Changes in unit labour costs in Germany and in the euro area excluding Germany

Similar documents
Labour market of the new Central and Eastern European member states of the EU in the first decade of membership 125

SUMMARY LABOUR MARKET CONDITIONS POPULATION AND LABOUR FORCE. UNRWA PO Box Sheikh Jarrah East Jerusalem

SUMMARY LABOUR MARKET CONDITIONS !!! !!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!! POPULATION AND LABOUR FORCE. UNRWA PO Box Sheikh Jarrah East Jerusalem

Appendix A: Economic Development and Culture Trends in Toronto Data Analysis

ASSESSING THE ECONOMIC IMPACT OF FOREIGN WORKERS IN MALTA

Trends in Labour Supply

HAS GROWTH PEAKED? 2018 growth forecasts revised upwards as broad-based recovery continues

INCOME INEQUALITY WITHIN AND BETWEEN COUNTRIES

Selected macro-economic indicators relating to structural changes in agricultural employment in the Slovak Republic

Online Appendices for Moving to Opportunity

The widening income dispersion in Hong Kong :

Explanations of Slow Growth in Productivity and Real Wages

Mexico s Wage Gap Charts

EXPORT-ORIENTED ECONOMY - A NEW MODEL OF DEVELOPMENT FOR THE REPUBLIC OF MOLDOVA

Speech given by Mervyn King, Governor of the Bank of England. At Salts Mills, Bradford, Yorkshire 13 June 2005

Under-five chronic malnutrition rate is critical (43%) and acute malnutrition rate is high (9%) with some areas above the critical thresholds.

Lebanon. Lebanon: the largest per capita recipient of refugees in the world

Ghana Lower-middle income Sub-Saharan Africa (developing only) Source: World Development Indicators (WDI) database.

The present picture: Migrants in Europe

The Maori Population A Profile of the Trends Within Iwi Rohe

The Jus Semper Global Alliance Living Wages North and South

and with support from BRIEFING NOTE 1

HIGHLIGHTS. There is a clear trend in the OECD area towards. which is reflected in the economic and innovative performance of certain OECD countries.

Study. Importance of the German Economy for Europe. A vbw study, prepared by Prognos AG Last update: February 2018

Britain s Population Exceptionalism within the European Union

Policy brief ARE WE RECOVERING YET? JOBS AND WAGES IN CALIFORNIA OVER THE PERIOD ARINDRAJIT DUBE, PH.D. Executive Summary AUGUST 31, 2005

Lessons from the U.S. Experience. Gary Burtless

Effects of the increase in refugees coming to Sweden

Le Sueur County Demographic & Economic Profile Prepared on 7/12/2018

Vista. The Texas Mexico border is a fast-growing region, a complex blend of U.S. and Mexican cultures, languages and customs.

The outlook for EU migration if the UK remains subject to the free movement of people

Mexico s Wage Gap Charts

European Integration Consortium. IAB, CMR, frdb, GEP, WIFO, wiiw. Labour mobility within the EU in the context of enlargement and the functioning

1. Define GDP. The market value of all final goods and services produced within a nation in a given time period

Understanding the Macroeconomic Impact of Migration in Malta

VENEZUELA: Oil, Inflation and Prospects for Long-Term Growth

3 Maastricht Criteria and the Inclusion of Underground Economy - the Case of Croatia *

RIS 3 Sicily SICILY IN PILLS

A REBALANCING ACT IN EMERGING EUROPE AND CENTRAL ASIA. April 17, 2015 Spring Meetings

Support Materials. GCE Economics H061/H461: Exemplar Materials. AS/A Level Economics

Emerging Market Consumers: A comparative study of Latin America and Asia-Pacific

The impact of Chinese import competition on the local structure of employment and wages in France

Riverside Labor Analysis. November 2018

GDP - AN INDICATOR OF PROSPERITY OR A MISLEADING ONE? CRIVEANU MARIA MAGDALENA, PHD STUDENT, UNIVERSITATEA DIN CRAIOVA, ROMANIA

Inclusive growth and development founded on decent work for all

Socio-Economic Developments in the opt First Half 2008

A COMPARISON OF ARIZONA TO NATIONS OF COMPARABLE SIZE

Part 1: Focus on Income. Inequality. EMBARGOED until 5/28/14. indicator definitions and Rankings

Over the past three decades, the share of middle-skill jobs in the

3 How might lower EU migration affect the UK economy after Brexit? 1

Alberta Immigrant Highlights. Labour Force Statistics. Highest unemployment rate for landed immigrants 9.8% New immigrants

Post-Secondary Education, Training and Labour September Profile of the New Brunswick Labour Force

Foreign workers in the Korean labour market: current status and policy issues

SYRIAN REFUGEE LABOUR INTEGRATION POLICY IN JORDAN

Quarterly Labour Market Report. February 2017

Rising inequality in China

RE-SHORING IN EUROPE: TRENDS AND POLICY ISSUES

3 1-1 GDP GDP growth rate Population size Labor force Labor participation rate Employed population

POLICY BRIEF. Assessing Labor Market Conditions in Madagascar: i. World Bank INSTAT. May Introduction & Summary

Labor Force Structure Change and Thai Labor Market,

Outlook - Winter 2018

Assignment. "Economic Profile of Vietnam"

Trends in inequality worldwide (Gini coefficients)

Republic of Estonia. Action Plan for Growth and Jobs for the implementation of the Lisbon Strategy

European Integration Consortium. IAB, CMR, frdb, GEP, WIFO, wiiw. Labour mobility within the EU in the context of enlargement and the functioning

Social and Demographic Trends in Burnaby and Neighbouring Communities 1981 to 2006

Population and Dwelling Counts

Migration and the European Job Market Rapporto Europa 2016

London Measured. A summary of key London socio-economic statistics. City Intelligence. September 2018

Labour Market Reform, Rural Migration and Income Inequality in China -- A Dynamic General Equilibrium Analysis

Economic benefits of gender equality in the EU

Migration and Development Brief

The State of Working Wisconsin Laura Dresser Joel Rogers Julie Whittaker Center on Wisconsin Strategy

Executive summary. Strong records of economic growth in the Asia-Pacific region have benefited many workers.

Harnessing Remittances and Diaspora Knowledge to Build Productive Capacities

Edexcel (A) Economics A-level

Macroeconomic Outlook and Challenges for the CEE Region. Luboš Komárek CFO Executive Summit Prague, 29 th April 2015

Jens Thomsen: The global economy in the years ahead

Poverty profile and social protection strategy for the mountainous regions of Western Nepal

Four years of economic policy reforms in Spain: An analysis of results from an EU perspective

Remittances and the Macroeconomic Impact of the Global Economic Crisis in the Kyrgyz Republic and Tajikistan

Poverty and Inequality

Economic Effects in Slovenia within Integration in European Union

Poverty in the Third World

Inequality in Indonesia: Trends, drivers, policies

Overcoming Labor Shortages: Prospects for Sustainable Economic Growth

CER INSIGHT: The biggest Brexit boon for Germany? Migration. by Christian Odendahl and John Springford 11 December 2017

Where have all the Wages Gone?

The Impact of Foreign Workers on the Labour Market of Cyprus

Discussion comments on Immigration: trends and macroeconomic implications

The labor market in Spain,

Ministry of Economic Affairs and Communications ECONOMIC SURVEY OF ESTONIA 2009

GLOBALIZATION, DEVELOPMENT AND POVERTY REDUCTION: THEIR SOCIAL AND GENDER DIMENSIONS

TIEDI Labour Force Update December 2012

ECON 141 Ch. 2 Dr. Mohammed Alwosabi

PRI Working Paper Series No. 2

How s Life in Canada?

Results and Key Findings

POPULATION STUDIES RESEARCH BRIEF ISSUE Number

German Welfare Capitalism: Crisis and Transition By Roland Czada

Transcription:

Since the end of the financial crisis, salaries in Germany have increased significantly and real wages are rising faster than productivity. The buoyancy of the German labour market explains this shift in wage dynamics compared to previous trends. The unemployment rate is at a twenty-five year low and is forcing wages upwards. Following fifteen years of wage restraint, the change also reflects distribution of value-added that is more favourable for workers, especially in sectors exposed to international competition. The introduction of a minimum wage in Germany led to substantial wage hikes for the beneficiaries, although the aggregate impact on employment and wages appears mitigated in the short term. This wage momentum is helping rebalance competitiveness between euro area countries as German unit labour costs have been rising more rapidly than the euro area average since 2011. This increase has been insufficient to offset the differences in these costs seen in the euro area between 1995 and 2007, however, and has not led to a noteworthy reduction of the German current-account surplus. The strong German labour market and wage rises have helped bolster households purchasing power but, to date, have failed to halt the sharp increase in the poverty rate over the last fifteen years. Changes in unit labour costs in Germany and in the euro area excluding Germany 7% wage restraint crisis 2011-2015 6% 5% 4% 3% 2% 1% 0% -1% -2% -3% 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 EA excluding Germany Germany Source: Eurostat, 2015 annual accounts; DG Trésor calculations. Scope: Entire economy.

1. German wage dynamics has shifted since the crisis Prior to the financial crisis, Germany had a wage restraint policy in place. The goal was to restrict wage growth to tackle unemployment and boost competitiveness. The policy was adopted by the social partners during the mid-1990s 1 and was expanded by the Hartz reforms in the early 2000s. Since the end of the crisis, the growth rate of German per capita wages has more than doubled compared to average figures between 1995 and 2010 (see table 1). Average salaries have increased owing to the rise in hourly wages and the levelling off of per capita working hours, following the fall due to the strong surge in part-time work before the crisis. At the same time, apparent labour productivity has slowed considerably, causing an increase in the job content of growth. Overall, real wages are now rising faster than productivity. This sustained wage momentum marks a shift with the past which was tainted by fifteen years of low wage growth, and is contributing to the rise in German unit labour costs 2. Since 2011, these costs have been increasing faster than the European average and this is helping to gradually and partially realign cost competitiveness between Germany and its European partners. That said, the gap, that appeared as from 1995, between German unit labour costs and those of the remainder of the euro area, is still substantial (see chart 1). Table1: Wage indices Average annual growth rate 1995-2010* 2011-2015* Hourly wage 1.8% 3.0% Per capita average wages 1.2% 2.8% Per capita average real wages 0.1% 1.6% Per capita productivity 1.6% 0.3% Source: Destatis, Eurostat, 2015 annual accounts; DG Trésor calculations. Scope: Non-agricultural market sectors. * Average annual growth rate between 1995 and 2010 and between 2011 and 2015. NB: Per capita average wages are calculated as the ratio of the total payroll to the number of workers. Real wages are deflated by private consumption prices. 1 In addition, at the time of reunification, labour costs were much higher in East Germany owing to lower productivity. Subsequently, between 1991 and 1995, large productivity gains in the East closed the majority of this gap. In light of this, this paper focuses on the period starting in 1995. 2 Labour cost indicator showing the cost per unit of value-added produced. It represents the ratio of nominal wages to labour productivity. TRÉSOR-ECONOMICS No. 202 July 2017 p 2

Chart 1: Changes in unit labour costs in the euro area 155 145 135 125 115 105 95 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011 2013 2015 EA 19 countries EA excl. Germany Germany Spain France Italy Source: Eurostat, 2015 annual accounts; DG Trésor calculations. Scope: Entire economy; Base 100 = 1995. How to read this chart: The time spans set out throughout this paper cover three periods: (i) the wage restraint policy conducted between 1995 and 2007, (ii) the crisis during which productivity and nominal wages took a hit and then recovered, (iii) the post-crisis period as from 2011. 2. Rationale for this new wage momentum 2.1 Wage increases in favour of German workers are a reaction to the changes affecting the German labour market The structural reforms of the labour market during the noughties 3 helped reduce the unemployment rate without driving wages upwards. These reforms fostered a fall in structural unemployment, meaning the unemployment rate below which prices pick up, and an increase in labour market participation, which both enabled wage rises to be reined in. In the aftermath of the crisis, German economic growth and the increase in its job content allowed for strong job creation. According to the OECD, the actual unemployment rate may have fallen below the structural unemployment rate since 2011. Leading to signs of labour market tightness, such as the lack of skilled labour in a number of sectors, this fall has driven wages upwards (see chart 2). The reaction of wages to the situation on the labour market is thought to have been tempered by the flattening of the Phillips curve, however 4. Moreover, the recent increase of immigration in Germany, especially with the influx of refugees in 2015 and 2016, has led to a rise in the working-age population which could partly rein in the upward pressure on wages. 3 The Hartz reforms together with the gradual phasing out of early retirement options, see Bouvard F., Rambert L., Romanello L., Studer N. (2013), How have the Hartz reforms shaped the German labour market? Trésor-Economics no. 110. 4 The Phillips curve depicts the short-run trade-off between the unemployment gap (i.e. the distance between the actual and natural unemployment rates) and wage inflation. See Blanchard O., Cerutti E., Summers L. (2015), Inflation and Activity: Two Explorations and Their Monetary Policy Implications, NBER Working Paper. TRÉSOR-ECONOMICS No. 202 July 2017 p 3

Chart 2: Unemployment and the growth in real wages 3% 2% 1% 0% -1% % 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 Source: Destatis. Scope: Entire economy. -2% 13 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011 2013 2015 Per capita real wages (deflated by private consumption prices) Unemployment rate (inverted right-hand scale) 2.2 but they also show that the gap in growth rates for wages and productivity is narrowing The pre-crisis wage restraint policy helped businesses increase their margins by more than eight percentage points between 1995 and 2007 (see chart 3). This increase reflects a difference between changes to real wages from a corporate standpoint (deflated by value-added prices) and those affecting productivity, mainly in the tradable sector (see box). Chart 3: Margin rates of non-financial companies (% of value-added) 48 46 German reunification 44 42 40 38 36 34 Source: Destatis. Scope: Non-financial companies. 32 1991 1993 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011 2013 2015 TRÉSOR-ECONOMICS No. 202 July 2017 p 4

The gap has not closed since 2011 (see chart 4). The fresh growth in real wages (deflated by private consumption prices 5 ), reflecting the sharing of companies value-added which is now more favourable for workers, may be explained by the ability of German firms to cover these wage hikes, which has been bolstered by gains from lower oil prices since 2014. Margin rates have reverted to their 2002 levels and have been almost stable since 2012 following the sharp slump in the wake of the financial crisis and the euro area debt crisis. Chart 4: Changes in real wages and labour productivity 150 145 140 135 130 125 120 115 110 105 100 95 German reunification wage restraint crisis 2011-2015 90 1991 1993 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011 2013 2015 Per capita average super-gross wages deflated by value-added prices Per capita average wages deflated by private consumption prices Per capita productivity Source: Destatis, Eurostat, 2015 annual accounts; DG Trésor calculations. Scope: Non-agricultural market sectors; Base 100 = 1995. 5 Since 2011, wages deflated by value-added prices (from a corporate standpoint) have varied in line with productivity and have grown less than wages deflated by consumption prices (from a workers standpoint) due to different price dynamics. Businesses cost competitiveness gains from wage restraint policies are reflected in value-added prices (via production prices), and are then passed on to export prices to boost price competitiveness. Consumption prices are not affected by export prices but also reflect imported inflation. Overall, this establishes a difference between consumption prices and value-added prices. TRÉSOR-ECONOMICS No. 202 July 2017 p 5

Box : Different wage and productivity trends between businesses in the tradable sector and those in the non-tradable sector The growth in German firms margin rates up to 2007 was mostly due to the increase in the tradable sector 6, which is exposed to international competition and principally covers industry (accounting for around 45% of total value-added). As real wage hikes were less than those of productivity, there was a sharp fall in unit labour costs. In the non-tradable sector 7 (excluding real estate, financial and non-market services 8 ) which mainly covers the service industries, real wages varied in line with productivity and grew marginally prior to the crisis (allowing the tradable sector to profit from stable domestic input costs and to combine cost competitiveness and the high-end positioning of German industry). The fall in unit labour costs and the increase of margin rates have therefore been much less marked than in the tradable sector. Since 2011, productivity has levelled off in the tradable sector and has fallen in the non-tradable sector (see chart 5). Besides the global slowdown in productivity, there may be a number of explanations for this situation in Germany: (i) labour hoarding owing to its scarcity in the coming years, (ii) the continuing creation of low-productivity, especially part-time, positions, in the wake of the Hartz reforms, (iii) lack of skilled labour. At the same time, the recent wage rises in both sectors is spurring a sharp increase in unit labour costs. This represents a narrowing of the gap accumulated between productivity and wages in the tradable sector, as well as a fall in productivity gains in the non-tradable sector. Chart 5: Changes in real wages and productivity per worker in the tradable and non-tradable sectors (excluding real estate, finance and non-market industries) 160 150 140 130 120 110 100 90 80 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011 2013 2015 Productivity in the tradable sector Productivity in the non-tradable sector Per capita super-gross real wages in the tradable sector Per capita super-gross real wages in the non-tradable sector Source: Eurostat, 2015 annual accounts; DG Trésor calculations; Scope: Entire economy; Base 100 = 1995. NB: Real wages are deflated by value-added prices. 6 The tradable sector encompasses the following industries: agriculture, forestry and fishing; manufacturing, mining and other similar industries; transportation and storage services; information and communication services. 7 The non-tradable sector encompasses the following industries: construction; wholesale and retail trade services; repair services of motor vehicles and motorcycles; accommodation and food services; financial and insurance activities; real estate activities; scientific and technical services; administrative and support services; public administration, education services, human health and social work services; other services. 8 It is more difficult to examine productivity in the finance industry (owing to the provision of financial services being measured indirectly), the real estate industry (including owner-occupied imputed rents) and the non-market services (due to the conventional assessment of non-market value-added). TRÉSOR-ECONOMICS No. 202 July 2017 p 6

2.3 The minimum wage has led to substantial wage hikes for the beneficiaries, although the macroeconomic repercussions on wages and employment appear minimal for the time being In 2015, Germany introduced a minimum wage of 8.50 per hour ( 8.84 since 1 January 2017), which benefitted around 10.5% of the workforce (four million contracts according to Destatis 9 ). It is estimated that it concerns a quarter of small enterprises, a quarter of unskilled workers and is more prevalent in eastern Germany (almost one worker out of five compared to one out of ten in western Germany) and in certain sectors (agriculture, construction, retail, taxis, accommodation and food services). The minimum wage provided unskilled workers with a substantial short-term hourly wage hike of 7.9% in eastern Germany and 3.5% in western Germany 10. Their total salaries, and those of workers with mini job contracts, grew over one and a half times more (by more than 4%) than those of other workers. Hourly labour costs have risen in the most-concerned sectors, whether tradable (transport, mining) or non-tradable (retail, restaurants), and prices have jumped significantly (taxis, delivery of newspapers, restaurants). As regards employment, the existence of the minimum wage has led to a substantial reduction in working hours for its recipients (9% for full-time workers) 11, particularly in the most-concerned sectors (accommodation and restaurants). It has also made marginal employment less appealing 12 and brought about a fall in the number of mini jobs representing the main activity. According to the institute IAB 13, these have been replaced by standard part-time contracts. Nevertheless, despite noticeable effects in a number of sectors, for the time being, the macroeconomic repercussions are minimal. The increase in per capita average wages and changes to underlying prices have remained stable compared to last year. The labour market has continued to be buoyant although, according to initial microeconomic studies, the rise in wage employment may have slowed (according to the institute IAB, 60,000 additional jobs could have been created had the minimum wage not been introduced 14 ). Overall, the Minimum Wage Commission considers that preliminary estimates do not enable adverse effects on employment and labour costs to be clearly identified. 9 The scope covers seasonal workers, the majority of interns and people with mini job contracts. Apprentices, young people under 18, certain interns and the long-term unemployed are excluded and would represent 1.5 million additional contracts according to Destatis. 10 See Minimum Wage Commission (2016), First evaluation report to the Federal Government pursuant to section 9(4) of the Minimum Wage Act on the effects of the statutory minimum wage, June. 11 See Statistisches Bundesamt (2016a), 1,9 Millionen Jobs mit Mindestlohn im April 2015, Press release no. 227 of 29 June. 12 The introduction of the minimum wage implicitly limits mini job working hours (the maximum monthly salary is 450) and the hourly cost becomes more than for standard positions (due to higher employer contributions). 13 See Vom Berge P., Kaimer S., Copestake S., Eberle J., Klosterhuber W., Krüger J., Trenkle S., Zakrocki V. (2016), Arbeitsmarktspiegel. Entwicklungen nach Einführung des Mindestlohns, IAB Forschungsbericht, no. 1/2016. 14 See Bossler M., Gerner H.D. (2016), Employment effects of the new German minimum Wage, evidence from establishment-level micro data, IAB Discussion paper. TRÉSOR-ECONOMICS No. 202 July 2017 p 7

A number of factors can be put forward to explain the minimal short-term macroeconomic repercussions: (i) First, the impact on wages was mitigated by the staggered introduction of the minimum wage as a two-year derogation period was allowed for companies covered by sectoral agreements. Destatis estimates that only 1.9 million workers were receiving the minimum wage in April 2015. (ii) Second, as mentioned above, businesses altered working hours for low-wage contracts to offset the impact of the minimum wage on the total payroll and to remain under the maximum wage level for mini jobs 15. This helps explain the smaller rise in average wages compared to the increase in hourly salaries for the relevant workers. (iii) Concurrently, businesses are thought to have forestalled the introduction of the minimum wage by flattening pay scales to offset the impact on the total payroll. In 2014, the wage growth for unskilled workers contracted (+1.2% vs +4.3% for executives) whereas, in 2015, wage growth for the mostskilled workers was reined in (+2.8% for executives vs +4.1% for unskilled workers). (iv) Lastly, the impact is mitigated as most sectors now have a negotiated minimum wage of more than 10. As a result, at present, the increase in low wages brought about by the introduction of the minimum wage has not spread across the entire pay scale. On the contrary, the fact that minimum wage raises take place every two years 16 could lead to an uneven profile in wage rise as companies could limit wage increases for the year prior to the raise. While it is still early to measure the effect of the minimum wage, it does appear to have contributed, in the short term, to narrowing the wage gaps between the Länder in eastern and western Germany and between the most- and least-skilled workers. However, from a macroeconomic standpoint, it has not led to a rise in average wages in the short term. 3. Ramifications for the German economy 3.1 Support for German households purchasing power Since the end of the financial crisis, increases in German wages have buttressed households purchasing power following a long period of German growth mainly driven by external demand. Lower inflation due to the oil crisis in 2014 and 2015 has also heightened the impact of higher salaries on purchasing power and household consumption. The average growth of households real disposable income has almost doubled since 2011 compared to the average increase prior to the financial crisis. In addition, since 2013, private consumption has contributed more to growth than foreign trade. 15 Working hours may also be under-estimated, spurred by the fact that it may benefit the worker to remain under the mini job wage ceiling so that his/her net and gross salaries are the same. This would not be the case with a standard job (subject to social security contributions). 16 Unlike the French statutory minimum wage (Smic), the German minimum wage is not indexed yearly to inflation. Every two years, an independent commission is tasked with providing the government with a raise proposal (in June to take effect on the following 1 January) taking into account wage developments. In 2017, the proposal was based on changes in negotiated salaries since the introduction of the minimum wage eighteen months previously. TRÉSOR-ECONOMICS No. 202 July 2017 p 8

However, there is still a gap between wage and productivity levels, materialised by fairly weak domestic demand and an excess of corporate savings which has an adverse effect on demand for the goods and services of other European countries. Corporate margin rates have been at the same level since 2012 and companies financing capacity stood at 3.5% of GDP in 2015, higher than the euro area average (1.6% for the euro area excluding Germany in 2015). 3.2 At present, this partial realigning of labour costs does not appear to be weighing on German export figures Prior to the crisis, the fall in German unit labour costs led to cost competitiveness gains (see chart 6). Most of these gains were used to improve either price competitiveness, via a reduction of German export prices compared to foreign export prices, or margins. At present, despite having increased faster than the European average over the last four years, German unit labour costs are only 17% higher than their 1995 level whilst those in the euro area have risen by 30%. Moreover, although there has been a slight dip in cost competitiveness, price competitiveness has remained almost stable owing to falling margins. German businesses still have excellent export performance levels and are continuing to generate a substantial balance of trade surplus. Chart 6: German cost competitiveness and price competitiveness 140 German reunification 130 120 110 100 90 80 1991 1993 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011 2013 2015 Price competitiveness Cost competitiveness Margin squeezing Source : OECD; DG Trésor calculations. Scope: Entire economy; Base 100 = Q1 1995. How to read this chart: A rise in competitiveness indicators reflects an improvement in Germany s position vis-à-vis its competitors. Price competitiveness is the ratio of foreign export prices to domestic export prices. Cost competitiveness is the ratio of foreign unit labour costs (ULCs) to domestic ULCs. Margin squeezing is the ratio of price competitiveness to cost competitiveness. As a result, improved cost competitiveness leads to either improved price competitiveness, or improved margins (less margin squeezing). TRÉSOR-ECONOMICS No. 202 July 2017 p 9

3.3 Toward less poverty? The fall in unemployment in Germany during the noughties did not lead to a corresponding reduction of the poverty rate. Conversely, the poverty rate 17 for the entire population jumped by more than five percentage points between 2000 and 2008. This was due to the combined effect of the growth of lowpaid jobs, with wages below the poverty line, and weakened redistribution (tightening of unemployment benefit conditions). This is in stark contrast to France where the poverty rate is lower 18 and has been stable over the last decade (see chart 7). The structural labour market reforms in the noughties enabled unemployed or inactive people to get back to work. That said, the upward mobility of low-wage workers has decreased 19. Since the crisis, the poverty rate for the entire population has remained stable despite the strong performance of the German labour market and the recent wage momentum. Due to the prevalence of low wages, the gap between the first and last income deciles is now one of the widest in Europe (3.9 compared to 2.9 in France). This meant that, in 2015, the proportion of workers aged over 18 (employed and self-employed) at risk of poverty after social transfers was 9.7% as against 7.5% in France. The renewed wage momentum and the introduction of the minimum wage, in favour of the least-skilled workers, should help smooth out some of the imbalances and therefore help reduce the number of working poor. The overall impact will nevertheless be contingent on the number of hours worked and the allocation of increases in the wage distribution scale. In addition, following the major influx of asylum seekers in 2015 and 2016, the gradual integration of mostly unskilled refugees in the labour market constitutes a further challenge for the German authorities as regards training. 17 The poverty rate is the number of people whose standard of living (disposable income after social transfers, adjusted for household size) is below the poverty line which is set at 60% of the median domestic standard of living. 18 This is not inconsistent with the similarities between France and Germany identified by the Gini index for income inequality after redistribution. The index documents inequality throughout the income distribution chain whereas the poverty rate index focuses on the lowest incomes. 19 See Kappeler A. and Fuentes Hutfilter A. (2014), Making economic growth more socially inclusive in Germany, OECD Economics Department Working Papers, no. 1175. TRÉSOR-ECONOMICS No. 202 July 2017 p 10

Chart 7: Poverty rate after social transfers (% of the total population) 20 18 16 14 12 10 8 6 4 2 Source: Eurostat. 0 2000 2005 2008 2013 2014 2015 Germany European Union Euro area France Diane de Waziers TRÉSOR-ECONOMICS No. 202 July 2017 p 11

TRÉSOR-ECONOMICS No. 202 July 2017 p 12