At the Conjunction of Love and Money: Comment on Julie A. Nelson, Does Profit-Seeking Rule Out Love? Evidence (or Not) from Economics and Law

Similar documents
Tracking Berle's Footsteps: The Trail of the Modern Corporation's Law Chapter

New institutional economic theories of non-profits and cooperatives: a critique from an evolutionary perspective

INSTITUTIONS MATTER (revision 3/28/94)

CHAPTER 19 MARKET SYSTEMS AND NORMATIVE CLAIMS Microeconomics in Context (Goodwin, et al.), 2 nd Edition

Democracy, and the Evolution of International. to Eyal Benvenisti and George Downs. Tom Ginsburg* ... National Courts, Domestic

The Challenge of Sustaining Capitalism

A Perspective on the Economy and Monetary Policy

National Cooperative Policy in Rwanda. Revised Version [1]

Robust Political Economy. Classical Liberalism and the Future of Public Policy

The Politics of Egalitarian Capitalism; Rethinking the Trade-off between Equality and Efficiency

Varieties of Capitalism in East Asia

General Rulebook (GEN)

11/7/2011. Section 1: Answering the Three Economic Questions. Section 2: The Free Market

Governance & Development. Dr. Ibrahim Akoum Division Chief Arab Financial Markets Arab Monetary Fund

BOOK REVIEWS. After War: The Political Economy of Exporting Democracy Christopher J. Coyne Stanford, Calif.: Stanford University Press, 2006, 238 pp.

15071/15 ADB/mk 1 DG B 3A

GENERAL INTRODUCTION FIRST DRAFT. In 1933 Michael Kalecki, a young self-taught economist, published in

Mehrdad Payandeh, Internationales Gemeinschaftsrecht Summary

CONSERVATISM: A DEFENCE FOR THE PRIVILEGED AND PROSPEROUS?

We the Stakeholders: The Power of Representation beyond Borders? Clara Brandi

SOCI 423: THEORIES OF SOCIAL DEVELOPMENT

FAIRNESS VERSUS WELFARE. Louis Kaplow & Steven Shavell. Thesis: Policy Analysis Should Be Based Exclusively on Welfare Economics

PARIS AGREEMENT. Being Parties to the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change, hereinafter referred to as "the Convention",

Delegation and Legitimacy. Karol Soltan University of Maryland Revised

Strengthening Financial Markets and Corporate Governance. Executive Summary

Invited Reaction Putting Theories of the Firm in Their Place: A Supplemental Digest of the New Institutional Economics

FCCC/CP/2015/10/Add.1 Annex Paris Agreement

Immigrant Entrepreneurship: Creating New opportunities UN Symposium on International Migration and Development, Turin, June 30, 2006

Economic Assistance to Russia: Ineffectual, Politicized, and Corrupt?

Theories of the Historical Development of American Schooling

KEY ISSUES FACING THE BAHAMAS ECONOMY IN THE 21 ST CENTURY REMARKS GIVEN BY MR. JULIAN W. FRANCIS, GOVERNOR THE CENTRAL BANK OF THE BAHAMAS

Strategy Approved by the Board of Directors 6th June 2016

The State, the Market, And Development. Joseph E. Stiglitz World Institute for Development Economics Research September 2015

ONEOK, INC. EXECUTIVE COMPENSATION COMMITTEE CHARTER

In The Law of Peoples, John Rawls contrasts his own view of global distributive

Running Head: POLICY MAKING PROCESS. The Policy Making Process: A Critical Review Mary B. Pennock PAPA 6214 Final Paper

Making Government Work For The People Again

Key Words: public, policy, citizens, society, institutional, decisions, governmental.

THE AMERICAN LAW INSTITUTE Continuing Legal Education. Business Entities: 2014 Update February 18, 2014 Video Presentation

senior economist in the Cabinet of the United Nations (UN) Secretary-General and as an IMF

NPT/CONF.2020/PC.II/WP.30

WHO DISCUSSION PAPER

THE BANK OF NOVA SCOTIA. Corporate Governance Policies

Fiduciaries, Federalization, and Finance Capitalism: Berle s Ambiguous Legacy and the Collapse of Countervailing Power

Exploring the fast/slow thinking: implications for political analysis: Gerry Stoker, March 2016

Why Labour Is Fit To Govern and Competent To Manage The Economy

INTRODUCTION PUBLIC POLICY FORUM: U.S. ATTORNEYS: ROLES AND RESPONSIBILITIES

KIM IL SUNG FOR THE STRENGTHENING OF COOPERATION BETWEEN THE NON-ALIGNED COUNTRIES IN THEIR NEWS SERVICES

Accessing Home. Refugee Returns to Towns and Cities: Experiences from Côte d Ivoire and Rwanda. Church World Service, New York

AGREEMENT FOR DISMISSAL OF WEST VALLEY PRESBYTERIAN CHURCH AND MUTUAL RELEASE OF CLAIMS

THE SEC AND THE ACCOUNTING PROFESSION: ISSUES FOR CONGRESS. Michael F. BARRETT, JR. *

Feed the Future. Civil Society Action Plan

POLI 359 Public Policy Making

The First Hundred Days relief, recovery, and reform John Maynard Keynes The Banking Acts Emergency Banking Relief Act BAILOUT

Constitution of the Harvard College Queer Student and Allies (QSA)

CHAPTER 1 PROLOGUE: VALUES AND PERSPECTIVES

Halve, between 1990 and 2015, the proportion of people whose income is less than $1 a day

Comments on Prof. Hodgson s The Evolution of Institutions: An Agenda for Future Theoretical Research

Lecture to the New York Telephone Company December 1933

The Justification of Justice as Fairness: A Two Stage Process

EFFICIENCY OF COMPARATIVE NEGLIGENCE : A GAME THEORETIC ANALYSIS

Shareholder Primacy s Corporatist Origins: Adolf Berle and The Modern Corporation. William W. Bratton* and Michael L. Wachter**

THE FUTURE OF PUBLIC POLICY

Book Reveiw: Where to From Here? Australian Egalitarianism under Threat by Argy, Fred

The Modern Corporation as Social Construction

Voting for Your Boss: An Economic Argument for Workplace Democracy

Economic Perspective. Macroeconomics I ECON 309 S. Cunningham

HOW DO PEOPLE THINK ABOUT THE SUPREME COURT WHEN THEY CARE?

On the Positioning of the One Country, Two Systems Theory

Black Economic Empowerment. Paper for Harold Wolpe Memorial Seminar, 8 June Dali Mpofu

When Thomas Piketty s Capital in the 21 st Century was published. Book Review. Anti-Piketty: Capital for the 21 st Century. Quarterly Journal of

Enlightenment of Hayek s Institutional Change Idea on Institutional Innovation

TST Issue Brief: Global Governance 1. a) The role of the UN and its entities in global governance for sustainable development

BOARDS OF GOVERNORS 2009 ANNUAL MEETINGS ISTANBUL, TURKEY

Management prerogatives, plant closings, and the NLRA: A response

Huntington Bancshares Incorporated Subject: Risk Oversight Committee Charter Number: CH-006

THE MULTIFACETED NATURE OF FAIRNESS IN COMPETITION POLICY

APGAP Reading Quiz 2A AMERICAN POLITICAL PARTIES

The Clinton Administration s China Engagement Policy in Perspective

Exam. Name. MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

The Soft Power Technologies in Resolution of Conflicts of the Subjects of Educational Policy of Russia

Review of Social Economy. The Uncertain Foundations of Post Keynesian Economics: Essays in Exploration. By Stephen P. Dunn.

BEE SEMINAR. Black Economic Empowerment MS FUTHI ZIKALALA MVELASE SENIOR OFFICIAL DEPARTMENT OF MINERALS AND ENERGY 20 NOVEMBER 2007

ALCOA STOCK INCENTIVE PLAN

SHANKER SINGHAM, DIRECTOR OF INTERNATIONAL TRADE AND COMPETITION, IEA

Decentralization has remained in the Nepalese

The Hanover Insurance Group, Inc. Compensation Committee Charter

IS STARE DECISIS A CONSTRAINT OR A CLOAK?

Submission to the Finance and Expenditure Committee on Reserve Bank of New Zealand (Monetary Policy) Amendment Bill

Bylaws of Petroleum Industry Data Exchange, Inc.

ECONOMICS AND COMPARATIVE POLITICS FORM IV

A Speech on the Occasion of the Launch of the Institute of Directors of Malawi, By Mr. Patrick D. Chisanga,

ASA ECONOMIC SOCIOLOGY SECTION NEWSLETTER ACCOUNTS. Volume 9 Issue 2 Summer 2010

DOES THE BALANCE-OF-PAYMENTS MATTER AT THE REGIONAL LEVEL?

FEDERALISM AND SUBNATIONAL POLITICAL COMMUNITY

24.03: Good Food 3/13/17. Justice and Food Production

Unofficial Translation

PRIVATIZATION AND INSTITUTIONAL CHOICE

EFFECTIVE VOIR DIRE, OPENING, AND CLOSING ARGUMENT FROM A PROPERTY OWNER S AND CONDEMNOR S PERSPECTIVE

Decentralized Law for a Complex Economy

Transcription:

At the Conjunction of Love and Money: Comment on Julie A. Nelson, Does Profit-Seeking Rule Out Love? Evidence (or Not) from Economics and Law William W. Bratton Professor Nelson has it absolutely right. Maximization is a thought construct that operates at an ideological level and is not descriptively robust. It is not a natural imperative, even as the need to profit certainly operates as a constraint, applying tightly or loosely depending on the particular firm and market. Nor should we think of the capitalist firm in terms of love or money. We should instead describe it around the and in love and money. This Comment will address a question that arises in the wake of Professor Nelson s intervention: Why did maximization come to dominate our thinking about firms? The answer is that academic paradigms and thinking about firms both tend to follow from the outside political economy. Indeed, capitalism itself has to take the outside political economy as it finds it and work with the social settlement it is handed. It just happens that for the last thirty years or so we have had a political economy that is particularly receptive to the maximization mindset. It was not always this way. The present paradigm displaced a predecessor borne of the Great Depression, a period in our history that pushed us into the arms of a protective, regulatory state. The accompanying mindset, which endured for decades, took us to the other side of the love and money divide. Now, if it does not sound quite right to describe the New Deal regulatory state as loving, perhaps a modification of the operative statement of opposing ideological positions can be accepted instead of love and money, we can oppose cooperation and competition, and stability and Professor of Law and Co-Director, Institute for Law & Economics, University of Pennsylvania Law School. 109

110 Journal of Law & Policy [Vol. 35:109 maximization. Whatever the characterization, a look back at the New Deal regulatory state and the theories that justified it helps us to understand the contingent character of the theories prevailing today, and to appreciate the tie between descriptive accuracy and the use of and rather than or as the conjunction. Drawing on some previous work, 1 I will present the New Deal mindset through the lens of the writings of Adolf Berle, one of its architects. Berle s writing continues to be invoked as deep background for today s shareholder primacy paradigm. But Michael Wachter and I have shown that the invocation rests on a faulty understanding of Berle. 2 When Berle elevated the shareholder interest over the management interest in a famous law review article published in 1932, his concern lay entirely with unchecked management power. 3 In the absence of some other, more effective check, he commended a trust for the shareholders benefit as a palliative. But as his contemporaneous writings make clear, his preferred mode of management power containment was government control. 4 He got that one year later during the New Deal s first hundred days. He would never again put forward the shareholder interest as a countervailing power within corporate law. And at no time did he advance shareholder value maximization as an appropriate corporate purpose. Indeed, when Berle returned to these topics a quarter century later, he changed his diagnosis and pronounced management power benign. 5 He had two reasons: first, the big stick, post-new Deal state was managing the economy from an unchallenged position of higher authority, and second, there was a solid political consensus in 1. See William W. Bratton, Berle and Means Reconsidered at the Century s Turn, 26 J. CORP. L. 737 (2001); William W. Bratton & Michael L. Wachter, Shareholder Primacy s Corporatist Origins: Adolf Berle and The Modern Corporation, 34 J. CORP. L. 99 (2008) [hereinafter Bratton & Wachter, Corporatist Origins]; William W. Bratton & Michael L. Wachter, Tracking Berle s Footsteps: The Trail of The Modern Corporation s Last Chapter, 33 SEATTLE U. L. REV. 849 (2010). 2. See Bratton & Wachter, Corporatist Origins, supra note 1, at 109 13. 3. See Adolf A. Berle, For Whom Corporate Managers Are Trustees: A Note, 45 HARV. L. REV. 1365, 1366 67 (1932). 4. See Bratton & Wachter, Corporatist Origins, supra note 1, at 128 30. 5. Id. at 133 34.

2011] At the Conjunction of Love and Money 111 support. 6 Berle depicted a regulatory state that could and did accurately articulate the social welfare function, and then guide and push the markets to the right result, unencumbered by the ideology of maximization. He described a benign equipoise amongst strong organizations, an equipoise constrained by a wider public consensus that empowered the central government and its social welfare agenda. The Depression was still a vivid memory, so the public wanted stability, in particular job security; if it took regulation to get us from here to there, fine. 7 Managers had to play ball. Whether they liked it or not, they were caught between the regulatory state and the public consensus. Failure to satisfy the public meant new regulation; avoidance of new regulation meant satisfying the public. So, as a practical matter, managers had to be public-regarding. Indeed, Berle described them as quasi-civil servants. 8 Meanwhile, the shareholders just did not matter. They were passive collectors of dividends with no productive role to play in the political economy. In fact, capital market constraints had ceased to matter more generally. Corporations got new equity capital by retaining earnings and only rarely went to Wall Street to sell stock. The markets served only to provide liquidity to the rich; there was no disciplinary value added. 9 Berle s writing thus lets us trace our evolution from the market driven political economy of the early twentieth century to a quasicorporatist state that privileged stability over maximization and sought an alignment of profit and public responsiveness. Significantly, the corporate law of Berle s time easily accommodated a quasi-civil service role for managers. It could do so again today without any need for adjustment. Corporate law does not require profit maximization now any more than it did then. In fact, corporate law could not successfully require maximization even if a corporate lawmaker ready to wield a maximization mandate suddenly appeared. Maximization can only be modeled. In the real world of going concerns no one really knows if wealth is being 6. Id. at 134. 7. Id. at 136 40. 8. Id. at 140 41. 9. Id. at 142 43.

112 Journal of Law & Policy [Vol. 35:109 maximized. 10 It follows that corporate law can only facilitate, clearing the field so that firms can attempt to maximize the value they produce (assuming an intensely competitive environment) or otherwise prosper in the absence of intense competition. Adherence to this facilitative mission keeps corporate law relatively unburdened by any ideology, at least apart from its basic commitment to capitalism. It offers a framework capacious enough to accommodate different political economies and social settlements. The framework, with its business judgment envelope, holds out room for cooperation with the state and redistribution on the one hand and room for leveraged buyouts and plant closings on the other. Meanwhile, corporate legal theories shift along with political economies, coloring in the capacious legal framework in accordance with the theorists presuppositions. To get a sense of today s colors, let us hypothesize how a maximizer would respond to the foregoing description of the corporate law framework. The description, one would hear, misses the point. To ask whether corporate law can be structured affirmatively to effect maximization puts the wrong question. Indeed, a maximizer happily would agree that corporations, left to their own institutional devices, will never push toward maximization. Such are the effects of agency costs. And that is where markets come in. Maximizers look at corporate law s capacious framework and see it constituting hierarchies that get in the way of the markets that should be left free to do the maximizing. And even if real world markets do not maximize perfectly, as they do in theoretical models, at least they do what they do spontaneously, free of the heavy hand of hierarchical direction. For today s corporate law maximizers, the crucial moment in the history of post-war economic theory is Jensen and Meckling s introduction of agency theory in 1976. 11 Neoclassical economists like Alfred Marshall assumed that firms maximized, but offered no 10. See William W. Bratton, An Anatomy of Corporate Legal Theory, 24 RES. L. & ECON. 21, 23 (2009). 11. See Michael C. Jensen & William H. Meckling, Theory of the Firm: Managerial Behavior, Agency Costs and Ownership Structure, 3 J. FIN. ECON. 305 (1976).

2011] At the Conjunction of Love and Money 113 microeconomic theory of the firm. 12 Hierarchical organization was thought to be intrinsically unsuited to such an exercise. 13 Jensen and Meckling s agency theory 14 opened the door to a microeconomic, market-driven picture of the corporation s internal workings a whole new world for maximizing. And crucially, it did so at a time when beliefs were shifting away from the Berlian political economy where regulation moderated competitive forces to one where competitive forces played an increasingly unregulated role. Stability lost out as the goal, replaced by competitive fitness in an uncontrollable international framework. Corporate legal theory, as always taking its instructions from the outside political economy, promptly reconstituted itself to look to deregulation and market controls. And so, from the 1980s on, corporate law has obsessed on the same structural question: Who should decide how the firm should be managed, the managers or the shareholders themselves? The question poses a choice between institutional security and a model driven by informational signals from the financial markets. The shareholder side contends that prevailing legal and institutional structures fail to provide a platform conducive to aggressive entrepreneurship, instead inviting management self-dealing and conservative decision making biased toward institutional stability. 15 It looks to actors in financial markets for corrective inputs. Unlike the managers, who are conflicted and risk averse, the shareholders, who look to the market price and nothing else, come to the table with a pure financial incentive to maximize value. 16 So the maximizers will readily agree that many firms survive indefinitely when making decisions that are not in their shareholders best interests. They just want to put a stop to it. I do not think the market control agenda makes sense as a policy proposition. 17 But for present purposes, the point is that maximization 12. William W. Bratton, Jr., The New Economic Theory of the Firm: Critical Perspectives from History, 41 STAN. L. REV. 1471, 1495 96 (1989). 13. Id. at 1496. 14. Jensen & Meckling, supra note 11, at 305 06. 15. See William W. Bratton & Michael L. Wachter, The Case Against Shareholder Empowerment, 158 U. PA. L. REV. 653, 666 (2010). 16. Id. 17. Id. at 688 716.

114 Journal of Law & Policy [Vol. 35:109 is a direction to which some people point, rather than a goal that firms must meet. They suggest that institutions can be structured so as to move us in that direction with markets as the means to the end. If you want market control, then a stripped-down model of the subject works well. Indeed, it works all too well, a point aptly stated by Professor Nelson: What this Article does seek to discredit is the belief that there is something intrinsic in the economic or legal structure of commerce that forces firms, inexorably, as if run on rails, to neglect values of care and concern in order to strive for every last dollar of profits. This widespread belief detracts from human or ecological welfare, for two reasons. First, it lets shareholders, directors, and managers of corporations morally off the hook for the social and environmental consequences of business decisions. Second, it places the entire burden of maintaining the moral order onto non-business entities, such as government, nonprofits, and families. 18 To see widespread adherence to the automaton model of the firm that Professor Nelson describes, along with an array of pernicious effects, just take a look at our present financial crisis. There is a prominent line of analysis that absolves the banks that caused the crisis (and the human actors in charge of them) from responsibility for their own externalities, depicting them as capitalists competing as usual. 19 From there, in a strange twist, blame befalls those who regulated, failed to regulate, or deregulated the companies that did the deeds. 20 All responsibilities for shortcomings in the moral order are ascribed to the government, while the companies themselves dodge the bullet. For further examples, all the reader has to do is open a newspaper. 18. Julie A. Nelson, Does Profit-Seeking Rule Out Love? Evidence (or Not) from Economics and Law, 35 WASH U. J.L. & POL Y 69, 71 72 (2011). 19. See, e.g., RICHARD A. POSNER, THE CRISIS OF CAPITALIST DEMOCRACY 77 79 (2010) (providing an explanation for why banks took the risks leading to the financial crisis in light of the externalities that led to the market collapse). 20. Id. at 79.

2011] At the Conjunction of Love and Money 115 I used to dismiss the amoral automaton firm as something that appealed only to ideologues at the fringe, and then only normatively. The financial crisis has shown this assumption to be naive. When the crisis first hit, I was sure that it amounted to enough of a shock to alter the habits of mind Professor Nelson describes. But I was wrong about that too.