Chapter 6 Online Appendix. general these issues do not cause significant problems for our analysis in this chapter. One

Similar documents
Introduction Why Don t Electoral Rules Have the Same Effects in All Countries?

Social Diversity Affects the Number of Parties Even under First-Past-the-Post Rules. October 26, 2015 ***Please do not cite without permission***

Part Three (continued): Electoral Systems & Linkage Institutions

Political Sophistication and Third-Party Voting in Recent Presidential Elections

Political Sophistication and Third-Party Voting in Recent Presidential Elections

Voting for Parties or for Candidates: Do Electoral Institutions Make a Difference?

Incumbency as a Source of Spillover Effects in Mixed Electoral Systems: Evidence from a Regression-Discontinuity Design.

! # % & ( ) ) ) ) ) +,. / 0 1 # ) 2 3 % ( &4& 58 9 : ) & ;; &4& ;;8;

1. The Relationship Between Party Control, Latino CVAP and the Passage of Bills Benefitting Immigrants

Mixed electoral systems and electoral system effects: controlled comparison and crossnational

Governance Issues under Japan s MMM: Intraparty Divisions, Winner-Take-All Stakes, & Bicameralism

Julie Lenggenhager. The "Ideal" Female Candidate

Reading the local runes:

Partisan Advantage and Competitiveness in Illinois Redistricting

Ticket-splitting and strategic voting under mixed electoral rules: Evidence from Germany

The Relative Electoral Impact of Central Party Co-ordination and Size of Party Membership at Constituency Level

Ohio State University

Experiments in Election Reform: Voter Perceptions of Campaigns Under Preferential and Plurality Voting

Electoral Systems and Evaluations of Democracy

Supplementary Materials for Strategic Abstention in Proportional Representation Systems (Evidence from Multiple Countries)

The Center for Voting and Democracy

ELITE AND MASS ATTITUDES ON HOW THE UK AND ITS PARTS ARE GOVERNED VOTING AT 16 WHAT NEXT? YEAR OLDS POLITICAL ATTITUDES AND CIVIC EDUCATION

Luck of the Draw? Members Bills, the Electoral Connection & Party List Placement

The California Primary and Redistricting

The Case of the Disappearing Bias: A 2014 Update to the Gerrymandering or Geography Debate

BCGEU surveyed its own members on electoral reform. They reported widespread disaffection with the current provincial electoral system.

Chapter 3. The Evidence. deposition would have to develop to generate the facts and figures necessary to establish an

A positive correlation between turnout and plurality does not refute the rational voter model

Leaders, voters and activists in the elections in Great Britain 2005 and 2010

For 40 years after Germany adopted its mixed-member electoral system,

Understanding Taiwan Independence and Its Policy Implications

Compare the vote Level 1

Strategic Voting In British Elections

CHOICE VOTING: ONE YEAR LATER

Compare the vote Level 3

Why are there only two major parties in US? [party attachments below]

The Cook Political Report / LSU Manship School Midterm Election Poll

Supplementary Material for Preventing Civil War: How the potential for international intervention can deter conflict onset.

REFORMING THE ELECTORAL FORMULA IN PEI: THE CASE FOR DUAL-MEMBER MIXED PROPORTIONAL Sean Graham

Of the 73 MEPs elected on 22 May in Great Britain and Northern Ireland 30 (41 percent) are women.

The psychological and mechanical effects of voting rules. Evidence from the Romanian parliamentary elections

Local Government Elections 2017

CALTECH/MIT VOTING TECHNOLOGY PROJECT A

CAN FAIR VOTING SYSTEMS REALLY MAKE A DIFFERENCE?

Electoral Studies. Strategic coalition voting: Evidence from Austria. Michael F. Meffert a, *, Thomas Gschwend b,1. abstract

Following the Leader: The Impact of Presidential Campaign Visits on Legislative Support for the President's Policy Preferences

Punishment or Protest? Understanding European Parliament Elections

The Determinants of Low-Intensity Intergroup Violence: The Case of Northern Ireland. Online Appendix

Chapter Four: Chamber Competitiveness, Political Polarization, and Political Parties

International Perspective on Representation Japan s August 2009 Parliamentary Elections By Pauline Lejeune with Rob Richie

Random tie-breaking in STV

The impact of different voting systems on the type of government, party representation and voter choice

BY Amy Mitchell, Katie Simmons, Katerina Eva Matsa and Laura Silver. FOR RELEASE JANUARY 11, 2018 FOR MEDIA OR OTHER INQUIRIES:

Wasted Votes: A Conceptual Synthesis and Generalization to the Case of PR Elections*

Electoral Reform: Making Every Vote Count Equally

Iowa Voting Series, Paper 4: An Examination of Iowa Turnout Statistics Since 2000 by Party and Age Group

Kim Lane Scheppele, Princeton University

Congruence in Political Parties

THE U.S. POLITICAL SYSTEM AND THE 2014 MIDTERM ELECTION. Hans Noel Georgetown University bit.ly/hansnoel

Abstract. Keywords. Single Transferable Vote; Voter Competence; Ballot Order Effect; Scotland; Ireland

Federal Primary Election Runoffs and Voter Turnout Decline,

Appendix for: The Electoral Implications. of Coalition Policy-Making

Rural America Competitive Bush Problems and Economic Stress Put Rural America in play in 2008

What is The Probability Your Vote will Make a Difference?

Incumbency Effects and the Strength of Party Preferences: Evidence from Multiparty Elections in the United Kingdom

Government and Politics

UK Election Results and Economic Prospects. By Tony Brown 21 July 2017

Comparing the Data Sets

Retrospective Voting

Who s to Blame? Punishing Poor Economic Performance in a Centralized Political System

The Local Elections. Media Briefing Pack. 18 th April, 2012

Do Ethnic Parties Exclude Women?

Analysis of local election results data for Wales 2004 (including turnout and extent of postal voting)

The best of both worlds or institutionalising electoral lottery?

Do Self-Identified Tactical Voters Actually Vote Tactically? What Tactical Voting Meant (and Didn t Mean) To British Voters in the 2010 Election

Electoral Reform in Bermuda. Ron Johnston, University of Bristol 1 Clive Payne, Nuffield College, Oxford 2

Why Wales Said Yes The 2011 Referendum. Roger Scully Aberystwyth, 24 th June 2011

4 However, devolution would have better served the people of Wales if a better voting system had been used. At present:

Iowa Voting Series, Paper 6: An Examination of Iowa Absentee Voting Since 2000

ANES Panel Study Proposal Voter Turnout and the Electoral College 1. Voter Turnout and Electoral College Attitudes. Gregory D.

Electoral Reform Questionnaire Field Dates: October 12-18, 2016

Support for Peaceable Franchise Extension: Evidence from Japanese Attitude to Demeny Voting. August Very Preliminary

British Election Leaflet Project - Data overview

THE SOUTH AUSTRALIAN LEGISLATIVE COUNCIL: POSSIBLE CHANGES TO ITS ELECTORAL SYSTEM

To What Extent Are Canadians Exposed to Low-Income?

Towards a hung Parliament? The battleground of the 2017 UK general election

Should I stay or should I go? An experimental study on voter responses to pre-electoral coalitions

The Case of the Disappearing Bias: A 2014 Update to the Gerrymandering or Geography Debate

Georg Lutz, Nicolas Pekari, Marina Shkapina. CSES Module 5 pre-test report, Switzerland

Second Order Electoral Rules and National Party Systems The Duvergerian effects of European Parliament elections

Designing for Equality

Supplemental Appendices

Can a party school be sophisticated? Citizen preferences for Electoral College reform. Jason Reifler Georgia State University

PARTISAN POLARIZATION DOMINATES TRUMP ERA FINDINGS FROM THE 2018 AMERICAN VALUES SURVEY

Where does Macron s success come from? A look at electoral shifts with an eye on the legislative elections

Chapter 6 Democratic Regimes. Copyright 2015 W.W. Norton, Inc.

Fair Division in Theory and Practice

Case Study: Get out the Vote

FOR RELEASE APRIL 26, 2018

The 2014 Election in Aiken County: The Sales Tax Proposal for Public Schools

Transcription:

Chapter 6 Online Appendix Potential shortcomings of SF-ratio analysis Using SF-ratios to understand strategic behavior is not without potential problems, but in general these issues do not cause significant problems for our analysis in this chapter. One potential problem with using SF-ratios to understand strategic behavior is that they cannot demonstrate who the key actors are. An SF-ratio around zero does not tell us if voters have cast ballots strategically or if there has been a strategic desertion of the race by candidates. However, this issue does not worry us here. To begin with, it is a problem in most individual-level surveys of voters, as such surveys tend to focus purely on the set of choices available to voters, not how they would have behaved in the face of a different set of candidates and/or parties. In addition, our concern in this chapter is not who the key strategic actors are, but rather the conditions under which strategic behavior (in the form of strategic defection) is most likely. Cox (2001) raises another potential problem that the meaning of SF-ratio values can be ambiguous: A value of one might occur when (a) both the second and third loser are considered potentially strong candidates and so, therefore, voters abandon neither or (b) when both are truly minor candidates, neither of whom receives many votes. Again, we do not believe that this issue raises significant problems for our analysis because we include in our models a measure of the competitiveness of the race between first and second place, which therefore makes it possible for us to distinguish between the (a) and (b) types of SF-ratio values of one. The ecological inference problem is the most obvious disadvantage to any analysis that uses aggregated data to understand individual behavior. That is, it is impossible to know which individual voters within a large group are driving aggregate patterns and for what reasons. As a 1

result, it is not always possible to draw accurate inferences about individual-level voter behavior based on data that are put together simply by aggregating thousands of votes. 1 Just Looking at SF-ratios (not the multivariate analysis) Effect of Mixed System Tier Linkage on Strategic Defection? Looking simply at the SF-ratio patterns in Appendix 6A, we see only limited evidence to suggest that there will be more strategic defection under unlinked mixed system rules. As we noted earlier, it is likely that there will be less strategic defection from poorly ranked candidates in systems where seat totals are primarily dependent upon PR vote success in short, where strategic behavior in the SMD tier will be unlikely to alter the total number of seats a party will win. It is possible that the lack of clear SF-ratio patterns that we see in Scotland and Wales are a result of their linked systems (see Appendix 6A1). That being said, linked systems in Germany and New Zealand appear to demonstrate the same clear pattern of SF-ratios leaning toward zero in the SMD tier as is the case in unlinked systems such as Japan s. 2 At the same time, in order to determine whether SF-ratio patterns really are based on strategic behavior, we need to control for factors such as the closeness of the race. For example, in contrast to substantially closer races in later years, the average margin of victory in Germany in 1953 was 22 percentage points, leaving many uncompetitive districts where strategic defection made little sense. Analysis that takes into account previous outcomes 1 Of course, this is also an issue for the other major approach to studying strategic voting in mixed-member systems, 2 If anything, the SF-ratio pattern shifted toward zero more quickly in Germany and New Zealand than in Japan. 2

The main model (Model 2 in Table 6.1) we used to estimate the impact of the different variables on SF-ratios does not take into account how past results shape current ones. That is, presumably, all else being equal, there will be no change in the SF-ratio from election to election. For this reason, it is useful to examine the relationship between the SF-ratio and the different variables here once we also include the SF-ratio in the previous election as an explanatory variable. For reasons that we explain in Appendix 6B, we do not include this variable in determining Figure 6.3. But we do include it in Model 4 in Table 6.1. When we include the SFratio in the previous election as an explanatory variable, we no longer find a statistically discernible effect of the margin of victory in new democracies. In either case, close races in SMDs in new democracies do not appear to have the expected effect of driving down the SFratio. We should add that in this alternative model the effect of the margin of victory in established democracies variable becomes smaller, but remains statistically significant: All else being equal, races in which one candidate dominates the competition have an expected SF-ratio of.38, as compared to.28 in very close races. Voters and Elites In our discussion in this chapter, we highlight the strategic defection of both voters and elites. Strategic defection by voters i.e., voters shifting their support from their most preferred candidate to one who is more likely to be competitive is the most commonly discussed form of strategic electoral behavior. However, at least as important is the behavior of elites: Party leaders, campaign contributors, and candidates themselves are much less likely to support potentially uncompetitive candidates, thereby helping to winnow down the number of strong 3

candidates. At the same time, elite defections are predicated in part on anticipated voter defections. Thus, the aggregate behavior of voters is critical to sending both elites and voters a signal as to who is competitive, and voters strategic behavior therefore is very much a part of the electoral outcomes and party systems that emerge. Some evidence suggestive of strategic defection in mixed-member systems Past analysis of ticket splitting under mixed systems offers suggestive evidence of the existence of greater strategic defection under SMD rules. For example, looking at elections in five mixed-member systems in the 1990s, Moser and Scheiner (2000) find that the average first place candidate won anywhere from 3.4 (in Lithuania) to 11.7 (in Japan) percentage points more votes in her SMD than her party won votes under PR within the district. Strategic voting is frequently held up as one of the principal reasons for this ticket splitting (Bawn 1999; Cox 1997; Fisher 1973; Roberts 1988; Reed 1999). Most studies assume that votes cast in PR balloting usually represent voters true preferences, and that many of the extra SMD votes going to the top candidates in SMDs under mixed systems are strategic ballots cast by voters who want to affect the race. Moser and Scheiner (2000) find that a candidate s place in the SMD election has a substantial impact on the difference between her votes under SMD balloting and her party s vote under PR: In the 1990s, most winning and second place candidates in Germany (1998), Japan (1996), and New Zealand (1999) received a larger number of SMD votes in their district than their party did in the SMD in PR balloting. In contrast, third and worse placed candidates were markedly less likely to have a positive SMD-PR vote gap: In Germany, for example, only three percent of first place candidates, but 94.5 percent of fourth place candidates won fewer SMD 4

votes than their party won PR ballots. In contrast, very different ticket splitting patterns existed in Russia (1999), where there was relatively little difference in the percentage of candidates at different ranks with a smaller number of SMD than PR votes: 33.3 percent of first place candidates and 28.9 percent of fourth place candidates received fewer SMD votes than their party won PR ballots in the district (Moser and Scheiner 2000). The implication is that in established democracies there are large numbers of voters who defect strategically from their top choice under plurality rules. In contrast, there is less evidence of such a pattern in new democracies. Johnston and Pattie s analysis of split ticket voting in the initial elections under the mixed-member systems in New Zealand, Scotland, and Wales indicates that many electors will only vote a split ticket when they receive and are convinced by information suggesting that this is a sensible strategy (2002: 598). Evidence from Hungary (Duch and Palmer 2001) Benoit (2001) provides similar evidence of strategic voting in Hungary. Germany We should add that, there was no overwhelming mode in the SF-ratio patterns in SMDs in 1953 in Germany, the country s first election in the postwar period under the mixed-member system (see Appendix 6A1). With the shift toward 0 in 1957, it appears that over time voters and elites strategically moved away from SMD candidates who were ranked lower than second place. Germany is unique in that its SF-ratios in PR regularly have modes that push toward zero. That being said, it should be noted that these modes are still somewhat removed from the more 5

extreme zero position. Moreover, Germany is unique among mixed-member systems in having two large parties that have dominated the country s politics for many years. Most likely, all of these features are due in part to Germany s somewhat high (five percent) legal threshold of representation in the PR tier. Russia As noted in Chapters 1 and 3, the PR vote in Russia arguably provided more information in the form of voter surveys that showed the relative support for PR parties, and thus indicated that some of these parties were unlikely to overcome the five percent legal threshold. However, similar information was usually not available for local SMD races between candidates (see Moser 1999). Even in 2003, independent candidates did not cease to be a major part of Russian elections. In the last election held using a mixed-member system, 77 independent candidates won election, which was less than United Russia s 97 seats but greater than the total seats won by all other parties. Predicted Effect of Tier Linkage We should add that, given the substantial strategic defection that we saw in Chapter 5 in the German and New Zealand linked systems and the fact that all of the postcommunist countries in our data set use unlinked systems, we did not feel confident that our results would show evidence of the impact of linkage mechanisms on strategic defection. Including previous election in the analysis 6

We also run Model 4 (Table 6.1), which replicates Model 2 but with a control for autocorrelation. We include as an independent variable SF-ratio t-1, which was the SF-ratio in the district in the previous election. Presumably, to some degree the SF-ratio we see in a district is simply a function of the past: Voters continue to cast ballots similar to how they did in the previous election. We had not controlled for this in Model 2 because using a lagged dependent variable forces us to drop the first election under the mixed system in any country and we assumed that one of the greatest shifts in strategic behavior would be from the first to the second election. In addition, we were unable to guarantee that district boundaries stayed the same for a number of our cases, and therefore including the lagged dependent variable forces us to reduce our number of cases even more. Nevertheless, we thought it important to make sure that leaving out this variable did not especially bias our results and therefore run Model 4, which includes as an explanatory variable the SF-ratio (with a logit transformation) from the district in previous election. The lagged dependent variable (SF-ratio t-1) has a strongly positive and significant relationship with the SF-ratio in the current election, but the results for the other variables do not change markedly. The coefficients on the margin of victory variables are smaller, but they continue to indicate the same patterns as seen in Model 2. We see no evidence of strategic defection in new democracies (Margin of Victory is now non-significant), but see quite a bit in established democracies. Election Number (log) now has a non-significant coefficient, but we attribute this to the elimination of the first election because we cannot compute a lagged dependent variable for the first election from the analysis, when we expect the greatest difference in strategic behavior between the first two elections. Also, it may be inappropriate to use time t information on the closeness of the race to predict voters strategic behavior in the election at time t. For reasons that we outline in Chapter 7

5, we are not terribly concerned by this issue, but to do due diligence we run Model 5, which is the same as Model 4 but now measure closeness of the race by using the Margin of Victory in the district in the previous election. We also use this measure to create a new interaction term between Margin of Victory (previous election) and Established Democracy. Given that including these t-1 measures of the closeness of the race means that we must necessarily drop any cases for which we cannot calculate previous election results in the district, there is no longer a need to avoid using the lagged dependent variable, so we also include SF-ratio t-1 in the model. The substantive meaning of the results for Model 5 does not differ markedly from those in Model 2: We still see a lack of evidence of strategic defection in new democracies and still find substantial strategic defection in established democracies. Indeed, as Figure 6.5 illustrates, the impact of the closeness of the race appears to be even greater using the lagged measures from Model 5 rather than the time t measures from Model 2. Additional Models We also run two additional versions of the model, but do not include their results in Table 6.1. We were concerned that perhaps Germany s (many) later elections were exerting too much influence on our results, so we ran a model that drops all elections after the first 4 for any country. There were no major changes in results, although the coefficient on Unlinked became non-significant (but still is negative). Also, we ran a model that replaced Election Number (log) with a dichotomous dummy variable that indicated if the election was the first under the mixed system. Again, the results for our most important variables most notably, the Margin of Victory variables did not change much, but here, too, the coefficient on the linkage variable became non-significant (but still is negative). In short, these results suggest that our findings 8

about strategic voting are very robust, but that we can be less confident about the impact of the SMD-PR linkage rules on SF-ratios. Additional Detail on the Established Democracy Cases The most obvious exceptions to the pattern of established democracies quickly shifting toward SF-ratios near zero are Scotland and Wales, where, despite a long history of democratic elections, SF-ratio patterns tended to show no clear pattern. Four reasons appear to account for the lack of clear patterns in these two cases: The first reason is akin to Cox s (1997: 79) condition for Duvergerian outcomes that voters be short-term instrumentally rational. As we discuss in Chapter 5, in both Scotland and Wales, there was a general sense on the part of voters as time went on that it was the central U.K. government and not their own Scottish or Welsh assembly that was really in charge (Boon and Curtice 2003; ESRC 2003: 4; Glendinning and Scully 2003). For voters who felt this way, there was far less reason to try to use votes for the sake of policy representation. Second, more along the lines of our theoretical discussion above, in both Scotland and Wales surveys indicate that voters had very little sense of the differences between the parties (Boon and Curtice 2003: 4; Glendinning and Scully 2003: 6, 18). Lacking such information, voters faced relative difficulty casting strategic votes. The fact that the SFratios in both the SMD and PR tiers are roughly similar to one another in both Scotland and Wales suggests that many voters ultimately focused simply on casting sincere votes in the SMD tier (although the analysis in Chapter 5 suggests that many others cast personal votes for a different party s candidates). Third, the existence of important regionalist parties in the Plaid Cymru in Wales and the Scottish Nationalist Party may have undermined another of Cox s conditions for strategic defection: These parties probably enjoyed a higher level of core support 9

than other third parties, and their supporters stuck with them despite little likelihood of success because they saw little significant difference between the more competitive parties. Finally, our data set includes only the first two elections in Scotland and Wales, and it is possible that SFratio patterns shifted toward zero later. In Japan, the shift toward zero occurred relatively slowly as well, not occurring until 2003, the third election under the new system. This lag is probably a function of a number of factors. Among established democracies, Japan has a relatively weak party system in the sense that independent candidates make up a fairly large part of the system and voting is highly candidate-centered. As a result, parties were probably less capable of structuring vote choices than they might have been in other established democracies. In addition, from 1993 on, the Japanese party system was in flux, with many new parties entering and exiting the system (Scheiner 2006). Further muddying the water for voters and elites, a number of small parties ran in every election. Most notably, until 2007 the Japan Communist Party (JCP) had a policy of running a candidate in nearly every district (Baker and Scheiner 2004). Supporters of the Communist Party candidates tend to be neither short-term instrumentally rational nor much interested in casting ballots for a lesser of two evils, thus going against two key conditions that Cox argues are necessary for Duverger s Law to hold. However, over time, these smaller parties have had less of a presence. They have run in fewer districts and voters have gradually shifted away from voting for them. 10

Trichotomous Dependent Variable We also run two additional models in which the dependent variable is the SF-ratio for each district broken down into one of three SF-ratio categories: 0-.25,.25.-.75, and.75-1.0. We decided to group the data into these categories because we deemed changes across categories more meaningful (e.g., a change from.1 to.3) than changes within categories (e.g., a change from an SF-ratio of.4 to one of.6). Following the literature (especially Cox 1997), we used relatively demanding criteria for our two extreme categories so that the Duvergerian outcome of 0 and non-duvergerian outcome of 1 were smaller than the middle category in order to better distinguish our two extreme categories. To the best of our knowledge, the Linear Mixed Model we used to analyze our continuous dependent variable was not available for a discrete variable with more than two choices, so here we run a random effects ordered probit model, where the trichotomous variable categories represent three discrete values in an ascending order. We run this using Generalized linear latent and mixed models (GLLAMMs) in Stata. In many ways, this trichotomous measure that categorizes results as either close to 0, close to 1, or in the middle is a more reasonable one, as small shifts in SF-ratios may be fairly meaningless from the perspective of understanding strategic defection, but shifts between the categories may tell us quite a bit more. Ultimately, the Duvergerian logic hypothesizes a dramatic shift to nearly zero, given widespread strategic defection from parties that are out of the running (or corresponding elite strategic behavior that is in anticipation of such voter defection). Using this new dependent variable, we run Models 7 and 8 (not show, which, respectively, use the same explanatory variables as, Models 2 and 5. In Model 7, our variables are based on the new democracy/established democracy dichotomy, with Margin of Victory measured for the current election. As shown in Table 6.2, the results for Model 7 are largely the 11

same as in Model 2, but the coefficient on Margin of Victory is no longer significant. In other words, there is no discernible impact of the closeness of the race in new democracies. The results for Model 8 are also quite similar to those in Model 5. Using the t-1 measure of Margin of Victory and a t-1 measure of the SF-ratio in the district, most of the variables remain statistically significant. However, again, closeness of the race (now lagged) is no longer statistically significant. [Table 6.2 about here] Given these results, we argue that the more difficult (and arguably telling) test of strategic voting a shift from middling SF-ratios to extreme ones correspond to our general argument that there is substantial evidence of strategic defection in established democracies but not in new ones. 12

Table 6.2: Random Effects Ordered Probit Model of Correlates of Trichotomous SF-ratio (7) Estab. vs. New (8) Lagged DV and Margin Coef. SE Coef. SE Election Number (log) -0.463 (0.021)*** 0.045 (0.042) SFPR 2.834 (0.069)*** 2.407 (0.099)*** Margin of Victory -0.116 (0.179) -0.536 (0.389) Established Democracy -1.136 (0.054)*** -1.612 (0.093)*** Margin*Estab. Dem. 1.070 (0.214)*** 2.195 (0.420)*** No SMD-PR Linkage -0.697 (0.043)*** -0.277 (0.061)*** SF-ratio t-1 0.616 (0.033)*** Cut-point 1-0.609 (0.068)*** 0.408 (0.128)*** Cut-point 2 1.059 (0.068)*** 1.956 (0.130)*** N 8,603 4,875 Number of countries 11 9 + p < 0.1, * p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001 ID Variable: Country (11) Unit of Analysis: Single-member district Dependent variable: Trichotomous SF-ratio (1 st loser vote divided by 2 nd loser vote) SF-ratio between 0 and.25 is coded as 0 between.25 and.75 is coded as 1 greater than.75 is coded as 2 13