A NOTE ON MONITORING COSTS AND VOTER FRAUD

Similar documents
WHEN IS THE PREPONDERANCE OF THE EVIDENCE STANDARD OPTIMAL?

The Fairness of Sanctions: Some Implications for Optimal Enforcement Policy

Political Economics II Spring Lectures 4-5 Part II Partisan Politics and Political Agency. Torsten Persson, IIES

CORRUPTION AND OPTIMAL LAW ENFORCEMENT. A. Mitchell Polinsky Steven Shavell. Discussion Paper No /2000. Harvard Law School Cambridge, MA 02138

Plea Bargaining with Budgetary Constraints and Deterrence

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE THEORY OF PUBLIC ENFORCEMENT OF LAW. A. Mitchell Polinsky Steven Shavell

political budget cycles

Supporting Information Political Quid Pro Quo Agreements: An Experimental Study

Agencies Should Ignore Distant-Future Generations

United States Court of Appeals For the Seventh Circuit Chicago, Illinois 60604

AP Gov Chapter 09 Outline

Lobbying and Bribery

Economic Analysis of Public Law Enforcement and Criminal Law

The Choice of Environmental Regulatory Enforcement by Lobby Groups

Making it Easier to Vote vs. Guarding Against Election Fraud

The Cost-Benefit Analysis of Crime*

Who Really Voted for Obama in 2008 and 2012?

Sentencing Guidelines, Judicial Discretion, And Social Values

The Economic Effects of Judicial Selection Dr. John A. Dove Faulkner Lecture Outline

Who Would Have Won Florida If the Recount Had Finished? 1

Migrants and external voting

A positive correlation between turnout and plurality does not refute the rational voter model

Is the F-Word Overused?

USING MULTI-MEMBER-DISTRICT ELECTIONS TO ESTIMATE THE SOURCES OF THE INCUMBENCY ADVANTAGE 1

Universitat Pompeu Fabra. Stanford Law School. December 1997

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES. Working Paper No. i63. NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge MA

Foundations of the Economic Approach to Law. Edited by AVERY WIENER KATZ

Working Paper: The Effect of Electronic Voting Machines on Change in Support for Bush in the 2004 Florida Elections

Fee Awards and Optimal Deterrence

Real Change for Afghan Women s Rights: Opportunities and Challenges in the Upcoming Parliamentary Elections

Who s to Blame? Punishing Poor Economic Performance in a Centralized Political System

POLITICAL PARTICPATION: VOTER IDENTIFICATION AND VOTER REGISTRATION REQUIRMENTS 1

Oregon. Voter Participation. Support local pilot. Support in my state. N/A Yes N/A. Election Day registration No X

Principle of Proportionality in Sentencing and Economic Approach in Criminology

Possible voting reforms in the United States

Misvotes, Undervotes, and Overvotes: the 2000 Presidential Election in Florida

To understand the U.S. electoral college and, more generally, American democracy, it is critical to understand that when voters go to the polls on

Law enforcement and false arrests with endogenously (in)competent officers

Legal Change: Integrating Selective Litigation, Judicial Preferences, and Precedent

THE EFFECT OF OFFER-OF-SETTLEMENT RULES ON THE TERMS OF SETTLEMENT

A Solution to the Problem of Nuisance Suits: The Option to Have the Court Bar Settlement. David Rosenberg and Steven Shavell *

Supplementary Materials for Strategic Abstention in Proportional Representation Systems (Evidence from Multiple Countries)

The Analytics of the Wage Effect of Immigration. George J. Borjas Harvard University September 2009

The Political Economy of State-Owned Enterprises. Carlos Seiglie, Rutgers University, N.J. and Luis Locay, University of Miami. FL.

Methodology. 1 State benchmarks are from the American Community Survey Three Year averages

Congressional Gridlock: The Effects of the Master Lever

HARVARD JOHN M. OLIN CENTER FOR LAW, ECONOMICS, AND BUSINESS

Do States Free Ride in Antitrust Enforcement?

Better Design Better Elections. A review of design flaws and solutions in recent national elections

The Economics of Crime: An Analysis of Crime Rates in America

Escalating Penalties for Repeat Offenders

The Effect of Electoral Geography on Competitive Elections and Partisan Gerrymandering

In the Margins Political Victory in the Context of Technology Error, Residual Votes, and Incident Reports in 2004

THE EFFECT OF EARLY VOTING AND THE LENGTH OF EARLY VOTING ON VOTER TURNOUT

ELECTIONS. Issues Related to State Voter Identification Laws. United States Government Accountability Office Report to Congressional Requesters

Ethical Considerations on Quadratic Voting

Allocating the US Federal Budget to the States: the Impact of the President. Statistical Appendix

While viewing this PBS Documentary video answer the following questions. 3. Is voting a Right or a Privilege? (Circle the answer)

YouGov Results in 2010 U.S. Elections

The Outlook for the 2010 Midterm Elections: How Large a Wave?

Party Platforms with Endogenous Party Membership

Please note: additional data sources are referenced throughout this presentation, including national exit polls and NBC/WSJ national survey data.

Corruption and Political Competition

Domestic Structure, Economic Growth, and Russian Foreign Policy

Campaigning in General Elections (HAA)

Chapter 14. The Causes and Effects of Rational Abstention

Laws and Norms: When Should We Expect to Find Norms. these gaps allow (for example people appreciate the freedom of choosing a path after

Forced to Policy Extremes: Political Economy, Property Rights, and Not in My Backyard (NIMBY)

Citizenship in 21 st Century America

DPA/EAD input to OHCHR draft guidelines on effective implementation of the right to participation in public affairs May 2017

'Wave riding' or 'Owning the issue': How do candidates determine campaign agendas?

Federal Primary Election Runoffs and Voter Turnout Decline,

Social Identity, Electoral Institutions, and the Number of Candidates

EFFICIENCY OF COMPARATIVE NEGLIGENCE : A GAME THEORETIC ANALYSIS

Government by the People: Why America Needs a Constitutional Right to Vote

The Arrow Impossibility Theorem: Where Do We Go From Here?

Texas Elections Part I

Agricultural Policy Analysis: Discussion

FAIRNESS VERSUS WELFARE. Louis Kaplow & Steven Shavell. Thesis: Policy Analysis Should Be Based Exclusively on Welfare Economics

Gerrymandering Decentralization: Political Selection of Grants Financed Local Jurisdictions Stuti Khemani Development Research Group The World Bank

3D Approach to Successful Ballot Measures. public affairs

Paul M. Sommers Alyssa A. Chong Monica B. Ralston And Andrew C. Waxman. March 2010 MIDDLEBURY COLLEGE ECONOMICS DISCUSSION PAPER NO.

Voting and Elections. CP Political Systems

A New Electoral System for a New Century. Eric Stevens

Who Voted for Trump in 2016?

The Criminal Justice Policy Process Liz Cass

Elections and the Courts. Lisa Soronen State and Local Legal Center

Committee on Rules & Administration Committee on Rules & Administration

PUBLIC ENFORCEMENT OF LAW

Florida RV Survey. 800 Registered Voters Statewide + Oversample of 600 Registered Republican Voters October 23-29, FL RV + GOP OS October 2017

Curriculum Vitae. A. Mitchell Polinsky

Partisan Advantage and Competitiveness in Illinois Redistricting

Does Political Competition Reduce Ethnic Discrimination?

Joint Committee on Criminal Justice. Richard C. Dieter

Voting Irregularities in Palm Beach County

AConstrainedChoiceProductivityandPoliticalActivity

Response to the Report Evaluation of Edison/Mitofsky Election System

Reform cycles and populist cycles

Non-Voted Ballots and Discrimination in Florida

Theory and practice of falsified elections

Transcription:

University of Colorado From the SelectedWorks of PHILIP E GRAVES 2014 A NOTE ON MONITORING COSTS AND VOTER FRAUD PHILIP E GRAVES, University of Colorado at Boulder ROBERT L SEXTON, Pepperdine University GARY GALLES, Pepperdine University Available at: https://works.bepress.com/philip_graves/101/

A NOTE ON MONITORING COSTS AND VOTER FRAUD Philip E. Graves* Professor of Economics University of Colorado Boulder, Colorado Philip.Graves@Colorado.edu Robert L. Sexton Professor of Economics Pepperdine University Malibu, California Robert.Sexton@pepperdine.edu and Gary Galles Professor of Economics Pepperdine University Malibu, CA 90263 Gary.Galles@pepperdine.edu Abstract: Election fraud can threaten democracy if many ineligible people are allowed to vote. The usual policy prescription is to increase monitoring cost. However, this is very costly. This paper proposes a more cost effective strategy: substitute tougher and consistent statutes across states against voter fraud.

Introduction The economics of crime literature [Becker 1968; Tullock 1971; Barro 1973; Ehrlich 1973, 1975; Becker and Landes 1974; Becker and Stigler 1974 and McCormick and Tollison 1984] introduces the concept of a market for criminal activities. In short, like a profitmaximizing firm, an individual commits a crime when the marginal benefit of this activity is greater than the marginal cost. The supply of criminal activity is a function of four factors: (1) the probability (risk) of capture, (2) the severity of the sanction if captured, (3) the expected profit from the criminal activity and (4) the opportunity cost of the crime. Any of these four variables can impact the crime rate. In this paper, we focus on the severity of the sanction. There is an optimal tradeoff between the probability and magnitude of fines. Under risk neutrality, the probability of catching a person engaging in an externality generating activity should be set as low as possible and the fine should be set as high as possible [see Polinsky and Shavell 1979]. For example, litter fines were increased from $500 to $1000 in many states where those laws were rarely enforced, a substitution of a tougher statute for potentially quite costly monitoring. In this article, we consider the separation of statute setting and enforcement efforts because often those setting standards do not consider the full cost of compliance. The role of policing, and its cost, in the setting of what may usefully be thought of as "optimal voting fraud limits" is an important but often overlooked feature of policies designed to reduce or eliminate voting fraud behavior. In a world of costly and imperfect enforcement, policy makers need to seek methods that make compliance cost effective. The problem is that voter fraud is usually difficult to detect without costly monitoring and investigation costs, especially in light of mail-in votes and failure to require picture ID s. Clearly, voter fraud is real and can affect elections: According to the Wall Street Journal, in

2001, the Palm Beach Post reported that more than 5,600 people who voted in Florida in the 2000 Presidential election had names and data that perfectly matched a statewide list of suspected felons who were barred from voting. Florida was decided by about 500 votes. In 2003, the Indiana Supreme Court overturned the result of a mayor's race because of absentee ballot fraud a case that led to a stricter Indiana ID law, recently upheld by the U.S. Supreme Court. A 2005 Tennessee state Senate race was voided after evidence of voting by felons, nonresidents and the deceased. A Washington State Superior Court judge found that the state's 2004 gubernatorial race, which Democrat Christine Gregoire won by 133 votes, had included at least 1,678 illegal votes. 1 Costly monitoring efforts involving independent observers suggest that a great deal of fraud occurred in the recent Russian elections, with the incumbent United Russia party estimated to have actually received only 36% of the vote rather than the official count of 47%. 2 Since the extensive use of independent observers to monitor voting fraud is very expensive, alternative approaches to monitoring have been explored, such as Photo Quick Count, in the context of Afghanistan elections. 3 However, high monitoring costs remain an obstacle in over-coming widespread voter fraud. One solution would be for the government to be less tolerant of fraudulent voting by setting higher fines. With higher fines a smaller amount of enforcement cost would be necessary to achieve a given reduction in fraudulent voting because of the deterrent effect. An optimal increase in the fine would be preferred to jail time because it would be less costly to taxpayers. Of course, there would still be court cost to prosecute the fraudulent voters but the deterrent effect of a higher fine would costlessly reduce the number of potential fraudulent voters and reduce monitoring costs.

Judge Richard Posner (2007) writes, One response, which has a parallel to littering, another crime the perpetrators of which are almost impossible to catch, would be to impose a very severe criminal penalty for voting fraud. Another, however, is to take preventative action, as Indiana has done by requiring a photo ID. 4 Enforcing the Limits As already noted, without stiff sanctions a fraction of voters might choose to fraudulently vote at levels that are non-optimally large from a social perspective. Specifically, individual voters will choose levels (equating marginal private benefits and marginal private costs) that are in excess of those which equate marginal social benefits and costs, a classic "externality" case in the jargon of economics. What is the optimal voter fraud limit? From economic theory, it would be where the marginal social cost and benefits of voter fraud were equated. [Note that the economist includes the benefits to engaging in voter fraud as true benefits, perhaps a philosophical difficulty for some]. Suppose one takes the private benefits from the fraudulent voter, properly measured (i.e. does the fraudulent voter really "benefit" from his or her actions?) as being small and views the social damages to other voters as being large. In this case, if regulatory compliance were achievable costlessly, the optimal voting fraud limit would be zero, or something quite near that. The crucial feature of our present model, which incorporates the fact that achieving the optimal voting fraud limit requires monitoring and enforcement, comes from the recognition that the average voter fraud level will depend on both tolerance of voter fraud (reflected in the penalties imposed) and on the cost of policing voter fraud. Formally, let the average voter fraud level, F, be a function of both the tolerance for voter fraud, T, and the level of policing, P. 5 This function is given by F(T,P). Over relevant ranges of

T and P, it is reasonable to assume that F increases at a decreasing rate with respect to T and decreases at a decreasing rate with respect to P. Letting subscripts represent partial derivatives with respect to the indicated variable, we have F1 > 0, F11 < 0, F2 < 0, F22 < O The private net benefit realized from the average voting fraud level is given by the function B(F). Since the purpose of a tougher sanctions is to keep voters from engaging in fraudulent voting as much as they otherwise would, it is assumed that B'(F) < 0 over the relevant range, with B"(F) < 0. The cost of externalities, E(F), is given as a function of average voting fraud level only, with E'(F) > 0 and E"(F) > 0. It is assumed that the marginal and average cost of policing is given by the positive constant Θ. Finally, it is assumed that there is some sanction, TMIN, below which it is politically impossible to lower the sanction further. 6 We are now in a position to express the objective of the voting fraud limit policy as solving for the T, P, and λ, which maximizes Z(T,P,λ)= B[F(T,P)]-E[F(T,P)] - ΘP + λ(t - TMIN) (1) The Kuhn-Tucker solution to this inequality-constrained maximization problem is: Z = [B'(F) - E'(F)] F1 + λ 0 (2) T Z = [B'(F) - E'(F)] F2 - Θ = 0 (3) P Z = T TMIN 0 (4) λ T, P, λ 0 (5) {[B'(F) - E'(F)] F1 + λ}t = 0 (6) λ(t TMIN) = 0 (7)

The intuition behind these conditions is clear. Condition (3) calls for an increase in policing until its marginal value, [B' - E'] F2, is equal to its marginal cost, Θ. Since Θ > 0 and F2 < 0, it follows from (3) that B' - E' < 0. This, along with the fact that F1 > 0, means that λ is strictly positive in (6), hence T TMIN = 0 from (7). The preceding model can readily be interpreted with reference to Figure 1, where the level of fraud is on the vertical axis. Larger levels of voter fraud are associated with greater tolerance (i.e., F2 > F1 > F*), holding constant policing effort. For a given level of tolerance, increased policing reduces fraud at a decreasing rate. Since policing is costly while tolerance can be changed by sanctions not employing society s scarce resources, the level of fraud that is socially optimal is F(0,TMIN) in Figure 1. The same level of fraud could be obtained on F2(P,T2), but that would require P0 level of costly policing. Were, however, the optimal level of fraud to become smaller when already at TMIN, policing could be increased from zero, ultimately to an amount that would yield zero fraud. This would be equivalent to the much less costly, but perhaps politically unpalatable T = 0 level on F*(P, T = 0).

F F(0,T MIN) F 2 (P, T 2) 0 P 0 F 1(P, T MIN) P F*(P, T = 0) Figure 1. Fraud levels as they vary by policing and tolerance. The relative resource savings from imposing more stringent sanctions as compared to greater policing effort should continue on efficiency grounds until tolerance is lowered (sanctions raised) to the political minimum. In this simple case the optimal fraudulent voting level is completely independent of the functions B(F) and E(F), with only the amount of policing being affected by the benefits or costs associated with fraudulent voting. Hence, in the context of the present model, there are only two ways to reduce the average level of fraudulent voting: stiffen the sanctions or raising the level of policing. The former is relatively socially costless in terms of resource usage (but perhaps not in terms of equity, the motivation for a TMIN) while the latter is not, since it costs more to put additional monitors at polling places and check the authenticity of mail-in votes. Obviously, the efficiency advantage

lies in substituting tougher sanctions for socially costly policing to the fullest extent possible, where public input is likely to be critical in the determination of TMIN. The relatively straight-forward implications of this theoretical model dealing with the economics of voter fraud raises the immediate question of the its empirical relevance: how much would greater emphasis on fines reduce voting fraud? In an ideal world, one would compare fraudulent voting percentages before and after the institution of fines of varying magnitude, that comparison being done both cross-sectionally and intertemporally in a panel data framework (to obtain evidence about the likely importance of information lags in compliance). However, as with most illegal activity, even rudimentary data on voting fraud is rarely available, with most evidence being essentially anecdotal as in the introductory examples. The voting context is particularly problematic, since a significant percentage of the electorate is likely to be sympathetic to fraudulent voting activity that favors the candidate that they wish to see elected (as opposed to, say, littering where virtually all, except the litterer, find litter to be aesthetically displeasing). Data limitations aside, most individuals in a democratic society have strong antipathy toward voter fraud generally, hence relatively high fines are unlikely to be widely condemned as unfair. As a consequence, despite lacking any deep understanding of their empirical impact, the clear qualitative prediction of their effect should be sufficient justification for substituting high fines for costly monitoring. Conclusions Once the cost of enforcing fraudulent voting is recognized, the tolerance should be set as low as politically feasible, that is, sanctions should be set as high as is politically feasible. The feasible level would be expected to depend on what the public believes is "fair," and this implies that public input into the appropriate level of tolerance would be desirable on equity grounds.

But surely the current climate of public opinion running strongly against voter fraud would lead to optimal fraudulent voting levels below the prevailing levels. And, as taxpayers, the public is likely to prefer tougher sanctions to costly detection efforts. Footnotes 1 Justice and Vote Fraud, Review and Outlook, Wall Street Journal, October 7, 2008. Retrieved October 16, 2012 http://online.wsj.com/article/sb122506752884870663.html?mod=googlenews_wsj 2 See Field Experiment of Electoral Fraud in Russian Parliamentary Elections, R. Enikolopov, et al. for a detailed discussion of the extent of voter fraud estimated to have occurred in this election. 3 See Institutional Corruption and Election Fraud: Evidence from a Field Experiment in Afghanistan, Michael Callen and James D. Long for a discussion of this lower-cost monitoring approach. 4 Crawford v. Marion County Election Board, 472 F.3d 953 (7th Cir. 2007), cert. granted, 128 S. Ct. 33 (2007) (consolidated with Ind. Democratic Party v. Rokita, 128 S. Ct. 34 (2007) p.100. 5 The authors have used this statute/policing tradeoff model in other research (Graves, Lee and Sexton, 1989). It is closely related to the seminal Becker (1968) contribution. 6 We let T be sufficiently low so that if the fraudulent voting level T were perfectly enforced, the result would be an average fraudulent voting level of F, F < T, where B'(F) - E'(F) > 0.

References Barro, Robert J. The Control of Politicians: An Economic Model. Public Choice, 14 (Spring 1973): 19-42. Becker, Gary S. Crime and Punishment: An Economic Approach, in Journal of Political Economy, 2:76, 169-217, 1968. Becker, Gary S. and William M. Landes, eds. Essays in the Economics of Crime and Punishment. New York: Columbia Univ. Press (for N.B.E.R.), 1974. Becker, Gary S. and George J. Stigler. Law Enforcement, Malfeasance, and the Compensation of Enforcers. Journal of Legal Studies, 3 (January 1974): 1-18. Callan, Michael and James D. Long. Institutional Corruption and Election Fraud: Evidence from a Field Experiment in Afghanistan, revise and resubmit, American Economic Review (February 2013), available at: http://econ.ucsd.edu/~mjcallen/pdfs/icaf.pdf Ehrlich, Isaac. Participation in Illegitimate Activities: A Theoretical and Empirical Investigation. Journal of Political Economy, 81 (May/June 1973): 521-65. Ehrlich, Isaac. The Deterrent Effect of Capital Punishment: A Question of Life and Death. The American Economic Review, 65 (June 1975): 397-417.

Enikolopov, Ruben, et al. Field Experiment of Electoral Fraud in Russian Parliamentary Elections. Proceedings of the National Academy of Science (www.pnas.org/cgi/doi/10.1073/pnas.1206770110; also available at: http:/ssrn.com/abstract=2193638) Graves, Philip E., Dwight R. Lee, and Robert L. Sexton, "Statutes versus Enforcement Costs: The Case of the Optimal Speed Limit," The American Economic Review, 79:4 (September 1989):932-36. McCormick, R.E. and R.D. Tollison, Crime on the Court, Journal of Political Economy 92:4 (April 1984):223-35. Polinsky, A. Mitchell and Shavell, Steven, The Optimal Tradeoff between the Probability and Magnitude of Fines, The American Economic Review (December 1979), 69 880-91.