Hawks and Doves at the Federal Reserve. Michael D Bordo, Rutgers University and the Hoover Institution, Stanford University

Similar documents
Perceived FOMC: The Making of Hawks, Doves and Swingers. Economics Working Paper 18108

Workshops Proceedings of OeNB Workshops. The European Integration Process: A Changing Environment for National Central Banks. October 21, No.

Voting regional Fed presidents to turn slightly more dovish in 2019?

Perceived FOMC: The Making of Hawks, Doves and Swingers

In Fed Watchers Eyes: Hawks, Doves and Monetary Policy

Communicating a Systematic Monetary Policy

Allan Meltzer and the History of the Federal Reserve. Michael D. Bordo. Rutgers, NBER, and the Hoover Institution, Stanford University

Quantifying Perceived Policy Preferences of the FOMC:

Monetary Theory and Central Banking By Allan H. Meltzer * Carnegie Mellon University and The American Enterprise Institute

The Rationale for Independent Monetary Policy

Legislating a Rule for Monetary Policy John B. Taylor

A Perspective on the Economy and Monetary Policy

Introduction. Copyright 2017 by the Board of Trustees of the Leland Stanford Junior University. All rights reserved.

I would like to add my voice to the chorus in thanking President Fisher and the

Charles I Plosser: A progress report on our monetary policy framework

The Most Dangerous Idea in Federal Reserve History: Monetary Policy Doesn t Matter

Structure and Functions of the Federal Reserve System

VITA. Short-Run Reserve Position Adjustment of New York City Banks (Chairman: Milton Friedman)

The New Chairman of the US Federal Reserve: What Can We Expect? January 2018

Fed Will 'Wait & Watch' Before Raising Interest Rates

Systematic Policy and Forward Guidance

INTERVIEW. John B. Taylor

Independence and the Scope of the Central Bank s Mandate. John B. Taylor 1 Stanford University. June 2016

To the Central Bank Governors Panel, Jackson Hole conference, Wyoming, USA. 27 August 2005

Who Will be the Next Chair of the Federal Reserve?

Federal Reserve Reform Proposals. John B. Taylor 1

Monetary Policy Strategies: A Central Bank Panel

The Uneasy Case for Janet Yellen

Friedman and the Bernanke-Taylor Debate on Rules versus Constrained Discretion

Does Political Business Cycle exist in India? By

Will Tim Kaine Help Hillary Clinton Get Elected?

SCHOOLS OF ECONOMICS. Classical, Keynesian, & Monetary

10/7/2013 SCHOOLS OF ECONOMICS. Classical, Keynesian, & Monetary. as Neo- Classical Supply Side Trickle Down Free Trade CLASSICAL THEORY

Governance, Transparency and Accountability in Colombian Central Bank and Financial Regulation

Rules Versus Discretion: Assessing the Debate Over the Conduct of Monetary Policy

The Cycle of Rules and Discretion in Economic Policy

Central banking and Monetary Policy: What Will Be the Post-Crisis New Normal?

ICES- El CEITER El CEITER IF EICELLEICE

Monetary Dialogue : Looking backward, looking forward

Council of Great Lakes Governors 17 Annual Leadership Summit Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland October 15, 1999

Towards an Exit Strategy: Discretion or Rules? Discorso Bruno Leoni John B. Taylor Stanford University. Palazzo Clerici, Milano

Sonja Steßl. State Secretary Federal Ministry of Finance

What the Political System Can Do to Help the Fed. Peter N. Ireland Boston College

Volume Author/Editor: Rendigs Fels and C. Elton Hinshaw. Volume URL:

The Federal Reserve at 100 A Look at its History and Future

IHS Outlook: Global Supply Chain Trends and Threats

Implications for the Desirability of a "Stage Two" in European Monetary Unification p. 107

Celebrating 20 Years of the Bank of Mexico s Independence. Remarks by. Ben S. Bernanke. Chairman. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System

GOING ALONE UK TO LEAVE THE EUROPEAN UNION - AN EXPAT SAVINGS TEAM UPDATE. Going alone - UK to leave the European Union

Prior to 1940, the Austrian School was known primarily for its contributions

The persuasive power of a Committee Chairman: Arthur Burns and the FOMC

Progressive Government Reform. Roosevelt, Taft, and Wilson

Constitutional Reform in California: The Surprising Divides

VITA. Short-Run Reserve Position Adjustment of New York City Banks (Chairman: Milton Friedman)

Patrick Adler and Chris Tilly Institute for Research on Labor and Employment, UCLA. Ben Zipperer University of Massachusetts, Amherst

Macroeconomics and Presidential Elections

Fed Up: Building an Economy

FRBSF ECONOMIC LETTER

Statutory Central Bank Independence in Taiwan A Review of the Central Bank of the Republic of China (Taiwan) Act. C. James Hueng

VIDEO STUDY GUIDE > COMMANDING HEIGHTS THE BATTLE FOR THE WORLD ECONOMY - PART 1 - THE CLASH OF IDEAS

David A. Hopkins. University of California, Berkeley Ph.D., Political Science, 2010 (dissertation chair: Eric Schickler) M.A., Political Science, 2002

Andreas Hornstein. Doctor of Philosophy, Economics, University of Minnesota, Diplom, Economics, Universität Konstanz, Germany, 1984

CONFIDENCE IN THE GLOBAL ECONOMY PREVAILS DESPITE UNCERTAINTIES

This Expansion Looks Familiar

The Election and the Markets

Karl Brunner, Monetarist

REGIONAL INFLUENCES ON FOMC VOTING PATTERNS

Froth and Bubble: The Inconsistency of Paul Krugman s Macroeconomic Analysis

Regional Influences on FOMC Voting Patterns

Estimating Central Bank Preferences Combining Topic and Scaling Methods

FOR RELEASE: SUNDAY, OCTOBER 13, 1991, A.M.

14 The distributional implications of US trade liberalisation with China

Productivity, Output, and Unemployment in the Short Run. Productivity, Output, and Unemployment in the Short Run

Good Governance of Monetary Policy in Canada: Lessons from the C.D. Howe Institute s Shadow Council

An Historical Perspective on Technological Shocks, Political Shocks and Globalization

The University of Akron Bliss Institute Poll: Baseline for the 2018 Election. Ray C. Bliss Institute of Applied Politics University of Akron

REPUBLICANS VS. DEMOCRATS:

Borrowing Credibility: Foreign Financiers and Monetary Regimes

ECN 110B: World Economic History II Spring 2012 University of California, Davis 1

John Maynard Keynes v. Friedrich Hayek Part I: The Battle of Ideas (Commanding Heights) 2. What economic concepts did John Maynard Keynes invent?

CIO Markets Report. Key Observations Implications Markets Charts. Stephen Sexauer, CIO. CIO Markets Report

University of California, Berkeley ECONOMICS 210C / ECONOMICS 236A MONETARY HISTORY SYLLABUS PART I: THE EFFECTS OF POLICY

Thinkwell s Homeschool Economics Course Lesson Plan: 36 weeks

Voting Power in the FOMC

inside the ivory tower 62 Foreign Policy ILLUSTRATION BY MARIA RENDON FOR FP

US Watch. The 2018 Midterms Three scenarios. Group Economics Financial Markets Research. Insights.abnamro.nl/en. 28 September 2018

vol.133 (1.March.2012) The BOJ s price stability goal rhetoric and practice

THE POLITICS OF INDEPENDENT CENTRAL BANKS

ITRN Syllabus Macroeconomic Economic Policy in a Global Economy Fall 2017 Monday `7.10 pm pm Founders Hall 470

A2 Economics. Enlargement Countries and the Euro. tutor2u Supporting Teachers: Inspiring Students. Economics Revision Focus: 2004

NEW YORK UNIVERSITY Department of Politics. V COMPARATIVE POLITICS Spring Michael Laver Tel:

Deconstructing Structural Unemployment

Christopher S. Parker Department of Political Science University of Washington 112 Gowen Hall University of Washington, Seattle

Do Parties Matter? A Political Model of Monetary Policy in Open Economies

United States: Midterm Elections and U.S. Economy

The Macro Polity Updated

Topics in European Economic History

A 13-PART COURSE IN POPULAR ECONOMICS SAMPLE COURSE OUTLINE

This PDF is a selec on from a published volume from the Na onal Bureau of Economic Research

ECONOMIC POLICYMAKING CHAPTER 17, Government in America

Transcription:

Hawks and Doves at the Federal Reserve Michael D Bordo, Rutgers University and the Hoover Institution, Stanford University Shadow Open Market Committee Meeting Harvard Club, New York City, New York October 19, 2018 1

Introduction The FOMC is close to a turning point. It is raising the policy rate at a measured pace to normalize monetary policy. At present the U.S. economy is in excellent shape with low unemployment (3.7%) and inflation close to its 2 % target. As long as these conditions continue the FOMC will continue its gradual tightening cycle. However, if inflation increases much beyond two per cent the FOMC is likely to tighten more leading to the possibility of triggering a recession. Even if that does not happen, other shocks including fiscal tightening as the Trump tax cuts end and a U.S. tariff -induced unraveling of global supply chains and a slowdown in East Asian aggregate demand could lead to a downturn. This would be nothing new. The Fed has mistimed its exit strategy in business cycle recoveries in every episode (with the exception of four) since 1920 (Bordo and Landon Lane 2012). How and when the Fed will react when the situation becomes tricky may be related to both the composition of the FOMC between governors and presidents and the policy preferences of its members-- whether they are hawks, doves or swingers. Normally the FOMC should have 12 voting members, 7 Governors appointed by the President and 5 Reserve bank Presidents (of whom New York is always present and the other four were on a rotating basis) who are appointed by their boards of directors. At present there are four serving governors (with three waiting to be confirmed by the U.S. Senate). There is a general belief that the President will pick governors who have views close to his own that Republican Presidents will pick hawks and Democratic Presidents will pick doves. 1 By contrast Reserve bank Presidents are chosen by their Boards of Directors who are less influenced by national politics and their policy preferences often reflect those associated historically with the district. 2 So for example St. Louis was always monetarist, Cleveland was 1 However there have been episodes in history where a Republican President concerned about his election chances would pick a dove. 2 In recent years, the Board of Governors in Washington has played a greater role in the Reserve Bank selection process. 2

anti-inflation as was Richmond and so their Presidents have generally been classified as hawks; whereas Boston, Kansas City have often been viewed as Keynesian oriented and dovish. In addition, other important factors may be important in determining FOMC members policy preferences including when they were born (eg before or after the Great Depression and the Great Inflation) and the University where many of them received their PHDs (freshwater schools like the University of Chicago or salt water schools like Berkeley). These attributes may be crucial in affecting FOMC members policy choices and whether we may have a hard or a soft landing. In a recent paper with Klodiana Istrefi of the Banque de France (Bordo and Istrefi 2018) we examined the policy preferences of FOMC members who served from the early 1960s to 2015 in relation to the ideology of who appointed them. We examined both Board governors relative to the party of the US Presidents that nominated them; and the Regional Federal Reserve Bank Presidents relative to the Board of Directors of the regional Federal Reserve Bank that appointed them. We investigated three types of policy makers: inflation fighting hawks, growth promoting doves, and swingers (i.e those members perceived as swinging between the hawkish and dovish camps at the FOMC). The hawk and dove measure (index) was compiled by Istrefi (2017) based on narrative records in US newspapers and other sources regarding the policy leanings of FOMC members with respect to the Federal Reserve s dual mandate. 3 As Figure 1 shows, the hawk and dove composition of the FOMC has varied considerably over time reflecting the annual rotation scheme of the FOMC, the turnover of members, and swings in preferences. 3 The hawk-dove measure is based on all the relevant information derived from the policymaker s background (origins, education, political interests and supporters), their economic beliefs (expressed in writings, testimonies, speeches) and actions (votes and dissents). To build the hawk-dove measure, about 20,000 articles or reports from more than 30 newspapers and referencing 130 members were read to collect quotes that are informative on the policy preferences of each member. These quotes were quantified as perceptions for either a hawk or a dove. Perceptions were traced year by year, for the whole tenure of the FOMC member. 3

Figure 1 Hawks and Doves at the FOMC (% of the share of voting FOMC members) Notes: The share of perceived hawks and doves for each FOMC, from 1963 to 2015. Perceived preferences are followed in real time, where the assigned preference of FOMC members in a meeting m, year t is based on perceptions before meeting m. In the chart, the share does not always add up to 100, as it can be that the policy preference of one or more members is not known yet. Source: Istrefi (2017). Ideology by Appointment The Partisan theory of monetary policy first formulated by Hibbs (1977) and empirically supported by Beck (1982), Stein (1985) and Alesina and Sachs (1988), among others, suggests that Democratic administrations prefer easy monetary policies and choose doves, whereas Republican administrations prefer tightness and choose hawks. Indeed, our analysis shows that Democratic Board nominees have been mostly perceived to be doves in their tenure at the FOMC and very few have been perceived as hawks (See Figure 2). The share of hawks does appear higher for Republican nominees, but a slightly higher share of them are also perceived 4

to be doves. This is not very surprising. First, if re-election motives are present, even Republicans might choose members with dovish preferences in expectation of policies to support growth and employment (eg. Richard Nixon, see Bordo, 2018a). Second, the U.S. president appoints the Board members, but each of them has to be confirmed by the Senate. Nominees have higher chances of confirmation if they are likable by both besides in the Senate. Our data show that 70% of the Board of Governors in our sample were confirmed in a Democratic majority Senate. Figure 2 Political or institutional philosophies get checked at the door? Note: The panel on the right abstracts from the regional Fed presidents for which the policy preference remained unknown. Source: Bordo and Istrefi (2018). By contrast, when focusing on Federal Reserve Bank Presidents who are appointed by their bank s board of directors, we observe a high share of hawks irrespective of the president s party (See Figure 2, second panel). Federal Reserve Bank presidents seem to be picked rather for having beliefs that go in line with those of the regional Federal Reserve Bank that they represent. This seems especially true for Federal Reserve banks that have a long tradition of institutional ideology (eg the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland s outspoken, inflation fighting 5

roots ). Thus several regional Feds, like the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas, the Federal Reserve Bank of New York or the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, have had presidents predominantly perceived as hawks (Figure 3). Figure 3 Ideology in the Federal Reserve Bank president Source: Bordo and Istrefi (2018). s The Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta and the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City had presidents predominantly perceived as swingers, whereas the Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia and the Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco had presidents predominantly perceived as doves. Beyond institutional memory and ideology, several other factors could explain this distribution of types, such as the ties of the Federal Reserve Banks with the Board of Governors (which is believed to have become more influential over time in choosing Federal Reserve Bank Presidents), how strong the ties of the Federal Reserve Banks with the commercial banks of the region are, or the conservative versus liberal tendencies of the region. 6

What moulds the central banker s type as a hawk or dove? In Bordo and Istrefi (2018) we highlight two important factors in molding the policy preferences of FOMC members who have served over the past 60 years: ideology by education, and events that shaped their lives before joining the FOMC. By ideology in education we mean the graduate schools that PhD economists on the FOMC studied at. We distinguish between freshwater schools like the University of Chicago, Rochester and UCLA associated with monetarist (stable money) views and scholars like Milton Friedman, Karl Brunner, Allan Meltzer and Robert Lucas on the one hand, and salt-water schools like Harvard, MIT, Yale and Berkeley associated with scholars like Paul Samuelson, Robert Solow and James Tobin who were Keynesians and who emphasized full employment over low inflation. Our results show that above 70% of members from freshwater schools have been hawks, while the majority of members from saltwater schools have been doves. We also found that members who did not have a PhD (eg bachelor s, master s, MBA) were less polarized; most of them were perceived as hawks irrespective of the school type. Figure 4 Ideology by education/schools of thought 7

Source: Bordo and Istrefi (2018). Our second salient determining factor is events that shape FOMC members lives. We examine for each member the major economic events (high inflation and high unemployment) that occurred during their early life (when born and until 25-30 years old). This investigation is motivated by the literature in political science and social psychology which suggests that people form their core economic and political beliefs mostly during the early stages of life (age 18 to 25), which then remain fairly unaltered for the rest of their lives. For instance, our results show that members who were born during the Great Depression tended to be doves and swingers. Those that lived their early life during periods of high inflation (like during the WW1 and the WW2) tended to be hawks (see Figure 5). 8

Figure 5 Great Inflation and Great Depression memories run deep Note: WWI (1914 1924) and WWII (1939 1949), each period includes the years of the war plus post war inflation years. Left panel: all FOMC members (n=119, excluding the unknown types); right panel: only FOMC members with impressionable years in the defined periods (n=89). The impressionable years are defined as ages of 18 to 25. In simplest terms, we found that the odds of being a hawk are higher when a member is born during a period of high inflation or graduated from a university linked to the Chicago School ( freshwater ). A dove is most likely born during a period of high unemployment like the Great Depression and graduated from a university with strong Keynesian beliefs ( saltwater ). 4, 5 4 Swingers share several background characteristics of doves, but not always. Being a non economist and having 9

Implications for Current and Future Policy The divide in views of the Board versus the regional Federal Reserve Bank presidents could be especially important today when the FOMC is short of three Board members, thus making the five regional Fed Presidents the voting majority (a rare situation for the governance of the Federal Reserve, see also Conti Brown, 2016). Historically the Federal Reserve Bank presidents have always been more independent and outspoken than the members of the Board, who have been more supportive of the Chairman of the Board of Governors. The last time a Board member dissented on policy was in 2005, in one of the last meetings of Chairman Alan Greenspan. Since then, the Federal Reserve Bank presidents have dissented 57 times, most of them for tighter policy. Thus, Chairman Powell might face a harder job in forming a consensus with a Federal Reserve Bank presidents led majority. A weak Board and a weak FOMC could find it challenging to manage further rate hikes in an environment of the termination of fiscal stimulus and trade policy uncertainty. A weak FOMC means trouble ahead if conditions deteriorate and a recession looms. In addition, it has been 35 years since the end of the Great Inflation and for some of the new FOMC members the Great Inflation is a distant memory and the seminal event in their formative years is the Great Moderation (1985 to 2003). Moreover, the macroeconomics that is taught in U.S. Graduate schools has converged around the New Keynesian model which combines elements of both freshwater and saltwater schools of thought. 6 graduated from universities with no immediate relation to freshwater / saltwater schools increases the odds, albeit slightly, of being a swinger. 5 We find a good match between the overall perceptions on the type with voting trends of the FOMC. Perceived hawks have a tendency towards tightening when they dissent (92 % of their dissents) and perceived doves have a tendency towards loosening when they dissent (94 % of their dissents). Hawks and doves have also a higher dissent rate per member, for tighter and easer policy, respectively. 6 Although there are to be sure distinct differences between what is emphasized in each of the two schools rules over discretion and the dominance of market solutions to the economy s ills in freshwater schools ; and managed discretion and the prevalence of market failures requiring government intervention in saltwater. 10

Ideological factors might also have become muted with time because the Federal Reserve, as is the case with many central banks around the world, has converged to an understanding of the importance of price stability ( and the use of flexible inflation targeting). Moreover, since the Great Financial Crisis of 2007-2008 the debate has largely been over financial stability, not price stability. Financial stability has become the growing concern of central banks, and a key difference among them is on exactly what role the financial stability objective should play in their policy making. Should central banks lean against the wind of asset price booms or clean up the mess after the boom busts? And if central banks lean against the wind, what tools should they use macro-prudential regulation or their policy interest rate? 7 Although it is too soon to tell, ideology could still play a role. Furthermore, the pendulum has been swinging away from the appointment of PhD economists as Presidents of the Regional Federal Reserve banks towards those with an MBA background with an emphasis on pragmatism and short run fixing. All of these recent forces suggest that the old hawk-dove distinction may not be quite as relevant as in the past for how the present FOMC will handle the next major inflection point in policy making. References Alesina, A and J Sachs (1988), Political Parties and the Business Cycle in the United States, 1948 1984, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 20(1): 63 82. Nathanael Beck (1982), "Parties, Administrations and American Macroeconomic Outcomes", American Political Science Review 76(1): 83 94. Michael Bordo (2018a), The Global Imbalances of the Bretton Woods System 1965 to 1973: U.S. Inflation, The Elephant in the Room paper presented at the World Economic History Congress. Cambridge, Mass July. 7 See Bordo (2018b). 11

Michael Bordo (2018b) An Historical Perspective on Financial Stability and Monetary Policy Regimes: A Case for Caution in Central Banks Current Obsession with Financial Stability Norges Bank Working Paper 5/2018 March Michael Bordo and John Landon Lane (2012) Exits from Recessions: The U.S. Experience, 1920-2007 chapter 8 in No Way Out: Persistent Government Interventions in The Great Contraction. (edited by) Vincent Reinhart. Washington DC AEI Press pp117-162. Michael Bordo and Klodiana Istrefi (2018), "Perceived FOMC: The Making of Hawks, Doves and Swingers," NBER Working Paper 24650. Peter Conti Brown (2016), The Power and Independence of the Federal Reserve, Princeton University Press Douglas A. Hibbs (1977), Political Parties and Macroeconomic Policy, American Political Science Review 71: 1467 87. Klodiana Istrefi (2017), In Fed Watchers' Eyes: Hawks, Doves and Monetary Policy, manuscript, Banque de France. Herbert Stein (1994), Presidential Economics, Third Edition, American Enterprise Institute. 12