Employer Attitudes, the Marginal Employer and the Ethnic Wage Gap *

Similar documents
Employer Attitudes, the Marginal Employer and the Ethnic Wage Gap *

Do Reported Attitudes towards Immigrants Predict Ethnic Discrimination?

MAGNUS CARLSSON, LUCA FUMARCO & DAN-OLOF ROOTH 2015:1. Does Labor Market Tightness Affect Ethnic Discrimination in Hiring?

Does Labor Market Tightness Affect Ethnic Discrimination in Hiring?

Field experiments on ethnic discrimination in the Swedish housing and labor market

Do Employers Use Unemployment as a Sorting Criterion When Hiring? Evidence from a Field Experiment

Neighborhood signaling effects, commuting time, and employment Evidence from a field experiment

Volume 29, Issue 4. Ethnic Discrimination in the Market Place of Small Business Transfers

Discrimination. Study Materials and Reading List Mariola Pytliková. VŠB-TechnicalUniversityOstrava, CReAM, IZA, CCP and CELSI

Uncertainty and international return migration: some evidence from linked register data

Applied Economics. Department of Economics Universidad Carlos III de Madrid

Volume 35, Issue 1. An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach

Does Work Experience Mitigate Discrimination?*

Bachelor essay. The relationship of earning differences and attitudes towards ethnic minority groups in Sweden

Benefit levels and US immigrants welfare receipts

Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US

Immigrant-native wage gaps in time series: Complementarities or composition effects?

Selection in migration and return migration: Evidence from micro data

Do when and where matter? Initial labor market conditions and immigrant earnings

English Deficiency and the Native-Immigrant Wage Gap

LABOUR-MARKET INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS IN OECD-COUNTRIES: WHAT EXPLANATIONS FIT THE DATA?

Table A.2 reports the complete set of estimates of equation (1). We distinguish between personal

Local labor markets and earnings of refugee immigrants

Seeking similarity: how immigrants and natives manage at the labor market

Immigrant Legalization

IS THE MEASURED BLACK-WHITE WAGE GAP AMONG WOMEN TOO SMALL? Derek Neal University of Wisconsin Presented Nov 6, 2000 PRELIMINARY

Employer Attitudes towards Refugee Immigrants

Permanent Disadvantage or Gradual Integration: Explaining the Immigrant-Native Earnings Gap in Sweden

Immigrant Assimilation and Welfare Participation Do Immigrants Assimilate Into or Out of Welfare?

Educated Preferences: Explaining Attitudes Toward Immigration In Europe. Jens Hainmueller and Michael J. Hiscox. Last revised: December 2005

Do Parties Matter for Fiscal Policy Choices? A Regression-Discontinuity Approach

Uppsala Center for Fiscal Studies

Immigration and Internal Mobility in Canada Appendices A and B. Appendix A: Two-step Instrumentation strategy: Procedure and detailed results

Explaining the 40 Year Old Wage Differential: Race and Gender in the United States

IMMIGRANT EARNINGS, ASSIMILATION AND HETEROGENEITY

Supplementary Materials for

Peers, neighborhoods and immigrant student achievement - evidence from a placement policy *

Effects of Institutions on Migrant Wages in China and Indonesia

THE GENDER WAGE GAP AND SEX SEGREGATION IN FINLAND* OSSI KORKEAMÄKI TOMI KYYRÄ

Human capital transmission and the earnings of second-generation immigrants in Sweden

F E M M Faculty of Economics and Management Magdeburg

Does Paternity Leave Matter for Female Employment in Developing Economies?

Is the Great Gatsby Curve Robust?

Ethnic enclaves and welfare cultures quasi-experimental evidence

IMMIGRATION REFORM, JOB SELECTION AND WAGES IN THE U.S. FARM LABOR MARKET

Urban Segregation and Employment Access of Ethnic Minorities. Yves Zenou, Stockholm University and GAINS

Ethnic Intergenerational Transmission of Human Capital in Sweden

Source country culture and labor market assimilation of immigrant women in Sweden: evidence from longitudinal data

Do (naturalized) immigrants affect employment and wages of natives? Evidence from Germany

December Do Doctors Lose from the Immigration of Doctors?* Per Lundborg** CEIFO, Stockholm university and SULCIS, Stockholm university

English Deficiency and the Native-Immigrant Wage Gap in the UK

Culture, Gender and Math Revisited

SIMPLE LINEAR REGRESSION OF CPS DATA

Honors General Exam PART 3: ECONOMETRICS. Solutions. Harvard University April 2014

Practice Questions for Exam #2

Corruption, Political Instability and Firm-Level Export Decisions. Kul Kapri 1 Rowan University. August 2018

Explaining Cross-Country Differences in Attitudes Towards Immigration in the EU-15

Wage Differences Between Immigrants and Natives in Austria: The Role of Literacy Skills

Crime and Corruption: An International Empirical Study

Wage Trends among Disadvantaged Minorities

Consequences of Immigrating During a Recession: Evidence from the US Refugee Resettlement Program

A Longitudinal Analysis of Post-Migration Education

Self-employed immigrants and their employees: Evidence from Swedish employer-employee data

I'll Marry You If You Get Me a Job: Marital Assimilation and Immigrant Employment Rates

Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation

Correcting Mistakes: Cognitive Dissonance and Political Attitudes in Sweden and the United States

Wage Differentials and Wage Determinants:

Inter- and Intra-Marriage Premiums Revisited: It s Probably Who You Are, Not Who You Marry!

Non-Voted Ballots and Discrimination in Florida

The Effect of Ethnic Residential Segregation on Wages of Migrant Workers in Australia

Labor Market Dropouts and Trends in the Wages of Black and White Men

TITLE: AUTHORS: MARTIN GUZI (SUBMITTER), ZHONG ZHAO, KLAUS F. ZIMMERMANN KEYWORDS: SOCIAL NETWORKS, WAGE, MIGRANTS, CHINA

I ll marry you if you get me a job Marital assimilation and immigrant employment rates

DETERMINANTS OF IMMIGRANTS EARNINGS IN THE ITALIAN LABOUR MARKET: THE ROLE OF HUMAN CAPITAL AND COUNTRY OF ORIGIN

Family Ties, Labor Mobility and Interregional Wage Differentials*

EXAMINATION 3 VERSION B "Wage Structure, Mobility, and Discrimination" April 19, 2018

Differential effects of graduating during a recession across gender and race

Dynamics of employment assimilation

Wage Effects of Search Methods for Immigrants and Natives: the Case of Sweden

Appendix to Sectoral Economies

Why Does Birthplace Matter So Much? Sorting, Learning and Geography

Congruence in Political Parties

School Performance of the Children of Immigrants in Canada,

Immigrant Employment and Earnings Growth in Canada and the U.S.: Evidence from Longitudinal data

Intergenerational Mobility, Human Capital Transmission and the Earnings of Second-Generation Immigrants in Sweden

Differences in remittances from US and Spanish migrants in Colombia. Abstract

Gender Wage Gap and Discrimination in Developing Countries. Mo Zhou. Department of Agricultural Economics and Rural Sociology.

Mother tongue, host country income and return migration

Bank Deregulation and Racial Inequality in America

The Evolution of Black-White Wage Inequality across Occupational Sectors in the US since the 1990s

Gender wage gap in the workplace: Does the age of the firm matter?

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE LABOR MARKET IMPACT OF HIGH-SKILL IMMIGRATION. George J. Borjas. Working Paper

Does the Concentration of Immigrant Pupils Affect the School Performance of Natives?

THREE ESSAYS ON THE BLACK WHITE WAGE GAP

Does Owner-Occupied Housing Affect Neighbourhood Crime?

Final, Form A Winter 2007 C. Tremblay

Are New Work Practices and New Technologies Biased against Immigrant Workers?

ETHNIC ENCLAVES AND IMMIGRANT LABOR MARKET OUTCOMES: QUASI-EXPERIMENTAL EVIDENCE 1

Supporting Information Political Quid Pro Quo Agreements: An Experimental Study

Congressional Gridlock: The Effects of the Master Lever

Transcription:

[Preliminary first version] Employer Attitudes, the Marginal Employer and the Ethnic Wage Gap * by Magnus Carlsson Linnaeus University & Dan-Olof Rooth Linnaeus University, IZA and CReAM Abstract: This study explores the link between employer attitudes toward ethnic minorities and the ethnic wage gap in the Swedish labor market. The analysis proceeds in two steps. First we conduct a field experiment on hiring in order to establish that a randomly selected employer is more likely to discriminate a minority job applicant in regions where the average employer has more negative attitudes. This analysis concludes that ethnic minority workers have an incentive to sort away from the most prejudiced employers in the labor market. If such sorting occurs the relative wage for minority workers will, according to Becker s theory of discrimination, be determined by the attitudes of the marginal employer. Hence, in the second step we contrast the impact of the attitudes of the marginal employer with the impact of the attitudes of the average employer on the ethnic wage gap. We find evidence for Becker s argument in that the ethnic wage gap is only affected by the attitudes of the marginal employer, but not by the one of the average employer. JEL classification: J64, J71 Key words: field experiments on hiring, employer discrimination, negative attitudes, ethnic wage gaps, regional variation * We would like to thank Olof Åslund, Oddbjörn Raaum and Matti Sarvimäki for helpful comments to this first draft. A research grant from the Faculty of Business, Economics and Design at Linnaeus University, one from the Centre for Economic Demography at Lund University, and another from the Swedish Council for Working Life and Social Research are gratefully acknowledged. School of Business and Economics, Linnaeus University, SE-391 82 Kalmar, Sweden; phone: +46 480 497187; email: Magnus.Carlsson@lnu.se Corresponding author. School of Business and Economics, Linnaeus University, SE-391 82 Kalmar, Sweden; phone: +46 480 497134; email: Dan-Olof.Rooth@lnu.se.

1. Introduction In many European countries, including Sweden, it has been observed that ethnic minorities perform worse in the labor market compared to the native population. Negative attitudes among employers toward minority workers have been suggested as one factor that potentially can explain part of the ethnic gaps that are observed in the labor market. However, very few studies have jointly analyzed attitudes and labor market outcomes in order to establish this link. 1 Typically, researchers have instead focused on either conducting surveys in order to measure attitudes or attempted to measure ethnic wage and employment gaps in the labor market. In the present study, we explore the attitude-discrimination link by analyzing the consequences of negative attitudes among employers for the ethnic wage gap in the Swedish labor market. We do this by taking into consideration one of Becker s (1957) important insights, namely, the distinction between the attitudes of a randomly selected employer and the attitudes of the marginal employer the employer that determines the relative market wage for minority workers. This distinction emerges because minority workers can sort away from the most prejudiced employers in the labor market. As a result, the market wage for minority workers is, according to Becker s model, determined by the most prejudiced employer that still hires some minority workers - the marginal employer. In order to analyze the consequences of negative attitudes for the ethnic wage gap we proceed in two steps. In the first step, we examine if there exist an incentive for minority worker to sort in accordance to Becker s model. This is done by analyzing hiring 1 A recent study is Charles & Guryan (2008). A Swedish study is Waisman & Larsen (2008). 1

discrimination at a randomly selected firm. More specifically, we conduct a field experiment where fictitious job applications which are randomly assigned either a native Swedish or an ethnic minority sounding name are sent to employers who advertise for labor. This approach guarantees that the researcher observes the same variables as the employers do and therefore a difference in the probability of being invited to a job interview can only be because the employers act on the name of the applicant. It is this difference in probabilities that quantifies the degree of discrimination. An incentive for minority workers to sort away from the most prejudiced employers requires a link between employers attitudes and the degree of ethnic discrimination such that more prejudiced employers also are more likely to discriminate. The existence of such a link is a basic assumption in Becker s model, which we test empirically by exploiting regional variation in attitudes as well as in the degree of ethnic discrimination. In the second step we analyze the consequences of negative attitudes among the employers for the ethnic wage gap in Sweden in a situation when sorting across employers is allowed for, that is, in a situation when the market clears. This step basically replicates the approach used by Charles & Guryan (2008), but for the Swedish case. We approximate the attitude of the marginal employer in a region with the score of the attitude measure being located at the regions share of minority workers. This adjusted attitude measure is then related to the ethnic wage gap at the regional level. In the field experiment we find that applicants with a Middle Eastern sounding name have approximately ten percentage points lower probability of being invited to an interview compared to applicants with a native Swedish sounding name. 2 More 2 This finding is in line with previous Swedish field experiments on ethnic discrimination in hiring, see Carlsson & Rooth (2007), Carlsson (2010) and Bursell (2007) 2

interestingly, the results also show that the estimated level of discrimination is correlated with attitudes at the regional level such that employers are more likely to discriminate in regions where attitudes towards ethnic minorities are more negative. This supports the existence of a link between prejudice in the public, employer prejudice and employer discrimination as in Becker s model. In light of this result minority workers have an incentive to sort away from the most prejudiced employers, since these employers are less likely to hire minority workers. The results from the analysis on the ethnic wage gap also indicate that to be the case since the attitudes of the marginal employer affect the ethnic wage gap, while the attitudes of the average employer does not. This difference between the impact of the attitudes of the marginal and the average employer is precisely what to expect if minority workers sort away from the most prejudiced employers in the labor market. The remaining of this paper is organized as follows. Section 2 reviews some previous studies in this area, while Section 3 presents the attitude measure being used. Section 4 then analyses the association between the attitude measure and the degree of discrimination found in the field experiment, while Section 5 analyses the association between the attitude measure and the ethnic wage gap. Section 6 closes the article with a discussion of the results. 2. Previous studies The second step of our analysis, that is, when the attitude measure is related to the ethnic wage gap at the regional level, is inspired by Charles & Guryan (2008). They test and confirm the predictions from Becker s (1957) seminal work on wage differentials and 3

employer prejudice by utilizing regional variation in population attitudes. Focus is on the attitudes of the marginal discriminator and not on the share of individuals with negative attitudes in a region. This is motivated by the fact that in Becker's original model Blacks are assumed to sort away from the employers with the most negative attitudes. The intuition is that if there is relatively low supply of Black workers (given by S 1 in Figure 1) there are enough non-discriminating employers so Blacks and Whites have equal wages. *** Figure 1 about here *** However, if the relative supply of Black workers shifts to S 2, there will not be enough non-discriminatory employers. In this case the attitudes of the marginal employer will determine the relative wage for Black workers. If a shift of the relative demand curve occurs from D to D such that the negative attitudes increases among those likely to be the marginal employer the relative wage for Black workers will decrease. This figure illustrates that when minority workers sort to the least prejudiced employers it is the attitudes of the marginal employer that matters most for the relative wage, not the share of employers with negative attitudes. Charles & Guryan relate wage differentials between White and Black workers to employer prejudice at the state level in the U.S. One of their main results is that the attitudes of the marginal employer significantly and negatively influences that White-Black wage gap, while they do not find such an effect for the average level of attitudes. 4

Another related study is Waisman & Larsen (2008) who take a somewhat different view on sorting. Instead of measuring the market wage differential, the case where sorting occurs, they take advantage of a Swedish refugee settlement policy, which basically implies random placement of refugees in regions, in an attempt to remove geographic sorting. However, sorting between employers within a region is still possible in their study. They find that negative attitudes increases the ethnic wage differential and also influences future mobility decisions of refugee immigrants away from more discriminating regions. Rooth & Aslund (2005) utilize the change in attitudes toward ethnic minorities following the terror attacks in New York on September 11, 2001, as a natural experiment to measure if a negative attitude has an affect on the labor market opportunities of minorities. They use this event as an exogenous attitude shifter and find that the relative probability of employment for minorities did in fact not decrease after 9/11. One possible explanation for this finding is that the attitudes of the marginal employer is more important than the average level of attitudes and that the attitudes of the marginal employer were unaffected by 9/11, that is, even if the average level of attitudes increased this increase only occurred because of more negative attitudes among employers to the right of the marginal employer in the prejudice distribution. Rooth (2010) also analyze the relationship between attitudes and discriminatory behavior, but at the firm level. In his study, recruiters from a sample of firms were involved in two experiments: a field experiment on discrimination in hiring and an experiment that measures their implicit attitudes as an IAT-score. This study finds that recruiters with higher IAT-scores which imply more negative implicit attitudes are 5

less likely to invite applicants with a Middle Eastern sounding name to a job interview compared to applicants with a typical Swedish name. Hence, he finds evidence for an existing link between employer attitudes and discrimination in hiring when sorting is not allowed for. 3. The attitude measures We find it quite likely that it is the same mechanisms that are the basis of the employers attitudes and the attitudes of the general public within a region. This assumption motivates the approximation of employer s average attitudes with the attitudes of the general public. To this end we use data obtained from FSI, which is a Swedish research institute that, among other things, measures attitudes of the Swedish population in various dimensions. 3 The attitude survey is conducted each year on a random sample of individuals in the population. By merging the years 2000 to 2008 a sample consisting of 19,555 respondents was obtained. The attitude measure that will be used in this study is constructed from the following question (own translation from Swedish): What do you think of the immigrants that we have received as a contribution to the Swedish population? The possible answers were 1) Very valuable, 2) Quite valuable 3) Not very valuable, 4) Not valuable at all, and 5) unsure, do not know. 4 For each respondent we also have information on in which municipality he or she lives at the time of the survey. This information is then used to construct two different attitude measures at the municipality level. The first measure is defined as the share in the municipality that responded 3 This is also the data being used by Aslund and Rooth (2005). 4 The survey also contained other question about immigrants and immigration to Sweden. However, these questions were more about immigration legislation, while the chosen question is about the immigrant group as individuals. 6

alternative 4 Not valuable at all, while the second measure is defined as the share that responded either 3 Not very valuable or 4 Not valuable at all. *** Figure 2 and 3 about here *** Figure 2 and 3 show the attitude distribution according to these two measures for the 290 municipalities in Sweden. As stated above we make the implicit assumption that the attitudes among the public also reflects, or proxies for, the attitudes of the employers. These two measures have a correlation of.82. 4. Hiring discrimination in the field experiment The field experiment on hiring, also being referred to as correspondence testing is a type of experiment where fictitious job applications are sent to real job openings was conducted within a large ethnic discrimination project. In this type of experiments ethnicity is being signaled by the name of the job applicant. Hence, we decided upon the names of the applicants, having either a typical Swedish or Middle Eastern sounding male name. The motivation for choosing the Middle Eastern minority group is that surveys indicate that the perceived level of discrimination is worst against individuals with a Middle Eastern background (see Lange, 2000; FSI, 2004). In this kind of experiment there can by construction be no sorting of applicants since the names of the applicants are randomly attached to the application by the researcher. Thus, the measured level of discrimination in this case is what the level of discrimination would be in the market if applicants with Swedish and Middle Eastern sounding names 7

applied for the same jobs. 5 By analyzing if this measure of discrimination co-varies with attitudes over municipalities it is possible to establish whether there exists an incentive for applicants with Middle Eastern sounding names to sort away from discriminating employers in the labor market. 4.1. Sampling During the experiment which was conducted from March 2007 to October 2007 all employment advertisements in thirteen selected occupations 6 found on the webpage of the Swedish employment agency were collected. 7 For these advertised jobs, 5,657 applications, 2,837 with a typical Swedish name and 2,820 with a Middle Eastern sounding name, were sent to 3,325 employers. All applications were sent by email; a clear majority of employers posting vacant jobs at this site accept applications by email. Jobs were applied to all over Sweden. For construction purposes, the applicants always signaled living in one of the two major cities of Sweden, Stockholm or Gothenburg, even when they applied for jobs in other areas of Sweden. Callbacks for interview were received via telephone (voice mailbox) or e-mail. To minimize inconvenience to the employers, invitations were promptly declined. 5 It should be noted here that not allowing for sorting is one of the main criticisms James Heckman (1998) points out when relying on the results of situation testing to inform on the level of ethnic discrimination in the labor market. 6 The thirteen included occupations were: shop sales assistants, cleaners, construction workers, restaurant workers, mechanics, motor-vehicle drivers, accountants, primary school teachers (math/science), primary school teachers (language), high school teachers, business sales assistants, computer professionals, and nurses. 7 According to labor related laws all new vacancies should be reported to the Swedish employment agency. However, these laws are not enforced and all vacancies are therefore not reported. Still it is the one site where most vacant jobs are to be found. 8

4.2. Generating applications One of the most important steps in conducting the field experiment was to create realistic job applications that fulfilled their purpose. Typical correspondence studies vary only the name put in the application (see Rich and Riach, 2002). The current field experiment uses a more general approach by also randomly varying other attributes. However, the starting point in this field experiment was similar as for the standard correspondence study. The first step was to construct a fixed frame, without content, for the resumes that determined typeface, layout and number of pages for the resumes. When constructing this frame, we took advantage of applications available on the webpage of the Swedish employment agency and our experience from previous conducted field experiments, see Carlsson and Rooth (2007), Rooth (2009), and Carlsson (2010). In the end, all applications consisted of two pages: a personal letter on one page and a CV on a second page. 4.3. Descriptive results The descriptive results of the field experiment are summarized in Table 1. 2,837 applications with native Swedish sounding names where sent, which in 762 cases resulted in an invitation to an interview. This corresponds to a callback rate of 26.9 percent. The corresponding figures for applicants with Middle Eastern sounding names are 2,820, 491, and 17.4, respectively. Hence, on average, there is a statistical significant difference of 9.5 percentage points in the callback rate favoring applicants with native Swedish sounding names. *** Table 1 about here *** 9

This difference is in line with Carlsson and Rooth (2007) and Bursell (2007) which also used the correspondence study methodology to measure ethnic discrimination in hiring. Carlsson (2010) found a larger ethnic difference in the callback rate, a potential explanation is that this experiment used applications signaling more qualified applicants, which helped job applicants with a native Swedish sounding name more. 4.4 Attitudes and discrimination In order to analyze whether negative attitudes against the minority have an effect on the difference in the probability of being invited to an interview for majority and minority job applicants we exploit variation in such attitudes across regions, that is, across municipalities. Using all 5,637 applications, the following equation was estimated using a Probit model (reporting marginal effects from the dprobit command in Stata and clustering standard errors on the job level). 8 Callback Attitudes in municipality i 1 Minority i 2 3 (1) i Attitudes in Minority municipality i i i Callback i is an indicator that equals one if sending application i resulted in an job interview offer, is the intercept for applicants with native Swedish sounding names, while 1 is the difference in the intercept for applicants with minority, in this case Middle Eastern, sounding names, and 2 is the slope coefficient for applicants with 8 The results are not sensitive to whether using the margfx command in Stata or the linear probability model. 10

native Swedish sounding names. Finally, the parameter of interest is 3, which measures if the slope coefficient is different for applicants with Middle Eastern sounding names, that is, if the probability of being invited to an interview for applicant with Middle Eastern sounding names is influenced, compared to applicants with native Swedish sounding names, by the attitudes in the municipality. In the first specification, a continuous variable is used as the attitude measure. The results are presented in Table 2. In the first two columns, a negative attitude is defined as the share in a region answering alternative three or four, while in the last two columns a negative attitude is defined as the share in a region answering alternative 4. The interaction variable between the share with negative attitudes in a municipality and the ethnic minority dummy variable constitute the explanatory variable of interest. Equation (1) is estimated both for all fourteen occupations as well as for only low skilled occupations. *** Table 2 about here *** As can be seen from the third row, the parameter estimate of the variable of interest is negative but only significant in one case. However, we suspect that there is scope for measurement error in the attitude measure since there are very few respondents in some municipalities. Therefore we proceed by constructing a dummy variable as our measure of attitudes. This dummy is constructed by simply dividing the municipalities into two groups, depending on whether the share of respondents with negative attitudes in the municipality is below or above the Swedish average. This should reduce the problem 11

with measurement error since most municipalities are expected to be correctly classified as being above or below the average. Equation (1) is then re-estimated with this newly constructed dummy variable. The results are presented in Table 3. *** Table 3 about here *** As can be seen from the last row, negative attitudes have in this model a significant effect, especially for low skilled occupations, on the difference in the probability of being invited to an interview for applicants with native Swedish and Middle Eastern sounding names. This ethnic gap is wider in municipalities where the attitudes are more negative. So far, we have shown that in the Swedish labor market there is ethnic discrimination in hiring at a randomly selected firm. Moreover, our results show that the probability of being invited for an interview is lower for applicants with Middle Eastern sounding names in municipalities where the attitudes is more negative than average. This means that there is a link between public prejudice, employer prejudice and discriminatory behavior when hiring. Therefore minority workers have an incentive to sort away from the most prejudiced employers. In the next section, we analyze the consequences of prejudice among employers for the ethnic wage gap when allowing for sorting by minority job applicants away from the most discriminating employers. 5. The ethnic wage gap In this section we proceed by in principle replicating the research design used by Charles and Guryan (2008) but for the Swedish case, and the analysis is performed on public 12

micro data. As shown in the previous section, minority workers have an incentive to sort away from the most prejudiced employers. Thus, market discrimination is expected to be lower compared to discrimination at a randomly selected firm in the field experiment. In this analysis, the same attitude measure will be used as in the previous section, and as before we will exploit differences in attitudes across municipalities. To start with, the share with negative attitudes among the public, which we assume also reflects the share with negative attitudes among employers, will be related to the ethnic wage differential. However, as explained earlier and motivated by Becker s theory, the relevant attitude measure to determine the relative wage for minority workers is the attitude of the marginal employer. Therefore we proceed by also analyzing how much of the ethnic wage gap can be explained by this particular measure of attitudes. Before turning to the analysis, let us clarify how sorting of minority members across municipalities because of wage differentials between municipalities would affect the results. If moving across municipalities is costless then the supply curves would shift such that the wage gap would be the same in all municipalities and the marginal discriminator would have the same attitudes in all municipalities. In other words, the implicit assumption we make is that there is a cost associated with moving across municipalities. This cost is the reason why we observe variation in the ethnic wage gaps and in the attitudes of the marginal discriminators across municipalities, which we exploit in the analysis. 13

5.1 Data The data consists of Swedish population data for 2003 taken from the registers at Statistics Sweden. The analysis is restricted to study only males aged 35-45 (more than 500,000 individuals), which is a subgroup of individuals that is likely to have stable income from work. In fact, we argue that the variation in our measure of earnings closely mimics the variation in the hourly wage. Annual earnings are the product of weeks worked during the year, hours worked per week, and the hourly wage. Since higher earnings are more likely to be based on similar amounts of time worked (hours and weeks), if we are right using a threshold for earnings should give an estimate of the ethnic gap that comes closer to the one expected for (log) hourly wages (if such data was available). 9 This seems to be the case since we get very similar results when we estimate the ethnic earnings gap for those earning above 100,000 SEK as when using the full data. The analysis is further restricted to study only individuals that are either native Swedes or have a non-nordic foreign background. An individual with a non-nordic foreign background is defined as a person who either immigrated from a non-nordic country more than 15 years ago (13,000 individuals) or is born in Sweden but has at least one parent born outside Scandinavia (24,000 individuals). This choice of ethnic groups is chosen in order not to erroneously exchange ethnic wage gaps with immigrant wage gaps, with the latter being more difficult to intepret/explain. Our dependent variable of interest will be log earnings (which includes the self-employed). The raw ethnic earnings gap in this subpopulation is approximately -13 percent. 9 Antelius and Björklund (2000) show, for Swedish circumstances, that if a threshold of 100,000 SEK (approximately 10,000 euro) is used when analyzing annual earnings based on tax records, one receives a return to education similar to the one obtained from analyzing hourly wages. 14

5.2 Empirical analysis and results The ethnic wage gap will be related to the fraction of individuals with negative attitudes in the municipality and also to the attitude of the marginal discriminator in the municipality. Our approximation of the attitude of the marginal discriminator is the answer (being 1 to 4) to the attitude question at percentile p of the answer distribution, where p is the fraction of individuals with foreign background in the municipality. Since it turns out that the percentile p always maps exactly on either answer 1 or 2 of the question, this measure is transformed into a dummy variable that equals zero if the marginal discriminator answered alternative 1 and one if the marginal discriminator answered alternative 2. Hence, the variation across regions in this measure, the marginal, might be different from the average attitude. In fact, the two measures have a very low correlation (r=.14). As discussed earlier, if minority members sort away from the most discriminatory employers this measure should be more related to the ethnic wage gap than the share with negative attitudes in the municipality. However, we start by analyzing how the share with negative attitudes among the public relates to the ethnic wage gap. The regression analysis controls for age, years of schooling and the share of individuals with a foreign background from outside the Nordic countries. The purpose with including the share of individuals with foreign background is to take into account the problem with unobserved variables. One possibility is that individuals with foreign background have poorer unobserved characteristics in municipalities with a large share of individuals with foreign background and that attitudes towards immigrants in such municipalities are more negative. Adding this control variable is an attempt to solve this issue. 15

The results for all occupations are presented in Table 4. Model 1 and 2 show the raw wage gap between majority and minority workers with and without municipality fixed effects. As can be seen in the third row in Model 3, 4 and 5 there is no evidence that the ethnic wage gap is related to the share of individuals among the public with negative attitudes towards immigrants in the municipality. Model 5 excludes municipalities with few individuals with foreign background; the results are essentially unaffected by this. *** Table 4 about here *** In the next step, we turn to the attitudes of the marginal discriminator and include the same control variables as before. As can be seen in the third row of column 2 and 3 in Table 5, the attitudes of the marginal discriminator are significantly related to the wage gap: the wage gap is approximately ten percent higher in municipalities where the marginal employer has more negative, or less positive, attitudes. *** Table 5 about here *** The analysis is repeated for low and medium skilled jobs. Table 6 is similar as before and shows the results for the fraction of individuals among the public that have negative attitudes. Not in this case either do we find any evidence for that this fraction is related to the wage gap. *** Table 6 about here *** 16

Turning to the marginal discriminator again reveals an even stronger relationship than for all occupations. This is in line with the results obtained in the field experiment. Our results in this section are also similar to what Charles & Guryan (2008) find for the U.S. *** Table 7 about here *** Before proceeding to the discussion we need to address the problem of omitted variable bias. We have tested for four possible such variables without finding them to impact on the main message being presented above. First, the purpose with including the share of individuals with foreign background in the municipality is precisely an attempt to take into account the problem with unobserved variables. One possibility is that individuals with foreign background have poorer unobserved characteristics in municipalities with a larger share of individuals with foreign background and that attitudes towards immigrants in such municipalities also are more negative. Adding (only) this control variable is an attempt to handle this issue and to exactly replicate the specification in Charles and Guryan (2008). Second, another unobserved variable that might be missing in the analysis is school quality. One possibility is that negative attitudes result in lower school quality for the minority. If this is observed by the employers, then the ethnic wage gap could to some extent reflect this, rather than negative attitudes among the employers. A potential solution to this problem is to, at the municipality level, control for average ethnic differences in scores at the standardized achievement tests that all pupils in Sweden take in math and language. 17

Third, controlling for variables that reflect local labor market conditions might also be important. Attitudes are (presumably) more negative in areas with poor labor market opportunities. Suppose that individuals with foreign background also have poorer unobserved characteristics in such areas. Without proper controls for local labor market conditions, there is a risk for obtaining a spurious correlation between attitudes and the ethnic wage gap in the analysis. This problem can potentially be solved by controlling for local labor market characteristics such as the number of long term unemployed and/or the local unemployment rate. Finally, an issue that concerns the measurement of the attitude of the marginal discriminator is that this measurement partly might be correlated with the share of individuals with foreign background in the municipality. To address this potential problem we have in the analysis included a linear control variable for the share of individuals with foreign background. However, the attitude measurement might also capture something related to the share of individuals with foreign background in a nonlinear way. An attempt to solve this would be to also include non-linear controls for the share of individuals with foreign background (a polynomial etc.) 6. Discussion This paper investigates the consequences of negative attitudes among the employers for the ethnic wage gap in the Swedish labor market. We started by confirming that there exists ethnic discrimination at a randomly selected firm in the Swedish labor market by conducting a field experiment. In the next step we took advantage of a survey to approximate the attitudes of the employers in the Swedish labor market. The constructed 18

attitude variable was then analyzed together with the results from the field experiment. This analysis showed that the probability of being invited to an interview for applicants with Middle Eastern sounding names is lower in municipalities where the attitudes among the employers are more negative. The experimental design allows us to interpret this as a causal effect, which was found especially strong for low skilled occupations. The conclusion from this part of the analysis is that minority groups such individuals with a Middle Eastern background have an incentive to sort away from the most prejudiced employers in the labor market. In the second part of the study we analyze the consequences of negative attitudes among employers for the ethnic wage gap by taking into account sorting in the analysis. In principle, this part replicates Charles and Guryan (2008) for the Swedish case. The findings here suggest that the attitudes of the marginal employer affects the ethnic wage gap, while there is no evidence for that the attitudes of the average employer is important for the wage gap. This is precisely what to expect if minority workers sort away from the most prejudiced employers in the labor market. Can this result be interpreted as a causal effect such that the attitudes of the marginal discriminator generate the ethnic wage gap? The main issue with this interpretation is the existence of municipality characteristics, which are not controlled for, and that are correlated both with unobserved productive characteristics of the minority and with attitudes. One way to try to address this problem is to include proper control variables at the municipality level, which did not change the results at this stage. 19

References Altonji, Joseph G. & Blank, Rebecca M. (1999), "Race and gender in the labor market," Handbook of Labor Economics, in: O. Ashenfelter & D. Card (ed.), Handbook of Labor Economics, edition 1, volume 3, chapter 48, pages 3143-3259 Elsevier. Aslund, O. & Rooth, D-O. (2005) "Shifts in attitudes and labor market discrimination: Swedish experiences after 9-11," Journal of Population Economics, 18(4): 603-629. Becker G. S. (1957) The Economics of Discrimination, Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Bertrand M. and Mullainathan S. (2004) Are Emily and Greg More Employable Than Lakisha and Jamal? A Field Experiment on Labor Market Discrimination, American Economic Review, 94(4): 991 1013 Bursell M. (2007) What's In a Name? A Field Experiment Test for the Existence of Ethnic Discrimination in the Hiring Process, Working Paper 2007:7, Linnaeus Center for Integration Studies (SULCIS), Stockholm University, Stockholm, Sweden Carlsson M. & Rooth D-O. (2007) Evidence of Ethnic Discrimination in the Swedish Labor Market Using Experimental Data, Labour Economics, 14(4): 716 729 Carlsson, M. (2010) "Experimental Evidence of Discrimination in the Hiring of First- and Second-generation Immigrants," LABOUR, 24(3): 263-278 Charles, K. & Guryan, J. (2008) "Prejudice and Wages: An Empirical Assessment of Becker's The Economics of Discrimination," Journal of Political Economy, 116(5): 773-809. FSI (2004), Några frågor om invandringen och invandrare/flyktingar, Forskningsgruppen för Samhälls-och Informationsstudier, Stockholm. Lange, A. (2000) Diskriminering, integration och etniska relationer. Integrationsverket, Norrköping. Riach, P. and Rich J. (2002) Field Experiments of Discrimination in the Market Place, The Economic Journal, 112: 480 518. Rooth, D-O (2010) "Automatic associations and discrimination in hiring: Real world evidence," Labour Economics, 17(3): 523-534. Waisman, G. & Larsen, B. (2008) "Do Attitudes Towards Immigrants Matter?" Linnaeus Center for Integration Studies (SULCIS) Working Papers 2008:5, Stockholm University, Stockholm, Sweden 20

Figures: Figure 1. The marginal discriminator. Notes: This figure is taken from Charles & Guryan (2008). 21

0 Share responding 4.1.2.3.4.5 0 Share responding 4.1.2.3.4.5 Figure 2. The share responding alternative 4 Not valuable at all. 0 100 200 300 290 municipalities (share sorted on size) Figure 3. The share responding 3 Not very valuable, or 4 Not valuable at all. 0 100 200 300 290 municipalities (share sorted on size) 22

Tables: Table 1. Result for correspondence testing. Typical Swedish name No. jobs = 2,837 Typical Middle Eastern name No. jobs = 2,820 Difference No. invitations to interview 762 491 Callback rate 26.9 17.4 9.5*** 2 Notes: This table reports the total result of the experiment. The critical -value at the one percent level of significance is 6.63 (***). The McNemar statistic for paired proportions is applied. Table 2. The probability of being invited to an interview Negative attitude = answering alternative 3 or 4 All occupations Low skilled occupations Middle Eastern sounding name -0,03 0,00 [0,05] [0,05] Share negative attitudes in municipality -0,11-0,10 [0,12] [0,13] Middle Eastern sounding name * -0,19-0,29* Negative attitude = answering alternative 4 All occupations Low skilled occupations -0,09*** -0,07** [0,03] [0,03] -0,11 0,18 [0,25] [0,27] -0,02-0,29 Share negative attitudes in municipality [0,15] [0,17] [0,32] [0,36] N 5635 3532 5635 3532 Notes: This table reports how attitudes affect the difference in the probability of being offered a job interview by using a continuous variable as attitude measurement. *, **, and *** denote the ten, five, and one percent significance level, respectively. Reported standard errors (in brackets) are adjusted for clustering on the job. Table 3. The probability of being invited to an interview Negative attitude = answering alternative 3 or 4 All Low skilled occupations occupations Middle Eastern sounding name -0,09*** -0,08*** [0,01] [0,01] Share negative attitudes in municipality above 0,00 0,00 average (Middle Eastern sounding name) * (Share negative attitudes in municipality above average) [0,02] -0,05* [0,03] [0,02] -0,07** [0,03] Negative attitude = answering alternative 4 All Low skilled occupations occupations -0,09*** -0,08*** [0,01] [0,01] -0,01 0,01 [0,02] [0,02] -0,03-0,05** [0,02] [0,02] N 5635 3532 5635 3532 Notes: This table reports how attitudes affect the difference in the probability of being offered a job interview, using a dummy variable as attitude measurement. *, **, and *** denote the ten, five, and one percent significance level, respectively. Reported standard errors (in brackets) are adjusted for clustering on the job. 23

Table 4. Log Earnings 2003. All occupations. Average attitudes. Variable (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) Minority -.145*** (.018) -.174*** (.012) -.149*** (.019) -.162*** (.015) -.176*** (.016) Average attitudes -.201*** (.068) Minority*Average attitudes -.095 (.162) -.172** (.080) -.097 (.170) -.205* (.109) -.094 (.164) Fraction immigrants.244 (.149).034 (.172) Municipality fixed effects no yes no no no R-square 0.06 0.08 0.06 0.06 0.07 No of observations 508,517 508.517 508,517 508.517 390,202 Note: *, **, and *** denote the 10, 5 and 1 percent significance level, respectively. Reported standard errors (in parentheses) are robust. The regression model also includes age and years of schooling. Table 5. Log Earnings 2003. All occupations. The marginal discriminator. Variable (1) (2) (3) Minority -.145*** (.018) -.082*** (.016) -.086*** (.016) Marginal discriminator.056*** (.015) Marginal discriminator*minority -.099*** (.026).040*** (.017) -.104*** (.024) Fraction immigrants.002 (.002) R-square 0.06 0.06 0.06 No of observations 508,517 508,517 508,517 Note: *, **, and *** denote the 10, 5 and 1 percent significance level, respectively. Reported standard errors (in parentheses) are robust. The regression model also includes age and years of schooling. 24

Table 6. Log Earnings 2003. Medium and lower level occupations. Average attitudes. Variable (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) Minority -.229*** (.021) -.218*** (.015) -.227*** (.022) -.216*** (.016) -.235*** (.017) Average attitudes.059 (.085) Minority*Average attitudes.125 (.167).047 (.075).119 (.163).103 (.108).116 (.161) Fraction immigrants -.164 (.152) -.302* (.179) Municipality fixed effects no yes no no no R-square 0.01 0.08 0.06 0.06 0.07 No of observations 290,867 290,867 290,867 290,867 290,867 Note: *, **, and *** denote the 10, 5 and 1 percent significance level, respectively. Reported standard errors (in parentheses) are robust. The regression model also includes age and years of schooling. Table 7. Log Earnings 2003. Medium and low level occupations. The marginal discriminator. Variable (1) (2) (3) Minority -.229*** (.021) -.137*** (.020) -.134*** (.020) Marginal discriminator -.004* (.017) Marginal disc*minority -.126*** (.030).011 (.013) -.120*** (.027) Fraction immigrants -.002 (.002) R-square 0.01 0.01 0.01 No of observations 290,867 290,867 290,867 Note: *, **, and *** denote the 10, 5 and 1 percent significance level, respectively. Reported standard errors (in parentheses) are robust. The regression model also includes age and years of schooling. 25