Online Appendix for. Home Away From Home? Foreign Demand and London House Prices

Similar documents
Mapping physical therapy research

List of Main Imports to the United States

GLOBAL RISKS OF CONCERN TO BUSINESS WEF EXECUTIVE OPINION SURVEY RESULTS SEPTEMBER 2017

The International Investment Index Report IIRC, Wuhan University

WORLDWIDE DISTRIBUTION OF PRIVATE FINANCIAL ASSETS

The National Police Immigration Service (NPIS) forcibly returned 412 persons in December 2017, and 166 of these were convicted offenders.

VISA POLICY OF THE REPUBLIC OF KAZAKHSTAN

SCALE OF ASSESSMENT OF MEMBERS' CONTRIBUTIONS FOR 1994

Networks and Innovation: Accounting for Structural and Institutional Sources of Recombination in Brokerage Triads

Hilde C. Bjørnland. BI Norwegian Business School. Advisory Panel on Macroeconomic Models and Methods Oslo, 27 November 2018

Statistical Appendix 2 for Chapter 2 of World Happiness Report March 1, 2018

APPENDIX 1: MEASURES OF CAPITALISM AND POLITICAL FREEDOM

World Refugee Survey, 2001

A Partial Solution. To the Fundamental Problem of Causal Inference

Round 1. This House would ban the use of zero-hour contracts. Proposition v. Opposition

Global Prevalence of Adult Overweight & Obesity by Region

South Africa - A publisher s perspective. STM/PASA conference 11 June, 2012, Cape Town Mayur Amin, SVP Research & Academic Relations

Translation from Norwegian

Delays in the registration process may mean that the real figure is higher.

Monthly Inbound Update June th August 2017

Income and Population Growth

The NPIS is responsible for forcibly returning those who are not entitled to stay in Norway.

KINGDOM OF CAMBODIA NATION RELIGION KING 3 TOURISM STATISTICS REPORT. September 2010

MIGRATION IN SPAIN. "Facebook or face to face? A multicultural exploration of the positive and negative impacts of

PISA 2015 in Hong Kong Result Release Figures and Appendices Accompanying Press Release

The Multidimensional Financial Inclusion MIFI 1

KINGDOM OF CAMBODIA NATION RELIGION KING 3 TOURISM STATISTICS REPORT. March 2010

Return of convicted offenders

2014 BELGIAN FOREIGN TRADE

On the Future of Criminal Offender DNA Databases

WSDC 2010: THE DRAW ROUND ZERO. PROPOSITION versus OPPOSITION NIGERIA CYPRUS CROATIA BULGARIA LEBANON PALESTINE BOSNIA AND HERZEGOVINA RUSSIA

Volume 30, Issue 1. Corruption and financial sector performance: A cross-country analysis

Tourism Highlights International Tourist Arrivals, Average Length of Stay, Hotels Occupancy & Tourism Receipts Years

CHAPTER I: SIZE AND GEOGRAPHICAL DISTRIBUTION OF THE POPULATION

Population Growth and California s Future. Hans Johnson

Migration and Integration

Equity and Excellence in Education from International Perspectives

2018 Social Progress Index

Summary of the Results

FAQ 7: Why Origins totals and percentages differs from ONS country of birth statistics

The National Police Immigration Service (NPIS) forcibly returned 375 persons in March 2018, and 136 of these were convicted offenders.

The Conference Board Total Economy Database Summary Tables November 2016

The National Police Immigration Service (NPIS) forcibly returned 429 persons in January 2018, and 137 of these were convicted offenders.

ARABPLAST 2019 FACT SHEET

The National Police Immigration Service (NPIS) returned 444 persons in August 2018, and 154 of these were convicted offenders.

World Peace Index Its Significance and Contribution to the Scientific Study of World Peace

LIST OF CHINESE EMBASSIES OVERSEAS Extracted from Ministry of Foreign Affairs of the People s Republic of China *

ELEVENTH EDITION 2018 A COMPREHENSIVE GUIDE TO SHIP ARREST & RELEASE PROCEDURES IN 93 JURISDICTIONS

Cambridge International Examinations Cambridge International Advanced Subsidiary and Advanced Level

Countries for which a visa is required to enter Colombia

The Cultural Origin of Saving Behaviour. Joan Costa Font, LSE Paola Giuliano, UCLA Berkay Ozcan*, LSE

Rankings: Universities vs. National Higher Education Systems. Benoit Millot

Higher education global trends and Emerging opportunities to 2020

Markets in higher education

Does One Law Fit All? Cross-Country Evidence on Okun s Law

Global Trends in Occupational Therapy. Ritchard Ledgerd Executive Director

Table A.2 reports the complete set of estimates of equation (1). We distinguish between personal

Second EU Immigrants and Minorities, Integration and Discrimination Survey: Main results

HUMAN RESOURCES IN R&D

Contributions to UNHCR For Budget Year 2014 As at 31 December 2014

A Global Perspective on Socioeconomic Differences in Learning Outcomes

Global Trends in Location Selection Final results for 2005

ASYLUM IN THE EU Source: Eurostat 4/6/2013, unless otherwise indicated ASYLUM APPLICATIONS IN THE EU27

SEVERANCE PAY POLICIES AROUND THE WORLD

The Three Elephants in the Room: Coal, Oil and Gas in the Primary Energy Consumption (PEC) and their CO2 Emissions up to 2013 Bernard CHABOT

CHILE NORTH AMERICA. Egypt, Israel, Oman, Saudi Arabia and UAE. Barge service: Russia Federation, South Korea and Taiwan. USA East Coast and Panama

Appendix to Sectoral Economies

2017 Social Progress Index

International investment resumes retreat

Share of Countries over 1/3 Urbanized, by GDP per Capita (2012 $) 1960 and 2010

KPMG: 2013 Change Readiness Index Assessing countries' ability to manage change and cultivate opportunity

Brigitte D Heygere. Senior Vice President Strategic Business Plan

Business Data For Engaging in International Real Estate Transactions in Idaho. National Association of REALTORS Research Division

2013 Country RepTrak Topline Report The World s View on Countries: An Online Study of the Reputation of 50 Countries

Estimating the foreign-born population on a current basis. Georges Lemaitre and Cécile Thoreau

Exploring relations between Governance, Trust and Well-being

Estimates of International Migration for United States Natives

SKILLS, MOBILITY, AND GROWTH

India, Bangladesh, Bhutan, Nepal and Sri Lanka: Korea (for vaccine product only):

The High Cost of Low Educational Performance. Eric A. Hanushek Ludger Woessmann

IMMIGRATION IN THE EU

TI Corruption Perception Index 1996

Trends in international higher education

Monitoring social and geopolitical events with Big Data

The Political Economy of Public Policy

A GAtewAy to A Bet ter Life Education aspirations around the World September 2013

AUSTRALIA S REFUGEE RESPONSE NOT THE MOST GENEROUS BUT IN TOP 25

Health Workforce and Migration : an OECD perspective

Dashboard. Jun 1, May 30, 2011 Comparing to: Site. 79,209 Visits % Bounce Rate. 231,275 Pageviews. 00:03:20 Avg.

PISA 2009 in Hong Kong Result Release Figures and tables accompanying press release article

Consumer Barometer Study 2017

GERMANY, JAPAN AND INTERNATIONAL PAYMENT IMBALANCES

Widening of Inequality in Japan: Its Implications

geography Bingo Instructions

Excuse me for my culture? Cultural Insights that Improve Safety. Dr. Nicklas Dahlstrom Human Factors Manager

GLOBALIZATION 4.0 The Human Experience. Presented to the World Economic Forum by SAP + Qualtrics

Human Resources in R&D

Emerging Asian economies lead Global Pay Gap rankings

Good Sources of International News on the Internet are: ABC News-

The Changing Relationship between Fertility and Economic Development: Evidence from 256 Sub-National European Regions Between 1996 to 2010

Transcription:

Online Appendix for Home Away From Home? Foreign Demand and London House Prices

List of Tables A.1 Summary statistics across wards..................... 14 A.2 Robustness of the results......................... 15 A.3 The role of individual components of the ICRG risk index....... 16 A.4 Cross-ward correlation between country of birth and ethnic group... 17 A.5 The role of isolated risk events...................... 18 A.6 Explaining cross-regional heterogeneity................. 19 A.7 Overview of sample composition..................... 2 A.8 Determinants of foreign demand effects across world regions...... 21 List of Figures A.1 Foreign-born people shares in London.................. 2 A.2 Average levels of political risk....................... 3 A.3 Cross-ward distribution of demographic, social and economic variables 4 A.4 Cross-ward distribution of the foreign-born people shares....... 5 A.5 Time series of capital flows into London s commercial real estate market 7 A.6 Foreign political risk and migration into the UK............ 8 A.7 Robustness check: clustering at the level of world regions....... 9 A.8 Simulation results: Identification of effects at different horizons.... 1 A.7 Nationalities of buyers in the Prime Central London area....... 13 A.8 Relationship between house prices and immigration shares....... 26

Figure A.1 Foreign-born people shares in London The figure reports the overall shares of foreign-born people in London. We use these shares in order to construct weighted averages of variables. India Bangladesh Jamaica Nigeria Pakistan Kenya Sri Lanka Cyprus South Africa USA South America Australia Germany Turkey Italy France Somalia North Africa Middle East New Zealand Hong Kong Spain....5 1 1.5 2 2.5 Poland Portugal Iran Japan Iraq Zimbabwe Malaysia Canada Sierra Leone China Greece Russia Sweden Singapore Netherlands Congo Belgium Denmark Austria Czech Republic Finland Romania....1.4 2

Figure A.2 Average levels of political risk The figure reports average levels of political risk, as captured by the ICRG indexes. In our estimation, we distinguish between countries with high political risk (higher than a threshold of 2) and low political risk (lower than 2). We adjust the raw index series reported by the PRS Group by subtracting them from a total value of 1. This insures that we can interpret higher index values as increases in risk. Somalia Iraq Nigeria Zimbabwe Pakistan Sierra Leone Algeria Bangladesh Congo Sri Lanka Kenya Lebanon Turkey Iran Egypt Syria India Russia Libya Israel China Brazil Saudi Arabia Argentina South Africa Romania Mexico Tunisia High risk countries... 2 4 6 8 Index value Jamaica Qatar Malaysia Greece UAE Spain Chile Cyprus Italy France Hong Kong Poland Czech Republic Japan Belgium USA Portugal Germany Singapore Australia Canada Austria Denmark New Zealand Netherlands Sweden Finland... Low risk countries 5 1 15 2 25 3 Index value 3

Figure A.3 Cross-ward distribution of demographic, social and economic variables The figure shows the distribution of selected variables, across the set of 624 London wards. We report the unit of measurement in parentheses, below the variable name. 1 5 Population density (no./ha) 2 1 Detached houses (percent) 6 4 2 Flats and maisonettes (percent) 1.6 118.8 236.1 3 6.1 2.1 48.6 95.1 4 6 4 2 Cars per household (no./hh.) 6 4 2 Net average income ( /week) 8 6 4 2 Median age (years) 1. 1.7 36 61 86 27. 36. 45. 6 4 2 Higher prof. occupations (percent) 8 6 4 2 Long term unemployed (percent) 1 5 Mortgage ownership (percent) 1.4 1 19. 1.8 3.4 24.8 53. 81.1

Figure A.4 Cross-ward distribution of the foreign-born people shares The figure shows the distribution of the shares of people born in respective countries or country groups, across the set of 624 London wards. We report the shares in percent of the total ward population. Austria.6 Belgium.7 Denmark.7 Finland.4 France 6.1 Germany.1 2.9 5 Greece 2.3 Italy 4.1 Netherlands.1.7 Portugal 3.9 Spain.1 1.9.6 Sweden 3.1 Czech Republic Romania Poland Russia Turkey Congo.5.1 2.9 1..6 7.4.7 Nigeria 11.5 Sierra Leone 2.8 Kenya.1 11. Somalia 3.7 South Africa 5.3.1 Zimbabwe.9

Figure A.4 Cross-ward distribution of the foreign-born people shares (continued) North Africa 4.9 Iran 2.7 Iraq 2.5 Middle East 3.9.6 Cyprus 1 China 1.2 6 Hong Kong.1 1.5.8 Japan 7.4 Malaysia 1.5 Singapore 1.2.6 South Africa 2.6.8 Bangladesh 32.3 India.1 25.7 Pakistan 9.5 Sri Lanka 8.1 Canada 1.3.6 USA 1.1 Jamaica 7.2 Australia New Zealand South America UK 3.1 2.9.1 2.2.1 41.7 96.

Figure A.5 Time series of capital flows into London s commercial real estate market The figure reports the evolution of capital inflows into the London commercial real estate market and their relationship with political risk. The data source is Real Capital Analytics. We report the sum of the total inflows from our sample countries with relatively high levels of political risk, as listed in Figure A.2. billion 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 21 211 212 213 37 36.5 36 35.5 35 34.5 34 33.5 33 ICRG index Capital inflows into commercial real estate sector (high risk countries) Aggregate level of political risk 7

Figure A.6 Foreign political risk and migration into the UK In this figure, we report the number of additional visas granted by the UK in 213, relative to 28. The line indicates univariate cross-country fitted values. On the horizontal axis, we report the change in political risk (measured by the ICRG index) between 28 and 213. In this representation, we exclude countries for which the number of visas or the number of people which enter the UK are equal to zero. Total number of visas Post crisis increase in UK visas granted (relative to base year) 2. Romania 1.5 Saudi Arabia 1..5 Congo Argentina Cyprus Hong Kong Libya Iraq Qatar Brazil Canada Egypt Chile Syria Japan Israel Singapore India France Pakistan LebanonMexico New Sri Lanka Algeria Zealand Australia Turkey ChinaTunisia Russia Malaysia.5 Zimbabwe Nigeria Kenya Jamaica Sierra Leone Bangladesh Somalia South Africa Iran 1. Austria Spain 1 5 5 1 15 2 Post crisis change in political risk (ICRG index) 8

Cumulative change in spreads (age points) Cumulative change in spreads (age points) Figure A.7 Robustness check: clustering at the level of world regions The figure reports the estimated average response of house prices in wards with high shares of foreign born people, following a shift to the high-risk regime. The empirical specifications corresponds to the following equations: s k t = µ k + δ t + ρ s k t 1 + L ζ l zt l k + u k t, and νt k = ω k + τ t + γ νt 1 k + l=1 L η l zt l k + ϵ k t, where zt k is the risk indicator of the ICRG index of political risk. In our benchmark specification, we consider the case L = 2 quarters. In Panel B, we report analogous impulse responses for the cross-ward spreads in transaction volumes and mortgage originations. The gray shaded areas (Registry dataset) and the dotted lines (Loans dataset) indicate 9% confidence intervals, based on double clustered standard errors at the region and year level. We determine the statistical significance of accumulated impulse responses and impute corresponding confidence intervals based on the critical values of the F-test. l=1 Panel A 4 3 2 1-1 2 4 6 8 1 12 14 16 18 2 Time horizon (quarters) 6 Registry dataset Loans dataset Panel B 4 2-2 -4-6 2 4 6 8 1 12 14 16 18 2 Time horizon (quarters) Volume of transactions Volume of mortgage loans 9

Figure A.8 Simulation results: Identification of effects at different horizons The table reports the distribution of estimated impulse responses across N = 2, Monte Carlo draws, based on the following assumption about the data-generating process: s t = ρ s t 1 + L l=1 ζ lz t l +u t. Here, z t is a random binary variable (z t {, 1}), that takes the value of 1 for a share q of the sample. We repeat the simulation for a set q {5,...,.55} (see horizontal axis). We further calibrate ρ =.11 and u t N(, 1.45), as estimated from our benchmark specification. We choose the number of observations T = 275 to correspond to the number of observations in our sample for the Southern Europe region. As in the benchmark specification, L = 2 quarters. For simplicity, we set ζ 1 = 1 and ζ l =, for l > 1, which corresponds to a flat impulse response profile. In Panel A, we report median estimates (thick lines) and respective 9 th percentiles (dotted lines). In Panel B, we report the standard deviation of estimated impulse responses across the full set of N replications. The dark black lines show estimated impulse responses for a horizon of 1 quarter, and light green lines for a horizon of 8 quarters. The vertical dotted lines indicate the actual frequency of risk shocks q = 6 for the Southern European region. In Panel C, we repeat the exercise by varying the persistence of the risk shock. In each period t, we draw a random risk shock. With a probability ρ, the risk regime continues in period t + 1. With a probability 1 τ, a new shock is re-drawn. By construction, the frequency of the risk shock is 5% in this case. The dark black lines show estimated impulse responses for a horizon of 1 quarter, and light green lines for a horizon of 8 quarters. The vertical dotted lines indicate the actual persistence of risk shocks τ = 7 for the Southern European region. Panel A Distribution of estimated impulse responses 2 1.5 Median (Horizon = 1 quarter) Median (Horizon = 8 quarters) 1 th and 9 th percentiles 1.5 -.5-1 Southern Europe (6).1.4.5.6 Frequency of risk shocks 1

Simulation results: Identification of effects at different horizons (continued) 1.8 Panel B Standard deviation of estimated impulse responses Horizon = 1 quarter Horizon = 8 quarters.6.4 Southern Europe (6).1.4.5.6 Frequency of risk shocks 11

Simulation results: Identification of effects at different horizons (continued).4 5 Panel C Standard deviation of estimated impulse responses Horizon = 1 quarter Horizon = 8 quarters 5 Southern Europe (7).15.1.1.4.5.6.7.8.9 Persistence of risk shocks 12

Figure A.7 Nationalities of buyers in the Prime Central London area 13

Table A.1 Summary statistics across wards The table reports mean values for selected variables, calculated for the wards in the top quintile of the respective distributions, according to the share of people born in our set of country regions. The population density is calculated using the usual resident population and the size of the area in hectares. The market share of flats indicates all people who were usually resident in the area at the time of the 21 census, who lived in an unshared dwelling, that was a flat, maisonette or apartment, as a percent of the total ward population. Net average income levels are estimated by the UK Office for National Statistics and expressed in pounds sterling per week. The information on vehicle ownership is based on the number of cars or vans owned, or available for use, by one or more members of a household, including company cars or vans available for private use. The share of people in higher professional occupations is reported as classified by the UK Office for National Statistics. The war`d-level degree of mortgage ownership is given by the number of households in the area at the time of the 21 census, who are holders of a residential mortgage, as a fraction of the total number of homeowners. 14 Population Market share Net Cars per Higher prof. Mortgage density of flats income household occupations holders (no/ha) (percent) ( /week) (no/hh.) (percent) (percent) Top 2% of wards with highest Southern Europe 11.99 68.51 58.8.63 1.86 55.71 shares of people born in: Eastern Europe 85.56 5.59 63.28.81 1.6 55.41 Russia 94.8 59.84 598.73 1.85 54.81 Middle East 9.17 54.38 537.1.73 8.51 57.16 Africa 77.9 46 494.82 6.27 61.35 South Asia 76.17 34.4 497.1.86 6.22 61.24 Asia-Pacific 97.42 62.38 641.28.73 12.74 54.92 South and Central America 89.76 48.87 484.24.68 6.52 63.81 UK 38.4 14.95 553.2 1.15 4.92 58.86 Full sample of wards 7.68 39.41 546.14.88 7.62 59.88

Table A.2 Robustness of the results The table reports estimated cumulative impulse responses of cross-ward price spreads to a foreign risk shock, based on the following model specification: s k t = µ k + δ t + ρ s k t 1 + L ζ l zt l k + u k t, where zt k is an indicator variable which takes the value of one if the respective risk measure is in the high-risk regime. We report impulse responses at a horizon of 2 years (8 quarters). The estimated impulse responses are multiplied by 1, for easier interpretation as percentage points. We use clustered standard errors at the country and year level. *, **, *** denote statistical significance at the 1%, 5%, and 1% level respectively. l=1 Robustness check: Property characteristics x ward fixed effects Foreign demand effect 1.27** Robustness check: Benchmark estimation excluding France Foreign demand effect 1.29** Placebo test: Benchmark estimation for low-risk countries Foreign demand effect -5 15

Table A.3 The role of individual components of the ICRG risk index Panel A reports the contribution of each of the 12 individual components to the total variation of quarterly changes of the ICRG index. Panel B reports estimation results from the following estimation specification: J=12 s k t = µ k + δ t + ρ s k t 1 + ζ j Zt 1 k + u k t, where Zt k is the level of the ICRG index of political risk in quarter t in country k. We use double clustered standard errors at the country and year level. *, **, *** denote statistical significance at the 1%, 5%, and 1% level, respectively. j=1 Panel A Variance decomposition of quarterly ICRG growth rates Government instability 19.8% Internal conflict 17.3% Investment profile 17.% External conflict 12.1% Socioeconomic conditions 7.2% Democratic accountability 6.9% Law and order 4.6% Military in politics 4.5% Corruption 4.% Ethnic tensions 3.7% Religion in politics 2.1% Bureaucratic quality.8% Panel B Contribution of individual ICRG components to foreign demand effects Religion in politics.184* External conflict.12** Internal conflict 8* Investment profile 75** Bureaucratic quality 59 Socioeconomic conditions 21 Ethnic tensions 7 Military in politics -19 Government instability -31 Corruption -9 Democratic accountability -.114 Law and order -56* 16

Table A.4 Cross-ward correlation between country of birth and ethnic group The table reports correlation coefficients between the ward-level share of people born in a given country and the share of the respective ethic group, relative to the total population of the ward. The difference between the two is that the latter measure also includes UK citizens and those that were born in the UK, but which belong to an ethnic group defined by the country of origin of their ancestors. are only able to compute these statistics for a small subset of the countries/world regions because the ethnic composition is recorded in the 21 census just for the nationalities/ethnic groups listed below. We Bangladesh.9991 Pakistan.9948 India.9751 China.8148 Africa.7579 17

Table A.5 The role of isolated risk events The table reports estimated cumulative impulse responses of cross-ward price spreads to a foreign risk shock, based on the following model specification: s k t = µ k + δ t + ρ s k t 1 + L ζ l zt l k + l=1 L ξ l z t l k + u k t. Here, z t k is an indicator variable which takes the value of one if two conditions are met: i) the ICRG index is in the high-risk regime in quarter t and ii) the ICRG index is not in the high-risk regime in any of h quarters before and after t. We report impulse responses at a horizon of 2 years (8 quarters). The estimated impulse responses are multiplied by 1, for easier interpretation as percentage points. We use clustered standard errors at the country and year level. *, **, *** denote statistical significance at the 1%, 5%, and 1% level respectively. l=1 z k t = 1 if no other risk event within: 3 quarters 4 quarters 5 quarters 6 quarters 7 quarters Foreign demand effect 1.3** 1.35** 1.35** 1.37** 1.35** - Isolated events 1.12** 1.11**.76**.7**.65** Number of obs. 175 175 175 175 175 Adj. R 2 8 8 8 8 8 18

Table A.6 Explaining cross-regional heterogeneity The table reports estimated coefficients from the following panel regression specification: ( ) L 4 s k t = µ k + δ t + ρ s k t 1 + ζ l + ξ j,l Fj k zt l k + u k t, l=1 j=1 where the F k variables are measures of population concentration within the city (calculated as crossward standard deviations), relative levels of riskiness (calculated as average levels of the ICRG index), inbound capital flows (calculated as relative contributions of different regions to total transaction volumes of commercial property in London) and inbound immigration flows (calculated as relative contributions of different regions to total registrations with National Insurance in London). For the two latter variables, we use region-level averages for each country in a given region. We report accumulated impulse responses for the horizons indicated in the column header. The estimated impulse responses are multiplied by 1, for easier interpretation as percentage points. Inference on the statistical significance of accumulated impulse responses is based on two-stage bootstrap standard errors, double-clustered at the country and year level. *, **, *** denote statistical significance at the 1%, 5%, and 1% level, respectively. 1 quarter 1 year Benchmark 2 years Unconditional effect -.9-1.7-1.85 Interaction terms: - Concentration within city.12-1 - Absolute level of riskiness.58 1.31 1.52 - Inbound capital flows 1.4 5.18 2.29 - Inbound immigration flows 2.54 2.33 5.47* Country fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Time fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Observations 1,75 1,75 1,75 Adj. R2 7 7.42 19

Table A.7 Overview of sample composition Number of obs. Relative freq. of Persistence Number of in high-risk regime high-risk regime of risk regime observations Africa 65 16.9% 9 385 South-Asia 43 19.5%.1 22 Middle East 37 13.5%.16 275 Southern Europe 15 5.5% 7 275 South-America 12 1.9% 4 11 Eastern Europe 7 4.2%.12 165 Russia 7 12.7% 1 55 Asia-Pacific 7 3.2%.17 22 Total 193 11.3%.19 175 2

Table A.8 Determinants of foreign demand effects across world regions Panel A reports measures of inbound capital flows (calculated as relative contributions of different regions to total transaction volumes of commercial property in London), population concentration within the city (calculated as cross-ward standard deviations), absolute levels of riskiness (calculated as average levels of the ICRG index) and inbound immigration flows (calculated as relative contributions of different regions to total registrations with National Insurance in London). The data sources are the commercial property transactions database provided by Real Capital Analytics, the Office of National Statistics, and the PRS Group. Panel B reports the relative measure of population concentration, calculated as the cross-ward standard deviation of foreign-born people shares, divided by the respective cross-ward mean. Panel A Population concentration within the city Absolute level of riskiness South-Asia 2.22 Africa 45.7 Middle East.6 South-Asia 45.29 Africa.59 Russia 38.59 South-America.59 Middle East 36.96 Southern Europe.41 South-America 29.1 Asia-Pacific 2 Eastern Europe 24.57 Russia.14 Southern Europe 21.77 Eastern Europe.14 Asia-Pacific 29 Inbound commercial property capital flows Inbound immigration flows Middle East 36.2% Eastern Europe 31.4% Asia-Pacific 32.5% South-Asia 21.6% Southern Europe 21.1% Southern Europe 19.% Russia 5.1% Asia-Pacific 11.4% South-Asia 4.8% Africa 9.7% South-America % Middle East 3.8% Eastern Europe.1% South-America 2.4% Africa % Russia.6% 21

Determinants of foreign demand effects across world regions (continued) Panel B Population concentration within the city (relative measure) South-Asia 1.8 Middle East 1.5 Africa 1.16 Southern Europe 1.13 Asia-Pacific 1.5 Eastern Europe.99 Russia.95 South-America.94 22

Bootstrap procedure For each of the N = 2, iterations, we start with residual bootstrap samples drawn from the transactions and loans datasets. We then construct a panel of estimated house price spreads s k t for each country k and quarter t. To account for the clustering of panel observations s k t in the second stage, we employ the procedure described by Cameron and Miller (215). We estimate equation (3) in three new separate residual bootstrap samples, and clusters are defined by the country level, the year level and the country cross year level, respectively. This procedure involves estimating 3N panel regressions for each model specification, and it delivers 3 estimated variance matrices. The final variance-covariance matrix is computed as the sum of the variance-covariance matrices obtained with clustering at the country and year level, subtracting the variancecovariance matrix obtained with clustering at the country cross year level. In some few cases, in the estimation of equation (6), we need to drop the extreme 1% of bootstrap draws, to insure that the estimated variance matrix is positive definite. We note that this two-stage correction is only necessary for the estimation of price effects. There is no first-stage estimation error in the computation of cross-ward volume spreads. 23

Immigration and House Prices One of the possibilities we consider in our specifications is that cross-border property investments into London are driven purely by a desire to move capital away from regions with high political and economic uncertainty, without any associated immigration of foreign purchasers into London. Yet another possibility is that safe-haven property investments incorporate an implicit or explicit future consideration by purchasers of future London-bound immigration. If this is indeed the case, when political or economic risks actually materialize, relatively fast moving capital flows towards London properties may be followed by relatively slow-moving subsequent increases in immigration. We therefore investigate whether price increases in wards with higher shares of foreign-born people are a signal of increased future immigration into those wards. Any such immigration might be expected to occur at a much lower frequency than the safe-haven price effects, with longer-lasting effects on the demographic structure of London. Given data availability, we use the U.K. Office for National Statistics census information recorded in 21 and 211 to test this hypothesis. We estimate the following regressions: f k w,211 = α + ρ k f k w,21 + π k 1 ln P w,21 + e k w,211, (A.1) f k w,211 = α + ρ k f k w,21 + π k 2 ln P w,21 + π k 3 u w,21 + e k w,211. (A.2) In these regressions, ln P w,21 is the actual log price change between 1996 and 21 in ward w, computed by equal-weighting prices of all properties transacted in ward w in each of those years. ln P w,21 and u w,21 are constructed by controlling for variation in price-impacting hedonic characteristics of properties at the ward level. ln P w,21 is the change in the fitted value of the price arising from hedonic price regressions in 1996 and 21 and u w,21 is the difference in the residuals from these regressions between these two time periods. In our interpretation of the results, we identify the coefficient π3 k with safe-haven demand effects for the purposes of this auxiliary exercise. We are limited by the fact that we only have two available vintages of the census data, from 21 and 211. Consequently, we are only able to run a cross-sectional regression to explain variation in the immigration share between these two vintages. This means that we cannot use time-variation in economic and political risk in our attribution of the impacts of safehaven demand effects on price, and hence, we simply attribute unexplained-by-hedonics variation in prices between 1996 and 21 ( u w,21 ) to safe-haven demand effects. If 24

other factors are responsible for this unexplained variation in prices, as long as they are uncorrelated with future immigration, we would expect them to act as classical measurement error, biasing π3 k towards zero. Together, specifications (A.1) and (A.2) allow us to check whether price changes have a role in predicting subsequent changes in future immigration over and above the lagged level of immigrants from country k residing in ward w. These regressions, while interesting, are only able to provide suggestive evidence on the interplay between house prices and immigration patterns, both across wards and through time. Figure A.8 shows estimates of equations (A.1) and (A.2). The figure shows that price changes in wards occurring between 1996 and 21 are a statistically significant and positive predictor of immigration occurring thereafter from Spain, Italy, Portugal, and China. The first bar in these plots corresponds to actual pre-21 price changes, while the second bar corresponds to the component of the price changes which is unexplained by property and ward characteristics. It is clear from these plots that the variation in hedonic characteristics between 1996 and 21 is not responsible for the predictive power of prices for the immigration shares. These results are consistent with safe-haven demand causing price pressure in ward-level house prices which subsequently results in immigration flows from these countries. However, it is worth noting here that we view this part of the analysis as far less precise than our earlier specifications which explain house price movements. The figures also show that these unexplained price changes are negative forecasters of immigration from the South Asian countries. This highlights another important limitation of this analysis of immigration, namely, that unexplained changes in wardlevel prices may be generated by a number of potential determinants, including safe haven flows from other countries. This in turn might act as a deterrent to relatively less well-off immigrants from other regions of the world. So, for example, if certain wards experienced unusual price increases from 1996 to 21 on account of safe-haven demand from, say, Russia, and if immigrants from, say, Sri Lanka shied away from wards with high price increases not caused by their own house purchases, then this would explain the negative coefficients π3 k that we detect for Sri Lanka. 25

Figure A.8 Relationship between house prices and immigration shares The figure reports the coefficients π k 1 and π k 3 from the regressions: f k w,211 = α + ρ k f k w,21 + π k 1 ln P w,21 + e k w,211, and f k w,211 = α + ρ k f k w,21 + π k 2 ln P w,21 + π k 3 u w,21 + e k w,211. Here, ln P w,21 is the actual log price change between 1996 and 21 in ward w, computed by equal-weighting prices of all properties transacted in ward w in each of those years. u w,21 is the residual price change in ward w, constructed by controlling for variation in price-impacting hedonic characteristics of properties at the ward level. ln P w,21 is the component of total price changes which can be attributed to changes in characteristics between the two time periods. The price variables are normalized by subtracting the in-sample mean and dividing by the standard deviation. The estimation sample consists of the 624 London wards. The total length of the bars indicates point estimates and the shaded areas correspond to 95% confidence intervals. The estimated standard errors are White heteroskedasticity-robust..15 Registry dataset.1 5 Italy China Spain Portugal India Sri Lanka Pakistan Loans dataset.15.1 5 Italy China Spain Portugal India Sri Lanka Pakistan Total average price changes Residual price changes 26