Growth and Poverty Reduction: An Empirical Analysis Nanak Kakwani

Similar documents
Interrelationship between Growth, Inequality, and Poverty: The Asian Experience

ERD. Working Paper. No. Interrelationship between Growth, Inequality, and Poverty: The Asian Experience. Hyun H. Son ECONOMICS AND RESEARCH DEPARTMENT

Asian Development Review

Growth, Inequality, and Poverty: An Introduction Nanak Kakwani, Brahm Prakash, and Hyun Son

Asian Development Bank Institute. ADBI Working Paper Series. Income Distributions, Inequality, and Poverty in Asia,

Income Distributions, Inequality, and Poverty in Asia,

Economic Growth and Poverty Alleviation in Russia: Should We Take Inequality into Consideration?

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr

Economic Growth, Income Inequality, and Poverty Reduction in People s Republic of China BO Q. LIN

Economic growth, inequality, and poverty in Vietnam

The Role of Labor Market in Explaining Growth and Inequality: The Philippines Case. Hyun H. Son

Does Inequality Matter for Poverty Reduction? Evidence from Pakistan s Poverty Trends

Poverty, Income Inequality, and Growth in Pakistan: A Pooled Regression Analysis

China s (Uneven) Progress Against Poverty. Martin Ravallion and Shaohua Chen Development Research Group, World Bank

The Real Wealth of Nations: Pathways to Human Development

Application of PPP exchange rates for the measurement and analysis of regional and global inequality and poverty

Poverty in Uruguay ( )

The Challenge of Inclusive Growth: Making Growth Work for the Poor

Inequality is Bad for the Poor. Martin Ravallion * Development Research Group, World Bank 1818 H Street NW, Washington DC

World Bank Releases World Development Indicators Seeking Alpha

The Social Policy and Development Centre (SPDC)

Poverty and Inequality

Augustin Kwasi Fosu 1. December 2010

The Trends of Income Inequality and Poverty and a Profile of

A poverty-inequality trade off?

ERD. Working Paper. Defining and Measuring Inclusive Growth: Application to the Philippines. Ifzal Ali and Hyun H. Son

Poverty and Inequality

PERSISTENT POVERTY AND EXCESS INEQUALITY: LATIN AMERICA,

Southern Africa Labour and Development Research Unit

Is the Great Gatsby Curve Robust?

POLICY OPTIONS AND CHALLENGES FOR DEVELOPING ASIA PERSPECTIVES FROM THE IMF AND ASIA APRIL 19-20, 2007 TOKYO

Poverty, growth and inequality

Trade led Growth in Times of Crisis Asia Pacific Trade Economists Conference 2 3 November 2009, Bangkok. Session 10

Spatial Inequality in Cameroon during the Period

INCLUSIVE GROWTH AND POLICIES: THE ASIAN EXPERIENCE. Thangavel Palanivel Chief Economist for Asia-Pacific UNDP, New York

ESTIMATING INCOME INEQUALITY IN PAKISTAN: HIES TO AHMED RAZA CHEEMA AND MAQBOOL H. SIAL 26

The Ghana Poverty and Inequality Report: Using the 6th Ghana Living Standards Survey 2016

Trends in inequality worldwide (Gini coefficients)

Determinants of Violent Crime in the U.S: Evidence from State Level Data

Household Income inequality in Ghana: a decomposition analysis

19 ECONOMIC INEQUALITY. Chapt er. Key Concepts. Economic Inequality in the United States

CHAPTER 2 LITERATURE REVIEWS

A Structural Analysis of Growth and Poverty in the Short-Term

vi. rising InequalIty with high growth and falling Poverty

Poverty of Ethnic Minorities in the Poorest Areas of Vietnam

Poverty and Inequality

Accounting for the role of occupational change on earnings in Europe and Central Asia Maurizio Bussolo, Iván Torre and Hernan Winkler (World Bank)

INCOME INEQUALITY WITHIN AND BETWEEN COUNTRIES

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE LABOR MARKET IMPACT OF HIGH-SKILL IMMIGRATION. George J. Borjas. Working Paper

There is a seemingly widespread view that inequality should not be a concern

Remittances and Poverty. in Guatemala* Richard H. Adams, Jr. Development Research Group (DECRG) MSN MC World Bank.

Impacts of Economic Integration on Living Standards and Poverty Reduction of Rural Households

Is Global Inequality Really Falling?

Poverty, Livelihoods, and Access to Basic Services in Ghana

Inequality in Indonesia: Trends, drivers, policies

Research Paper No. 2006/41 Globalization, Growth and Poverty in India N. R. Bhanumurthy and A. Mitra *

DRIVERS OF DEMOGRAPHIC CHANGE AND HOW THEY AFFECT THE PROVISION OF EDUCATION

The Impact of Trade Liberalisation on Poverty and Welfare in South Asia: A Special Reference to Sri Lanka

Poverty Profile. Executive Summary. Kingdom of Thailand

Inequality and economic growth

Lao People's Democratic Republic

Explanatory note on the 2014 Human Development Report composite indices. Cambodia. HDI values and rank changes in the 2014 Human Development Report

Tourism, Poverty and Taxation: A Case of Thailand

POVERTY IN MALAWI, 1998

Was the Late 19th Century a Golden Age of Racial Integration?

This note analyzes various issues related to women workers in Malaysia s formal private

Economic Growth and Poverty Reduction: Lessons from the Malaysian Experience

Table A.2 reports the complete set of estimates of equation (1). We distinguish between personal

Chapter. Sampling Distributions Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved

Unequal Provinces But Equal Families? An Analysis of Inequality and Migration in Thailand 1

Income Distributions and the Relative Representation of Rich and Poor Citizens

Explanatory note on the 2014 Human Development Report composite indices. Solomon Islands

Global Income Inequality by the Numbers: In History and Now An Overview. Branko Milanovic

Levels and Trends in Multidimensional Poverty in some Southern and Eastern African countries, using counting based approaches

Poverty in the Third World

Poverty and Inequality

HOW ECONOMIES GROW AND DEVELOP Macroeconomics In Context (Goodwin, et al.)

International Remittances and the Household: Analysis and Review of Global Evidence

Assessment of the Impact of Pro-Poor Growth on Poverty in Developing Countries

Demographic Changes and Economic Growth: Empirical Evidence from Asia

Cross-Country Intergenerational Status Mobility: Is There a Great Gatsby Curve?

THE IMPACT OF INTERNATIONAL AND INTERNAL REMITTANCES ON HOUSEHOLD WELFARE: EVIDENCE FROM VIET NAM

REVIEW POVERTY, INCOME INEQUALITY, AND HEALTH CARE CONSUMPTION IN THAILAND

Human Capital and Income Inequality: New Facts and Some Explanations

Growth and inequality effects on poverty reduction in Italy

International Trade and Inequality

Inequality and Poverty in Rural China

The Trade Liberalization Effects of Regional Trade Agreements* Volker Nitsch Free University Berlin. Daniel M. Sturm. University of Munich

Poverty, Inequality and Trade Facilitation in Low and Middle Income Countries

CH 19. Name: Class: Date: Multiple Choice Identify the choice that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Trade, Employment and Inclusive Growth in Asia. Douglas H. Brooks Jakarta, Indonesia 10 December 2012

PROJECTION OF NET MIGRATION USING A GRAVITY MODEL 1. Laboratory of Populations 2

ECONOMIC GROWTH* Chapt er. Key Concepts

East Asian Currency Union

Volume 36, Issue 1. Impact of remittances on poverty: an analysis of data from a set of developing countries

Outline: Poverty, Inequality, and Development

Rewriting the Rules of the Market Economy to Achieve Shared Prosperity. Joseph E. Stiglitz New York June 2016

Research Report. How Does Trade Liberalization Affect Racial and Gender Identity in Employment? Evidence from PostApartheid South Africa

Analyzing the Nature and Quantifying the Magnitude of the Employment Linkage 03

Is Government Size Optimal in the Gulf Countries of the Middle East? An Answer

Transcription:

Growth and Poverty Reduction: An Empirical Analysis Nanak Kakwani Abstract. This paper develops an inequality-growth trade off index, which shows how much growth is needed to offset the adverse impact of an increase in inequality on poverty. The empirical analysis based on this index shows that pro-poor policies will have a greater payoff for poverty reduction in Thailand, while growthmaximizing policies may be more adequate for Korea and Lao PDR. For the Philippines, a mixture of growth and pro-poor policies may be deemed as adequate. Further, the paper shows that countries with low initial inequality will have a greater poverty reduction payoff from growth, whereas countries with high initial inequality will have a greater poverty reduction payoff from pro-poor policies. Finally, the paper suggests that if our focus is on ultra poverty, then pro-poor policies would be of greater benefit. Introduction H ow sensitive is the incidence of poverty to economic growth? This issue has been the subject of extensive research in recent years. A large amount of cross-country evidence suggests that growth and poverty reduction are strongly positively correlated. This result is consistent with the trickle down theory that some benefits of growth will always trickle down to the poor. Thus, the incidence of poverty can diminish with growth even if the poor receive only a small fraction of total benefits. A recent World Bank study by Dollar and Kraay (2000) has come out with a much stronger result that the income of the poor rises one-for-one with overall growth. It means that the proportional benefits of growth enjoyed by the poor are the same as those by the nonpoor. An important implication of this research is that growth is good for the poor irrespective of the nature of growth. Thus, governments Nanak Kakwani is a professor in the University of New South Wales. The author wishes to acknowledge the expert assistance provided by Hyun Son. Asian Development Review, vol. 18, no. 2, pp. 74-84 2000 Asian Development Bank

Growth and Poverty Reduction: An Empirical Analysis 75 need not follow pro-poor polices with a focus on poverty reduction. To achieve a rapid reduction in poverty, they should focus on maximizing economic growth while maintaining macroeconomic stability. The World Bank study, although highly influential, is based on cross-country regressions, which can indicate only the average trends. Individual country experiences can be quite different. We cannot have the same policy prescriptions for all countries. For some countries, the growth-maximizing policies may be adequate but for other countries, there may be a need to have pro-poor growth policies with a focus on reducing inequality (for a detailed discussion of pro-poor growth see Kakwani and Pernia 2000). The degree of poverty depends upon two factors: average income and income inequality. The increase in average income reduces poverty and the increase in inequality increases it. Thus, the change in poverty can be decomposed into two components: one is the growth component relating to change in mean income, and the other is the inequality component relating to change in inequality. The magnitudes of two components provide the relative sensitivity of poverty reduction to growth and inequality. It is obvious that if the growth component dominates over the inequality component, then growth-maximizing policies may be adequate in achieving a rapid reduction in poverty. If the inequality component dominates, then the policies that are pro-poor and thus reduce inequality should be adopted. The main objective of the present paper is to measure the tradeoff between inequality and growth, which shows how much growth is needed in order to offset the adverse impact of an increase in inequality on poverty. The magnitude of this tradeoff is estimated for four countries, namely, Republic of Korea (Korea), Thailand, Lao PDR, and Philippines. These four countries are at different stages of development and will require different policies to achieve a rapid reduction in poverty. The magnitude of the inequality growth tradeoff gives an indication of the policies that individual countries should follow. Economic Growth and Poverty Reduction Suppose income x of an individual is a random variable with distribution function given by F(x). Let z denote the poverty line, then H = F(z) is the proportion of individuals whose income falls below the poverty line or H is the proportion of poor in the society. H is the most popularly used poverty measure and is called the headcount ratio. The headcount ratio is a crude measure of poverty. The percentage of the population that is poor does not reflect the intensity of poverty suffered by the poor. A suitable measure of poverty should take into account the following three indicators of poverty:

76 Asian Development Review (i) percentage of poor (ii) aggregate poverty gap (iii) distribution of income among the poor A general class of a poverty measure, which combines these three characteristics of poverty can be written as ( z, x) θ = z P f ( x) dx (1) 0 where f(x) is the density function of x and P P < 0, > 0, 2 x x 2 P ( z, z) = 0 and ( z x) P, is a homogenous function of degree zero in z and x. Foster, Greer, and Thorbecke (1984) proposed a class of poverty measures that is obtained by substituting α z x P(z, x) = (2) z in (1), where α is the parameter of inequality aversion. For α = 0, θ = H, that is, the headcount ratio. This measure gives equal weight to all poor irrespective of the intensity of their poverty. For α =1, each poor is weighed by his or her distance from the poverty line, relative to z. This measure is called the poverty gap ratio. For α =2, the weight given to each poor is proportional to the square of his or her income shortfall from the poverty line. This measure is called the severity of poverty ratio. This measure satisfies all the three indicators of poverty stated above. The degree of poverty depends on two factors: the average level of income and the extent of inequality in income distribution. Thus a poverty measure can always be written as ( µ, L( p) ) θ = θ (3) where µ is the mean income of the society and L(p) is the Lorenz function measuring the relative income distribution. L(p) is the percentage of income that is enjoyed by the bottom p percent of the population.

Growth and Poverty Reduction: An Empirical Analysis 77 The growth effect measures the effect of a change in µ on θ when L(p) remains constant. On the other hand, the redistribution (or inequality) effect measures the effect of a change in L(p) on θ when µ remains constant. The total effect of economic growth on poverty can be decomposed into two factors: (i) the impact of growth when the inequality does not change, and (ii) the impact of change in inequality when the mean income of the society is kept constant. The measures of these two effects are presented in the next two sections. Growth Effect To measure the growth effect, Kakwani (1993) derived the elasticity of θ with respect to µ, keeping L(p) fixed. This elasticity is given by 1 z P η θ = x f ( x) dx (4) θ 0 x P which is always negative in view of < 0. For the headcount measure P(z,x) = 1, x the elasticity is derived as ( z) zf η H = < 0 (5) H which is the percentage of poor who will cross the poverty line as a result of a 1 percent growth in the mean income of the society. Substituting (2) into (4) gives the elasticity of the Foster, Greer, and Thorbecke class of poverty measures denoted by θ α with respect to µ as θα ηα = µ µ θ α α θ = ( θ ) α 1 θ α α (6) for α 0, which will always be negative because θα is a monotonically decreasing function of α. This elasticity for the poverty gap ratio is obtained by substituting α = 1 in (6), which gives µ η1 = ( z µ ) (7)

78 Asian Development Review where µ is the mean income of the poor. µ The magnitude of η 1 depends on, which measures the depth of poverty. z µ The smaller is, the greater is the depth of poverty. It can be noted that the z µ absolute magnitude of elasticity in (7) is an increasing function of, from which z we may conclude that the impact of economic growth on poverty reduction (when inequality does not change) is smaller (larger) when the depth of poverty is larger (smaller). Inequality Effect η α is the pure growth elasticity, measuring the impact of economic growth on poverty reduction when the inequality of income (measured by the Lorenz curve) does not change with growth. However, economic growth may increase or decrease inequality. Growth may be called pro-poor if it reduces inequality so that the poor benefit proportionally more than the rich. The measurement of the effect of inequality on poverty is a difficult task because inequality can change in infinite ways. Here we follow Kakwani (1993) and make a simple assumption that the entire Lorenz curve shifts. Using this assumption, the elasticity of poverty with respect to the Gini index can be written as 1 z Ρ θ = ( x µ ) f ( x) dx, (8) θ 0 x which shows that if the economic growth leads to an increase in the Gini index by 1 percent, the incidence of poverty will increase by ε θ percent, provided the poverty line is less than the mean income µ. For the Foster, Greer, and Thorbecke poverty measures, the inequality elasticity is given by αθα 1 ( µ z) εα = µ + (9) θ z α For α Ο. This elasticity for the poverty gap ratio is obtained by substituting α = 1 in (9), which gives

Growth and Poverty Reduction: An Empirical Analysis 79 ( µ µ ) ε1 = ( z µ ) (10) which will always be positive. µ It can be seen that ε 1 increases monotonically with, which implies that z the adverse impact of increase in inequality on poverty will be larger (smaller) when the depth of poverty is smaller (larger). Tradeoff between Inequality and Poverty Economic growth increases mean income, which has an impact of reducing poverty. If economic growth also increases inequality, then poverty increases. What is the tradeoff between inequality and growth? If the Gini index increases by 1 percent, how much should be the growth rate in order that poverty does not increase? The total proportional change in poverty may be written as dθ dµ dg = ηθ + ε θ (11) θ µ G where the first term in the right-hand side measures the impact of growth on poverty (affecting the mean income) and the second component measures the impact of change in the Gini index on poverty. Equating the total proportionate change in poverty to zero, we obtain the inequality growth tradeoff index (IGTI) as µ G εθ IGTI = φθ = = (12) G µ η θ If, for example, IGTI is equal to 3.0, it means that a 1 percent increase in the Gini index will require a growth rate of 3 percent in order to offset the adverse impact of increase in inequality. It also means that by following pro-poor policies, if we can reduce the Gini index by 1 percent, then this policy is equivalent to having an additional 3 percent growth rate. This suggests that the larger the IGTI, the greater will be the benefits of following pro-poor policies that would reduce inequality. The IGTI for the Foster, Greer, and Thorbecke class of poverty measures is given by

80 Asian Development Review φα = zθα z + ( µ z) θα ( θα 1 θα) 1 (13) Substituting α =1 in (13) gives the IGTI for the poverty gap ratio as θ 1 = ( ) µ µ µ which is clearly a decreasing function of µ. This means that the greater the poverty depth, the larger the IGTI. Thus, in the countries, where poverty depth is higher, then pro-poor policies will be more effective in reducing poverty. Empirical Analysis The methodology developed herein is applied to four countries, namely, Korea, Thailand, Lao PDR, and Philippines. These countries are at different levels of development with different levels of poverty and inequality. Korea and Thailand are cited as tiger economies in the Asian and Pacific region. Their per capita GDP growth has been on average over 6 percent for a long period of time until the economic crisis in mid-1997 brought a halt to their impressive growth performance. Although both countries have experienced a rapid reduction in poverty, Korea s performance in poverty reduction has been much superior (Kakwani and Son 2000). Korea achieved high growth while maintaining low inequality whereas Thailand achieved high growth but at the cost of acquiring high inequality. The Philippines s performance in both growth and poverty reduction has not been so good compared with Korea and Thailand. While its growth rate has been much lower, it has maintained a high level of inequality and also high incidence of poverty. Lao PDR is the poorest of the three countries. Almost 45 percent of the population were identified as poor in 1992-1993; fortunately the percentage of poor declined to about 38.7 percent in 1997-1998 (Kakwani 2000b). The rapid poverty reduction was achieved due to an average annual growth rate of 4.6 in the per capita real GDP during the past five years. Poverty elasticity was computed using the unit record data for the four countries. To compute the elasticity we need to know the poverty threshold for each country. We utilized the threshold for each of the four countries (Kakwani and Prescott 1999 for Korea, Kakwani and Krongkaew 2000 for Thailand, Kakwani 2000a for the Philippines and Kakwani 2000b for Lao PDR). The values of growth and inequality elasticity along with the IGTI index are presented in Table 1.

Growth and Poverty Reduction: An Empirical Analysis 81 Table 1: Growth and Inequality Elasticity and their Tradeoff Poverty Gap Ratio Severity of Poverty Ratio Growth Inequality Growth Inequality Countries Elasticity Elasticity IGTI Elasticity Elasticity IGTI Thailand, 1998-2.94 11.96 4.07-3.27 16.65 5.10 Philippines, 1998-1.83 4.25 2.32-2.15 6.77 3.14 Korea, 1998-3.52 4.32 1.23-3.76 6.24 1.66 Lao PDR, 1997-1998 -2.41 2.27 0.94-2.90 3.83 1.32 IGTI means inequality growth tradeoff index. The value of IGTI for Thailand is computed to be 4.04 (for the poverty gap ratio), which means that an increase of 1 percent in the Gini index will require a growth rate of about 4 percent in order that the incidence of poverty does not change. It also means that a reduction of inequality by 1 percent is equivalent to having a growth rate of 4 percent. This result suggests that a strategy of inequality reduction will have greater payoff for poverty reduction than the strategy of promoting economic growth. This cannot be said for Korea and Lao PDR. The values of the IGTI for Korea and Lao PDR are 1.23 and 0.94, respectively. These results suggest that the payoff for the strategy of inequality reduction in these countries is much lower and therefore the growth maximization may be adequate for them to achieve a rapid reduction in poverty. For the Philippines, the value of IGTI is 2.32, which is much lower than that of Thailand but much higher than that of Korea and Lao PDR. Thus for the Philippines, a mixture of growth and pro-poor policies may be deemed as appropriate. How does the initial level of inequality affect the choice of policies? To see this effect, we generated a new income distribution by uniformly shifting the Lorenz curve of the original income distribution downward by 5 percent so that the new distribution had the same mean income as the original distribution but a 5 percent higher value for the Gini index. This new distribution is referred to as the distribution with high inequality. Similarly, we generated a low inequality distribution by uniformly shifting the Lorenz curve upward by 5 percent, which will have a 5 percent lower value for the Gini index. The original income distribution is referred to as the distribution with medium inequality. We computed the IGTI for the three income distributions. The empirical results given in Table 2 show that the value of IGTI increases monotonically with inequality; the higher the inequality, the greater the value of IGTI. This result holds for all the four countries. From these results, we may conclude that the countries with a higher initial level of inequality may be able to reduce poverty more rapidly by following inequality-reducing policies. The countries with low initial inequality can afford to follow growth-maximizing policies.

82 Asian Development Review Table 2: Growth and Inequality Elasticity and their Tradeoff for Different Levels of Initial Inequality Poverty Gap Ratio Severity of Poverty Ratio Growth Inequality Growth Inequality Countries Elasticity Elasticity IGTI Elasticity Elasticity IGTI Thailand, 1998 Low Inequality -4.22 15.52 3.68-4.84 21.03 4.34 Medium Inequality -2.94 11.96 4.07-3.27 16.65 5.10 High Inequality -2.08 9.56 4.60-2.23 13.78 6.17 Korea, 1998 Low Inequality -4.02 4.69 1.17-4.37 6.68 1.53 Medium Inequality -3.52 4.32 1.23-3.76 6.24 1.66 High Inequality -3.06 3.98 1.30-3.25 5.86 1.80 Lao PDR, 1997-1998 Low Inequality -2.73 2.39 0.88-3.31 3.97 1.20 Medium Inequality -2.41 2.27 0.94-2.90 3.83 1.32 High Inequality -2.13 2.17 1.02-2.55 3.70 1.45 Philippines, 1998 Low Inequality -2.27 4.75 2.10-2.75 7.45 2.71 Medium Inequality -1.83 4.25 2.32-2.15 6.77 3.14 High Inequality -1.49 3.86 2.59-1.69 6.23 3.69 IGTI means inequality growth tradeoff index. Do we need to follow different policies when our focus is on reducing ultra poverty? To investigate this question, we computed the IGTI for the ultrapoor, who are defined as those having a lower poverty line. The poverty line was uniformly reduced by 20 percent. The calculated values of the IGTI for the poor and ultrapoor are presented in Table 3. It is noted that the value of IGTI is uniformly higher for the ultrapoor compared to those for the poor. This suggests that inequality-reducing policies will be more beneficial for the ultrapoor than for the poor. Thus, if our focus is on reducing ultra poverty, then we should be more inclined to adopt pro-poor policies.

Growth and Poverty Reduction: An Empirical Analysis 83 Table 3: Growth and Inequality Elasticity and their Tradeoff for Poor and Ultrapoor Poverty Gap Ratio Severity of Poverty Ratio Growth Inequality Growth Inequality Countries Elasticity Elasticity IGTI Elasticity Elasticity IGTI Thailand, 1998 Poor -2.94 11.96 4.07-3.27 16.65 5.10 Ultrapoor -3.35 17.21 5.14-3.67 23.13 6.30 Korea, 1998 Poor -3.52 4.32 1.23-3.76 6.24 1.66 Ultrapoor -3.82 6.63 1.74-4.09 9.12 2.23 Lao PDR, 1997-1998 Poor -2.41 2.27 0.94-2.90 3.83 1.32 Ultrapoor -3.05 3.90 1.28-3.38 5.86 1.73 Philippines, 1998 Poor -1.83 4.25 2.32-2.15 6.77 3.14 Ultrapoor -2.17 6.35 2.92-2.45 9.50 3.87 IGTI means inequality growth tradeoff index. Conclusion A simple message of this paper is that we cannot have the same policies for all countries. For some countries, growth-maximizing policies may be adequate and for others, there may be a need to have pro-poor policies focusing on reducing inequality. The choice of policies may be made based on the inequality growth tradeoff index, which has been developed in the paper. The empirical analysis shows that pro-poor policies will have a greater payoff for poverty reduction in Thailand, while growth-maximizing policies may be more adequate for Korea and Lao, PDR. For the Philippines, a mixture of growth and pro-poor policies may be deemed as adequate. Further, the paper indicates that the initial level of inequality is important in determining the appropriate policies for a country. Countries with low initial inequality will have a greater poverty-reduction payoff from growth, whereas countries with high initial inequality will have a greater poverty-reduction payoff from pro-poor growth. Finally, the paper suggests that the poverty-reduction payoff from growth is lower for the ultrapoor than for the poor. Thus, if our focus is on reducing ultra poverty, then pro-poor policies would be of greater benefit.

84 Asian Development Review References Dollar, D., and A. Kraay, 2000. Growth is Good for the Poor. The World Bank, Washington, D.C. Foster, J., J. Greer, and E. Thorbecke, 1984. A Class of Decomposable Poverty Measures. Econometrica 52(3):761-66. Kakwani, N., 1993. Poverty and Economic Growth with Application to Cote D Ivoire. Review of Income and Wealth 39(2, June):121-39., 2000a. Poverty, Inequality and Wellbeing with Focus on Mindanao. Asian Development Bank, Manila. Mimeo., 2000b. Poverty in Lao PDR. Asian Development Bank, Manila. Mimeo. Kakwani, N., and M. Krongkaew, 2000. Analysing Poverty in Thailand. Journal of the Asia Pacific Economy 5(1&2):141-60. Kakwani, N., and E. Pernia, 2000. What is Pro-poor Growth? Asian Development Review 18(1):1-16. Kakwani, N., and N. Prescott, 1999. Impact of Economic Crisis on Poverty and Inequality in Korea. University of New South Wales, Sydney, Australia. Unpublished paper. Kakwani, N., and H. Son, 2000. Asian Recovery: A Social Perspective. Asian Development Bank, Manila. Mimeo.