least squares (OLS) and instrumental variable estimates of the interaction effect are virtually identical. Consequently, only 6 OLS results are reported in this paper. Table 1 reports the coefficients of the interaction variable for the different socioeconomic outcomes. Panel A includes all cities for which information on the metro variables is available, whereas Panel B includes only those cities (42 in number) for which Cutler, Glaeser, and Vigdor (1999) report segregation indices in every year. For discrete outcomes (idleness, single motherhood) we report 2 After this paper was submitted for publication, we became aware of Vigdor (1999) which also argues that the adverse effects of ghettos are a relatively recent phenomenon. 3 The 1960 microdata sample does not identify metropolitan areas and so that year cannot be used in this paper. 4 Individuals are idle if they are neither in school nor employed. We do not analyze educational attainment because a large proportion of blacks resided in areas other than those in which they were educated, especially in the 1940 and 1950 data. For the analysis of income, we restrict the sample to wage and salary workers who were employed during the census week, not in school, and who reported positive wage and salary income in the previous year. Because the 1940 census only reports wage and salary income, we use this income measure in each year for the sake of comparability. The results for the other years are similar if total income is used instead. Single mothers are those who have never been married but have had a child. Data to construct this variable are not available in 1940 and 1950. 5 See Table 1 for data sources. Segregation is measured using a dissimilarity index based on the distribution of people across census tracts within a city or metropolitan area. The measure lies between 0 and 1, and higher values correspond to higher levels of segregation. 6 Given that we are most interested in the coefficient s change over time, only a changing OLS bias would confound our interpretation of the findings. There are three slight differences between our approach and Cutler and Glaeser s: first, our samples include only whites and blacks (not Asians or other nonwhites); second, our samples include only men or only women, not both; and third, we group 20 30-year-olds together whereas Cutler and Glaeser separate 20 24-year-olds from 25 30-year-olds. The substantive findings are not affected by these differences.

W.J. Collins, R.A. Margo / Economics Letters 69 (2000) 239 243 241 Table 1 Segregation and socioeconomic outcomes: Coefficients of black 3 segregation interaction 1940 1950 1970 1980 1990 Panel A: All available cities Idleness 20.1264 20.1949 0.0529 0.2095 0.5287 (0.1508) (0.2390) (0.0785) (0.0636) (0.0580) Wage and salary income 20.3151 20.4058 0.0622 20.1146 20.5649 (0.1778) (0.3215) (0.1560) (0.1093) (0.1237) Single motherhood n.a.. n.a. 0.0255 0.1760 0.4573 (0.0479) (0.0547) (0.0414) Panel B: Overlapping sample of cities Idleness 20.1211 20.4062 0.0556 0.0805 0.3010 (0.1667) (0.3089) (0.1055) (0.1245) (0.1121) Wage and salary income 20.3916 21.0024 20.1467 20.1517 20.7371 (0.1697) (0.3552) (0.1790) (0.2280) (0.3657) Single motherhood n.a. n.a 20.0786 20.0390 0.5136 (0.0788) (0.1096) (0.0686) a Notes: The table reports the coefficients and standard errors (in parentheses) on the black3segregation interaction from a series of regressions. Each regression also includes: the metropolitan area s proportion of labor force in manufacturing, proportion of population that is black, segregation level, and median family or household income; interactions of each metropolitan area variable with the black indicator; and dummies for each year of age. In 1950, 30 year-olds are excluded because the school attendance variable is available only for those under 30. In 1940, 1950, and 1990, person weights from the IPUMS are used in the regressions; 1970 and 1980 samples do not require weights. According to availability, median family wage and salary income is used to calculate each city s median income in 1940; median family total income is used in 1950 and 1970; median household total income is used in 1980 and 1990. The overlapping sample of cities are those cities for which segregation and population measures are available for every year from Cutler et al., 1999. Standard errors are adjusted for heteroskedasticity and clustering within metropolitan areas. From 1940 to 1980 top-coded incomes are multiplied by 1.4. In 1990, for each observation with top-coded income, the IPUMS assigns the median value of top-coded incomes in the state of residence. The full set of regression results are available upon request. Sources: Individual data are from the IPUMS (Ruggles and Sobek). Some metropolitan area variables (percent black, median income, and manufacturing) are calculated using the IPUMS samples. Other metropolitan area variables (dissimilarity indices for segregation, city population figures) are from Cutler, Glaeser, and Vigdor (1999). Metropolitan area codes from Cutler, Glaeser, and Vigdor (1999) are amended when necessary (and possible) to match the metropolitan area codes of the IPUMS. a 7 linear probability estimates of the coefficients. The analysis of idleness and incomes reported in this paper is restricted to males. For all three outcomes we were able to confirm Cutler and Glaeser s (1997) findings for 1990; namely, higher levels of segregation were associated with greater idleness, lower incomes, and an increased incidence of single motherhood among African-Americans. However, the results for the other census years are generally quite different. Except for incomes in 1940 and 1950 in the Panel B sample of cities, there is little or no evidence that segregation was positively related to idleness and single motherhood prior to 1980. By 1980, however, segregation was positively associated with 7 Probit analysis yields similar results.

242 W.J. Collins, R.A. Margo / Economics Letters 69 (2000) 239 243 idleness and single motherhood, though the effects are statistically significant only in the Panel A sample. 3. Discussion The primary purpose of this paper has been to document that the ghettos-are-bad conclusion is a comparatively recent historical phenomenon. Here we speculate about some of the factors that may have caused the correlation between segregation and socioeconomic outcomes to reverse direction, leaving a fuller analysis of causality to future work. Ironically, the Civil Rights Movement and its attendant anti-discrimination legislation may be one such factor. Prior to the ending of dejure and customary segregation in public accommodations, restaurants, and access to retail establishments in the 1960s, African-Americans in urban areas conducted most of their economic transactions in racially segregated markets that were essentially coterminous with racially segregated residential neighborhoods. The demise of segregation in economic life greatly widened the consumption choices available to (middle-class) blacks, but also reduced the demand for the services of black-owned businesses and, eventually, the (relative) demand for urban black labor. Role model effects that are correlated with segregation may be a second factor. Partly as a consequence of the positive correlation between income and suburban residence, the average black person may now have less contact with better educated people (of both races) than previously. Consistent with this hypothesis, Cutler and Glaeser (1997), p. 862, show that an index of education exposure for blacks (greater than zero if blacks are residentially concentrated with more educated people, and negative if the reverse were true) in 1990 was higher in cities with lower levels of segregation. Third, post-war suburbanization may have increased average commuting times for blacks, which Cutler and Glaeser show is positively correlated with idleness and negatively correlated with wages (1997, p. 863). Jackson (1985) and Collins and Margo (2000) discuss the role of government policy in promoting suburban residence and home ownership for whites relative to blacks. Increases over time in the proportion of single mothers may have important intergenerational consequences, as Cutler and Glaeser (1997), p. 863, have shown that a higher incidence of single motherhood among older black women raises the incidence among younger black women (see also Wilson, 1987). Also over time, increases in crime, particularly crime associated with illegal drugs, may have been an important factor behind the emergence of a positive correlation between idleness and segregation. Another factor worth investigating is rising wage inequality. It is well-known that rising wage inequality has been associated with a slowdown in black white wage convergence and declining labor force participation among males in the 1980s (Juhn et al., 1991). Finally, our results suggest that whatever the explanatory power of any of the factors listed above, a full explanation will have to account for the somewhat different timing of change between the Panel A and Panel B samples of cities. That is, for a constant sample of relatively large cities (Panel B), ghettos turn bad in the 1980s, whereas adding new cities to the sample in each census year (Panel A) suggests that the negative effects of segregation emerged in the 1970s.

W.J. Collins, R.A. Margo / Economics Letters 69 (2000) 239 243 243 Acknowledgements This work was made possible by the historical data on residential segregation compiled by David Cutler, Edward Glaeser, and Jacob Vigdor (1999). We appreciate their willingness to share the data. References Borjas, G., 1995. Ethnicity, neighborhoods, and human capital externalities. American Economic Review 85, 365 390. Case, A., Katz, L., 1991. The company you keep: The effect of family and neighborhood on disadvantaged youth. NBER Working Paper 3705. Collins, W.J., Margo, R.A., 2000. Race and home ownership: A century-long view. Explorations in Economic History, forthcoming. Cutler, D.M., Glaeser, E.L., 1997. Are ghettos good or bad? Quarterly Journal of Economics 112, 827 872. Cutler, D.M., Glaeser, E.L., Vigdor, J.L., 1999. The rise and decline of the American ghetto. Journal of Political Economy 107, 455 506. Glaeser, E., Sacerdote, B., Scheinkman, J., 1996. Crime and social interactions. Quarterly Journal of Economics III, 508 548. Glazer, N., Moynihan, D., 1963. Beyond the Melting Pot. MIT Press, Cambridge MA. Handlin, O., 1959. The Uprooted. Harvard University Press, Cambridge MA. Jackson, K.T., 1985. Crabgrass Frontier: The Suburbanization of the United States. Oxford University Press, New York. Juhn, C., Murphy, K.M., Pierce, B., 1991. Accounting for the slowdown in black white wage convergence. In: Kosters, M. (Ed.), Workers and their Wages: Changing Patterns in the United States. AEI Press, Washington, DC, pp. 107 143. Kain, J., 1968. Housing segregation, Negro employment, and metropolitan decentralization. Quarterly Journal of Economics 82, 175 197. Vigdor, J.L., 1999. Locations, outcomes, and selective migration. Unpublished paper, Terry Sanford Institute of Public Policy, Duke University. Wilson, W., 1987. The Truly Disadvantaged: The Inner City, the Underclass, and Public Policy. University of Chicago Press, Chicago.